Skip to main content

Full text of "Social Institutions"

See other formats


THE  BOOK  WAS 
DRENCHED 


OU_158631>5 


SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 


PRENTICE-HALL  SOCIOLOGY  SERIES 
edited  by  Herbert  Blumer 


SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

In  An  Era  of  NVorld  Upheaval 

by 
HARRY  ELMER  BARNES 


New  York 

PRENTICE-HALL,  INC. 
1942 


COPYRIGHT,  1942,  BY 
PRENTICE-HALL,  INC. 

70  Fifth  Avenue,  New  York 

ALL  RIGHTS  RESERVED.      NO  PART  OF  THIS  BOOK  MAY  BE  REPRO- 
DUCED IN  ANY  FORM,  BY  MIMEOGRAPH  OR  ANY  OTHER  MEANS, 
WITHOUT  PERMISSION   IN  WRITINfi  PROM   THR  PTIHLTSHRRS. 


PRINTED  IN  THE  UNITED  STATES  OF  AMERICA 


To 
FRANK  HAMILTON  HANKINS 


Preface 


THIS  book  attempts  to  describe  and  appraise  our  institutional  equip- 
ment in  a  period  of  far-reaching  and  unpredictable  social  change.  We 
are  now  in  the  midst  of  a  great  world-revolution,  comparable  only  to 
the  dawn  of  history,  the  breakup  of  ancient  pagan  civilization  in  the 
later  Roman  Empire,  and  the  disintegration  of  medieval  culture  in 
the  fifteenth  and  sixteenth  centuries.  Ours  is  an  even  more  critical  period 
of  cultural  transformation  because  the  tempo  is  far  swifter  than  in  any 
earlier  era  of  change  and  because  the  problems  of  control  and  adjustment 
involved  are  infinitely  more  complex  than  they  were  in  simpler  agrarian 
and  provincial  epochs. 

The  chief  reason  why  we  find  ourselves  encompassed  by  world-shaking 
changes  is  that  our  material  culture — our  science  and  technology — has 
moved  ahead  much  more  rapidly  than  the  social  institutions  through 
which  we  seek  to  control  and  utilize  our  mechanical  facilities.  In  an  era 
of  •  dynamos,  transoceanic  clippers,  radios,  television,  and  automatic 
machines  we  still  rely  on  institutions  which  had  reached  maturity  in 
the  days  of  Abraham  Lincoln — many  of  them  at  the  time  of  George 
Washington.  The  social  thinking  and  institutions  of  the  stagecoach  era 
have  signally  failed  to  sustain  a  society  which  boasts  stratosphere  air- 
liners. 

Classical  culture  fell  because  Greek  and  Roman  ideas  and  institutions 
— Utopian  philosophy  and  imperial  politics — got  ahead  of  the  limited 
technology,  especially  in  the  realm  of  transportation.  Our  culture,  on 
the  other  hand,  is  gravely  threatened  because  our  machines  have  moved 
far  beyond  our  social  thinking  and  institutional  patterns.  We  shall 
never  enjoy  any  assurance  of  personal  security  or  international  peace 
until  our  institutions  catch  up  with  our  unprecedentedly  rich  and  diver- 
sified material  culture. 

Since  the  backward  state  of  our  institutional  heritage  is  the  outstand- 
ing cause  of  the  present  sorry  state  of  the  civilized  world,  no  realistic 
writer  can  very  well  be  expected  to  present  a  eulogistic  or  optimistic 
appraisal  of  social  institutions  in  our  day.  He  may  well  pay  .tribute  to 
any  actual  virtues  in  our  institutional  setup,  but  he  should  also  be 
frank  and  candid  in  revealing  the  obvious  anachronisms  and  defects* 
There  is  no  possibility  of  achieving  essential  institutional  reforms  until 
we  have  come  to  recognize  the  need  for  such  improvement.  The,  realistic 
assessment  of  our  institutions  set  forth  in  the  pages  of  this  book  is  not 
offered  in  a  mood  of  carping  criticism  but  as  the  indispensable  forerum^r 
of  changes  that  must  be  made  if  we  are  to  retain  our  freedom  and  bring 


viii  PREFACE 

about  security  and  peace  for  the  mass  of  mankind.  We  cannot  logically 
expect  people  to  support  reform  unless  they  are  made  aware  that  reform 
is  necessary. 

The  real  friends  of  our  American  way  of  life  are  those  who  recognize 
and  fearlessly  reveal  the  obvious  danger  signals  that  are  evident  on 
every  side,  and  who  seek  to  eliminate  the  threats  to  our  social  order 
while  there  is  yet  time  and  opportunity.  The  most  dangerous  enemies 
we  have  are  not  the  "crackpots"  who  peddle  cheap  and  naive  panaceas. 
Such  persons  at  least  recognize  that  something  is  wrong,  though  their 
remedy  may  be  as  bad  or  worse  than  the  malady  itself.  The  real  menace 
to  our  civilization  is  to  be  found  in  those  who  insist  on  living  in  a  "fools' 
paradise"  of  smug  conceit  and  complacency,  conducting  a  sort  of  "sit- 
down  strike"  against  intelligence,  and  insisting  that  nothing  is  wrong 
in  this  best  of  all  possible  worlds.  Such  adamant  smugness  inevitably 
charts  the  course  of  society  from  decadence,  through  dry  rot,  to  crisis 
and  totalitarianism. 

Never  was  candor  more  needed  than  in  a  period  of  war  and  readjust- 
ment. Our  leaders  have  proclaimed  that  they  hate  war  and  despise 
it  as  a  system  of  international  policy,  even  if  we  currently  have  to 
fight  to  assure  a  less  unstable  and  less  warlike  world  in  the  future.  To 
eulogize  war,  in  itself,  as  a  noble  human  experience  is  to  lock  arms 
ideologically  with  Hitler  and  the  Black  Dragon  minions  of  the  Mikado, 
and  to  concede  by  implication  that  they  are  right  in  their  bellicose 
philosophy.  The  exigencies  of  wartime  doubtless  require  a  rigor  in 
social  control  exceeding  that  which  will  suffice  for  peaceful  days.  But 
we  should  make  sure  that  emergency  measures  are  limited  to  the  emer- 
gency and  are  not  greater  than  the  emergency  requires.  There  is  little 
to  be  gained  in  carrying  the  Four  Freedoms  to  the  Antipodes  if  we 
surrender  them  indefinitely  in  our  own  country.  Never  will  informed 
intelligence  be  more  essential  than  in  the  difficult  period  of  post-war 
readjustment.  It  will  be  a  poor  preparation  for  that  critical  era  if  we 
are  forced  to  "park"  our  mentalities  for  the  duration.  Cerebration  is 
not  something  which  can  be  put  in  mothballs  and  withdrawn  at  will. 

Since  it  is  quite  impossible  to  understand  the  nature  and  current 
problems  of  any  social  institution  without  a  full  knowledge  of  its  evolu- 
tion in  the  past,  much  attention  is  given  to  the  history  of  each  of  the 
institutions  discussed  in  this  book.  It  is  hoped  that  this  historical  back- 
ground will  not  only  clarify  understanding  but  will  also  promote  greater 
tolerance  and  more  constructive  thinking.  5ft)thing  else  is  so  conducive  to 
urbanity  and  open-mindedness  as  historical  studies,  and  no  other  subject 
so  completely  demands  these  qualities  and  attitudes  as  does  the  study 
of  social  institutions.  It  can  safely  be  said  that  no  other  book  of  its 
kind  in  any  language  provides  so  ample  an  historical  background  for 
the  appraisal  of  our  institutional  problems  and  readjustments. 

This  book,  like  all  scientific  historical  and  sociological  works,  is  com- 
mitted to  the  thesis  of  cultural  determinism.  Yet  it  does  not  go  to  the 
Billy  extreme  of  ignoring  personal  agents  in  the  social  process.  Capi- 


PREFACE  ix 

talism,  for  example,  does  not  operate  in  a  void  without  personal 
capitalists,  nor  does  party  government  function  without  politicians.  But 
our  criticisms  and  condemnations,  if  any,  are  directed  against  institutions 
rather  than  the  individuals  who  merely  reflect  and  execute  these  insti- 
tutional trends.  However  blameworthy  a  speculating  utility  magnate, 
a  corrupt  politician,  a  racketeer,  or  a  venal  propagandist  may  be,  he  is 
a  creature  of  his  time  and  folkways.  It  will  do  little  good  to  denounce 
or  punish  him  unless  we  also  proceed  to  alter  the  institutional  patterns 
which  produce  such  types. 

At  th^  outset  we  seek  to  make  clear  how  institutions  arise  from  the 
need  for  group  discipline,  which  enables  man  to  exploit  the  all-essential 
advantages  of  cooperative  effort.  We  show  how  the  efficiency  of  insti- 
tutions is  directly  related  to  their  ability  to  serve  the  needs  of  a 
particular  type  of  culture  at  any  given  time.  When  they  get  out  of 
adjustment  with  the  material  basis  of  life,  they  decline  in  efficiency  and 
often  prove  an  obstruction  to  social  well-being.  Such  is  the  situation 
in  our  day,  when  cultural  lag,  or  the  gulf  between  our  musty  and  decadent 
institutions  and  our  dynamic  technology,  is  the  outstanding  cause  of  our 
social  problems  and  perplexities. 

Next,  we  turn  to  the  leading  economic  institutions  of  our  time — 
industry,  capitalism,  and  property.  The  contributions  which  these  have 
made  to  human  progress  and  prosperity  are  fully  recognized,  while  their 
current  deficiencies  are  frankly  indicated,  in  the  hope  that  the  reforms 
required  may  be  made  before  the  system  collapses  and  collectivism  inter- 
venes to  apply  drastic  measures  of  rehabilitation.  Society  cannot  well 
tolerate  indefinitely  the  spectacle  of  mass  starvation  and  deprivation 
in  the  midst  of  potential  plenty. 

Our  treatment  of  political  institutions  revolves  about  the  crisis  in 
democracy  and  liberty  in  our  time.  The  present  framework  of  our 
democratic  government  is  supplied  by  the  national  state  and  constitu- 
tional government.  The  national  state  has  grown  overburdened  and 
top-heavy  as  a  result  of  the  increasing  variety  and  complexity  of  the 
problems  with  which  government  has  to  deal,  and  it  maintains  a  potent 
bellicosity  which  holds  over  mankind  a  perpetual  threat  of  war.  Con- 
stitutions, instead  of  being  regarded  as  the  means  to  the  end  of  orderly 
and  efficient  government,  all  too  frequently  become  ends  in  themselves. 
This  situation  creates  an  air  of  awe  and  reverence  which  handicaps  all 
efforts  to  adjust  our  governmental  machinery  to  the  changing  needs  of 
a  dynamic  society. 

Political  parties  provide  the  technique  of  representative  government 
and  democracy,  but  they  have  a  proclivity  to  develop  corrupt  and  un- 
democratic trends  and  to  foster  inefficiency  in  governmental  action. 
Party  government  is  remarkably  proficient  in  producing  politicians, 
namely,  men  who  are  experts  in  getting  elected  and  preparing  to  get 
reflected.  But  it  is  lamentably  inefficient  and  defective  in -providing 
us  with  statesmen,  namely,  officials  who  know  what  to  do  after  they 
are  elected. 


x  PREFACE 

Our  traditional  democracy  was  formulated  and  introduced  in  a  simple, 
agrarian  culture,  with  few  political  problems  and  in  an  era  when  little 
scientific  knowledge  was  available  about  man  and  society.  It  was 
inevitable  that  such  a  system  of  government  would  be  unsuited  to  exer- 
cise political  control  over  an  urban,  industrial  world-civilization.  Unless 
this  fact  is  speedily  recognized  and  the  older  democracy  is  revamped  in 
harmony  with  the  social  realities  of  our  day  and  in  accord  with  the 
teachings  of  social  science,  there  is  little  prospect  that  democratic  govern- 
ment can  be  sustained.  The  true  friends  of  democracy,  then,  are  those 
who  recognize  this  challenging  fact  and  seek  to  reconstruct  democratic 
government  while  there  is  an  opportunity  to  do  so.  Those  who  stub- 
bornly defend  archaic  policies  and  practices  are  the  best  friends  of  the 
totalitarianism  which  eagerly  waits  "just  around  the  corner."  Huey 
Long  may  well  have  had  a  brilliant  "hunch"  when  he  suggested  that 
Fascism  is  likely  to  come  to  America  in  the  name  of  democracy.  Most 
of  the  really  dangerous  proto-Fascist  organizations  in  our  country  flaunt 
the  word  "democracy"  or  "freedom"  in  their  official  titles. 

Since  liberty  is  one  of  our  main  advantages  and  prizes,  as  over  against 
the  totalitarian  way  of  life,  it  is  especially  important  that  we  pay 
attention  to  the  current  crisis  in  liberty.  Our  civil  liberties  were  won 
and  catalogued  back  in  the  seventeenth  century,  and  we  have  done 
lamentably  little  to  extend  and  buttress  them  since  that  era.  The 
middle  class  or  bourgeoisie  which  fought  for  them  and  triumphed  is 
now  being  challenged,  and  its  long  ascendency  over  society  is  passing 
away.  Bureaucracy,  begotten  of  the  need  for  ever  greater  governmental 
intervention,  is  not  too  solicitous  of  liberty.  Crisis  government  can 
rarely  be  a  libertarian  government.  Never  was  it  more  true  that  we 
need  to  exercise  that  "eternal  vigilance"  which  is  the  price  of  an  assured 
liberty. 

In  our  chapters  on  law  we  condense  and  summarize  the  indictment  of 
our  current  legal  ideas  and  practices  which  have  been  put  forward  in 
recent  years  by  progressive  lawyers.  It  is  high  time  that  such  reforms 
be  executed  as  will  render  unsupportable  the  frequent  quip  that  law  has 
no  relation  to  justice  or  that  lawyers  make  more  litigation  than  they 
settle.  Denial  of  justice  invites  revolt,  and  there  is  little  "rule  of 
law"  in  revolutionary  or  totalitarian  regimes.  Legal  reforms  are  as 
much  a  matter  of  self-interest  on  the  part  of  the  legal  profession  as 
they  are  a  concern  of  society  at  large. 

Nothing  is  more  novel  in  our  age  thanlfee  amazing  agencies  for  the 
communication  of  information  and  the  many  devices  for  the  molding 
of  public  opinion.  Though  propaganda  is  as  old  as  histo'ry — probably 
older  than  a  written  language — the  techniques  now  employed  in  propa- 
ganda are  far  different  from  what  they  were  in  an  era  before  the  daily 
newspaper,  the  radio,  and  the  moving  pictures.  In  a  democratic  society 
we  are  especially  dependent  upon  accurate  mass  information.  Misin- 
formation and  deliberate  distortion  by  our  agencies  of  communication 
imperil  free  government  and  liberal  institutions.  The  main  safeguard 


PREFACE  xi 

of  a  liberal  democracy  is  full  public  knowledge  of  the  devices  and 
methods  of  propaganda,  so  that  the  citizenry  may  be  both  informed  and 
forewarned.  Censorship  is  the  first  step  on  the  road  to  totalitarian 
suppression  of  ideas.  We  must  be  on  our  guard  against  unnecessary 
invasions  of  liberty  and  the  denial  of  freedom  of  expression.  Censorship 
is  the  indispensable  tool  of  the  dictator. 

In  the  section  on  the  family  and  community  we  describe  those  changes 
in  society  and  culture  which  have  undermined  the  old  rural  family  life 
and  its  associated  practices  and  have  disrupted  most  other  primary 
institutions.  Suggestions  are  offered  as  to  how  the  family  might  be 
firmly  reconstructed  in  accord  with  our  new  modes  of  living  arid  could 
be  made  to  serve  our  age  as  well  as  the  traditional  rural  family  of  yore 
met  the  needs  of  a  simpler  life.  New  forms  of  community  organization 
are  slowly  arising  to  take  over  the  tasks  formerly  executed  by  leading 
primary  groups  such  as  the  neighborhood,  the  play  group,  and  the  like. 

Finally,  we  treat  those  institutions  which  promote  richer  living  among 
men.  The  origins  of  religion  are  surveyed,  its  antiquities  revealed,  and 
its  potential  services  to  contemporary  society  clearly  indicated.  Educa- 
tion is  presented  as  the  chief  hope  that  we  have  of  guiding  society  along 
the  path  of  progress  through  planned  and  orderly  change  rather  than  by 
revolution  and  violence.  But  education  cannot  perform  this  indis- 
pensable service  unless  it  recognizes  its  responsibilities  and  adopts  the 
attitudes  and  techniques  which  these  responsibilities  logically  impose. 
Quietism  and  timidity  in  education  only  lay  the  ground  for  the  agitator 
and  the  revolutionist.  More  complete  and  more  realistic  instruction 
in  the  social  sciences  is  obligatory,  if  education  is  to  aid  in  preserving 
the  democratic  way  of  life. 

Our  machines  have  provided  us  with  a  potential  age  of  security  and 
leisure.  Either  we  shall  realize  this  "dream  of  the  ages"  through  sub- 
duing machines  to  human  service  or  they  will  tear  our  culture  asunder 
and  there  will  be  neither  leisure  nor  abundance.  If  civilization  survives, 
the  main  task  of  the  future  will  be  the  conquest  of  leisure,  thus  supplant- 
ing the  chief  problem  of  the  past,  which  has  been  the  procurement  of 
subsistence  through  long  hours  of  toil.  Recreation  and  art  may  provide 
us  with  two  of  the  most  hopeful  modes  of  leisure-time  expression,  but 
we  are  as  yet  only  on  the  borderline  of  an  adequate  development  of 
either  of  them  as  a  phase  of  the  daily  life  of  man. 

We  stand  at  one  of  the  great  turning  points  in  the  history  of  human 
civilization.  Whether  we  will  move  ahead  to  security,  peace,  and  a 
life  worthy  of  human  beings  or  will  revert  to  barbarism  through  con- 
tinued misuse  of  our  unique  opportunities  and  facilities,  depends  upon 
our  ability  to  modernize  our  institutional  patterns.  If  this  book  helps 
in  some  slight  degree  in  promoting  institutional  reconstruction  it  will 
have  served  its  purpose. 

HARRY  ELMER  BARNES 

Cooperstown,  N.  Y. 
July  21,  1942 


Table  of  Contents 


PABT  I 

THE  FOUNDATION  AND  FRAMEWORK  OF 
SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

PAGES 

I.  T^HEj^                                                                   .............  3 

»   The  Need  and  Purpose  of  Social  Organization  .............  3 

•  The  Historical  Development  of  the  Forms  of  Social  Organization  5 

•  Types  of  Social  Bonds   ...................................  7 

The  Leading  Forms  of  Social  Groups  .......................  10 

Primary  Groups  and  the  "We"  Group    ....................  13 

Society,  Community,  and  Associations   .....................  15 

The  Value  and  Contributions  of  Social  Organization   .......  16 

The  Modes  of  Group  Activity  and  Social  Control   .........  18 

Society  and  the  Social  Organism  ...........................  19 

II.  A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS  ...................  22 

Basic  Human  Drives    ....................................  22 

The  Human  Needs  That  Arise  from  the  Basic  Drives  .......  23 

Some  Outstanding  Human  Activities  and  Interests  That  Grow 

Out  of  Basic  Human  Needs   ...........................  24 

*—•  Social    Institutions:    the    Machinery    through   Which    Society 

Carries  On  Its  Activities  ...............................  29 

.Primary  and  Secondary  Institutions   .......................  31 

Institutions  and  Social  Efficiency   ..........................  35 

Evolution  of  Social  Institutions  ........................  38 


III.  CULTURAL  LAG  AND  THE  CRISIS  IN  INSTITUTIONAL  LIFE  ...  48 

The  Transitional  Character  of  Our  Era  ....................  48 

How  the  Gulf  between  Machines  and  Institutions  Came  About  52 
Some  Social  and  Cultural  Implications  of  the  Gulf  between 

Machines  and  Institutions   .............................  55 

The  Institutional  Lag  in  Contemporary  Culture  .............  58 

Are  We  Living  in  a  Scientific  Age?  .........................  63 


xiii 


xiv  TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 

PART  II 
ECONOMIC  INSTITUTIONS  IN  AN  ERA  OF  WORLD  CRISIS 

CHAPTER  PAGE 

IV.  SOME  PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION  OF  INDUSTRY 66 

Some  Suggested  Stages  of  Industrial  Evolution 66 

Outstanding  Aspects  of  the  Evolution  of  Agriculture   69 

Outstanding  Trends  in  the  Evolution  of  Manufacturing   ....  85 

Leading  Periods  in  the  Development  of  Trade  and  Commerce  98 

Leading  Forms  of  Control  Over  Industry    103 

The  Motives  of  Industrial  Effort   Ill 

V.  CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS  113 

*The  Fundamental  Nature  of  Economic  Problems   113 

The  Historical  Background  and  Rise  of  Capitalism 115 

The  Ascendency  of  Finance  Capitalism  125 

Some  Defects  in  the  System  of  Finance  Capitalism 127 

Industrial  Capitalism,  Industrial  Waste,  and  Inadequate  Mass 

Purchasing  Power : . .  137 

Is  Capitalism  Worth  Saving?    146 

Some  Problems  of  Capital  and  Labor 149 

The  Problem  of  Industrial  Unemployment 153 

Old  Age  as  an  Industrial  and  Social  Problem 156 

The  Outlook  for  Capitalism  in  the  United  States 158 

VI.  THE  INSTITUTION  OF  PROPERTY  IN  THE  LIGHT  OF  SOCIOLOGY 

AND  HISTORY   160 

Basic  Definitions  and  Concepts  160 

Some  Psychological  Foundations  of  Property   164 

Property  Drives  in  the  Light  of  Psychology,  Ethnology,  and 

Sociology    165 

Some  Outstanding  Phases  of  the  History  of  Property 168 

The  Inheritance  of  Property  185 

The  Social  Justification  of  Property  and  Property  Rights  ....  189 

Some  Outstanding  Abuses  of  Property   195 

Some  Major  Inroads  on  Private  Property  Today  197 

The  Future  of  Private  Property   198 

PART  III 

POLITICAL  AND  LEGAL  INSTITUTIONS  IN  TRANSITION 
VII.  THE  FRAMEWORK  OF  DEMOCRACY:   THE  NATIONAL  STATE 

AND    CONTITUTIONAL    GOVERNMENT     200 

An  Outline  of  the  History  of  Nationalism  200 

Nationalism,  State  Activity,  and  the  Growing  Complexity  of 

Political  Problems    217 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS  xv 

CHAPTER  PAGE 
VII.  THE  FRAMEWORK  OF  DEMOCRACY:    THE  NATIONAL   STATE 
AND  CONSTITUTIONAL  GOVERNMENT  (Cont.) : 

/'Nationalism,  Patriotism,  and  War  Psychology 219 

The  Rise  of  Constitutional  Government  and  the  Ascendency  of 

Republics    221 

VIII.  THE  TECHNIQUE  OF  DEMOCRACY:   POLITICAL  PARTIES  AND 

PARTY  GOVERNMENT 229 

The  Role  of  Political  Parties  in  Modern  Government  229 

The  Rise  of  Party  Government   232 

Outstanding  Problems  of  Party  Government     239 

Corruption  and  Extravagance  Under  Party  Government   ....  248 

Reform  Measures  and  Their  Fate   259 

IX.  THE  CRISIS  IN  AMERICAN  DEMOCRACY  AND  THE  CHALLENGE 

TO  LIBERTY     268 

A  Brief  History  of  Democracy    268 

Some  Major  Assumptions  of  Democracy  in  the  Light  of  Their 

Historical  Background    274 

Democracy  Put  to  the  Test   278 

Democracy  and  the  Political  Future    287 

The  Struggle  for  Civil  Liberties  290 

X.  WAR  As  A  SOCIAL  INSTITUTION  309 

How  War  Complicates  Social  Problems   309 

Outstanding  Phases  of  the  Evolution  of  Warfare f  .  .  310 

The  Underlying  Causes  of  War  in  Contemporary  Society  ....  326 

The  Impact  of  War  on  Society  and  Culture   339 

Prelude  to  the  Second  World  War 345 

The  Social  Revolution  Behind  the  Second  World  War  348 

XI.  LAW  AND  JUSTICE  As  A  SOCIAL  PROBLEM   353 

Our  Lawyer-made  Civilization    353 

Leading  Stages  in  the  Evolution  of  Law  355 

Modern  Theories  and  Schools  of  Law 370 

Current  Criticisms  of  Our  Legal  Institutions  and  Practices  ....  372 

Defects  in  the  Current  System  of  Law  377 

Problems  Arising  Out  of  Law-making  381 

XII.  LAW  IN  ACTION  AND  PROBLEMS  OF  LEGAL  PROCEDURE 392 

Law  in  the  Courtroom   392 

Natural  Law,  Constitutional  Law,  and  the  Protection  of  Property  406 

Corporation  Law  and  Commercialized  Legal  Practice  417 

Activities  and  Methods  of  Rank-and-File  Lawyers  425 

Some  Outstanding  Defects  in  the  Criminal  Law  432 

The  Travesty  of  the  Jury  Trial   437 

Suggested  Reforms  in  Legal  Practice  and  Courtroom  Procedure  442 


xviii  TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 

CHAPTER  PAGE 
XIX.  LEISURE,  RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS  (Cont.)  : 

Landmarks  in  the  Development  of  Art  .....................  839 

The  Growth  of  Art  in  the  United  States  ....................  844 

Trends  in  Contemporary  American  Art  ....................  850 

The  New  Deal  Art  Projects  ................................  856 

OF  '  OURllTUTIONAL  CRISIS    ......  862 


SELECTED  REFERENCES   .......................................     881 

INDEX  ......................................................     915 


PART  I 

The  Foundation  and  Framework  of 
Social  Institutions 


CHAPTER   I 

The  Foundations  of  Social  Institutions 

The  Need  and  Purpose  of  Social  Organization 

VIEWED  solely  as  an  animal,  man  is  markedly  inferior  to  many  other 
members  of  the  animal  kingdom.  He  lacks  the  strength  of  the  bear  or 
the  elephant,  the  speed  of  the  leopard  or  the  antelope,  the  eyesight  of  the 
hawk  or  the  eagle,  the  ferocity  of  the  tiger,  the  scent  of  the  bloodhound, 
or  the  endurance  of  the  ox.  He  has  also  been  unable  entirely  to  offset 
the  biologically  disastrous  effects  of  adjusting  himself  to  locomotion  on 
his  hind  legs. 

Man  has  been  compelled  to  compensate  for  his  physical  weakness  by 
cooperative  social  endeavor  with  his  kind.  The  individual  man  in  a 
primitive  state  was  no  match  for  the  cave  bear,  but  through  organiza- 
tion and  cooperative  activity  he  has  been  able  to  overcome  all  other 
members  of  the  animal  kingdom.  Today,  our  modern  firearms,  which 
are  the  product  of  centuries  of  cooperative  effort,  enable  man,  single- 
handed,  to  conquer  the  most  powerful  beasts  remaining  on  the  planet. 
The  creation  of  an  articulate  language  has  enabled  him  to  put  his  culture 
on  a  verbal  or  symbolic  basis,  thus  making  possible  the  development  of 
consciously  created  forms  of  culture  and  institutions.1 

Another  important  reason  for  social  organization  is  the  fact  that  man 
is  by  nature  a  "social  being,"  as  Aristotle  once  called  him.  Since  mem- 
bers of  the  human  race  naturally  and  spontaneously  assemble,  it  became 
necessary,  even  in  small  and  primitive  groups,  to  create  some  rules  to 
guide  the  process  of  living  together.  These  rules  were*  not  at  first  the 
product  of  any  deliberate  plan.  Men  automatically  came  together, 
struggled  for  livelihood,  and  cooperated  for  defense.  In  the  process,  they 
created  social  habits,  institutions,  classes,  and  purposive  groups;  and  in 
time  complex  social  organization  was  built  up.  Social  organization  was 
and  is  both  inevitable  and  indispensable. 

Social  organization  may  seem  a  vague  and  forbidding  term,  and  the 
treatment  of  the  subject  by  some  sociologists  has  been  made  terrifyingly 
complex  and  difficult.  But  it  is  easy  enough  to  visualize  what  we  mean 


i  See  L.  A.  White,  "The  Symbol :  The  Origin  and  Basis  of  Human  Behavior,"  in 
The  Philosophy  of  Science,  Williams  &  Wilkins  Co.,  October,  1940,  pp.  451  ff. 

3 


4      THE   FOUNDATIONS  OF  SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS 

by  social  organization  if  we  but  look  about  ourselves  in  twentieth-century 
society. 

We  see  very  few  persons  wandering  about  aimlessly,  indulging  in 
strictly  individualized  musings  and  day-dreaming,  oblivious  to  what  is 
going  on  in  the  world  about  them.  The  great  majority  of  people  are 
actively  engaged  in  forms  of  behavior  in  which  their  actions  are  joined 
to  the  efforts  of  others.  We  find  members  of  families  which  provide  for 
the  daily  life  of  most  human  beings.  We  see  schools,  churches,  art 
museums,  courthouses,  and  the  like,  where  men  cooperate  to  teach  chil- 
dren, worship  God,  view  the  great  artistic  achievements  of  the  past,  and 
enforce  the  laws  of  the  land  that  protect  life  and  property.  Great  fac- 
tories pour  out  their  clouds  of  smoke  to  carry  on  those  industrial  enter- 
prises which  supply  our  material  needs.  Railroads  carry  their  products 
all  over  the  country,  along  with  a  large  and  varied  human  cargo.  Police 
direct  traffic  and  arrest  violators  of  the  law.  Bands  of  soldiers  may  pass, 
reminding  us  of  the  united  power  of  the  government  and  of  wars. 
Crowds  hurrying  to  stadiums  to  witness  football  games  emphasize  our 
commercialized  sports  and  organized  recreation.  The  radio  and  the 
movies  bring  before  us  the  thoughts  and  deeds  of  man  all  over  the  earth 
and  provide  us  with  entertainment.  Stately  banks  and  palatial  homes 
call  our  attention  to  the  existence  of  wealth  and  property.  All  these 
everyday  situations  attest  the  extent  and  variety  of  the  social  organi- 
zation which  man  has  brought  into  being  to  make  human  life  more 
efficient  and  pleasant. 

When  we  speak  of  social  organization  we  mean  both  the  efforts  of  men 
to  accomplish  certain  purposes — usually  the  satisfaction  of  vital  human 
needs — and  the  social  groups  and  structures  that  result  from  such  efforts. 
In  other  words,  social  organization  has  both  a  functional  and  a  structural 
import.  In  a  functional  sense,  it  manifests  the  collective  activities  of 
mankind  to  achieve  certain  desirable  ends,  from  raising  children  to  dis- 
tributing goods  and  fighting  wars.  Out  of  such  functional  efforts  arise 
groups  which  carry  on  these  activities,  such  as  the  family,  the  corpora- 
tion, the  state,  and  the  like.  In  any  comprehensive  view,  social  organi- 
zation, in  its  structural  implications,  includes  the  structure  of  social 
groups,  the  general  structure  of  the  prevailing  culture  of  mankind  at  any 
time  and  place,  and  the  whole  framework  of  social  institutions.  What 
all  this  involves  will  become  clearer  in  the  course  of  this  and  the  next 
chapter.  The  full  import  and  extent  of  social  organization  can  be 
grasped  only  when  we  keep  in  mind  both  the  functional  activities  to 
achieve  social  goals  and  the  structural  outgrowth  of  such  social  efforts. 

When  we  say  that  social  organization,  in  a  functional  sense,  is  an 
effort  to  achieve  certain  results,  it  would  seem  to  imply  that  all  social 
organization  is  the  outgrowth  of  deliberate  effort  and  conscious  thought. 
Much  of  it  is  such,  especially  in  the  higher  forms  of  social  organization 
and  the  more  advanced  cultures,  but  there  is  a  considerable  portion  of 
social  organization  which  is  natural,  spontaneous  and  unconscious.  The 
family,  which  ia  the  basic  form  of  social  organization,  grows  out  of  such 


THE  FOUNDATIONS  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS      5 

unconscious  forces  as  sex  attraction,  filial  affection,  and  the  like.  Eco- 
nomic groups  may  be  stimulated  by  sheer  hunger  and  cold.  Associations 
larger  than  the  family  grow  in  part  out  of  the  natural  sociability  of  man- 
kind, which  requires  no  deliberation.  Social  organization  also  exhibits 
an  unconscious  response  to  many  forms  of  geographical  pressure.  Even 
in  those  forms  of  social  organization  where  deliberation  plays  a  large  or 
dominant  role,  social  activities  and  structures  are  strongly  influenced  by 
factors  that  have  an  unconscious  or  habitual  basis. 

In  the  most  profound  sense,  however,  social  organization  is  a  product 
of  the  very  nature  of  man  himself.  Man's  peculiar  physical  nature  and 
biological  equipment  are  such  that  he  has  been  compelled  to  associate 
and  cooperate  with  his  fellow-men  for  the  purpose  of  insuring  his  exist- 
ence, comfort,  protection  and  progress. 

The  Historical  Development  of  the  Forms  of 
Social   Organization 

Owing  to  his  inherent  physical  weakness,  man  has  been  compelled  to 
exploit  his  natural  tendency  to  associate  in  groups.  While  it  has  pro- 
duced a  considerable  cramping  of  individual  freedom  and  initiative,  this 
social  restraint  is  the  price  that  man  has  had  to  pay  for  the  indispensable 
advantages  of  cooperative  endeavor.  The  forms  of  social  organization 
throughout  history  have  differed  widely  as  to  size,  complexity  of  relation- 
ships, and  clarity  and  consciousness  of  purpose.  The  earliest  forms  were 
mainly  brought  about  by  the  sex  impulse,  family  life,  and  the  natural 
sociability  of  man,  operating  in  geographic  and  climatic  conditions. 
The  social  groups  were  small.  The  relationships  of  individuals  and 
classes  were  rudimentary  and  simple.  There  was  but  slight  development 
of  any  rational  or  conscious  purpose  in  social  organization.  The  general 
theory  was  that  the  existing  forms  of  social  grouping,  class  distinctions, 
and  individual  relations  were  the  product  of  divine  will — an  outgrowth 
of  revelations  from  the  supernatural  world.  The  progress  from  these 
simple  hordes  and  local  groups  of  primitive  society  to  modern  world 
organization  has  been  brought  about  by  (1)  the  gradual  education  and 
discipline  of  man  in  group  life,  (2)  the  progress  of  technology,  which  has 
complicated  social  relationships  and  given  man  greater  mobility  and 
more  control  over  his  environment,  and  (3)  the  growth  of  intelligence 
and  a  symbolic  culture,  which  has  led  man  gradually  to  transform  natural 
and  spontaneous  types  of  association  into  a  social  organization  founded, 
to  some  degree  at  least,  upon  a  conscious  and  rational  grasp  of  its  pur- 
poses and  advantages. 

In  later  chapters,  we  shall  trace  the  history  of  the  various  types  and 
systems  of  social  organization.  We  can  here  only  pause  to  indicate  the 
nature  and  significance  of  the  development,  of  the  leading  types  of  social 
groupings  and  institutions. 

Economic  life  has  advanced  from  a  natural  economy,  resting  upon  the 
appropriation  of  the  gifts  of  nature,  with  the  simplest  cooperation  of 


6      THE  FOUNDATIONS  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

various  members  of  the  family,  to  modern  technology,  the  factory  system, 
corporate  forms  of  organization,  and  world  markets.  Political  life  has 
passed  from  the  personal  domination  of  the  chiefs  and  elders  of  a  small 
kinship  group  to  the  modern  centralized  state,  which  assumes  to  control 
every  field  of  human  endeavor.  The  geographical  scope  of  political  con- 
trol has  expanded  in  an  equally  striking  fashion  from  small  groups  to 
large  national  states  occupying  half  a  continent,  while  many  contemporary 
writers  predict,  as  well  as  urge,  the  necessity  of  political  organization  on 
a  world-wide  scale. 

Law  has  progressed  from  the  customary  usages  and  taboos  of  primitive 
peoples  to  the  great  system  of  law  worked  out  in  the  Roman  Empire  and 
embodied  in  the  Code  of  Justinian,  the  old  and  famed  English  Common 
Law,  the  Code  Napoleon,  the  German  Imperial  Code,  and  the  complex 
web  of  constitutional  law,  spun  out  in  the  course  of  protecting  private 
property  in  the  United  States.  Tens  of  thousands  of  lawyers  are  kept 
busy  administering  law,  and  the  costs  thereof  run  into  billions  of  dollars 
annually. 

Religious  life  and  organization  have  advanced  from  the  crude  efforts 
of  primitive  peoples  to  ward  off  evil  spirits  and  exploit  the  aid  of  benevo- 
lent supernatural  beings  to  great,  world-wide  ecclesiastical  organizations, 
embodying  theological  aims  and  religious  activities,  as  well  as  elaborate 
participation  in  various  forms  of  cultural  and  social  endeavor. 

Education  has  advanced  from  the  simple  inculcation  of  tribal  usages 
and  rites  to  great  national  systems  of  public  instruction  which,  in  the 
United  States,  cost  some  three  billions  each  year.  Venerable  educational 
traditions  have  arisen,  such  as  Scholasticism,-  Humanism  and  classical 
education,  scientific  and  vocational  instruction,  and  education  in  the 
social  sciences.  Divers  schools  of  education,  from  traditional  discipli- 
narians to  exponents  of  Progressive  Education,  contend  for  primacy. 
There  is  bitter  dispute  as  to  whether  education  should  merely  conserve 
the  heritage  from  the  past  or  work  for  a  better  social  order  in  the  future. 

Art  has  moved  ahead  from  crude  drawing  on  the  cave  walls  of  the  Stone 
Age  to  the  great  achievements  of  Periclean  Athens,  the  efflorescence  of 
the  Renaissance,  the  various  national  schools  of  art,  the  collection  of 
artistic  treasures  valued  at  billions  of  dollars  in  impressive  museums, 
systematic  artistic  education,  and  the  attempt  to  make  the  creation  and 
appreciation  of  art  a  vital  phase  of  modern  life  and  a  means  of  solving 
the  new  problems  of  leisure. 

It  is  impossible  to  speak  of  social  organization  in  an  intelligent  fashion 
unless  we  keep  ever  before  us  the  genetic  point  of  view,  which  emphasizes 
the  fact  that  present  forms  of  social  organization  have  developed  from 
much  more  simple  and  rudimentary  types  in  the  past,  and  are  undoubtedly 
now  headed  toward  even  more  complicated  forms  of  expression.  Social 
organization  and  human  institutions  cannot  be  viewed  intelligently  in  a 
static  perspective.  They  must  be  looked  upon  as  part  of  a  great  evolving 
body  of  human  culture,  ever  moving  towards  either  greater  perfection  or 
more  easily  demonstrable  inadequacy. 


THE  FOUNDATIONS  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS      7 


Types  of  Social   Bonds 

The  first  important  type  of  influence  for  throwing  men  together  in 
social  groups  may  be  called  the  geographical  factor  or  the  physical  en- 
vironment. More  attractive  climate,  better  fishing  or  hunting,  superior 
fertility  of  soil,  better  protection  against  marauding  neighbors,  favorable 
routes  of  travel,  strategic  locations  of  various  types,  and  the  existence  of 
natural  resources  of  high  value  to  the  group,  from  the  primitive  flint  beds 
to  modern  oil  reserves  and  rubber  plantations,  have  served  to  bring  men 
together  in  social  groups,  from  the  stone  ages  to  our  own  day.  However, 
it  need  never  be  assumed  that  similar  geographic  influences  invariably 
have  an  identical  effect  upon  all  groups  of  men.2  Culture,  namely,  the 
sum  total  of  human  achievement,  is  the  dynamic  fact  in  human  society 
and  history.  Human  nature  and  group  life  are  too  complex  in  their 
character  to  react  with  invariable  uniformity  to  the  same  type  of  external 
influence. 

Along  with  the  geographic  forces  impelling  man  to  associate  must  be 
placed  sex  attraction  and  the  natural  biological  process  of  procreation. 
The  humSToffspring  matures  more  slowly  than  the  offspring  of 'most 
other  types  of  animal  life,  thus  requiring  a  longer  period  of  association 
with,  and  dependence  upon,  the  mother.  Since  human  animals  have 
always  manifested  a  decisive  tendency  towards  permanent  mating,  the 
family,  whatever  its  subsequent  artificial  social  limitations  and  controls, 
is  fundamentally  a  biological  product.  It  rests  upon  potent  and  per- 
sistent biological  factors.  * 

When  coupled  with  certain  economic  situations  and  juristic  concep- 
tions, the  family  may  constitute  the  basis  of  social  organization.  This 
was  particularly  true  in  ancient  communities  organized  around  the  power 
and  authority  of  the  patriarch  in  a  simple  pastoral  or  agricultural  society. 
Here  the  family  set  up  a  rather  thorough  domination  of  economic,  re- 
ligious, cultural,  and  juristic  institutions.  Some  modern  social  reformers, 
most  notably  the  late  Frederic  Le  Play  and  his  followers,  would  revive 
something  like  this  patriarchal  type  of  family  control,  and  make  it  the 
basis  of  social  reconstruction  in  our  industrial  and  urban  age. 

In  primitive  society,  there  was  also  an  extremely  potent  quasi-biological 
type  of  social  bond,  namely,  the  element  of  kinship,  real  or  assumed. 
While  kinship  or,  as  it  has  been  called,  gentile,  society,  was  by  no  means 
universal  in  primitive  society,  it  was  extremely  common.  Kinsmen  were 
supposed  to  be  related  by  blood  through  descent  from  some  mythical 
ancestor,  frequently  a  totemic  animal.  This  kinship  notion  made  such 
types  of  primitive  society  a  strong  "closed  shop."  Kinsmen  alone  could 
function  as  members  of  the  group,  and  nfcw  members  could  be  brought 
into  the  group  only  through  elaborate  forms  of  initiation,  such  as  blood 
transfusion  and  other  forms  of  symbolic  adoption. 


2Cf.  Roderick  Peattie,  Geography  in  Human  Destiny,  Stewart,  1941. 


8      THE   FOUNDATIONS  OF  SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS 

The  other  main  biological  force  acting  as  a  social  bond  is  that  of  racial 
kinship.  In  so  far  as  race  has  any  scientific  significance,  it  means  a 
fundamental  biological  similarity  revealed  in  such  things  as  head  form, 
facial  angle,  the  cross-section  of  the  hair,  pigmentation,  and  various 
structural  affinities  of  a  technical  nature. 

In  the  early  days  of  human  society,  racial  purity  and  the  importance 
of  race  in  social  groupings  were  much  more  marked  than  at  present. 
Today  the  long  and  extensive  intermingling  of  peoples,  the  .growth  of 
greater  tolerance  towards  racial  mixture,  and  the  gradual  increase  of  the 
importance  of  cultural  factors  have  served  to  reduce  the  literal  importance 
of  race  as  a  social  bond.  Yet  distinguished  writers  have  never  laid  more 
stress  upon  the  importance  of  race  in  society  than  at  the  present  time. 
Racial  theories  have  never  had  so  great  a  vogue  or  prestige  as  they  enjoy 
in  Nazi  Germany.  Whatever  the  scientific  errors  in  the  current  dogmas 
about  race,  the  real  or  alleged  factor  of  racial  unity  remains  a  potent 
element  in  the  formation  and  control  of  social  groups.  Indeed,  Adolf 
Hitler  built  up  one  of  the  most  cohesive  states  of  modern  times  around 
the  revival  of  the  Aryan  myth  and  the  alleged  creation  of  a  pure  Aryan 
hegemony  in  Germany. 

Fourth,  we  may  note  the  psychological  bonds  in  society.  One  of  the 
most  potent  is  what  F.  H.  Giddings  emphasized  many  years  ago  under 
the  heading  of  "the  consciousness  of  kind,"  namely,  the  pleasurable  effect 
of  the  recognition  of  similarities.  This  leads  like  to  seek  like  and  to 
avoid  those  unlike  themselves.  It  is  the  most  fundamental  factor  in 
developing  social  grouping  on  the  basis  of  pleasure  and  spontaneous 
response.  There  are  a  number  of  other  psychological  factors  of  a  com- 
parable type,  such  as  sex  attraction,  imitation,  and  social  suggestion,  the 
nature  and  operation  of  each  of  which  has  been  the  subject  of  elaborate 
sociological  treatises.8 

Another  potent  psychological  influence  leading  man  to  group  life  has 
been  the  reaction  to  fear  of  one  sort  or  another,  with  the  resulting  aggre- 
gation of  men  into  groups  for  mutual  protection.  The  nature  and  variety 
of  these  groups  have  been  as  varied  in  their  form  and  extent  as  human 
fears  themselves.  We  can  point  to  the  binding  of  men  together  to  repel 
insects,  animals,  and  human  enemies,  and  also  to  their  organization  to 
resist  floods,  fires,  and  the  supposed  evils  and  dangers  from  the  super- 
natural world.  Herbert  Spencer  once  said  that  the  fear  of  the  living 
produced  the  state,  and  fear  of  the  dead  created  religion. 

Finally,  we  may  discern  the  gradual  growth  of  a  conscious  or  purposeful 
basis  for  social  grouping.  Consciousness  of  kind,  imitation,  and  reaction 
to  fear  originally  developed  chiefly  on  a  spontaneous  or  automatic 
foundation.  With  the  continued  growth  of  social  life,  man  has  gradually 
tended  to  reflect  upon  its  value  to  him.  This  has  led  to  a  definite  desire 
to  improve  and  extend  the  various  forms  of  social  organization.  Instinc- 
tive and  intuitive  foundations  of  social  life  have  gradually  been  supple- 


3  Such,  for  example,  as  Gabriel  Tarde's  Laws  of  Imitation. 


THE  FOUNDATIONS  OF  SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS      9 

mented  by  conscious  purpose  and  rational  control.  Social  evolution 
gradually  emerges  into  social  planning. 

Very  early  in  the  history  of  human  society,  similarity  of  occupations 
or  vocations  constituted  a  basis  for  community  of  interest  and  the  increase 
of  mutual  understanding.  This  was  true  even  of  primitive  priests, 
hunters,  fishermen,  weapon-makers,  shepherds,  husbandmen,  and  mer- 
chants. With  the  increasing  complexity  of  economic,  social,  and  cultural 
life,  and  the  growth  of  a  rational  perception  of  the  nature  of  social 
processes,  mutual  interest,  arising  out  of  common  occupation  or  vocation, 
has  become  an  ever  more  effective  basis  of  social  organization  and  group 
life.  So  potent  and  popular  has  it  become  that  some  writers  are  urging 
the  reorganization  of  society  to  make  the  mutual  interest  of  vocational 
groups  (business,  professions,  or  trades)  the  basis  of  social,  cultural,  and 
political  life — thus  creating  a  "functional  society." 

A  common  cultural  outlook  and  group  interests  have  long  constituted 
a  significant  element  in  promoting  group  life,  as  well  as  in  bringing  about 
social  unity.  Common  language,  common  historic  traditions,  a  similar 
educational  heritage  and  ideals,  and  relative  identity  of  aesthetic  aspira- 
tions have  served  to  give  groups  cultural  uniformity,  as  well  as  to  separate 
them  from  other  groups  with  different  cultural  ideals  and  achievements. 

Religion  has  been  an  important  factor  in  promoting  group  life  and 
social  organization.  It  has  divided  society  into  the  two  great  religious 
groups  of  priesthood  and  believers,  and  has  also  separated  mankind  into 
vast  organizations  founded  upon  similarity  of  religious  beliefs.  Equally 
important  has  been  the  influence  of  religion  upon  other  forms  of  social 
bonds  and  social  institutions.  Religion  was  originally  derived  from  the 
various  types  of  supposed  supernatural  control  over  nature  and  society. 
Social  systems  in  the  past  have  been  viewed  as  primarily  a  product  of 
divine  revelation.  Hence  the  prevailing  types  of  religious  beliefs  have 
constituted  a  powerful  force  vindicating  and  enforcing  the  existing  social 
order.  Religion  has  thus  been  a  vital,  cohesive  factor  in  itself,  and  also 
has  been  one  of  the  most  powerful  forces  maintaining  the  integrity  of 
group  life. 

At  the  apex  of  all  other  forms  of  social  bonds,  more  powerful  and 
probably  more  artificial  than  any  other,  is  the  political  or  juristic  bond. 
From  early  days  it  has  been  found  necessary  to  have  some  ultimate 
power  in  society  capable 'of  controlling  mankind,  particularly  in  crises, 
and  of  giving  a  coherent  and  permanent  direction  to  the  various  types  of 
group  life.  This  external  control,  existing  primarily  for  the  purpose  of 
maintaining  general  or  public  order,  has  come  to  be  known  as  the  political 
factor  in  society — in  historic  times  it  has  been  called  the  state.  With 
the  progress  of  civilization,  the  state  has  become  progressively  more 
purposeful,  more  rational,  and  in  certain  ways  more  tolerant  and  dis- 
criminating. In  the  recent  growth  of  totalitarianism  we  may  note,  how- 
ever, a  trend  towards  irrationality  and  intolerance  in  politics  which  may 
prove  of  considerable  duration.  / 

The  fact  that  man  has  always  lived  and  functioned  as  a  member  of 


10    THE  FOUNDATIONS  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

a  social  group  has  left  a  more  definite  impress  upon  his  personality  and 
culture  than  any  other  force  operating  upon  human  life.  The  groups  in 
which  man  has  lived  have  made  it  possible  for  him  to  develop  material 
culture.  They  have  also  given  man  his  outlook  upon  life,  his  chief  ideas, 
his  scale  of  values,  and  his  dominating  loyalties.  Without  the  group  of 
which  he  is  a  member,  the  human  animal  would  not  only  be  devoid  of 
culture;  he  could  not  even  maintain  the  lowest  form  of  physical  existence 
in  the  face  of  the  dangers  and  difficulties  which  confront  him. 

One  important  point  concerning  human  institutions  and  culture  is  that 
they  differ  from  all  other  forms  of  animal  behavior  in  being  based  upon 
language,  communication,  and  symbolic  relations: 

The  natural  processes  of  organic  evolution  brought  into  existence  in  man,  and 
man  alone,  a  new  and  distinctive  ability:  the  ability  to  use  symbols.  The  most 
important  form  of  symbolic  expression  is  articulate  speech.  Articulate  speech 
means  communication  of  ideas;  communication  means  preservation — tradition — 
and  preservation  means  accumulation  and  progress.  The  emergence  of  the 
organic  faculty  of  symbol-using  has  resulted  in  the  genesis  of  a  new  order  of 
phenomena:  a  superorganic  or  cultural  order.  All  civilizations  are  born  of,  and 
are  perpetuated  by,  the  use  of  symbols.  A  culture,  or  civilization,  is  but  a 
particular  kind  of  form  (symbolic)  which  the  biologic,  life-perpetuating  activities 
of  a  particular  animal,  man,  assurfie. 

Human  behavior  is  symbolic  behavior;  if  it  is  not  symbolic  it  is  not  human. 
The  infant  of  the  genus  homo  becomes  a  human  being  only  as  he  is  introduced 
into  and  participates  in  that  superorganic  order  of  phenomena  which  is  culture. 
And  the  key  to  this  world  and  the  means  of  participation  in  it  is — the  symbol4 

It  is  well  to  keep  this  fact  in  mind.  Otherwise,  we  are  likely  to  forget 
that  social  bonds,  group  activities,  and  institutionalized  forms  of  behavior 
would  be  utterly  impossible  were  it  not  for  articulate  speech  and  the  use 
of  symbols. 

The  Leading  Forms  of  Social  Groups 

The  wide  range  of  social  bonds  analyzed  in  the  preceding  section  have 
led  to  the  development  of  definite  types  of  social  groups.  First,  we 
should  note  the  groups  which  owe  their  existence  primarily  to  various 
types  of  geographic  pressure  or  attraction,  fin  the  earliest  days,  social 
groupings  were  more  directly  and  effectively  conditioned  by  geographic 
factors  than  by  any  other  influence.) 

Hunters  and  fishers  collected  in  swamps  and  jungles  where  fish  and 
game  abounded  and  where  nature  offered  good  hiding  and  protection. 
Herdsmen  lived  on  plains  where  pastures  were  good.  Early  farmers 
gathered  where  land  was  fertile  and  water  was  available  to  stimulate 
vegetation. 

Though  man  has  overcome  the  influence  of  geography  to  a  far  greater 
degree  than  in  primitive  times,  the  distribution  of  humanity  over  the 
planet  still  bears  an  immediate  relation  to  the  environmental  factors. 


*  Leslie  A.  White,  op.  cit.,  pp.  462-463. 


THE   FOUNDATIONS  OF   SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS     11 

Even  in  the  United  States,  physical  factors  still  exert  a  powerful  influ- 
ence over  social  life  and  cultural  expression.  As  the  late  Frederick  Jack- 
son Turner  pointed  out,  perhaps  the  most  vital  fact  about  American 
society  today  is  the  existence  of  sections  with  distinct  types  of  economic 
interests  and  cultural  achievements.5  The  geographic  situation  has 
created  these  sections  and  given  character  and  expression  to  their  in- 
dustrial, social,  and  cultural  life. 

-Vrhe  psycho-biological  bond  in  human  society  has  produced  the  family. 
This  institution  not  only  perpetuates  race ;  it  is  also  the  leading  factor  in 
the  education  of  the  young,  and  has  important  economic,  juristic  and 
cultural  functions  as  well.  Whatever  sweeping  modifications  may  take 
place  in  the  organization  of  the  family,  and  however  much  the  educational 
function  of  the  family  may  be  improved  by  the  introduction  of  psy- 
chology, sexology,  mental  hygiene,  and  pedagogy,  it  may  be  assumed 
that  human  society  can  never  dispense  with  the  institution  of  the  family. 
It  is  likely  to  remain  the  basic  unit  in  social  organization. 

The  psychological  bond  in  human  society  can  scarcely  be  held  to 
produce  any  unique  and  permanent  types  of  groups.  Rather,  it  is  essen- 
tial to  the  formation  of  every  form  of  social  group  because  it  creates 
spontaneous  sociability,  cultural  affinity,  or  community  of  material  in- 
terests. Probably  the  closest  approximation  to  what  may  be  called  a 
distinctly  psychological  form  of  social  organization  is  the  modern  crowd 
or  mob,  the  behavior  of  which  was  studied  a  generation  ago  by  the  old- 
fashioned  crowd  psychologists,  such  as  Gustave  Le  Bon,  and  has  been 
analyzed  in  recent  days  much  more  profoundly  by  writers  like  Everett 
Dean  Martin.  Any  sound  understanding  of  modern  urban  life  must  be 
based  upon  an  adequate  knowledge  of  crowd  psychology.  With  the 
progress  of  the  movies,  the  radio,  and  other  new  agencies  of  communica- 
tion, entire  populations  are  taking  on  many  aspects  of  crowd  behavior.6 

The  bond  of  mutual  material  interest  has  been  so  important  in  human 
society  that  several  schools  of  historians  and  social  scientists  have  co6$ 
tended  that  mutual  interest  has  been  the  vital  source  of  group  life  through- 
out history.  While  this  is  doubtless  an  exaggerated  conception,  no 
historian  questions  the  enormous  influence  which  has  been  exerted  upon 
the  origin  and  transformation  of  social  groups  by  common  material 
interests.  This  force  held  together  the  primitive  fishing  and  hunting 
bands.  It  has  likewise  created  the  economic  groups  which  exist  today, 
such  as  the  various  crafts,  industrial  organizations,  labor  unions,  em- 
ployers' associations,  trade  associations,  and  agricultural  societies.  It 
has  promoted  the  growth  of  economic  organizations  designed  to  further 
definite  forms  of  mutual  interest;  among  these  are  chambers  of  com- 
merce, rotary  clubs,  and  labftr  unions.  It  lies  at  the  roots  of  modern 
propaganda.  Since  the  Industrial  Revolution,  human  society,  for  better 
or  worse,  has  become  economic  or  materialistic  in  its  scale  of  values. 


5  Turner,  "Sections  and  Nations,"  Yale  Review,  October,  1922. 
«  See  below,  Chap.  XIII. 


12    THE  FOUNDATIONS  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

Today  we  can  probably  hold  that  the  economic  bond  stands  next  to  the 
biological  in  power  and  extent  of  influence. 

The  vocational  and  professional  groups  in  contemporary  society  have 
grown  out  of  a  combination  of  the  bond  of  mutual  interest  and  the 
community  of  cultural  objectives.  Such  groups  embody  everything  from 
the  skilled  trades  to  the  organizations  of  surgeons,  artists,  explorers,  and 
laboratory  scientists.  The  spirit  engendered  in  such  organizations, 
having  as  their  goal  a  more  intensive  and  effective  promotion  of  the 
ideals  of  the  group,  is  one  of  the  most  dynamic  influences  existing  today 
for  the  advancement  ef  human  culture.  Indeed,  many  writers  are  advo- 
cating the  reconstruction  of  political  life,  so  as  to  base  representative 
government  upon  vocational  groups  rather  than  upon  the  old  territorial 
districts  which  antedate  the  rise  of  modern  industry  and  the  dominion 
of  professionalism. 

One  of  the  oldest  and  certainly  one  of  the  most  persistent  forms  of 
social  grouping  has  grown  out  of  man's  interest  in  the  supernatural  world 
and  his  hope  of  maintaining  a  congenial  relationship  between  it  and  his 
own  mundane  realm.  A  fear  of  the  supernatural  world,  combined  with 
the  desire  to  exploit  it  so  as  to  improve  his  prosperity,  was  as  dominant 
a  factor  in  the  group  life  of  primitive  man  as  material  well-being  and 
industrial  effort  are  in  contemporary  culture. 

This  religious  bond  has  produced  the  most  widely  varied  forms  of 
groups,  from  the  totemites  and  magical  brotherhoods  of  primitive  man 
to  great  world  churches.  It  has  created  such  permanent  organizations 
as  the  religions  of  the  Jews,  the  Christians,  and  the  Muslims,  as  well  as 
such  striking  but  temporary  organizations  as  the  Crusaders  of  the  Middle 
Ages. 

In  our  own  age  the  predominantly  supernatural  motivation  of  religious 
bodies  has  been  supplemented  by  the  desire  to  use  the  religious  urge  to 
advance  social  well-being.  This  religious  social  effort  has  created  such 
organizations  as  the  Y.M.C.A.,  the  Knights  of  Columbus,  the  Y.M.H.A., 
the  Federal  Council  of  the  Churches  of  Christ,  and  the  Catholic  National 
Welfare  Association. 

The  cultural  bond  in  human  society,  like  the  psychological  factors,  can 
hardly  be  said  to  have  created  special  forms  of  social  organization  entirely 
distinct  from  economic,  professional,  or  religious  groups.  There  are,  of 
course,  many  organizations  of  artists  and  of  those  who  wish  to  support 
various  phases  of  art.  There  are  foundations  for  the  support  of  art,  and 
schools  for  artists.  Different  schools  and  traditions  of  art  create  groups 
to  further  their  ideals.  The  struggle  of  diverse  cultural  ideals,  in  an 
effort  to  promote  a  particular  form  of  culture  or  artistic  ideal,  is  a  power- 
ful factor  in  the  advancement  of  man's  scientific,  aesthetic,  and  educa- 
tional life. 

The  bonds  growing  out  of  mutual  interest  and  the  need  for  group  pro- 
tection have  produced  our  many  types  of  political  organization,  from  the 
rudimentary  council  of  elders,  the  tribal  assemblies,  and  other  simple 
forms  of  primitive  political  life,  to  a  representative  federal  republic  like 


THE  FOUNDATIONS   OF  SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS     13 

the  United  States  of  America.  Thoughtful  writers  have  come  to  the 
conclusion  that  even  the  great  national  states  of  the  present  time  must 
be  regarded  as  but  a  stage  in  political  evolution.  There  must  be  some 
form  of  world  organization  which  will  avert  war  and  make  possible  a 
more  widespread  and  generally  diffused  appropriation  of  the  cooperative 
effort  of  man. 

Primary  Groups  and  the  "We"  Group 

One  of  the  most  important  aspects  of  the  analysis  of  group  life  and 
social  organization  is  the  recognition  of  certain  basic  and  elemental 
associations  which  we  have  come  to  know  as  "primary  groups,"  a  term 
made  immortal  by  the  late  Charles  H.  Cooley: 

By  primary  groups  I  mean  those  characterized  by  intimate  face-to-face  asso- 
ciation and  cooperation.  They  are  primary  in  several  senses,  but  chiefly  in 
that  they  are  fundamental  in  forming  the  social  nature  and  ideals  of  the  in- 
dividual. The  result  of  intimate  association,  psychologically,  is  a  certain  fusion 
of  individualities  in  a  common  whole,  so  that  one's  very  self,  for  many  purposes, 
at  least,  is  the  common  life  and  purpose  of  the  group.  Perhaps  the  simplest 
way  of  describing  this  wholeness  is  by  saying  that  it  is  a  "we";  it  involves  the 
sort  of  sympathy  and  mutual  identification  for  which  "we"  is  the  natural  ex- 
pression. One  lives  in  the  feeling  of  the  whole  and  finds  the  chief  aim  of  his 
will  in  that  feeling.  ... 

The  most  important  spheres  of  this  intimate  association  and  cooperation — 
though  by  no  means  the  only  ones — are  the  family,  the  play-group  of  children, 
and  the  neighborhood  or  community  group  of  elders.  These  are  practically 
universal,  belonging  to  all  times  and  all  stages  of  development,  and  are  accord- 
ingly a  chief  basis  of  what  is  universal  in  human  nature  and  human  ideals.7 

The  family,  which  is  the  most  fundamental  of  the  primary  groups,  we 
have  already  described  as  a  bio-social  unit  growing  out  of  sex  attraction 
and  parental  and  filial  love.  The  play  group  is  partly  biological  and 
partly  regional,  being  founded  upon  the  association  of  children  of  neigh- 
boring families  to  express  the  spontaneous  human  tendency  to  play  and 
mimic.  The  play  group  may  also  develop  temporary  associations  based 
on  the  common  interests  of  playmates.  Kimball  Young  calls  this  form 
of  primary  group  a  "congeniality"  group. 

Primary  groups  socialize  the  individual,  give  him  his  notions  of  ele- 
mentary justice  and  social  ideals  and  obligations,  train  him  in  the  rudi- 
ments of  social  intercourse,  and  lay  the  basis  for  all  later  expansion  of 
social  contacts  and  responsibilities.  Down  to  the  rise  of  modern  indus- 
trialism and  urban  life,  the  majority  of  men  had  few  contacts  beyond 
primary  groups.  The  current  social  chaos  and  disintegration  is  due  in 
a  large  measure  to  the  breakdown  of  primary  groups  in  our  urban- 
industrial  age  and  the  failure  to  bring  into  being  any  adequate  substitute 
for  the  socializing  function  formerly  executed  by  the  primary  groups  of 
an  agrarian  civilization. 


7  C,  H.  Cppjey,  Social  Organization,  Scribner,  1909,  pp. 


14    THE  FOUNDATIONS  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

Primary  groups  are  characterized  chiefly  by  face-to-face  association. 
Secondary  groups  may  exist  without  the  necessity  of  all,  or  even  most, 
of  the  members  ever  meeting  in  face-to-face  situations.  Such  are  scien- 
tific associations,  political  parties,  religious  denominations,  economic 
associations,  labor  unions,  and  the  like.  Secondary  groups  are  more 
formal  and  impersonal  than  primary  groups  and  also  more  permanent 
and  purposive  in  character.  They  are  usually  founded  consciously  to 
accomplish  a  given  purpose. 

This  conception  of  primary  and  secondary  groups  is  not,  so  far,  differ- 
ent from  F.  H.  Giddings'  idea  of  component  and  constituent  societies. 
According  to  Professor  Giddings,  component  societies  are  those  of  a 
partially  biological  or  genetic  character  which  are  natural,  self-sufficing 
if  necessary,  and  self-perpetuating.  Such  are  families,  neighborhoods, 
towns,  villages,  and  the  like.  Constituent  societies,  on  the  other  hand, 
are  not  at  all  genetic  or  self-perpetuating  in  a  biological  sense.  They 
are  consciously  created  to  carry  on  specific  activities;  good  examples  are 
corporations,  political  parties,  philanthropic  societies,  scientific  associa- 
tions, and  religious  organizations. 

Closely  related  to  the  notion  of  primary  and  secondary  groups  is  the 
distinction  between  (1)  "we-groups"  or  "in-groups"  and  (2)  "others- 
groups"  or  "out-groups."  As  Professor  Cooley  has  pointed  out,  primary 
groups  ar6  distinguished  especially  by  their  "we"  feeling.  This  distinc- 
tion between  "we-groups"  and  "others-groups"  was  especially  strong  and 
important  in  primitive  society,  but  it  is  still  very  potent  and  constitutes 
a  fundamental  basis  of  international  friction  and  warfare,  as  well  as  of 
social  conflict  and  class  hostility.  The  "we-group"  is  characterized  by 
spontaneous  solidarity,  mutual  sympathy,  loyalty,  and  pride  by  the 
members  of  the  group.  Such  groups  extend  all  the  way  from  frontier 
families  and  neighborhoods  to  great  national  states.  The  "others-group" 
is  made  up  of  those  towards  whom  the  "we-group"  entertains  feelings  of 
strangeness,  suspicion,  antagonism,  hatred,  conflict,  and  fear. 

This  sense  of  "we"  and  "others"  starts  with  families  and  neighborhoods 
which  are  suspicious  of  strange  families  and  neighborhoods.  It  may 
extend  to  whole  peoples,  as  in  the  distinction  between  Jew  and  Gentile 
and  Greek  and  Barbarian.  National  states  are  perhaps  the  largest,  most 
impressive,  and  most  dangerous  expressions  of  the  sense  of  "we-groups" 
and  "others-groups."  Our  own  country  is,  for  us,  a  "we-group,"  while 
foreign  countries  are,  from  our  point  of  view,  an  "others"  or  "out"  group. 
Within  states  we  have  the  divisions  into  employers  and  laborers,  em- 
ployers' associations  and  labor  unions,  capitalists  and  "Reds."  Labor 
unions  are  an  "in-group"  to  organized  workers,  but  they  are  an  "out- 
group"  to  employers,  especially  to  those  hostile  to  organized  labor.  The 
distinction  applies  to  the  religious  field  in  the  case  of  the  non-religious 
or  irreligious  as  against  the  church-going  public.  There  may  even  be 
hostility  between  different  elements  in  the  "we-groups"  in  national  states. 
Examples  are  the  rivalry  between  the  Congress  of  Industrial  Organiza- 
tions (CIO)  and  the  American  Federation  of  Labor  (AFL),  the  rivalry 


THE  FOUNDATIONS  OF  SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS     15 

between  Catholics  and  Protestants,  and  the  hostility  between  different 
groups  of  "Reds,"  such  as  Socialists  and  Communists,  or  even  the  bitter 
sectarian  strifes  among  the  Communists  themselves.  Upon  the  possi- 
bility of  mitigating  the  "we-group"  and  "others-group"  feeling  depends 
the  prospect  of  seriously  lessening  class  strife  and  international  war. 

Society,  Community,  and  Associations 

Another  mode  of  analyzing  the  nature  of  social  organization  has  been 
suggested  by  a  number  of -writers  such  as  Ferdinand  Tonnies,  Ludwig 
Stein,  fimile  Durkheim,  F.  H.  Giddings,  and,  particularly,  R.  M.  Maclver. 
Professor  Madver's  conception  is  derived  mainly  from  Tonnies.  He 
classifies  the  chief  forms  of  social  organization  under  the  headings  of 
society,  communities,  and  associations.  To  him,  society  is  a  universal 
term  which  embraces  the  whole  range  of  human  relationships.  Social 
organization,  within  the  general  framework  of  society,  falls  into  two 
main  types:  communities  and  associations.  The  community  represents 
the  result  of  spontaneous  association,  growing  out  of  psychic  affinity  and 
community  of  culture  and  local  interests: 

By  a  community  I  mean  any  area  of  common  life,  village,  or  town,  or  district, 
or  country,  or  even  wider  area.  To  deserve  the  name  community,  the  area 
must  be  somehow  distinguished  from  further  areas,  the  common  life  may  have 
some  characteristic  of  its  own  such  that  the  frontiers  of  the  area  have  some 
meaning.  All  the  laws  of  the  cosmos,  physical,  biological,  and  psychological, 
conspire  to  bring  it  about  that  beings  who  live  together  shall  resemble  one 
another.  Wherever  men  live  together  they  develop  in  some  kind  and  degree 
distinctive  common  characteristics,  manners,  traditions,  modes  of  speech,  and 
so  on.  These  are  the  signs  and  consequences  of  an  effective  common  life.  It 
will  be  seen  that  a  community  may  be  part  of  a  wider  community,  and  that 
all  community  is  a  question  of  degree.  For  instance,  the  English  residents  in 
a  foreign  capital  often  live  in  an  intimate  community  of  their  own,  as  well  as 
in  the  wider  community  of  the  capital.  It  is  a  question  of  the  degree  and 
intensity  of  the  common  life.  The  one  extreme  is  the  whole  world  of  men,  one 
great  but  vague  and  incoherent  common  life.  The  other  extreme  is  the  small 
intense  community  within  which  the  life  of  an  ordinary  individual  is  lived,  a 
tiny  nucleus  of  common  life  with  a  sometimes  larger,  sometimes  smaller,  and 
always  varying  fringe.  Yet  even  the  poorest  in  social  relationships  is  a  member 
in  a  chain  of  social  contacts  which  stretches  to  the  world's  end.  In  the  infinite 
series  of  social  relationships  which  thus  arise,  we  distinguish  the  nuclei  of  in- 
tenser  common  life,  cities  and  nations  and  tribes,  and  think  of  them  as  par 
excellence  communities.8 

By  associations  Maclver  means  not  only  groups  but  what  are  also 
frequently  classified  by  sociologists  as  institutions;  namely,  socially 
approved  modes  of  dealing  with  the  more  important  problems  and  ques- 
tions of  social  life  in  the  divers  fields  of  human  endeavor: 

An  association  is  an  organization  of  social  beings  (or  a  body  of  social  beings 
as  organized)  for  the  pursuit  of  some  common  interest  or  interests.  It  is  a 


8  R.  M.  Maclver,  Community:  A  Sociological  Study,  Macmillan,  1917,  pp.  22  ff. 


16    THE  FOUNDATIONS  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

determinate  social  unity  built  upon  common  purpose.  Every  end  which  men 
seek  is  more  easily  attained  for  all  when  all  whom  it  concerns  unite  to  seek  it, 
when  all  cooperate  in  seeking  it.  Thus  you  may  have  an  association  corre- 
sponding to  every  possible  interest  of  social  beings.  Community  bubbles  into 
associations  permanent  and  transient,  and  no  student  of  the  actual  social  life 
of  the  present  can  help  being  struck  by  the  enormous  number  of  associations 
of  every  kind,  political,  economic,  religious,  educational,  scientific,  artistic, 
literary,  recreative,  which  today  more  than  ever  before  enrich  the  communal 
life.8 

The  state  is  a  form  of  association  or  institution,  but  it  is  distinguished 
from  other  associations  by  the  scope  of  its  interests,  the  thoroughness  of 
its  organization,  and  its  power  to  use  political  law  and  coercive  force. 
While  it  is  primarily  regulative,  negative,  and  repressive  in  its  operation, 
it  can  achieve  much  in  a  positive  and  constructive  way,  provided  its  re- 
lation to  communities  and  other  associations  is  properly  recognized  in 
the  constitution  and  in  current  legislation.  The  state  should  control 
other  associations  to  the  extent  of  assuring  that  they  serve  the  interests 
of  the  community  in  the  highest  possible  degree,  but  at  this  point  its 
interference  should  cease.  Some  associations  require  a  higher  degree 
of  state  control  than  now  exists,  while  others  need  more  freedom.  The 
only  scientific  policy  in  this  respect  must  be  pragmatic  and  dynamic  and 
based  on  a  careful  study  of  the  cogent  facts. 

The  Value  and  Contributions  of  Social   Organization 

Without  the  numerous  forms  of  social  organization,  human  life  and 
civilization  would  be  quite  impossible.  Let  us  indicate  some  of  the  ways 
in  which  social  organization  achieves  its  very  important  service. 

First  and  foremost  stands  the  matter  of  mutual  aid.  This  may  take 
the  form  of  very  simple  and  direct  cooperation,  such  as  the  cooperative 
aid  in  agricultural  operations,  the  repulsion  of  an  invader  or  wild  animals, 
the  putting  out  of  forest  fires,  or  any  number  of  other  simple,  spontaneous 
forms  of  group  endeavor.  It  develops  further  in  simple  forms  of  the 
division  of  labor,  such  as  the  mutual  agreement  upon  the  distribution  of 
'labor  during  a  camping  or  hunting  trip.  In  our  day  it  has  evolved  into 
the  detailed  specialization,  regimentation,  and  subordination  that  charac- 
terize modern  industrial  and  social  life. 

In  every  case,  the  power  and  efforts  of  the  unaided  individual  are 
enormously  multiplied  and  the  potential  skill  and  efficiency  of  society 
greatly  enhanced.  There  are  many  problems  and  tasks  in  which  the 
individual  himself,  taken  alone  and  unaided,  is  essentially  impotent,  but 
yield  readily  to  the  combined  efforts  of  a  group.  Further,  through  a 
system  in  which  each  individual  is  assigned  tasks  for  which  he  is  per- 
sonally most  competent  and  for  which  he  has  the  greatest  amount  of 
enthusiasm,  we  are  able  to  make  the  greatest  possible  use  of  human  ability 
and  energy.  Thousands  of  years  ago,  in  fact,  Plato,  in  his  Republic, 


THE  FOUNDATIONS  OF  SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS     17 

made  the  division  of  labor  and  social  specialization  the  essence  of  social 
justice  and  the  ideal  of  social  reconstruction.  Adam  Smith  revived  the 
same  idea  nearly  two  centuries  ago  in  The  Wealth  of  Nations. 

Social  organization  is  also  absolutely  essential  to  the  creation  of  social 
order  and  stability.  Whatever  achievements  might  be  wrought  in  the 
way  of  industrial  effort  and  artistic  creation,  these  would  be  extremely 
precarious  and  ephemeral  were  it  not  for  their  protection  through  those 
forms  of  social  control  which  prevent  anarchy,  disorder,  confusion,  and 
unlawful  appropriation  of  individual  and  group  products.  From  the 
days  of  the  primitive  local  group  to  the  modern  national  state,  social 
organization  has  insured  to  each  individual  and  group  the  more  or  less 
permanent  possession  of  the  products  of  its  efforts. 

Finally,  there  is  no  such  thing  as  a  self-created  and  self-contained 
human  individual,  except  in  a  purely  metaphysical  sense.  The  mature 
human  personality  is  not  a  biological  creation,  independent  of  its  social 
setting.  Personality  is  itself  primarily  a  product  of  social  organization 
and  can  achieve  its  complete  expression  only  through  a  well-integrated 
adjustment  to  the  forms  of  society  in  which  the  individual  finds  himself. 
The  normal  individual  is  preeminently  the  person  who  is  happily  and 
effectively  adjusted  to  the  social  world  about  him,  and  satisfied  with  the 
particular  tasks  which  society  imposes  upon  him. 

The  facts  mentioned  in  the  preceding  pages  summarize  the  advantages 
which  have  come  to  man  from  social  organization.  But,  like  all  else  in 
human  life,  a  price  has  been  exacted  for  these  gains.  Most  notable 
among  the  costs  of  social  organization  has  been  the  discipline  imposed 
upon  the  individual  by  the  group,  with  the  resulting  loss  of  freedom, 
initiative,  and  independence.  Social  organization  has  been  brought  about 
at  the  price  of  much  social  stagnation  and  intolerance.  This  has  slowed 
down  social  progress,  discouraged  innovations,  and  perpetuated  outworn 
traditions  and  customs.  David  S.  Muzzey  has  graphically  stated  this 
important  fact  about  the  cost  of  social  organization  in  the  way  of  generat- 
ing intolerance,  conformity,  and  conservatism: 

• 

The  student  of  anthropology,  psychology  and  sociology  comes  to  wonder  how 
such  moderate  progress  as  we  have  achieved  in  toleration  has  been  accomplished. 
For  unnumbered  centuries  rigid  custom  ruled  our  remote  ancestors,  To  depart 
from  the  ritual  prescribed  for  hunt  or  harvest,  to  violate  the  tabus  which  em- 
bodied the  awful  sanctions  of  supernatural  power,  was  to  endanger  the  very 
existence  of  the  tribe.  At  the  entrance  to  every  path  of  independent  thought 
or  individual  action  stood  the  angel  with  a  flaming  sword  in  his  hand.  The 
stranger  was  eo  ipso  the  enemy,  the  protege  of  hostile  divinities  and  the  practiser 
of  destructive  arts.  In  the  course  of  time,  by  ways  and  from  some  motives  of 
which  we  have  no  recorded  knowledge,  some  anonymous  heroes  with  hearts  of 
"triple  bronze"  dared  to  break  through  the  sacred  bonds  of  custom— else  we 
should  still  be  living  in  caves  or  huts.  But  the  vast  majority,  with  little  courage 
and  less  discernment,  went  to  swell  the  mass  of  blind  conformity.  Realizing,  as 
we  now  do,  that  the  few  original  and  innovating  minds  have  had  to  drag  through 
the  centuries  the  dead  weight  of  complacent  custom,  as  the  small  heads  of  pre- 
historic monsters  dragged  their  huge  bodies  through  swamp  and  slime,  we  may 
wonder  that  mankind  was  not  permanently  mired  in  intellectual  stagnation.  .  .  . 


18    THE  FOUNDATIONS  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

Institutions  have  supervened  to  confirm  and  conserve.  They  have  been  estab- 
lished by  and  for  men  of  like  belief,  like  speech,  like  blood,  like  habits,  to 
strengthen  their  religious,  patriotic,  racial  and  social  convictions  of  the  superiority 
of  these  institutions  to  those  of  people  of  other  beliefs,  speech,  blood  or  habits. 
Toleration  has  never  been  a  charter  article  in  the  planting  of  churches,  states 
and  schools.  And  if,  in  very  recent  years,  it  has  made  any  way  in  these  institu- 
tions, it  has  been  by  dint  of  strenuous  efforts  and  by  virtue  of  developments 
alien  to  their  original  purpose.10 

Conservatism,  conformity,  intolerance,  and  stagnation,  brought  about 
by  social  organization  and  herd  discipline,  have  plagued  earlier  genera- 
tions, and  they  remain  to  threaten  the  very  existence  of  twentieth-century 
civilization.  They  are  responsible  for  what  is  known  as  cultural  lag, 
namely,  the  failure  of  our  institutional  development  to  keep  pace  with 
the  progress  in  science,  invention,  and  industry.  Cultural  lag  is  more 
responsible  than  all  other  causes  combined  in  producing  war,  political 
corruption,  poverty,  misery,  crime,  and  other  major  evils.  Indeed,  this 
resistance  to  institutional  and  intellectual  changes  may  destroy  civiliza- 
tion as  we  know  it  today  and  throw  mankind  back  into  chaos  and  social 
disintegration.11 

The  Modes  of  Group  Activity  and  Social  Control 

The  most  universal  and  perhaps  most  elementary  means  of  exercising 
social  control  over  the  individual  and  of  rendering  permanent  the  influ- 
ence of  the  group  is  the  influence  of  public  opinion,  as  applied  by  sugges- 
tion, discussion,  propaganda,  and  direct  inculcation  of  commands.  While 
public  opinion,  taken  by  itself,  can  rarely  apply  physical  force  to  execute 
its  mandates,  it  can  bring  to  bear  a  very  powerful  influence  through  the 
desire  of  every  individual  to  be  well  thought  of  by  his  fellow  citizens. 
Social  disapproval  can  also  bring  about  very  serious  practical  disad- 
vantages to  the  individual,  thus  exploiting  the  power  of  material  interest.' 
Along  with  such  informal  means  as  family  discussions,  the  exhortations 
of  the  pulpit,  and  the  rhetoric  of  the  platform,  are  the  more  permanent 
factors  and  institutionalized  agencies,  such  as  the  press,  radio,  movies, 
education,  and  propaganda.  To  a  large  degree,  public  opinion  controls 
cultural  ideals  and  values  and  also  public  morals,  in  so  far  as  these  are 
not  brought  under  the  dominion  of  legislation  and  the  courts. 

Another  more  direct  and  artificial  means  of  promoting  and  controlling 
group  action  are  specific  programs  of  various  social  groups.  These 
programs  embody  the  desires,  aspirations,  and  modes  of  procedure  of 
the  particular  groups,  and  make  possible  the  organization  of  group  force 
behind  such  specific  objectives.  Such  programs  are  the  objectives  of 
labor  unions,  chambers  of  commerce,  cooperative  organizations,  religious 
groups,  reform  groups,  and  the  like. 


10  Essays  in  Intellectual  History  Dedicated  to  James  Harvey  Robinson,  Harper, 
1929,  pp.  7-S. 

11  See  Chap.  III. 


THE  FOUNDATIONS  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS     19 

Frequently,  group  programs  are  sufficiently  ambitious  or  of  a  sufficiently 
distinct  public  nature  to  find  their  way  ultimately  into  legislation.  They 
then  have  behind  them  the  physical  force  of  the  state.  Once  its  will  is 
embodied  in  legislation,  the  group  can  make  use  of  the  physical  fact  of 
punishment  as  applied  through  the  force  of  the  state.  It  need  no  longer 
rely  entirely  upon  the  informal  pressure  of  public  opinion;  it  can  evoke 
political  authority,  as  expressed  in  various  compulsive  organs,  from  the 
standing  army  to  the  local  constabulary. 

The  degree  to  which  group  policies  are  enforced,  either  by  the  influ- 
ence of  public  opinion  or  by  the  physical  force  of  the  state,  depends  pri- 
marily upon  the  cultural  conditions  existing  in  any  group.  As  E.  A.  Ross 
and  F.  H.  Giddings  have  pointed  out,  the  more  highly  developed  the 
culture  of  the  society,  the  greater  the  unity  and  uniformity  of  cultural 
ideals,  the  more  widely  distributed  the  material  posessions,  and  the 
greater  the  ethnic  homogeneity,  the  greater  the  reliance  that  will  be 
placed  upon  public  opinion  as  a  sufficiently  certain  and  potent  source  of 
control  over  group  life.  On  the  other  hand,  the  wider  the  diversities  of 
culture,  material  possessions,  group  ideas,  and  ethnic  derivation,  the 
more  society  will  be  compelled  to  rely  upon  the  intervention  of  the  state 
and  upon  resort  to  the  various  forms  and  agencies  of  political  coercion. 

Society  and  the  Social  Organism 

For  a  generation  or  so  after  the  science  of  sociology  had  been  launched 
a  century  ago  by  August  Comte,  it  was  devoted  mainly  to  comparing 
society  to  the  biological  organism.  While  this  notion  is  no  longer  re- 
garded as  being  of  vital  importance,  it  is  illuminating  and,  when  properly 
qualified,  still  has  its  uses  in  clarifying  the  character  of  social  organiza- 
tion. 

Experts  have  described  the  nature  of  the  biological  organism  and  have 
shown  that  the  human  body  is  really  a  great  complex  of  cooperating 
cells  and  physiological  systems.  Society  is  likewise  a  complex  type  of 
•organism: 

A  mechanical  system  is  a  collection  of  parts  externally  related;  it  changes  by 
an  alteration  of  its  parts;  and  has  reference  to  an  end  which  is  outside  of  itself. 
A  chemical  system  is  a  compound  of  parts  which  are  absorbed  in  a  whole;  it 
does  not  change  except  by  dissolution;  and  it  has  no  end  to  which  it  refers.  In 
an  organism,  on  the  other  hand,  the  relations  of  the  parts  are  intrinsic ;  changes 
take  place  by  an  internal  adaptation;  and  its  end  forms  an  essential  element 
in  its  own  nature.  We  see,  in  short,  that  an  organism  is  a  real  whole,  in  a  sense 
which  no  other  kind  of  unity  is  so.  It  is  "in  seipso  totus,  teres,  atque  ro- 
tundus."  .  .  .  We  may  define  it,  therefore,  as  a  whole  whose  parts  are  intrin- 
sically related  to  it,  which  develops  from  within,  and  has  a  reference  to  an  end 
that  is  involved  in  its  own  nature.12 

The  first  generation  of  distinguished  sociological  writers,  made  up  of 
such  men  as  Herbert  Spencer,  Paul  von  Lilienfeld,  Albert  Schaffle,  and 


12  J.  S.  Mackenzie,  Introduction  to  Social  Philosophy,  Maclehose,  Glasgow,  1895, 
pp.  141-143. 


20    THE  FOUNDATIONS  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 


Worms,  emphasized  the  close  resemblance  between  human  society 
and  the  biological  organism.13  Perhaps  the  most  illuminating  discussion 
of  this  subject  was  that  offered  by  Spencer.  He  enumerated  in  clear 
fashion  the  fundamental  similarities  between  society  and  an  organism. 
First,  both  are  distinguished  from  inorganic  matter  by  an  augmentation 
of  mass  and  visible  growth  during  a  greater  part  of  their  existence. 
Second,  as  both  increase  in  size  they  increase  in  complexity  of  structure. 
Third,  the  progressive  differentiation  of  structure  in  both  is  accompanied 
by  a  comparable  differentiation  of  functions.  Fourth,  evolution  estab- 
lishes in  both  social  and  animal  organisms  not  only  differences  but  defi- 
nitely coordinated  differences  of  such  a  character  as  to  make  each  other 
possible.  Fifth,  the  analogy  between  a  society  and  an  organism  is  still 
more  evident  when  it  is  recognized  that,  conversely,  every  organism  is  a 
society.  Finally,  in  both  society  and  the  organism,  the  life  of  the  aggre- 
gate may  be  destroyed  while  the  units  live  on, 

On  the  other  hand,  there  are  three  important  differences  to  be  noted 
between  society  and  the  biological  organism.  First,  in  an  individual 
organism  the  component  parts  form  a  concrete  whole  and  the  living  units 
are  bound  together  in  close  contact,  whereas  in  the  social  organism  the 
component  parts  fofm  a  discrete  whole  and  the  living  units  are  free  and 
more  or  less  dispersed.  Again,  and  even  more  fundamental,  in  the  indi- 
vidual organism  there  is  such  a  differentiation  of  functions  that  some 
parts  become  the  seat  of  feeling  and  thought  and  others  are  practically 
insensitive,  while  in  the  social  organism  no  such  specialization  exists; 
there  is  no  social  mind  or  sensorium  apart  from  the  individuals  that 
make  up  the  society.  A  result  of  this  second  difference  is  the  third 
distinction:  that,  while  in  the  organism  the  units  exist  for  the  good  of 
the  whole,  in  society  the  whole  exists  for  the  good  of  the  individual 
members. 

The  theory  of  the  social  organism  was  carried  still  further  by  the 
distinguished  French  writer,  Alfred  Fouill£e,  who  laid  great  emphasis 
upon  the  evolutionary  and  purposeful  liature  of  the  social  organism, 
contending  that  the  social  organism  is  really  a  contractual  one,  embody- 
ing a  specific  desire  to  achieve  a  definite  purpose: 

In  fact  at  what  moment  does  an  assemblage  of  men  become  a  society  in  the 
true  sense  of  the  word?  It  is  when  all  the  men  conceive,  more  or  less  clearly,  a 
type  of  organism  which  they  can  form  through  uniting  themselves,  and  when 
they  do  effectively  unite  themselves  under  the  determining  influence  of  that 
conception.  We  have  thus  an  organism  which  exists  because  it  has  been  thought 
and  wished,  an  organism  born  of  an  idea  ;  and  since  that  common  idea  involves 
a  common  will,  we  have  a  ...  contractual  organism.14 

In  .the  same  way  that  in  a  healthy  biological  organism  we  must  have 
cooperative  endeavor  and  a  harmonious  working  of  all  the  subordinate 


18  See  H.  E.  Barnes  and  Howard  Becker,  Social  Thoughts  from  Lore  to  Science, 
2  Vols  Heath,  1938,  Vol.  I,  pp.  677-692. 

^14  Alfred  Fouillee,  La  Science  sociale  contemporaine,  Paris,  1888,  p.  115.  This 
view  was  also  shared  by  the  great  Belgian  sociologist  Guillaume  de  Greef. 


THE   FOUNDATIONS   OF   SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS     21 

physiological  systems,  so  in  the  social  organism,  if  it  is  to  be  as  construc- 
tive and  useful,  there  must  be  a  harmonious  and  cooperative  functioning 
of  the  various  classes  and  institutions  in  society: 

Social  development  involves  the  harmonious  development  of  the  constituent 
members  of  society.  This  is  one  of  the  elements  of  truth  contained  in  what  is 
called  the  organic  conception  of  society.  To  speak  of  society  as  if  it  were  a 
physical  organism  is  a  piece  of  mysticism,  if  indeed  it  is  not  quite  meaningless. 
But  the  life  of  society  and  the  life  of  an  individual  do  resemble  one  another  in 
certain  respects,  and  the  term  "organic"  is  as  justly  applicable  to  the  one  as  to 
the  other.  For  an  organism  is  a  whole  consisting  of  interdependent  parts.  Each 
part  lives  and  functions  and  grows  by  subserving  the  life  of  the  whole.  It 
sustains  the  rest  and  is  sustained  by  them,  and  through  their  mutual  support 
comes  a  common  development.  And  this  is  how  we  would  conceive  the  life 
of  man  in  society  in  so  far  as  it  is  harmonious.15 

Finally,  there  is  no  fundamental  opposition  between  the  conception  of 
a  highly  developed  personality  and  of  a  properly  functioning  social  organ- 
ism. Personality  finds  its  complete  expression  only  in  social  organiza- 
tion and  cooperative  endeavor,  while  social  organization  can  exist  in  an 
effective  fashion  only  on  the  basis  of  the  spontaneous  and  eager  partici- 
pation of  all  the  constituent  individuals: 

It  [the  ideal  society]  must  include  such  a  degree  of  freedom  as  is  necessary 
for  the  working  out  of  the  individual  life.  It  must  include  such  a  degree  of 
socialism  as  is  necessary  to  prevent  exploitation  and  a  brutalizing  struggle  for 
existence,  as  well  as  to  secure  to  each  individual  such  leisure  as  is  required  for 
the  development  of  the  higher  life.  It  must  include  such  a  degree  of  aristocratic 
rule  as  is  necessary  for  the  advance  of  culture  and  for  the  wise  conduct  of  social 
affairs.  .  .  . 

That  there  is  no  contradiction  between  the  independence  which  is  now  claimed 
for  the  individual  and  the  fact  of  his  social  determination,  becomes  evident  when 
we  consider  the  nature  of  that  determination  and  of  that  independence.  That 
the  individual  is  determined  by  his  society  means  merely  that  his  life  is  an 
expression  of  the  general  spirit  of  the  social  atmosphere  in  which  he  lives.  And 
that  the  individual  is  independent  means  merely  that  the  spirit  which  finds 
expression  in  him  is  a  living  force  which  may  develop  by  degrees  into  something 
different.16 


15  L.  T.  Hobhouse,  Social  Evolution  and  Political  Theory,  Columbia  University 
Press,  1913,  p.  87. 
•    16  Mackenzie,  op.  cit.,  pp.  157-158,  293. 


CHAPTER   II 
A  Panorama  of  Social  Institutions 

Basic  Human  Drives 

PSYCHOLOGISTS,  notably  Robert  S.  Woodworth,  have  suggested  that 
human  activity  grows  out  of  certain  basic  drives  or  impulses  which  are 
the  spontaneous  expression  of  the  human  being  as  a  biological  organism. 
The  first  of  these  drives  is  for  self-preservation.  There  is  a  basic  will-to- 
live  which  is  extinguished  only  in  pathological  or  abnormal  situations  that 
lead  to  suicide. 

Another  fundamental  drive  is  for  self-perpetuation.  This  arises  out 
of  the  sex  impulses,  without  any  conscious  relation,  at  first,  to  procreation 
or  the  perpetuation  of  the  human  race.  For  hundreds  of  thousands  of 
years  human  beings  seem  to  have  had  no  knowledge  that  there  is  a  direct 
connection  between  sexual  intercourse  and  the  bearing  of  children.  The 
desire  to  perpetuate  the  family  name,  the  wish  to  prevent  race  suicide, 
or  the  thought  of  providing  recruits  for  a  national  army,  are  considera- 
tions only  of  a  late  period. 

A  third  strong  drive  is  for  self-expression.  In  its  origins,  this  is  a 
biological  urge  for  the  expression  of  personality  in  various  forms  of  physi- 
cal activity  with  appropriate  verbal  accompaniments,  and  it  may  be 
stimulated  by  such  environmental  factors  as  hunger,  physical  surround- 
ings, temperature,  and  the  presence  of  other  persons.  Most  psychologists 
regard  this  impulse  as  less  fundamental  than  the  drives  for  self-preserva- 
tion and  self-perpetuation.  But  some  students  of  conduct,  notably  the 
late  Dr.  Alfred  Adler,  believe  that  the  drive  for  self-expression  is  the 
most  important  of  the  vital  human  urges  and  that  its  frustration  is  the 
chief  cause  of  mental  and  nervous  instability. 

These  drives  arise  in  the  individual  independent  of  social  surroundings 
and  would  manifest  themselves  even  if  the  individual  lived  in  total  isola- 
tion. Under  normal  circumstances  they  are  sharply  conditioned  by  the 
fact  that  man  is  a  social  being  and  dwells  in  groups  made  up  of  other 
individuals  beset  by  the  same  urges.  We  have  already  noticed  how  man's 
capacity  for  self-preservation  has  been  enormously  strengthened  by  the 
fact  that  human  groups  are  far  stronger  than  the  isolated  individual,  who 
alone  is  no  match  for  many  other  members  of  the  animal  kingdom. 

Likewise,  the  drive  for  self -perpetuation  is  socially  conditioned.  The 
sex  impulses  are  capable  of  realization  only  in  the  company  of  a  person 

22 


A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS          23 

of  the  opposite  sex.  In  any  organized  society  one  is  limited  in  the  choice 
of  a  person  of  the  opposite  sex  by  social  institutions.  With  the  procrea- 
tion of  children,  a  family  group  arises  which  provides  an  immediate  social 
situation  and  a  new  form  of  social  control  over  the  drive  for  self-perpetua- 
tion. In  highly  developed  cultures  there  are  elaborate  forms  of  social 
conditioning  which  either  stimulate  or  discourage  the  drive  for  self-per- 
petuation, such  as  the  encouragement  of  population  growth  by  military 
dictators,  the  stimulation  of  sexual  activity  by  lascivious  entertainment, 
and  the  birth-control  programs  of  social  reformers. 

The  drive  to  self-expression  would  be  to  a  large  degree  meaningless, 
confused,  and  futile  unless  exercised  in  a  social  setting.  While  the  iso- 
lated individual  naturally  indulges  in  plenty  of  physical  action,  it  is 
obvious  that  the  more  normal  forms  of  self-expression  in  fighting,  work- 
ing, playing,  art,  and  music  all  require  a  social  setting  for  their  manifesta- 
tion. 

Therefore,  we  may  conclude  that  while  the  fundamental  human  drives 
are  biological,  arising  spontaneously  in  each  individual,  their  expres- 
sion is  carried  out  within  social  surroundings  and  they  are  compre- 
hensively controlled  by  the  codes  which  society  creates  for  its  guidance. 
They  may  be  regarded  as  the  dominant  forces  leading  to  social  life  and 
organization.  They  impel  man  to  action  to  meet  his  needs,  and  the 
resulting  action  leads  to  social  relationships  and  their  control  by  social 
codes  and  social  institutions. 

The  Human   Needs  That  Arise  from  the 
Basic  Drives 

The  evolution  of  society  may  be  regarded  as  an  ever  more  complicated 
and  efficient  effort  to  provide  for  the  satisfaction  of  the  needs  resulting 
from  the  basic  drives.  Out  of  the  drive  for  self-preservation  arises  the 
need  for  food,  clothing,  shelter,  and  health.  It  indirectly  but  very  potently 
produces  a  need  for  the  group  cooperation  which  is  essential  to  the 
preservation  of  human  beings  in  any  considerable  number  over  any  appre- 
ciable period  of  time.  Not  only  is  group  life  indispensable  as  a  means 
of  protection  against  powerful  animal  enemies  but  it  also  makes  possible 
a  more  efficient  provision  of  food,  clothing,  and  shelter.  Our  modern 
business  enterprise  is  basically  the  outcome  of  the  drive  for  self-preserva- 
tion. 

Sex  attraction,  romantic  love,  marriage,  affection  for  children,  filial 
devotion,  and  the  desire  to  provide  a  livelihood  for  members  of  the  family 
all  are  needs  growing  out  of  the  biological  urge  for  self-perpetuation.  In 
time,  more  complicated  needs  are  seen  to  arise  from  this  drive,  such  as 
those  for  social  control  over  sex  expression  and.  forms  of  family  life,  for 
population  policies,  whether  designed  to  increase  or  restrict  population 
growth,  and  for  eugenic  programs  to  stimulate  the  drive  to  self  perpetu- 
ation on  the  part  of  the  abler  members  of  society  and  to  restrict  it 
among  the  allegedly  lower  order  of  human  beings. 


24         A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

The  needs  that  grow  out  of  the  drive  for  self-expression  are  innumer- 
able Fighting  and  working  are  two  of  the  more  elemental.  There  is  no 
reason  for  believing  that  man  is  biologically  a  fighting  or  working  animal. 
But  physical  and  social  surroundings  have  impelled  him  to  fight  and,  so 
far,  only  the  favored  few  have  been  able  to  live  without  working.  Most 
fighting  is  now  a  cultural  anachronism,  though  we  still  fight  world  wars. 
And  if  we  apply  our  machinery  to  the  service  of  mankind  there  will  be 
less  need  for  extensive  work.  It  is  alleged  that  man  has  a  natural  "in- 
stinct of  workmanship."  If  this  be  so,  any  such  impulse  to  craftsmanship 
is  more  closely  related  to  art  than  to  labor. 

Less  fundamental  but  very  important  needs  arising  out  of  the  drive 
to  self-expression  are  those  for  play  and  for  artistic  and  musical  expres- 
sion. Even  animals  play,  and  there  is  every  reason  to  believe  that  man 
has  indulged  in  playful  activity  throughout  the  million  or  more  years  in 
which  he  has  existed.  The  play  need  expresses  itself  all  the  way  from 
the  informal  games  of  small  and  intimate  groups  to  the  commercialized 
sports  which  pack  one  hundred  thousand  persons  into  a  football  stadium 
or  pile  up  a  million-dollar  purse  for  a  championship  prizefight.  Away 
back  in  the  Old  Stone  Age  we  find  impressive  expressions  of  the  artistic 
urge  in  the  cave  paintings.  And  primitive  peoples  have  musical  instru- 
ments and  fairly  well  developed  types  of  musical  expression, 

The  quest  for  superiority  is  a  definite  outgrowth  of  the  drive  for  self- 
expression.  This  creates  a  need  on  the  part  of  some  to  assert  their 
dominion  over  others.  It  has  made  an  important  contribution  to  the 
origins  of  government  and  the  beginnings  of  warfare. 

Curiosity  seems  to  be  another  significant  outgrowth  of  the  drive  for 
self-expression.  Very  early,  man  began  to  raise  the  question  of  the  why 
and  the  wherefore  of  the  matters  he  observed  in  daily  life.  Religion 
gave  him  his  earliest  answer  by  suggesting  supernatural  causes.  In  due 
time,  some  men  doubted  this  explanation  and  sought  in  science  and 
philosophy  an  explanation  based  upon  natural  causes.  Religion,  science, 
and  the  conflicts  between  the  two  further  stimulated  the  growth  of 
philosophy.  Much  of  our  intellectual  life  has  thus  been\  created  and 
guided  by  the  curiosity  of  human  beings. 

Some  Outstanding   Human  Activities  and   Interests 
That  Grow  Out  of  Basic  Human  Needs 

'  Mankind  is  definitely  conditioned  by  the  physical  environment  which 
he  inhabits.  On  the  one  hand,  there  is  a  great  deal  of  passive  adaptation 
to  the  environment  as  man  finds  it.  '  In  warm  climates  he  wears  little 
clothing  and  in  cold  climates  he  puts  on  much  of  it.  In  the  more  rudi- 
mentary forms  of  culture  the  reaction  of  man  to  the  physical  environment 
was  mainly  one  of  passive  adaptation.  *  As  civilization  progressed,  man 
was  able,  more  and  more,  to  subdue  nature  to  his  needs.  He  learned  to 
domesticate  animals,  clear  ground,  raise  crops,  thus  bringing  into  existence 
agriculture — one  of  the  greatest  steps  ever  taken  by  man  in  exploiting 


A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS          25 

nature  for  the  benefit  of  humanity.  Still  later,  through  science  and 
technology  man  learned  to  dig  for  minerals  and  create  a  metal  culture. 
Man  discovered  how  to  produce  and  utilize  steam  power  and,  later,  elec- 
tricity. This  not  only  increased  his  capacity  to  exploit  nature  for  food, 
clothing,  and  shelter,  but  also  enabled  him  to  travel  and  communicate  ever 
more  rapidly  and  over  greater  space.  Physical  features  like  seas  and 
oceans,  which  were  once  insuperable  barriers,  became  agencies  for  more 
facile  transportation.  Airplanes  enabled  man  to  soar  easily  over  moun- 
tain ranges  that  had  earlier  defied  human  transit. 

/  The  bounty  and  operations  of  nature  have  also  stimulated  other  forms 
of  human  activity.  Most  earlier  forms  of  religion  were  based  upon  wor- 
ship .and  ritual  connected  with  life  and  death,  and  the  growth  and  decay 
of  vegetation.  Natural  features,  such  as  the  heavenly  bodies,  mountains, 
deserts,  rivers,  seas,  springs,  and  forests  contributed  their  quota  of  gods 
and  spirits.  Natural  cataclysms,  such  as  volcanic  eruptions,  earthquakes, 
tidal  waves,  floods,  hurricanes,  and  fires  promoted  the  growth  of  religion 
and  superstition.  In  later  days,  they  stimulated  cooperative  activities 
in  repairing  the  damage  done  and,  when  possible,  in  preventing  its  recur- 
rence. The  beauties  of  nature  encouraged  travel  and  made  an  important 
contribution  to  recreational  activities.  Very  recently  in  human  experi- 
ence, man  has  discovered  the  folly  of  unnecessary  waste  in  exploiting 
nature  and  has  launched  impressive  campaigns  for  the  conservation  and 
replacement  of  natural  resources. K 

-  The  need  for  health  and  physical  well-being  has  given  rise  to  a  large 
number  of  activities.*  Man  has  sought  to  discover  the  cause  of  illness. 
The  search  for  the  answer  to  this  problem  has  led  from  superstition 
and  magic  to  the  rise  of  medical  science.  *  For  thousands  of  years,  man 
has  sought  to  mitigate  the  suffering  incident  to  sickness,  and  to  restore 
health.  This  has  produced  activities  ranging  from  the  incantations  of 
the  primitive  medicine  man  to  the  systematized  medical  practice  of  the 
Mayo  clinic  and  great  urban  health  centers.  In  our  day,  the  activities 
related  to  illness  and  the  search  for  good  health  cost  over  four  billion 
dollars  a  year  in  the  United  States  alone. 

Closely  related  to  medical  practice,  and  hospital  care  are  sanitary 
engineering  and  public  health  activities,  which  have  given  us  our  supplies 
of  pure  water  for  cities,  sewage  disposal,  garbage  removal,  and  innumer- 
able other  activities  reducing  the  likelihood  of  infection  and  the  spread 
of  disease.  Health  education  and  safety  education  occupy  the  time  of 
thousands.  Child-saving  institutions  are  numerous,  although  their  work 
is  expensive.  Many  scholars  devote  their  attention  to  the  departments 
of  health,  medical  research,  the  study  of  population  trends,  and  other 
matters  directly  related  to  health  and  reproduction. 

The  task  of  earning  a  living  has  produced  more  human  activity  than 
any. other  fundamental  need.  Indeed,  mankind  has  spent  most  of  its 
time  thus  far  in  quest  of  a  living. '  Man's  search  for  food,  clothing,  and 
shelter  has  given  rise  to  the  pastoral  industry,  to  agriculture,  and  manu- 
facturing. In  order  to  distribute  the  food  and  goods  thus  produced. 


26         A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

markets  have  come  into  being  and  great  stores  have  been  constructed. 
A  medium  of  exchange  has  been  produced  to  facilitate  the  exchange  of 
goods,  and  a  banking  and  credit  system  has  been  built  up." 

The  problem  of  how  to  get  man  to  work  has  occupied  the  attention  of 
many,  from  the  days  of  slave  labor  to  the  modern  factory  and  labor 
unions.  ^The  need  for  training  persons  to  produce  more  effectively  has 
given  birth  to  scientific,  technical,  and  vocational  education.'  The  prob- 
lems connected  with  industry,  trade,  and  banking  have  been  the  major 
causes  of  the  evolution  of  government  and  law.  Indeed,  the  government 
is  assuming  ever  greater  control  over  every  phase  of  economic  life.  Many 
persons  are,  for  various  reasons,  unable  to  make  a  living  and  billions  of 
dollars  are  spent  each  year  on  the  care  of  the  indigent  and  helpless. 

The  accumulation,  protection,  and  transfer  of  property,  incidental  to 
making  a  living  and  piling  up  wealth,  call  forth  activities  on  the  part 
of  numerous  bankers,  lawyers,  and  related  professional  men. 

A  variety  of  human  needs  have  contributed  to  the  desire  for  more  effec- 
tive transportation  and  communication.  Trade  has  been  one  of  these. 
Man  has  desired  to  widen  the  opportunity  for  the  accumulation  of  raw 
materials  and  the  distribution  of  finished  products.  War  has  been  an- 
other stimulant  to  better  transportation.  Emperors,  kings  and  generals 
have  wished  to  move  their  troops  more  rapidly  and  over  greater  distances. 
Government  has  promoted  the  growth  of  transportation.  When  large 
states  were  created,  it  was  necessary  for  representatives  of  the  central 
government  to  move  rapidly  over  the  domain.  One  of  the  chief  reasons 
for  the  fall  of  the  Roman  Empire  was  the  inadequate  technique  of  trans- 
portation and  communication  for  administration  over  so  vast  an  area. 
Travel,  curiosity,  and  recreation  have  also  prompted  the  effort  to  secure 
more  efficient  methods  of  transportation. 

These  demands  for  better  transportation  have  given  rise  to  innumerable 
activities  and  achievements.  The  wheeled  vehicle  has  moved  ahead  from 
the  ox-cart  to  the  streamlined  train  of  our  day.  Water  transport  has 
progressed  from  primitive  rafts  to  great  liners  like  the  Queen  Mary. 
More  recently,  man  has  been  able  to  leave  the  land  and  water  altogether 
•and  to  soar  through  the  air  more  speedily  and  over  ever  greater  distances. 
The  routes  of  travel  have  made  headway  from  pathways  through  primor- 
dial forests  and  marshes  to  six-lane  concrete  highways,  four-track  rail- 
roads, and  ship  canals.  All  of  these  phases  of  transportation  have  pro- 
vided labor  for  an  ever  greater  number  of  scientists,  technicians,  me- 
chanics, and  laborers,  and  have  served  an  ever  larger  body  of  persons. 

In  order  to  facilitate  group  cooperation  and  the  exchange  of  ideas, 
man  found  it  necessary  to  provide  effective  methods  of  communication. 
First,  he  worked  out  a  language,  which  for  many  thousands  of  years  was 
purely  a  spoken  tongue.  Some  four  thousand  years  ago,  he  devised  an 
alphabet  which  made  possible  a  written  language.  The  mastery  of  the 
art  of  writing  gave  us  books,  periodicals,  and  newspapers.  These  required 
the  creation  of  libraries  for  the  collection  and  preservation  of  literary 
products,*  These  facilities  for  communication  enabled  man  to  create  a 


A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS          27 

cultural  heritage — a  civilization  based  on  verbal  symbols,  that  could  be 
handed  down  from  generation  to  generation.  This  is  one  of  the  outstand- 
ing achievements  in  which  man  is  superior  to  the  other  animals. 

The  growth  of  steam  power  and  electricity  made  possible  ever  more 
rapid  transmission  of  information.  The  national  postal  services  system- 
atized this  communication.  Newspapers  provided  for  rapid  collection 
and  distribution  of  news  items.  The  telegraph,  exploiting  electrical 
power,  transmitted  words  more  rapidly  than  steam  would  permit.  More 
recently,  the  telephone  and  the  radio  have  made  possible  the  instanta- 
neous transmission  of  spoken  words.  The  movies  have  revolutionized 
methods  of  visual  communication.  Space  and  time  have  been  all  but 
eliminated  in  contemporary  communication. 

Various  political  and  social  forces  have  sought  to  control,  select,  or 
censor  the  information  communicated  over  the  new  facilities,  thus  raising 
the  problems  of  censorship  and  propaganda.  Many  are  engaged  in  fur- 
thering bbth  of  these,  while  others  are  battling  against  such  influences 
and  seeking  to  keep  the  freedom  of  communication  unimpaired. 

The  needs  connected  with  sex,  the  family,  and  the  home  have  given 
rise  to  a  wide  variety  of  activities.  Love  and  courtship  produce  many 
activities  expressing  amorosity,  display,  and  affection.  The  institution 
of  marriage  requires  the  activities  of  those  connected  with  religion  and 
the  law.  Homes  create  problems  of  architecture  and  housing.  The  ne- 
cessity of  providing  a  livelihood  for  the  family  leads  to  innumerable  forms 
of  industrial  and  professional  effort.  The  rearing  of  a  family  calls  forth 
many  activities  of  an  educational,  religious,  and  cultural  character.  The 
school,  the  church,  recreational  facilities  and  those  connected  with  art 
and  music  are  all  involved  here. 

Families  lead  to  neighborhoods  and  communities,  and  the  cooperative 
activities  natural  thereunto,  such  as  exchange  of  work  and  services,  edu- 
cational efforts,  community  organization,  religion,  and  recreation.  In 
modern  urban  life  the  activities  within  the  family  are  being  reduced  and 
the  responsibility  for  substitute  activities  is  being  assumed  more  and 
more  by  the  community. 

Probably  the  most  extensive  human  activities,  next  to  the  activities 
which  grow  out  of  making  a  living  and  rearing  a  family,  are  associated 
with  government.  These  run  all  the  way  from  the  government  of  a  rural 
township  to  the  administration  of  the  British  Empire.  We  have  town, 
county,  city,  state,  national,  and  colonial  governments.  As  civilization 
becomes  more  complex,  there  are  more  and  more  social  relations  which 
the  government  has  to  regulate.  As  a  result,  ever  more  people  are  em- 
ployed in  various  forms  of  government  activity;  and  the  cost  becomes 
ever  greater.  In  the  United  States  there  are  over  a  million  persons 
on  the  Federal  pay  roll  alone,  and  in  1932  the  total  cost  of  all  govern- 
mental agencies,  federal,  state  and  local,  was  fourteen  billion  dollars.  It 
has  increased  considerably  since  that  time — to  eighteen  billions  in  1938, 
and  to  astronomical  figures  since  1941. 

An  important  phase  of  governmental  responsibility  is  that  connected 


28         A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

with  law  and  order,  and  the  prevention  of  crime.  It  has  been  estimated 
that  the  depredations  of  criminals  and  racketeers  cost  at  least  five  billion 
dollars  a  year,  and  that  the  money  spent  on  various  forms  of  gambling 
is  at  least  that  large.  The  cost  of  apprehending,  convicting,  and  impris- 
oning criminals  runs  into  the  billions  each  year  in  this  country. 

Another  form  of  governmental  activity  which  employs  a  vast  personnel 
is  that  related  to  armament  and  war.  In  Europe,  in  recent  years,  mil- 
lions have  been  employed  directly  in  war  and  the  munitions  trade,  and 
the  United  States  is  now  following  rapidly  in  the  footsteps  of  Europe — 
indeed,  far  outdoing  Europe  in  armament  production.  Even  under  nor- 
mal conditions,  over  two  thirds  of  our  total  Federal  expenditures  go  to 
paying  for  wars  past,  present,  and  future.  The  proposed  expenditures  for 
armament  in  1941-1942  far  exceed  the  total  cost  of  eight  years  of  the 
New  Deal. 

We  may  now  consider  the  wide  range  of  activities  which  grow  out  of 
the  drive  for  self-expression.  Outstanding  is  the  matter  of  play  and 
recreation.  This  has  been  important  since  primitive  times,  but  it  was 
first  systematized  on  a  large  scale  in  the  games  of  the  Greeks  and  in  the 
"bread-and-circus"  program  of  the  Roman  Empire.  The  development 
of  informal  recreation,  supervised  play,  and  commercial  sports  in  the 
twentieth  century  has  become  so  extensive  that  in  the  United  States  alone 
about  ten  billion  dollars  are  spent  each  year  upon  it.  The  automobile 
has  contributed  more  than  anything  else  to  the  recent  increase  of  recrea- 
tional activities  and  the  cost  thereof.  Recreation  provides  activity  not 
only  for  those  who  participate,  but  also  for  those  who  supervise  play, 
construct  the  buildings  and  other  equipment  in  which  it  is  carried  on, 
manufacture  various  forms  of  pleasure  vehicles,  conduct  the  moving- 
picture  industry,  the  radio  industry,  cabarets,  nightclubs,  and  resort 
hotels. 

A  more  refined  use  of  leisure  time  are  the  many  forms  of  self-expression 
manifested  in  art  and  music.  The  activities  connected  with  the  arts 
have  increased  greatly.  What  was  once  a  luxury  of  the  few  is  now  com- 
ing to  be  cultivated  by  the  many.  Art  and  music  have  been  promoted 
•for  propaganda  purposes  by  the  totalitarian  states,  and  in  this  country 
the  New  Deal  subsidized  a  good  deal  of  artistic  development  to  provide 
employment.  The  deliberate  cultivation  of  community  activities  has 
also  contributed  notably  to  the  popularization  of  art  and  music.  We 
have  community  singing,  dancing,  and  art  exhibitions.  The  movies  have 
done  something  to  popularize  art,  and  the  radio  has  done  a  great  deal  to 
popularize  music.  Both  art  and  music  are  being  extensively  promoted 
through  education.  There  has  been  a  great  increase  in  the  number  of 
art  museums,  with  a  capital  invested  in  the  United  States  now  exceeding 
75  million  dollars.  The  art  collections  housed  therein  are  valued  at  over 
a  billion  dollars.  Both  public  and  private  architecture  are  constructed 
with  an  eye  to  beauty  as  well  as  sheer  utility. 

Curiosity,  as  a  product  of  the  drive  of  self-expression,  manifests  itself 
through  the  diverse  activities  associated  with  religion,  science,  and 


A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS          29 

philosophy.  Not  only  do  we  have  the  activities  directly  connected  with 
the  worship  and  maintenance  of  church  institutions,  but  the  church  also 
carries  on  many  activities  only  indirectly  connected  with  worship,  such 
as  missionary  enterprise,  medical  missions,  various  forms  of  social  and 
community  service,  and  art.  The  total  cost  of  religious  activities  runs 
into  the  billions  of  dollars  each  year. 

Science,  which  was  the  amusement  of  a  few  amateurs  only  two  or  three 
centuries  ago,  has  become  a  major  enterprise  of  the  human  race.  Many 
thousands  of  persons  are  engaged  in  scientific  activities,  the  cost  of  which 
certainly  amounts  to  hundreds  of  millions  of  dollars  yearly.  Applied 
science  or  technology  provides  even  greater  activity  and  enterprise  and 
lies  at  the  basis  of  modern  industrial  life. 

As  a  result  of  the  various  drives,  needs,  and  activities,  the  human  race 
has  built  up  an  elaborate  social  heritage,  made  up  of  beliefs,  customs, 
ideas,  and  institutions.  These  are  cherished  by  society,  which  desires  to 
transmit  them  from  one  generation  to  another.  This  has  led  to  the 
development  of  extensive  educational  activities. 

Social    Institutions:  The  Machinery  Through 
Which  Society  Carries  On   Its  Activities 

The  complexity  of  modern  life  has  been  produced  by  the  desire  to 
satisfy  the  needs  growing  out  of  the  fundamental  drives  for  self-preserva- 
tion, self -perpetuation,  and  self-expression.  It  is  obvious  that  society 
could  not  carry  on  without  some  organized  effort  and  direction  for  its 
varied  activities.  This  is  supplied  by  social  institutions,  which  represent 
the  social  structure  and  machinery  through  which  human  society  organ- 
izes, directs,  and  executes  the  multifarious  activities  required  to  satisfy 
human  needs.  Walton  H.  Hamilton  has  provided  us  with  a  comprehen- 
sive definition  of  social  institutions: 

Institution  is  a  verbal  symbol  which,  for  want  of  a  better  word,  describes  a 
cluster  of  social  usages.  It  connotes  a  way  of  thought  or  action  of  some  prev- 
alence and  permanence,  which  is  embedded  in  the  habits ,  of  a  group  or  the 
customs  of  a  people.  .  .  .  Institutions  fix  the  confines  of  and  impose  form 
upon  the  activities  of  human  beings.  The  world  of  use  and  wont,  to  which  we 
imperfectly  accommodate  pur  lives,  is  a  tangled  and  unbroken  web  of  institutions. 
The  range  of  institutions  is  as  wide  as  the  interests  of  mankind.  .  .  .  Arrange- 
ments as  diverse  as  the  money  economy,  classical  education,  the  chain  store, 
fundamentalism  and  democracy  are  institutions.  They  may  be  rigid  or  flexible 
in  their  structures,  exacting  or  lenient  in  their  demands ;  but  alike  they  constitute 
standards  of  conformity  from  which  an  individual  may  depart  only  at  his  peril. 
About  every  urge  of  mankind  an  institution  grows  up;  the  expression  of  every 
taste  and  capacity  is  crowded  into  an  institutional  mold.1 

In  the  beginning,  human  institutions  were  in  no  sense  the  product  of 
any  deliberate  effort.  Man  spontaneously  expresses  his  impulses  in  liv- 


1  Article,  "Institution,"  Encyclopedia  of  the  Social  Sciences,'  Macmillan,  Vol.  8,  p.  84. 


30          A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

ing.  In  doing  so  he  develops  definite  customs  and  social  habits  which 
seem  to.  work  and  are  repeated.  In  due  time  they  become  sanctified  and 
generally  a  divine  origin  is  attributed  to  them  by  early  man: 

Social  institutions  are  simply  social  habits  which  are  systematized,  instituted 
or  established  by  groups,  and  have  still  stronger  sanctions  attached  to  them  than 
do  simple  customs.  They  carry  a  step  further  the  establishment  of  the  social 
habit  through  the  exercise  of  authority  or  compulsion  on  the  part  of  a  group.  .  .  . 

Institutions  may  be  defined  as  habitual  ways  of  living  together  which  have  been 
sanctioned,  systematized,  and  established  by  the  authority  of  communities.2 

It  is  appropriate  and  desirable  to  summarize  concisely  at  this  point  the  essen- 
tial nature  of  a  social  institution.  A  social  institution  is  a  complex  of  concepts 
and  attitudes  regarding  the  ordering  of  a  particular  class  of  unavoidable  or  indis- 
pensable human  relationships  that  are  involved  in  satisfying  certain  elemental 
individual  wants,  certain  compelling  social  needs,  or  other  eminently  desirable 
social  ends.  The  concepts  and  attitudes  are  condensed  into  mores,  customs, 
traditions  and  codes.  Individually,  the  institution  takes  the  form  of  habits 
approved  and  conditioned  in  the  individual  by  the  group;  socially  it  is  a  struc- 
ture, evidencing  itself  in  standardized  and  ordered  relationships  and  often  finding 
additional  functional  effectiveness  through  associations,  organizations,  and  physi- 
cal extensions.8 

We  may  now  consider  in  a  little  more  detail  how  institutions  arise.  We 
have  seen  how  man's  basic  drives  and  needs  impel  him  to  action  and  ex- 
pression. At  first,  he  operated  in  a  natural  or  "trial-and-error"  manner. 
If  these  methods  were  efficient  enough  to  preserve  and  perpetuate  life, 
they  were  accepted  by  the  group  and  passed  on  from  generation  to  genera- 
tion. In  other  words,  they  became  social  habits,  or  what  sociologists  call 
"folkways."  As  the  folkways  persist,  they  grow  in  fixity,  prestige,  and 
power.  When  folkways  become  compulsory,  and  departure  brings  group 
censure  and,  at  times,  severe  punishment,  they  have  developed  into 
"customs."  Although  customs  are  a  powerful  control  over  man  and  his 
behavior,  they  are  usually  unconscious  in  their  operation.  It  is  taken  for 
granted  that  they  are  right.  In  time,  certain  customs  become  the  object 
of  rational  thought  and  are  judged  the  best  form  of  conduct  known  in 
meeting  a  particular  need.  Such  customs  are  known  as  "mores."  When 
definite  rules,  regulations,  codes,  and  social  structures  are  created  to 
enforce  and  perpetuate  the  mores,  they  become  institutions.  As  Professor 
J.  0.  Hertzler  puts  it: 

When  interests,  ideas,  sentiments  and  beliefs,  in  the  form  of  folkways,  customs, 
conventions,  rights,  and  mores,  appear  in  more  coherent  and  rational  forms,  as 
precipitated  types  of  social  procedure  or  more  or  less  definitely  organized  struc- 
tures for  regulating  the  intercourse  between  the  members  of  social  groups,  they 
become  institutions.4 


2C.  A.  Ellwood,  The  Psychology  of  Human  Society,  Appleton-Century,  1925,  pp. 
90-91. 

s  J.  0.  Hertzler,  Social  Institutions,  McGraw-Hill,  1929,  pp.  67-68. 
*lbid.f  p.  108. 


A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS          31 

Perhaps  the  best  summary  which  has  ever  been  given  on  the  develop- 
ment of  institutions  is  that  set  forth  by  William  Graham  Sumner  in  his 
important  work  on  Folkways: 

Men  in  groups  are  under  life  conditions;  they  have  needs  which  are  similar 
under  the  state  of  the  life  conditions ;  the  relations  of  the  needs  to  the  conditions 
are  interests  under  the  heads  of  hunger,  love,  vanity,  and  fear;  efforts  of  num- 
bers at  the  same  time  to  satisfy  interests  produce  mass  phenomena  which  are 
folkways  by  virtue  of  uniformity,  repetition,  and  wide  concurrence.  The  folk- 
ways are  attended  by  pleasure  or  pain  according  as  they  are  well  fitted  for  the 
purpose.  Pain  forces  reflection  and  observation  of  some  relation  between  acts 
and  welfare.  At  this  point  the  prevailing  world  philosophy  suggests  explanations 
and  inferences,  which  become  entangled  with  judgments  of  expediency.  How- 
ever, the  folkways  take  on  a  philosophy  of  right  living  and  life  policy  for  wel- 
fare. .  .  .  When  the  elements  of  truth  and  right  are  developed  into  doctrines 
of  welfare,  the  folkways  are  raised  to  another  plane.  They  then  become  capable 
of  producing  inferences,  developing  into  new  forms,  and  extending  their  con- 
structive influences  over  men  and  society.  Then  we  call  them  the  mores.  The 
mores  are  the  folkways,  including  the  philosophical  and  ethical  generalizations 
as  to  societal  welfare  which  are  suggested  by  them,  and  inherent  in  them,  as 
they  grow.  .  .  .  They  are  the  ways  of  doing  things  which  are  current  in  a  society 
to  satisfy  human  needs  and  desires,  together  with  the  faiths,  notions,  codes,  and 
standards  of  well-living  which  inhere  in  those  ways,  having  a  genetic  connection 
with  them.  By  virtue  of  the  latter  element  the  mores  are  traits  in  the  specific 
character  of  a  society  or  a  period.  They  pervade  and  control  the  ways  of  think- 
ing in  all  the  exigencies  of  life,  returning  from  the  world  of  abstractions  to  the 
svorld  of  action,  to  give  guidance  and  to  win  revivification.  ...  At  every  turn 
we  find  new  evidence  that  the  mores  can  make  anything  right.  What  they  do 
is  that  they  cover  a  usage  in  dress,  language,  behavior,  manners,  etc.,  with  the 
mantle  of  current  custom,  and  give  it  regulation  and  limits  within  which  it  be- 
comes unquestionable.  The  limit  is  generally  a  limit  of  toleration.  .  .  .  The 
most  important  fact  about  the  mores  is  their  dominion  over  the  individual. 
Arising  he  knows  not  whence  or  how,  they  meet  his  opening  mind  in  earliest 
childhood,  give  him  his  outfit  of  ideas,  faiths,  and  tastes,  and  lead  him  into 
prescribed  mental  processes.  They  bring  to  him  codes  of  action,  standards,  and 
rules  of  ethics.  They  have  a  model  of  the  man-as-he-should-be  to  which  they 
mould  him,  in  spite  of  himself  and  without  his  knowledge.  If  he  submits  and 
consents,  he  is  taken  up  and  may  attain  great  social  success.  If  he  resists  and 
dissents,  he  is  thrown  out  and  may  be  trodden  under  foot.  The  mores  are 
therefore  an  engine  of  social  selection.  Their  coercion  of  the  individual  is  .the 
mode  in  which  they  operate  the  selection.  .  .  .  Property,  marriage,  and  religion 
are  the  most  primary  institutions.  They  began  in  folkways.  They  became  cus- 
toms! They  developed  into  mores  by  the  addition  of  some  philosophy  of  welfare, 
however  crude.  Then  they  were  made  more  definite  and  specific  as  regards  the 
rules,  the  prescribed  acts,  and  the  apparatus  to  be  employed.  This  produced 
a  structure  and  the  institution  was  complete.  .  .  .5 

Primary  and  Secondary  Institutions 

The  fundamental  or  primary  institutions  are  elemental  and  sponta- 
neous in  their  origin  and  development,  following  the  process  so  well  de- 
scribed by  Sumner.  Such  are  institutions  like  the  family,  property,  basic 
occupations,  government,  or  war.  As  civilization  develops,  secondary 
institutions  of  a  deliberate  character  arise.  These  usually  are  subordi- 


6  W.  G.  Sumner,  Folkways,  Ginn,  1907.  pp.  30,  32-34,  54,  59,  97-98,  173-174,  521-522. 


32          A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

nate  institutions  within  the  larger  field  of  primary  institutions.  For 
example,  government  is  a  primary  institution  which  has  evolved  sponta- 
neously. But  a  republic  is  a  deliberate  form  of  government  and  a 
secondary  institution.  Property  is  a  primary  institution  with  a  long 
evolutionary  heritage,  while  an  inheritance  tax  is  a  secondary  institution. 
As  stated  by  Professor  Hertzler,  "Every  operative  and  controlling  activity 
of  a  given  society  takes  place  through  institutions  ranging  from  those 
which  satisfy  vital  and  permanent  needs  to  those  relatively  superficial 
and  transitory."6 

Only  recently  has  mankind  approached  primary  institutions  in  a 
rational  fashion,  and  then  incompletely  and  imperfectly.  They  are  far 
more  important  than  the  secondary  institutions,  although  the  latter  are 
much  more  numerous  in  our  day.  Let  us  review  some  of  the  more  im- 
portant of  our  primary  institutions. 

Very  basic  are  those  connected  with  industry,  for  a  large  portion  of 
mankind  is  dependent  upon  it  for  existence.  Industrial  activities  have 
been  institutionalized  under  various  forms.  The  earliest  type  of  organ- 
ization was  provided  by  the  family.  Slavery  constituted  another  widely 
institutionalized  form  of  industrial  effort,  especially  in  antiquity.  The 
gild  system  of  the  Middle  Ages  was  followed  by  the  putting-out  system, 
and  then  by  capitalistic  institutions.  Agriculture  and  trade,  in  the 
course  of  their  evolution,  have  also  provided  many  forms  of  institutions 
within  the  framework  of  industrial  effort. 

Industrial  effort  and  war  have  combined  to  create  the  institution  of 
property,  which  at  first  was  mainly  though  not  exclusively  communal, 
and  has  since  become  increasingly  personal  and  private.  There  have 
been  varied  ways  of  transmitting  property,  an  interesting  example  being 
the  system  of  primogeniture  under  which  the  eldest  son  inherits  the  prop- 
erty, at  least  the  landed  property,  of  his  father.  So  important  and  cher- 
ished an  institution  is  private  property  today  that  other  institutions,  such 
as  industry,  law,  ethics,  and  education,  are  in  large  part  devoted  to  pro- 
ducing, protecting,  and  perpetuating  private  property. 

The  primary  institution  growing  out  of  the  drive  for  self-perpetuation 
and  the  sexual  needs  arising  therefrom  has  been  the  family,  which  has 
been  organized  through  monogamy,  or  the  marriage  of  one  man  and  one 
woman,  through  polyandry,  the  marriage  of  one  woman  to  a  number  of 
men,  or  through  polygyny  (usually  known  as  polygamy),  the  marriage  of 
one  man  to  a  number  of  women.  Though  an  institution  existing  for 
the  purpose  of  procreation,  the  family  has  often  contributed  to  other 
types  of  institutional  activities,  especially  those  associated  with  industry, 
religion,  and  education.  Another  institution  growing  out  of  the  sexual 
needs  of  man  has  been  prostitution,  which  was  accepted  and  approved, 
even  sanctified,  in  earlier  periods  of  history.  Today  it  is  in  ill-repute  in 
most  countries  of  the  west  and  no  longer  enjoys  its  institutional  prestige. 

The  need  for  social  cooperation  has  produced  the  many  and  diverse 


«Hert*ler>  Social  InMrtions,  McGraw-Hill,  1929,  pp,  67-68. 


A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS          33 

institutions  associated  with  group  life.  These  include  the  family,  the 
neighborhood  group,  the  community  organization,  the  state  and  govern- 
ment, law  and  the  courts,  and  ethics  or  codes  of  right  and  wrong  conduct 

At  the  outset  a  private  or  personal  affair,  war  has  become  so  thoroughly 
institutionalized  that  we  have  a  definite  law  of  war  and  accepted  usages 
associated  with  war.  Peacetime  relations  among  nations  are  conductcc 
through  diplomacy,  which  has  become  a  leading  public  institution.  At- 
tempts are  made  to  avert  war  through  such  institutions  as  arbitration 
The  relations  among  groups  have  given  rise  to  various  other  institution- 
alized forms  of  behavior.  Many  of  these  are  provided  by  attempts  tc 
further  and  control  trade,  such  as  the  institutions  associated  with  inter- 
national exchange,  tariffs,  and  trade  laws. 

The  need  to  travel  from  place  to  place  has  brought  about  many  insti- 
tutional safeguards.  Travelers  have  certain  rights  which  are  accepted 
among  civilized  states.  The  passport  is  a  form  of  secondary  institution 
which  illustrates  this  matter.  Neutrals  in  foreign  states  have  recognized 
rights,  and  there  are  well-established  practices  governing  the  control  oi 
trains  and  ships. 

Communication  has  been  widely  institutionalized.  Fundamental  here 
is  the  institution  of  language.  The  whole  body  of  learning,  including 
literature,  art,  science,  and  philosophy,  represents  an  institutionalized 
accumulation  of  the  methods  and  results  of  communication  throughout 
history. 

The  activities  growing  out  of  human  curiosity  have  been  given  insti- 
tutional guidance  and  protection.  Indeed,  religion  is  one  of  the  funda- 
mental primary  institutions.  At  one  time  it  exerted  a  vast  influence  over 
most  other  institutions,  such  as  industry,  the  family,  the  state,  and  ethics. 
It  still  has  an  influence  far  wider  than  the  field  of  worship.  Within  the 
fundamental  religious  institution  as  a  whole  there  have  been  specialized 
forms  of  institutionalized  religious  activity,  as  exemplified  by  the  several 
great  world  religions.  And  within  each  of  these  there  are  innumerable 
secondary  institutions  such  as  conversion,  baptism,  and  various  sacra- 
ments. 

Science  is  not  a  fundamental  institution  like  religion,  since  it  has  a 
very  recent  origin,  but  it  includes  many  forms  of  secondary,  or  rational, 
institutionalized  expression  which  govern  research  and  the  distribution 
and  acceptance  of  scientific  discoveries.  Applied  science,  or  technology, 
is  well  institutionalized  by  the  laws  and  usages  associated  with  inventions 
and  patent  rights. 

Play,  sports,  and  recreation,  while  producing  no  primary  institutions, 
have  plenty  of  secondary  institutional  expression,  especially  since  the 
rise  of  supervised  play  and  commercial  recreation.  The  playground  is 
one  of  the  major  institutions  of  contemporary  urban  life.  Art  and 
music  are  not  lacking  in  institutional  framework. 

Education  is  an  institution  with  a  long  background,  but  it  has  become 
especially  formidable  and  imposing  in  our  day.  Education  has  the  inter- 
esting institutional  function  of  preserving  and  transmitting  the  other 


34         A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

institutions.  More  and  more,  educators  and  reformers  are  suggesting 
that  education  should  not  blindly  transmit  the  total  social  heritage  but 
should  criticize  and  select  from  it,  rejecting  that  which  is  obviously  out- 
worn and  erroneous.  But,  thus  far,  this  critical  and  selective  function 
of  education  has  been  primarily  a  dream. 

Most  of  the  primary  institutions  have  been  mentioned,  but  the  second- 
ary institutions  growing  out  of  these  are  almost  without  number.  Take, 
for  example,  the  primary  institution  of  government.  There  are  three 
fundamental  forms  of  government,  even  in  modern  times — monarchy, 
aristocracy,  and  democracy.  Within  democracy,  there  are  usually  three 
branches  of  government— executive,  legislative,  and  judicial.  The  or- 
ganization of  each  of  these  branches  may  differ  widely  in  character,  but 
each  variety  has  become  an  institution  where  it  exists.  Democracies  are 
usually  run  by  parties,  but  these  may  represent  a  two-party  system  or  a 
group  system.  Candidates  may  be  nominated  by  caucuses  or  direct  pri- 
maries. They  may  be  elected  directly  or  indirectly,  by  popular  vote, 
or  the  decision  of  special  bodies.  The  legislature  may  have  three  houses, 
two  houses,  or  one  house.  Some  democracies  may  be  conducted  on  a  civil 
service  basis,  and  others  be  wholly  devoted  to  the  spoils  system.  In  some 
countries  judges  are  elected,  and  in  others  they  are  appointed.  Some 
democracies  are  conservative,  while  others  are  radical  and  make  use  of 
the  initiative,  the  referendum,  and  recall.  But  all  these  expressions  of 
democratic  government — caucuses,  primaries,  parties,  and  the  referendum 
— are  secondary  institutions  which  spawn  from  the  parent  institution  of 
government. 

The  same  primary  institutions  exist  among  all  peoples  at  any  given 
level  of  civilization;  that  is,  all  have  industrial  institutions,  property, 
families,  government,  religion,  and  education.  This  basic  uniformity  is 
explained  by  the  fact  that  mankind  constitutes  only  one  animal  species 
and  all  men  are  fundamentally  alike  in  their  physical  makeup.  Hence 
they  manifest  the  same  basic  drives  for  self-preservation,  self-perpetua- 
tion, and  self-expression.  In  other  words,  the  human  factor  is  a  constant, 
whether  found  among  the  Hottentots  or  the  Eskimo.  The  fundamental 
needs  which  arise  out  of  these  basic  drives  are  correspondingly  similar. 
The  urges  to  self-expression  on  the  part  of  human  beings  have  a  broad 
uniformity.  And  the  physical  weakness  of  man,  the  same  everywhere, 
has  led  him  to  collect  with  others  in  group  life: 

Both  men  and  their  life-conditions  are  pretty  much  alike;  there  is  a  general 
similarity  between  the  expedients  adopted  for  the  realization  of  interests  in  all 
places  and  times.  They  have  a  family  likeness.  They  all  reflect  the  inveterate 
conditions  of  life  on  earth.7 

While  this  uniformity  may  be  observed  in  the  few  basic  institutions  of 
mankind,  diversity  is  the  rule  with  respect  to  their  special  manifestations 
taken  on  in  time  and  space. 

All  peoples  are  governed  in  one  way  or  another  but  the  methods  which 

7  W.  G.  Sumner  and  A.  G.  Keller,  The  Science  of  Society,  4  Vols.  Yale  University 
Press,  1927,  Vol.  I,  p.  29. 


A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS          35 

are  utilized  to  achieve  government  are  extremely  diversified.  So  it  is 
with  every  other  form  of  human  institutions.  All  people  normally  marry 
and  raise  children  but  the  institutions  and  practices  associated  with  love, 
courtship,  marriage,  and  the  status  and  responsibility  of  the  sexes  differ 
in  a  most  impressive  manner.  One  can  only  grasp  the  real  extent  of  this 
diversity  by  reading  such  a  book  as  Sumner's  Folkways. 

But  there  is  one  uniformity  to  be  observed  in  all  this  diversity.  This 
is  the  fact  that  everywhere  people  believe  that  their  particular  institu- 
tions are  the  right  ones  and  the  best  ones.  In  most  places,  even  yet,  the 
majority  of  the  people  regard  their  institutions  as  being  of  divine  origin. 
This  is  even  true  of  the  attitude  of  the  people  of  the  United  States  towards 
the  Constitution,  which  was  made  as  recently  as  the  late  eighteenth  cen- 
tury by  men  who  deliberately  voted  in  the  Constitutional  Convention  to 
keep  the  name  of  God  out  of  the  Constitution. 

Institutions  and  Social   Efficiency 

We  have  pointed  out  how  institutions  develop  out  of  human  nature. 
Human  nature  gives  rise  to  certain  basic  drives.  These  drives  create 
fundamental  human  needs.  The  needs  in  turn  produce  activities  to 
satisfy  them.  When  such  activities  become  habitual  and  socially  sanc- 
tioned, they  emerge  into  customs  and  institutions.  But  the  customs  and 
institutions  themselves  are  quite  distinct  from  human  nature.  Human 
nature  is  relatively  constant  and  uniform,  while  the  whole  body  of  insti- 
tutions, called  human  nurture,  is  diversified  and  subject  to  extensive 
changes,  however  gradual  such  change  may  be.  Man  (homo  sapiens)  has 
been  on  the  planet  for  fifty  thousand  years — perhaps  far  longer.  But 
during  all  this  time,  when  human  nature  has  been  biologically  constant, 
we  have  passed  from  tribal  institutions  to  those  of  the  contemporary 
urban-industrial  world  civilization.  Every  form  of  industry,  property, 
family,  social  group,  government,  warfare,  religion,  and  education  of 
which  we  have  any  knowledge  has  grown  up,  flowered,  decayed,  or  per- 
sisted within  this  period. 

This  fact  concerning  the  relative  fixity  of  human  nature  in  a  biological 
sense  should  not,  however,  lead  us  to  take  too  rigid  a  view  of  the  character 
and  workings  of  human  nature.  Human  behavior  is  the  product  of  two 
forces:  (1)  the  physical  and  social  environment,  and  (2)  the  responses 
of  the  physical  organism  of  man  to  this  environment.  Though  the 
physical  organism  of  man  may  not  change,  its  responses  are  bound  to 
alter  as  new  stimuli  arise  with  each  radical  change  in  the  physical  or 
social  environment.  Hence  there  is  no  reason  to  doubt  that  our  human 
nature,  the  same  biologically,  responds  quite  differently  in  a  metropolitan 
center  from  the  way  it  did  in  the  simple  environment  of  the  cave-dwellers* 
The  behavior  of  people  in  Soviet  Russia  in  1940,  as  contrasted  with  their 
behavior  under  Tsarist  auspices  in  1910,  is  a  dramatic  illustration  of  the 
way  in  which  human  responses  may  change  in  rapid  and  sweeping  fashion 
without  any  transformation  in  the  biological  make-up. 


36         A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

These  considerations  have  an  important  bearing  upon  the  frequent 
assertion  that  we  cannot  get  a  better  form  of  society  unless  we  change 
human  nature.  If  we  moved  from  tribal  culture  to  metropolitan  civi- 
lization without  any  change  in  the  biological  basis  of  human  nature,  we 
can  bring  about  relatively  minor  changes  in  government  or  economic  life 
without  a  change  in  human  nature.  The  most  suitable  human  institu- 
tions would  probably  be  those  which  conform  most  closely  to  the  nature 
and  needs  of  man,  but  thus  far  there  has  been  little  effort  to  discover  the 
actual  nature  of  mankind  and  to  identify  and  establish  the  institutions 
most  compatible  with  this  nature.  Our  institutional  life  has  been  mainly 
the  product  of  blind  groping  by  peoples  encompassed  by  ignorance,  sta- 
bilized and  transmitted  over  countless  generations.  Only  those  institu- 
tions which  have  been  notoriously  out  of  adjustment  with  human  nature 
and  incapable  of  satisfying  human  needs  have  been  discarded.  Even 
then,  such  institutions  were  not  deliberately  set  aside,  but  the  peoples  who 
clung  to  them  were  extinguished  by  those  possessing  more  adequate 
institutions. 

Everything  known  as  progress  has  been  a  phase  or  product  of  our 
institutional  equipment.  Biologically,  the  man  who  lived  in  caves  in 
the  Old  Stone  Age  forty  or  fifty  thousand  years  ago  was  just  like  the  man 
who  lives  in  metropolitan  New  York  or  London.  All  that  separates  them 
is  the  result  of  institutional  development.  However,  the  relative  efficiency 
of  institutions  at  any  time  remains  a  very  real  question.  Hence,  while 
institutions  are  indispensable  and  their  achievement  is  impressive,  there 
remains  a  very  real  question  as  to  their  relative  efficiency  at  any  time. 
Certainly  our  institutions  when  they  arose  could  not  have  been  very 
efficient.  They  were  the  chance  expedients  of  ignorant,  primitive  men. 
They  were  the  result  of  trial  and  error.  They  then  might  be  preserved 
and  approved,  even  if  the  margin  of  success  was  just  great  enough  to 
enable  the  group  to  survive.  But,  even  so,  the  chances  are  that  any 
given  institution  is  more  efficient  at  the  time  of  its  origin  than  at  any 
later  time.  When  it  begins,  it  bears  at  least  some  direct  relationship  to 
the  conditions  of  life  as  it  is  then  lived.  But  as  life  conditions  change, 
the  institution  usually  remains  unchanged,  gets  more  and  more  out  of 
date  and  becomes  less  adequate.  Yet  social  reverence  for  institutions 
has  made  it  impossible  for  mankind  to  grasp  this  elementary  truth  and 
seek  to  provide  institutions  better  adapted  to  the  new  ways  of  life.  It 
is  certain  that  all  civilizations  which  have  fallen — and  all  great  civiliza- 
tions prior  to  our  own  day  have  disintegrated — have  done  so  because  of 
inadequate  and  outgrown  institutions.  The  decay  of  civilizations  cannot 
be  attributed  to  human  nature,  for  that  is  the  same  yesterday,  today, 
and  tomorrow. 

The  great  revolutions  which  have  taken  place  have  invariably  come 
about  when  institutions  were  notoriously  out  of  adjustment  with  existing 
technology  and  ways  of  life.8  The  dawn  of  history— the  first  notable 


8  For  more  detail  on  the  great  world  revolutions,  see  pp.  48  ff. 


A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS          37 

world-revolution — came  when  the  domestication  of  animals,  the  inven- 
tion of  agriculture,  and  the  improvement  of  implements  and  weapons  had 
given  man  a  technology  no  longer  adapted  to  the  simple  life  of  small 
primitive  groups.  It  was  a  technology  suited  to  conquest,  expansion,  and 
enrichment. 

But,  in  time,  all  of  these  processes  went  further  than  the  underlying 
ancient  technology  warranted.  A  great  Roman  empire  arose  which  could 
not  be  administered  on  the  basis  of  horse  and  camel  transport,  courier 
communication,  and  the  handicraft  industry.  It  went  to  pieces  in  the 
second  great  world-revolution  from  the  third  to  the  seventh  centuries 
of  the  Christian  era. 

The  third  major  world-revolution  came  when  the  rudimentary  local 
and  provincial  institutions  of  the  Middle  Ages  were  no  longer  adapted 
to  the  new  ways  of  life  initiated  by  the  compass,  better  ships,  world- 
trade,  the  curiosity  of  explorers,  and  the  greed  of  merchants.  So  the 
Middle  Ages  came  to  an  end  and  modern  times  came  into  being  between 
the  days  of  Columbus  and  those  of  Napoleon. 

Today,  we  are  trying  to  control  the  technology  of  an  age  of  dynamos, 
streamlined  trains,  airplanes,  radios,  and  moving-pictures  through  in- 
stitutions most  of  which  were  already  in  existence  at  the  time  of  Napoleon 
Bonaparte.  The  vast  discrepancy  between  our  technology  and  our 
institutional  life  in  our  day  suggests  that  we  are  at  the  present  time  on 
the  eve  of  a  fourth  great  world-revolution. 

The  main  reason  why  our  social  institutions  get  out  of  adjustment 
with  our  technology — our  tools  and  machines — is  that  we  are  far  more 
deliberate  in  fashioning  and  in  changing  tools  and  machines.  There  is 
also  more  obvious  and  concrete  evidence  to  show  us  whether  or  not  our 
tools,  machines,  and  vehicles  are  working  well  than  there  is  with  respect 
to  the  adequacy  of  our  institutions.  Man  has  not  always  been  so  rational 
and  deliberate  in  choosing  and  altering  his  technological  equipment. 
Tools  and  vehicles  were  once  sanctified,  and  altered  only  very  gradually 
and  gingerly.  They,  also,  were  thought  to  be  of  divine  origin.  A 
famous  anthropologist  tells  of  a  tribe  in  Polynesia  which  used  a  noto- 
riously unseaworthy  canoe,  while  its  neighbors  had  very  efficient  boats. 
But  the  people  with  the  risky  canoe  would  not  abandon  it  because  they 
feared  that  the  gods  would  be  angry  and  drown  the  whole  tribe. 

But  even  in  primitive  times,  as  Alexander  Golden weiser  pointed  out 
in  his  Robots  or  Gods,  man  was  more  rational  towards  his  tools  than 
towards  his  institutions.  He  was  much  more  willing  to  make  changes 
and  improvements  in  his  implements  and  weapons  than  in  his  customs 
and  ideas.  Today,  we  are  almost  totally  rational  in  inventing  and 
adopting  new  machines.  Only  vested  economic  interests  in  older  and 
inefficient  machinery  prevent  us  from  adopting  newer  and  better  types. 
Mechanical  invention  has  become  customary.  However,  we  remain  al- 
most as  superstitious  concerning  our  institutions  and  their  deliberate 
alteration  as  primitive  men.  "Social  invention"  is  still  only  a  challenging 
phrase  and  a  noble  dream. 


38         A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

Thus  far,  changes  in  human  institutions  have  been  accomplished 
mainly  in  an  unconscious  fashion.  The  migration  of  peoples  to  new 
habitats  and  their  contacts  with  different  customs  and  institutions,  revo- 
lutionary changes  in  technology;  like  the  domestication  of  animals,  the 
invention  of  agriculture,  the  mastery  of  navigation,  the  discovery  of 
metal-working,  have  forced  people  unconsciously  to  modify  their  intitu- 
tions.  But  there  have  been  few  instances,  until  very  recently,  of  epoch- 
making  changes  in  institutions  which  have  been  undertaken  and  accom- 
plished in  a  deliberate  fashion. 

Proposals  to  bring  about  deliberate  changes  in  our  institutions  have 
not  been  lacking,  but  those  who  recommended  such  action,  with  the  ex- 
ception of  Plato  and  a  few  others  in  antiquity,  have  lived  in  relatively 
modern  times.  The  first  considerable  group  of  writers  to  recommend  a 
deliberate  reform  of  institutions  were  the  Utopian  Socialists  of  the  late 
eighteenth  and  nineteenth  centuries.  They  were  followed  by  Karl  Marx 
and  the  Socialists  who  recommended  revolutionary  changes.  But  not 
until  the  totalitarian  states  of  Russia,  Italy,  and  Germany  came  into 
existence  was  there  any  wholesale  wiping  out  of  existing  institutions  and 
the  substitution  of  a  new  pattern  of  life. 

Most  civilized  people  hope,  however,  that  a  better  method  of  deliberate 
social  change  can  be  found  than  the  technique  of  revolutionary  totali- 
tarianism. Nearly  three-quarters  of  a  century  ago,  Lester  F.  Ward 
suggested  that  social  scientists  study  institutions  and  offer  recommenda- 
tions for  their  change  when  they  get  out  of  adjustment  to  the  existing 
needs.  This  would  insure  expert  guidance  and  safeguard  against  vio- 
lence. But,  thus  far,  Ward's  benevolent  suggestions  have  received  little 
popular  support  and  have  never  been  given  a  comprehensive  trial. 

One  observation  may  be  made  with  considerable  assurance.  That  is 
that  the  most  impressive  turning-point  in  history  will  come  when  human- 
ity becomes  capable  of  examining  its  institutions  in  deliberate  fashion 
and  adjusting  them  to  the  service  of  existing  needs. 

The  Evolution  of  Social    Institutions 

Whether  or  not  institutions  change  and  develop  with  an  inevitable 
uniformity  which  can  be  described  and  predicted  is  a  question  that  has 
been  vigorously  discussed.  A  generation  back,  social  scientists  were 
much  under  the  spell  of  the  evolutionary  doctrines  set  forth  by  Lamarck, 
Spencer,  Darwin  and  others.  Many  of  them  felt  that  the  laws  of  cosmic 
and  organic  evolution  could  be  carried  over  and  made  to  apply  to  the 
development  of  social  institutions.  Today,  there  is  almost  unanimity  of 
opinion  to  the  contrary. 

If  there  are  laws  governing  the  development  of  institutions,  it  is  evi- 
dent that  they  have  no  relationship  to  the  laws  of  organic  evolution. 
Human  nature  has  not  changed  for  at  least  fifty  thousand  years  while 
human  institutions  have  undergone  tremendous  changes  in  this  period. 
The  question  is  whether  there  a*e  laws  which  determine  the  evolution  of 


A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS          39 

institutions  and  make  their  development  inevitable  and  uniform.    Let 
us  review  some  oustanding  opinions  on  this  subject. 

The  great  Roman  philosophic  poet,  Lucretius,  suggested  that  social 
institutions  might  have  passed  through  evolutionary  phases.  But  his 
amazingly  modern  ideas  were  no  more  than  a  hunch.  The  first  writer 
to  devote  a  great  deal  of  attention  to  the  question  was  the  French 
philosopher,  August  Comte.  Although  he  wrote  before  the  days  of 
Darwin,  he  was  much  influenced  by  the  evolutionary  ideas  of  the  German 
and  French  philosophers  of  the  era  of  Romanticism  and  was  familiar  with 
the  revolutionary  views  of  Lamarck.  In  his  System  of  Positive  Polity, 
he  wrote  that  society  passes  through  three  great  stages  of  development: 
(1)  the  theological  and  military;  (2)  the  metaphysical  and  legalistic; 
and  (3)  the  scientific  and  industrial.  William  A.  Dunning  has  sum- 
marized Comte 's  notion  of  social  evolution:  * 

1.  In  the  theological  and  military  stage  social  relations  are  determined,  both 
in  general  and  in  particular,  by  force.    Conquest  is  the  guiding  aim  of  society. 
Industry  exists  only  for  the  production  of  the  necessities  of  physical  life,  and 
slavery  is  the  status  of  the  producers. 

2.  In  the  metaphysical  and  legalistic  stage  the  military  spirit  still  predominates, 
but  industrial  conditions  are  making  themselves  felt.    Slavery  gradually  gives 
way  to  serfage  and  then  to  civil,  though  not  political,  liberty  for  the  individual. 
The  growth  of  industry  is  pronounced,  but  its  end  is  chiefly  to  promote  military 
ends.    Eventually  it  becomes  itself  the  most  important  cause  of  war.    As  a 
whole  this  stage  is  transitional  and  indeterminate. 

3.  In  the  scientific  and  industrial  stage  industry  has  become  dominant.    It  is 
the  first  influence  in  the  relations  of  individuals  to  one  another,  and  it  tends  to 
control  all  the  relations  of  society.    Social  activity  as  a  whole  oecomes  directed 
to  the  sole  end  of  production,  i.e.,  to  the  adaptation  of  nature  to  the  needs  of 
man,  and  in  this  is  the  essence  of  civilization.9 

Probably  no  other  writer  devoted  so  much  attention  to  the  evolution 
of  institutions  as  Herbert  Spencer,  the  eminent  English  philosopher  of 
the  nineteenth  century.  He  worked  out  a  philosophy  of  evolution  all 
his  own,  and  he  believed  that  its  principles  applied  to  the  physical  uni- 
verse, to  living  matter,  and  to  all  social  institutions.  His  formula  of 
evolution  was  based  on  the  idea  of  integration  and  differentiation. 
Matter  first  integrates  and  then  there  is  a  differentiation  of  the  specific 
parts  or  organs,  which  become  ever  more  perfectly  suited  to  their  duties. 
Social  institutions  are  subject  to  the  same  law.  Civilization  has  passed 
through  two  main  stages.  In  the  first,  military  considerations  dominated 
social  institutions  and  in  the  second,  industrial  life  gave  color  to  civi- 
lization. F.  H.  Giddings  has  admirably  condensed  Spencer's  theory  of 
evolution  and  its  application  to  social  institutions: 

Societies  are  organisms  or  they  are  super-organic  aggregates. 
Between  societies  and  environing  bodies,  as  between  other  finite  aggregates 
in  nature,  there  is  an  equilibration  of  energy.    There  is  an  equilibration  between 


9  W.  A.  Dunning,  A  History  of  Political  Theories  from  Rousseau  to  Spencer, 
Macmillan,  1920,  pp.  30&-394. 


40          A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

society  and  society,  between  one  social  group  and  another,  between  one  social 
class  and  another. 

Equilibration  between  society  and  society,  between  societies  and  their  environ- 
ment, takes  the  form  of  a  struggle  for  existence  among  societies.  Conflict  be- 
comes an  habitual  activity  of  society. 

In  this  struggle  for  existence  fear  of  the  living  and  of  the  dead  arises.  Fear 
of  the  living,  supplementing  conflict,  becomes  the  root  of  political  control.  Fear 
of  the  dead  becomes  the  root  of  religious  control. 

Organized  and  directed  by  political  and  religious  control,  habitual  conflict 
becomes  militarism.  Militarism  moulds  character  and  conduct  and  social  organ- 
ization into  fitness  for  habitual  warfare. 

Militarism  combines  small  social  groups  into  larger  ones,  these  into  larger  and 
yet  larger  ones.  It  achieves  social  integration.  This  process  widens  the  area 
within  which  an  increasingly  large  proportion  of  the  population  is  habitually  at 
peace  and  industrially  employed. 

Habitual  peace  and  industry  mould  character,  conduct  and  social  organization 
into  fitness  for  peaceful,  friendly,  sympathetic  life. 

In  the  peaceful  type  of  society  coercion  diminishes,  spontaneity  and  individual 
initiative  increase.  Social  organization  becomes  plastic,  and  individuals  moving 
freely  from  place  to  place  change  their  social  relations  without  destroying  social 
cohesion,  the  elements  of  which  are  sympathy  and  knowledge  in  place  of  primi- 
tive force. 

The  change  from  militarism  to  industrialism  depends  upon  the  extent  of  the 
equilibration  of  energy  between  any  given  race  and  those  of  other  races,  between 
society  in  general  and  its  physical  environment.  Peaceful  industrialism  cannot 
finally  be  established  until  the  equilibrium  of  nations  and  of  races  is  established. 

In  society,  as  in  other  finite  aggregates,  the  extent  of  the  differentiation  and 
the  total  complexity  of  all  the  evolutionary  processes  depend  upon  the  rate  at 
which  integration  proceeds.  The  slower  the  rate  the  more  complete  and  satis- 
factory is  the  evolution.10 

It  was  natural  that  the  theory  of  organic  evolution  set  forth  by  Charles 
Darwin  in  his  Origin  of  Species  should  have  a  wide  influence  on  social 
thinking.  Many  writers  of  the  time,  including  Spencer,  were  stressing 
the  resemblance  between  human  society  and  the  biological  organism. 
A  large  group  of  sociologists,  who  called  themselves  "Social  Darwinists," 
attempted  to  apply  Darwinism  to  the  evolution  of  social  institutions, 
although  Darwin  himself  did  not  sanction  any  such  procedure.  Darwin 
had  held  that  the  struggle  for  existence  and  the  survival  of  the  fittest  is 
the  key  to  organic  evolution.  So  the  Social  Darwinists  held  that  war, 
in  human  society,  is  comparable  to  the  struggle  for  existence  in  the  bio- 
logical world.  On  this  basis  they  attributed  the  origin  of  government, 
social  classes,  property,  and  slavery  to  war  and  conquest.  Many  of 
them  also  believed  that  war  purifies  the  race  by  killing  off  the  weaker. 
They  all  agreed  that  war  is  the  most  important  force  in  the  evolution  of 
social  institutions.  This  line  of  thought  was  bitterly  attacked  by  other 
writers,  notably  the  Russian  sociologist,  Jacques  Novicow. 

The  most  thoroughgoing  attempt  to  discover  just  how  far  Darwin's 
principles  and  formulas  can  be  applied  to  the  evolution  of  social  institu- 
tions was  made  by  Albert  Galloway  Keller  of  Yale  University. 


10  F.  H.  Giddings,  Sociology,  Columbia  University  Press,  1908,  pp,  29-30, 


A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS          41 

Professor  Keller  addresses  his  Societal  Evolution  u  to  an  answer  to  the 
following  question:  "Can  the  evolutionary  theory  ...  be  carried  over 
into  the  social  domain  without  losing  all  or  much  of  the  significance  it 
possesses  as  applied  in  the  field  of  natural  science?"  Keller  holds  that, 
so  far  as  the  formula  of  evolution  has  been  adopted  by  sociologists,  it 
has  been  the  doctrine  of  evolution  elaborated  by  Spencer,  which,  he 
thinks,  is  not  a  scientific  but  a  philosophic  concept.  Hence  it  is  high 
time  that  the  really  scientific  formulas  of  Darwin  be  appropriated  by 
sociology,  and  the  doctrine  of  the  "transformation  of  the  incoherent 
homogeneous  into  the  coherent  heterogeneous"  be  displaced  by  that  of 
"variation,  selection,  transmission,  and  adaptation."  If  it  is  true,  as 
Keller  attempts  to  prove,  that  the  Darwinian  doctrine  is  applicable  to 
social  processes,  the  question  arises  as  to  how  far  society  can  control  this 
evolutionary  process  and  artificially  improve  institutions,  as  breeders 
improve  the  stock  of  animals  by  artificial  selection. 

In  the  first  place,  Keller  finds  that  societal  evolution  is  primarily  mental 
and  not  physical.  The  conception  of  the  "mores"  developed  by  Sumner 
is  the  basis  of  his  theory  of  societal  evolution.  By  the  mores  is  meant 
the  ways  of  doing  things  which  a  particular  society  approves.  The 
mores  are  analogous  to  the  germ  cells  and  embryos  in  the  organic  world ; 
they  are  the  "raw  material"  through  which  societal  evolution  operates. 

Keller  next  proceeds  to  discover  whether  or  not  the  main  factors  in 
the  Darwinian  theory  of  evolution — variation,  selection,  transmission 
and  adaptation — are  also  exemplified  in  the  evolution  of  the  mores.  He 
believes  that  they  are. 

Variation  in  the  mores  is  shown  by  the  fact  that  no  two  groups  possess 
identical  codes  of  customary  procedure.  These  variations  arise  from 
the  differences  among  groups  in  their  reactions  to  the  stimulation  of 
their  environment. 

Keller  finds  three  types  of  societal  selection — automatic,  rational,  and 
counter.  Automatic  selection  involves  no  conscious  adaptation  of  means 
to  a  preconceived  end,  but  is  effected  spontaneously  through  the  processes 
of  war,  subjection,  class-conflict,  and  competition.  He  has  some  harsh, 
but  in  the  main  justifiable,  words  for  those  who  would  put  an  end  to  this 
natural  process  of  the  elimination  of  the  socially  unfit: 

Sentimentalists,  warm  of  heart,  but  soft  of  head,  petition  complaisant  execu- 
tives to  let  loose  upon  society  the  wolves  that  have  been  trapped  and  should 
have  been  eliminated  once  for  all;  to  set  the  scotched  snakes  free  again.  The 
pseudo-heroic  and  pathetic  aspects  of  the  life  of  the  black-hearted  criminal  are 
rehearsed  until  he  seems  to  be  a  martyr,  and  the  just  judge  who  condemns  him 
a  persecutor  and  a  brute.  All  of  which  is  done  by  volatile  spirits  under  the 
illusion  that  they  are  thereby  conserving  the  delicacy  of  the  'ethical  sense'  or 
what  not,  instead  of  proving  recreant  to  plain  duties  as  members  and  supporters 
of  civilized  society.12 


11  Second  edition,  Macmillan,  1931. 

12  Op.  tit.tpp.  114-115. 


42         A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

Rational  selection,  the  social  analogue  of  the  breeder's  art,  takes  place 
in  society,  but  in  different  degrees  among  the  various  types  of  mores. 
Those  mores  connected  with  matters  of  superstition  and  sentiment,  like 
religion  and  sex,  are  most  difficult  to  change.  Those  not  thus  entangled 
open  a  wider  field  for  deliberate  improvement.  To  a  certain  extent,  the 
leaders  in  thought  can  determine  the  direction  in  which  changes  in  the 
mores  will  occur,  but  even  such  persons  are  limited  by  the  tyranny  of 
public  opinion. 

Mores  connected  with  the  maintenance  of  society — industry— are  the 
least  wrapped  up  in  sentiment,  and  hence  rational  selection  finds  its 
widest  application  in  the  economic  field.  Every  important  change  in 
economic  organization  is  followed  by  a  consequent,  though  not  necessarily 
equal,  transformation  in  the  other  mores.  Thus,  though  it  is  impossible 
directly  to  modify  all  social  institutions,  the  changes  can  be  achieved  in 
this  roundabout  manner.  Therefore,  Keller's  answer  to  the  question  as 
to  whether  society  can  control  its  own  evolution  ends  in  a  new  version 
of  economic  determinism.  He  guards,  however,  against  allowing  his 
arguments  to  be  interpreted  as  favoring  the  socialist  propaganda.  One 
may  accept  the  dogma  of  the  fundamental  importance  of  economic  insti- 
tutions without  giving  assent  to  the  Marxian  deductions  from  this  prin- 
ciple. 

By  counter-selection,  Keller  means  that  type  of  societal  selection 
which  renders  the  human  race  biologically  less  fit.  The  modern  social 
factors  in  counter-selection,  which  are  described  by  Friedrich  Wilhelm 
Schallmayer,  are  mainly  war,  modern  industry,  celibacy,  later  marriage, 
and  the  sterility  of  the  upper  classes.  But  counter-selection,  while  dis- 
astrous biologically,  may  have  social  and  cultural  compensations. 
Societal  selection  operates  primarily  among  groups  rather  than  in- 
dividuals, and  hence  insofar  as  it  secures  social  advantages  which  are 
greater  than  the  biological  loss,  it  is  to  be  commended.  Keller  regards, 
the  eugenic  program  advanced  by  Galton  and  Pearson  as  impracticable, 
since  it  involves  interference  with  the  type  of  mores — the  sexual — which 
is  most  resistant  to  rational  control. 

Transmission,  in  societal  terminology,  is  not  possible  in  the  sense  of 
biological  heredity,  but  the  mores  are  transmitted  through  the  medium  of 
tradition,  which  operates  automatically  through  imitation  and  inherit- 
ance, and  artificially  through  education. 

Adaptation  in  the  mores  is  the  outcome  of  the  operation  of  the  processes 
of  variation,  selection,  and  transmission.  Every  social  custom  or 
institution  is  the  result  of  an  adaptation  of  the  life  of  a  people  to  the 
environmental  conditions  which  confront  them.  Even  though  the  par- 
ticular adjustment  may  later  be  an  anachronism,  it  should  not  be  con- 
demned absolutely,  for  it  must  have  once  been  useful  or  it  would  not 
exist.  The  different  forms  of  government  are  but  one  aspect  of  this 
social  adaptation  to  the  necessary  conditions  of  social  existence. 

Keller  thus  demonstrates  the  applicability  of  the  Darwinian  formula  to 
the  processes  of  social  evolution  in  a  broad  general  way.  It  is  debatable, 


A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS          43 

however,  whether  we  can  find  any  real  explanation  of  the  fundamental 
social  processes  in  a  demonstration  of  the  resemblances  between  the  life 
processes  of  the  organism  and  society. 

The  most  influential  book  attempting  to  work  out  the  laws  and  stages 
that  govern  the  evolution  of  social  institutions  was  Lewis  Henry  Morgan's 
Ancient  Society,  published  in  1877.18  Morgan  was  a  wealthy  "business 
man  who  devoted  himself  to  a  study  of  anthropology  and  attempted  to 
formulate  a  scheme  of  social  evolution.  It  was  his  notion  that  human 
institutions  follow  a  definite  pattern  of  evolution  and  that  their  stages 
of  development  are  much  the  same  the  world  over.  This  uniformity  of 
evolution  he  attributed  to  the  general  similarity  of  basic  human  wants 
and  the  underlying  unity  of  the  human  mind: 

The  history  of  the  human  race  is  one  in  source,  one  in  experience  and  one  in 
progress  .  .  .  inventions  and  discoveries  show.  .  .  .  the  unity  of  origin  of  man- 
kind, the  similarity  of  human  wants  in  the  same  stage  of  advancement,  and  the 
uniformity  of  the  operations  of  the  human  mind  in  similar  conditions  of  society. 
.  .  .  The  principal  institutions  of  mankind  have  been  developed  from  a  few 
primary  germs  of  thought;  .  .  .  the  course  and  manner  of  their  development 
was  predetermined,  as  well  as  restricted  within  narrow  limits  of  divergence  by 
the  natural  logic  of  the  human  mind  and  the  necessary  limitations  of  its  powers. 
Progress  has  been  found  to  be  substantially  the  same  in  kind  in  tribes  and 
nations  inhabiting  different  and  even  disconnected  continents,  while  in  the  same 
status,  with  deviations  from  uniformity  in  particular  instances  produced  by 
special  causes.  .  .  .  the  experience  of  mankind  has  run  in  nearly  uniform 
channels;  human  necessities  in  similar  conditions  have  been  substantially  the 
same  and  the  operations  of  the  mental  principle  have  been  uniform  in  virtue  of 
the  specific  identity  of  the  brain  of  all  the  races  of  mankind.  .  .  . 

Like  the  successive  geological  formations,  the  tribes  of  mankind  may  be 
arranged,  according  to  their  relative  conditions,  into  successive  strata.  When 
thus  arranged,  they  reveal  with  some  degree  of  certainty  the  entire  range  of 
human  progress  from  savagery  to  civilization.  A  thorough  study  of  each  succes- 
sive stratum  will  develop  whatever  is  special  in  its  culture  and  characteristics 
and  yield  a  definite  conception  of  the  whole,  in  their  difference  and  their  rela- 
tions. .  .  ,14 

Following  out  his  general  evolutionary  scheme,  Morgan  held  that 
culture  everywhere  had  passed  through  three  stages:  savagery,  barbarism, 
and  civilization.  In  the  periods  of  savagery  and  barbarism,  there  were 
three  stages  of  development  within  each.  The  lowest  stage  of  savagery 
lasted  from  the  beginning  of  the  human  race  to  the  acquisition  of  a  fish 
subsistence  and  a  knowledge  of  the  use  of  fire.  These  achievements 
introduced  the  middle  stage  of  savagery.  This  continued  until  man 
invented  the  bow-and-arrow,  which  brought  him  into  the  upper  stage  of 
savagery.  Man  attained  the  stage 'of  barbarism  with  the  invention  of 
the  art  of  pottery.  This  entitled  him  to  rank  in  the  lower  stage  of 
barbarism.  When  man  learned  to  domesticate  animals  in  the  old  world, 
to  cultivate  corn  in  the  new  world,  and  to  build  abodes  of  brick  and  stone 


18  See  B.  J.  Stern,  Lewis  Henry  Morgan:  Social  Evolutionist,  University  of  Chicago 
Press,  1931. 
i*L.  H.  Morgan,  Ancient  Society,  Holt,  1877.    Cited  in  Stern,  op.  cit.,  pp.  131-2. 


44         A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

he  entered  upon  the  middle  stage  of  barbarism.  When  he  learned  how 
to  smelt  iron  and  to  use  iron  tools  and  weapons,  he  emerged  into  the 
upper  stage  of  barbarism.  He  entered  civilization  when  he  invented  a 
phonetic  alphabet,  and  created  a  government  based  upon  territory  and 
property  rather  than  upon  tribal  relationships. 

In  his  doctrine  of  social  evolution,  Morgan  held  that  man  had  originally 
lived  in  small  and  unorganized  hordes.  Next,  man  entered  what  Morgan 
called  gentile  society,  based  upon  real  or  alleged  blood  relationship.  In 
its  earliest  form,  these  relationships  were  traced  through  mothers,  thus 
creating  a  maternal  society.  In  time,  relationships  were  traced  primarily 
through  the  fathers,  and  a  patriarchal  type  of  society  came  about.  When 
government  came  to  be  based  upon  territorial  residence  and  the  posses- 
sion of  property,  the  era  of  kinship  or  gentile  society  came  to  an  end  and 
civil  society  arose. 

Morgan  not  only  set  forth  theories  of  social  evolution  in  general,  but 
also  expounded  doctrines  relative  to  the  evolution  of  particular  institu- 
tions such  as  the  family.  He  held  that  the  family  had  passed  through 
a  number  of  forms.  The  first  was  the  consanguine  family,  in  which 
brothers  and  sisters  married.  The  next  type  was  the  punaluan,  which 
was  designed  to  prevent  the  intermarriage  of  brothers  and  sisters  by 
imposing  a  taboo  thereupon  through  a  gentile  organization.  Then  came 
the  third  or  syndyasmian  family,  which  was  a  marriage  of  single  pairs 
but  without  exclusive  cohabitation.  The  fourth  form  of  family  was  the 
patriarchal  family,  consisting  of  the  marriage  of  one  man  to  several  wives. 
Finally,  man  attained  the  fifth  and  highest  form  of  marriage,  the  mono- 
gamiany  which  meant  the  marriage  of  one  man  to  one  woman  with  ex- 
clusive cohabitation.  This  last  form  was  encouraged  by  the  rise  of 
property  and  its  legal  transmission  to  offspring. 

No  other  book  ever  published  in  the  field  of  the  social  sciences  has 
exerted  so  great  an  influence  upon  our  ideas  regarding  the  evolution  of 
social  institutions  as  did  Morgan's  Ancient  Society.  For  a  generation 
it  was  the  bible  of  anthropologists  and  sociologists.  In  the  twentieth 
century,  however,  more  critical  anthropologists,  led  by  Franz  Boas  and 
his  disciples,  have  bitterly  attacked  Morgan's  ideas  and  have  claimed 
that  his  notions  of  invariable  and  inevitable  social  evolution  do  not 
square  with  observed  facts.  Perhaps  the  most  complete  attempt  to 
refute  Morgan  is  contained  in  Robert  H.  Lowie's  Primitive  Society. 
Most  anthropologists  and  sociologists  share  Lowie's  views.  On  the  other 
hand,  Leslie  A.  White,  an  admirer  of  Morgan,  is  now  undertaking  to 
rehabilitate  Morgan's  general  conception  of  social  evolution,  without 
necessarily  approving  of  all  of  Morgan's  specific  notions. 

Whatever  the  deficiencies  in  the  details  of  Morgan's  theory  of  social 
evolution,  the  dynamic  element  in  it  is  of  permanent  value.  This  rests 
upon  the  contention  that  culture  advances  and  institutions  change  as 
the  technological  elements  in  man's  control  over  his  environment  are 
enlarged  and  improved.  We  have  noted  how  Morgan  related  the  stages 
in  human  progress  from  savagery  to  civilization  directly  to  the  progress 


A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS         45 

in  weapons,  tools,  the  use  of  metals,  and  the  domestication  of  animals. 
Morgan  also  made  a  contribution  of  great  value  in  showing  how  pro- 
foundly social  institutions  have  been  affected  by  the  institution  of  prop- 
erty and  the  methods  of  transmitting  it  through  inheritance  practices. 
Morgan's  stress  upon  technological  and  economic  elements  in  institutional 
change  and  readjustment  was  sound  and  of  vital  importance.  Its  endur- 
ing value  has  been  overlooked  by  critics  who  have  concentrated  upon 
less  important  aspects  of  his  evolutionary  philosophy  and  system  and 
upon  errors  in  matters  o'f  detail. 

While  the  issue  is  by  no  means  settled,  it  is  doubtful  if  there  are  any 
universal  laws  determining  the  evolution  of  social  institutions,  which 
make  their  development  uniform  and  inevitable,  independent  of  time 
and  special  historical  conditions.  To  hold  that  there  are  such  laws 
would  be  almost  like  adopting  a  sociological  version  of  orthodox  Christian 
theology  or  oriental  fatalism.  The  historical  evolution  of  society  is  not 
chaotic  or  without  cause  or  order,  but  there  is  little  probability  that  it 
is  pre-determined  by  any  immutable  laws. 

About  all  that  can  be  done  is  to  formulate  rather  tentative  notions  of 
social  causation.  A  reasonable  view  would  be  something  like  the  follow- 
ing: We  have  as  the  two  relatively  constant  factors  in  history  the  original 
nature  of  man  and  the  geographical  environment  in  a  given  area,  but 
these  cannot  be  said  to  be  absolutely  static,  and  they  are  so  involved 
with  other  conditioning  influences  that  their  interaction  is  constantly 
varying  in  nature  and  extent.  The  original  nature  of  man,  reacting  to 
a  particular  form  of  geographic  stimulation,  will  produce  a  characteristic 
outlook  on  life.  The  latter  will,  in  turn,  control  to  a  considerable  degree 
the  extent  to  which  science  and  technology  can  emerge  and  develop.  The 
state  of  technology  rather  Sharply  conditions  the  nature  of  the  economic 
life  which  exists  in  any  age  and  area.  The  economic  institutions  tend  to 
have  a  powerful  conditioning,  and  sometimes  a  determining,  influence 
over  the  other  institutions  and  cultural  elements:  social,  political,  juristic, 
religious,  ethical,  educational,  and  literary. 

Yet  this  is,  in  reality,  an  over-simplified  statement  of  the  historical 
process.  Cause  and  effect  are  constantly  acting  and  interacting  upon 
each  other.  A  few  basic  mechanical  inventions,  such  as  printing  or  new 
methods  of  transmitting  information,  may  so  alter  the  life  of  man  as 
completely  to  transform  the  dominating  psychology  of  any  age.  Again, 
certain  psychological  and  cultural  factors  may  at  times  have  sufficient 
power  to  obstruct  the  obvious  dictates  of  material  prosperity.  The  skein 
of  historical  development  is  a  tangled  and  complicated  one.  It  is  a 
profound  historian  who  can  solve  the  problems  of  historical  causation  in 
any  single  epoch,  to  say  nothing  of  making  an  effort  to  formulate  a 
universally  valid  interpretation  of  human  history  as  a  whole. 

Viewing  the  course  of  history  in  a  large  way,  one  may  say  that  social 
institutions  often  seem  to  have  passed  through  some  fairly  widespread 
stages  of  development  of  a  reasonably  clear  and  distinct  nature.  We  may 
illustrate  this  briefly. 


46         A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL  INSTITUTIONS 

Government  seems  to  have  begun  on  a  family  basis  and  then  extended 
to  clan  and  tribal  government,  one's  position  in  government  being  de- 
termined by  what  is  called  gentile  society,  based  upon  real  or  fictitious 
blood  relationship.  Between  this  tribal  form  of  government  and  purely 
civil  government,  based  upon  territorial  residence  and  property,  there  is 
an  intermediate  stage,  founded  upon  personal  relationships,  which  we 
know  of  as  feudalism.  Civil  government  has  developed  through  the 
city-states,  monarchies,  empires,  representative  government,  and  de- 
mocracy. But  right  now  democracy  seems  to  be  suffering  a  setback  in 
favor  of  a  return  to  dictatorship  in  a  streamlined  setting. 

In  the  field  of  economic  life,  industry  seems  to  have  been  organized, 
first  in  the  family,  next  in  special  associations  of  workers  known  in  the 
Middle  Ages  as  gilds,  then  in  the  putting-out  system,  and  finally  in  the 
factory  system.  In  the  accumulation  and  application  of  wealth  the 
first  stage  was  of  a  personal  character,  which  has  been  called  the  napkin 
economy,  to  be  hoarded  or  spent  as  one  wished.  In  modern  times,  what 
is  known  as  capitalism  evolved.  This  involved  a  systematic  accumula- 
tion and  re-investment  of  money  in  business  enterprise  to  make  a  profit. 
Capitalism  itself  has  passed  through  various  stages  of  development  such 
as  commercial  capitalism,  industrial  capitalism,  monopoly  capitalism, 
and  finance  capitalism. 

Property  was  at  first  mainly  communal,  though  very  early  in  primitive 
society  there  were  various  forms  of  personal  property  and  well-recognized 
private  property  rights.  From  the  dawn  of  history  to  our  own  day 
property  has  mainly  been  held  in  private  possession,  and  elaborate  forms 
of  legal  sanction  have  been  developed  to  protect  private  property.  More 
recently,  the  state  has  intruded  upon  private  property  rights  through  such 
things  as  inheritance  taxes,  and  income  taxes.  In  some  states,  like 
Soviet  Russia,  the  state  has  taken  over  all  property  involved  in  the  pro- 
duction and  distribution  of  wealth.  Marked  tendencies  along  the  same 
lines  have  developed  in  Fascist  states. 

In  the  field  of  technology  there  was  general  evolution  from  the  use  of 
unchanged  natural  objects,  to  the  invention  of  the  tool,  the  development 
of  machinery  after  the  Industrial  Revolution,  and  the  appearance  of 
automatic  machinery  in  the  electrical  age.  Power  has  also  passed 
through  broad  stages  of  development.  First  we  have  the  power  of  the 
human  hand,  next  the  power  of  tools,  then  water  power,  steam  power, 
and  in  our  own  day  the  rise  of  electric  power. 

The  family  seems  to  have  shown  no  evolutionary  development  within 
historic  times.  The  usual  type  of  family  has  been  monogamous.  Other 
types  of  family,  such  as  the  polygynous  and  the  polyandrian,  have  been 
highly  specialized,  transient,  and  the  product  of  peculiar  conditions. 

Nor  do  there  seem  to  have  been  any  evolutionary  tendencies  in  those 
achievements  connected  with  aesthetics  and  the  fine  arts.  They  do  not 
seem  to  follow  any  definite  laws  of  development,  but  are  spontaneous  and 
unpredictable.  They  are,  however,  almost  always  colored  and  condi- 
tioned by  the  general  state  of  economic  and  political  life. 


A  PANORAMA  OF  SOCIAL   INSTITUTIONS          47 

There  are  some  fairly  well  defined  periods  in  the  development  of 
religion.  The  first  period  seems  to  have  been  one  in  which  man  believed 
in  generalized  and  impersonal  supernatural  power.  Then,  the  super- 
natural powers  were  endowed  with  personality,  in  what  we  know  of  as 
the  stage  of  animism.  In  time,  these  personified  spirits  were  divided  into 
good  and  evil  spirits.  Next,  man  came  to  conceive  of  a  supreme  good 
and  evil  spirit,  each  aided  by  a  large  group  of  subordinate  good  and  evil 
spirits,  respectively.  This  stage  was  reached  by  the  dawn  of  recorded 
history  and  there  has  been  no  fundamental  change  in  orthodox  religion 
since  that  time.  In  the  nineteenth  and  twentieth  centuries,  attempts 
have  been  made  to  promote  secular  cults,  divorced  from  supernaturalism. 
These  have  ranged  all  the  way  from  Auguste  Comte's  religion  of  Hu- 
manity to  Communism  and  Fascism. 

A  generation  ago  it  was  customary  to  regard  these  trends  in  the  de- 
velopment of  institutions  as  hard,  fixed,  inevitable,  and  uniform  stages. 
We  now  know  that  any  such  idea  was  over-simplified  and  untenable. 
There  are  undoubtedly  general  tendencies  in  social  evolution,  but  to  each 
of  them  there  have  been  notable  exceptions.  Such  developmental  trends 
help  to  clarify  our  notions  of  historical  changes  and  of  the  growth  of 
institutions,  but  they  present  no  confirmation  of  the  dogma  of  invariable 
social  evolution,  according  to  any  definite  pattern  or  pre-determined  by 
any  immutable  laws. 


CHAPTER   111 
Cultural  Lag  and  the  Crisis  in  Institutional  Life 

The  Transitional   Character  of  Our   Era 

ONE  OF  the  most  difficult  tasks  of  the  historian  is  to  attain  clear  per- 
spective on  his  own  age.  It  is  often  much  easier  to  understand  the  past. 
Yet  standing  by  itself,  the  past  has  only  a  musty  antiquarian  significance. 
Once  we  understand  how  the  past  created  the  present,  we  may  begin  to 
see  what  light  the  past  and  the  present  throw  on  the  probable  course  of 
future  events. 

It  is  probable  that  the  chief  lesson  which  a  study  of  the  past  offers  is 
the  overwhelming  evidence  that  we  are  living  in  one  of  the  great  transi- 
tional periods  of  man  on  this  planet.  It  is  always  dangerous  to  draw 
direct  analogies  with  the  past,  for  historical  epochs  never  reproduce 
themselves  exactly.  Attempts,  for  instance,  to  find  explicit  lessons  for 
our  generation  in  the  later  Roman  Empire  are  likely  to  prove  misleading. 
It  is  futile  to  identify,  in  any  detail,  a  dictatorial,  pre-capitalistic,  pre- 
industrial  society  and  an  economy  of  scarcity  with  a  democratic,  urban, 
industrial  civilization  which  has  attained  a  potential  economy  of 
abundance.1 

Yet  certain  broad  historical  analogies  are  sound,  useful,  and  illuminat- 
ing. Most  relevant  is  the  suggestion  that  we  are  living  in  the  early  days 
of  the  fourth  great  world-revolution  in  history.  The  three  previous  eras 
of  sweeping  social  and  cultural  transformation  roughly  comparable  to 
ours  were  (1)  the  passage  from  pre-literary  culture  to  so-called  historic 
civilization — the  dawn  of  history — somewhere  between  6000  B.C.  and 
3500  B.C.,  (2)  the  gradual  disintegration  of  classical  culture  in  the  later 
centuries  of  the  western  Roman  Empire,  around  300-600  A.D.,  and 
(3)  the  supplanting  of  medieval  civilization  by  early  modern  culture  and 
institutions  between  1500  and  1800. 

The  conception  of  a  world-revolution  is  not  limited  to  the  violent 
change  which  we  usually  associate  with  the  word  revolution,  although, 
thus  far  in  human  experience,  war  and  civil  violence  have  accompanied 
the  disintegration  of  old  social  orders  and  the  inauguration  of  new  ones. 
•  By  a  world-revolution  we  mean  a  fundamental  change  in  social  institu- 


i  See  such  efforts  in  H.  S.  Hadley,  Rome  and  the  World  Today,  Putnam,  1922; 
and  H.  J.  Haskell,  The  New  Deal  in  Old  Rome,  Knopf,  1939. 

4? 


CULTURAL  LAC  AND  SOCIAL  CRISIS  49 

tions  and  patterns  of  life,  in  the  social  and  economic  basis  of  the  control 
over  human  society.  A  new  class  of  leaders  is  thrown  up.  Either  new 
institutions  arise  or  sweeping  changes  are  made  in  those  which  hold  over 
from  an  earlier  pattern  of  culture.  A  new  type  of  civilization  comes  into 
being.  The  basic  patterns  of  society  are  reconstructed. 

At  the  dawn  of  history  in  the  ancient  Near  East,  military  chieftains 
from  the  earlier  tribal  society  built  up  little  feudal  kingdoms  and  city- 
states.  Adroit  and  powerful  rulers  of  such  political  units  conquered 
others  and,  in  time,  created  kingdoms  and  empires.  They  built  up  vast 
wealth,  founded  on  rich  landlords  and  a  wealthy  commercial  class.  A 
powerful  priesthood,  it  was  thought,  kept  the  favor  of  the  gods  and 
brought  supernatural  aid  to  the  conquerors.  The  same  process  was  re- 
peated when  the  Roman  Republic  and  the  Roman  Empire  were  created 
in  later  millenniums. 

Another  great  world-revolution  took  place  when  Roman  imperial 
society  disintegrated  after  300  A.D.  and  the  Germanic  tribal  chieftains 
and  kings  seized  control  of  western  Europe.  They  built  a  new  social 
order  founded  primarily  upon  powerful  landlords,  thus  creating  what  we 
know  as  medieval  feudalism.  In  time,  powerful  national  monarchies 
arose,  but  nothing  was  created  which  reproduced  the  great  empires  of 
oriental  and  classical  antiquity.  The  manors  and  guilds  dominated 
economic  life,  and  Catholic  social  ethics  controlled  business  and  financial 
practices.  The  Catholic  Church  and  Scholastic  philosophy  reigned  su- 
preme in  the  intellectual  realm. 

Following  1500  another  world-revolution  came  along,  this  time  pro- 
pelled chiefly  by  the  rising  power  of  the  merchant  class — the  new  bour- 
geoisie. At  first  they  supported  the  kings  against  their  old  traditional 
enemies,  the  feudal  lords,  thus  promoting  the  growth  of  royal  absolutism. 
However,  the  kings  became  an  even  greater  menace  than  the  feudal  lords 
had  once  been;  so  the  bourgeoisie  took  up  arms  against  the  kings  and 
either  displaced  them  or  subordinated  them  to  a  system  of  representative 
government  dominated  by  the  middle-class  merchants  and  businessmen. 

The  wars  of  Cromwell  against  Charles  I,  the  ousting  of  James  II,  the 
American  Revolutionary  War,  and  the  wars  of  the  French  Revolution 
and  Napoleon  were  only  incidental  military  episodes  in  the  great  social 
revolution  in  the  course  of  which  the  merchant  class  replaced  the  feudal 
landlords  as  the  dominant  class  in  western  society.  Napoleon,  in  any 
profound  historical  sense,  was  only  an  instrument  of  social  change  hasten- 
ing the  process,  as  Stalin  and  Hitler  later  sped  up  the  fourth  great  social 
revolution,  in  which  proletarian  leaders  may  oust  the  moguls  of  capital- 
ism in  the  dominion  of  society. 

The  third  world-revolution  that  produced  modern  times  probably 
bears  the  closest  resemblance  to  our  age.  In  the  three  centuries  follow- 
ing 1500,  the  typical  medieval  institutions  (such  as  a  decentralized  feudal 
government,  an  agricultural  economy  operated  according  to  the  manorial 
technique,  the  gild  control  of  urban  industry,  local  markets  and  national 
fairs  to  facilitate  exchange  of  goods,  the  theory  of  the  just  price  and 


50  CULTURAL   LAC  AND  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

other  moral  limitations  on  greed  and  sharp  business  practices,  the  great 
unified  international  Roman  Catholic  ecclesiastical  state,  and  the  Scholas- 
tic system  of  education)  were  undermined  or  completely  supplanted. 

In  their  place  arose  typical  institutions  of  the  early  modern  age — the 
centralized  national  state,  first  absolutistic  and  then  representative, 
farming  by  free  tenants  under  great  landlords,  an  increasingly  commer- 
cial and  industrial  economy,  the  domestic  or  putting-out  system  of  indus- 
trial control,  national  and  world  trade,  capitalistic  ideals  and  methods, 
the  quest  of  private  profits  by  any  means  not  flagrantly  illegal,  the  great 
schism  in  the  Catholic  world-state  produced  by  Protestantism,  and  the 
ascendency  of  Humanistic  ideals  in  education. 

Had  a  scholar  suggested  in  1500  that  the  civilization  of  his  age  was 
about  to  undergo  a  sweeping  transformation,  he  would  have  been  ignored 
or  ridiculed.  But  just  this  thing  happened.  By  1800,  medieval  civiliza- 
tion was  no  more,  except  in  the  more  backward  parts  of  Europe. 

So,  in  the  second  third  of  the  twentieth  century,  it  is  hard  to  believe 
that  we  may  be  in  about  the  same  condition  in  which  the  western  world 
found  itself  around  1500.  Yet  plenty  of  evidence  supports  the  opinion 
that  we  have  already  instituted  more  far-reaching  changes  than  any 
previous  century  has  ever  witnessed — perhaps  the  most  fundamental 
transition  in  man's  experience.  ,  There  are  at  least  two  important  con- 
trasts between  former  transitional  epochs  and  our  own.. 

In  the  first  place,  the  changes  which  lie  ahead  of  us,  for  better  or  for 
worse,  will  probably  be  carried  through  far  more  rapidly  than  in  the  past. 
The  civilization  of  earlier  ages  could  keep  going,  in  one  way  or  another, 
for  a  long  time  under  adverse  conditions.  Except  for  war,  invasion,  and 
devastation,  complete  breakdowns  were  infrequent.  There  might  be  less 
dried  beef,  flour,  and  meal  for  the  larder,  and  less  fodder  for  the  cattle. 
A  more  than  usual  number  of  babies,  calves,  and  sheep  might  die  of  mal- 
nutrition ;  the  standard  of  living  might  be  lowered  in  the  few  towns  that 
existed ;  yet,  somehow,  mankind  managed  to  get  along.  Scores  of  causes 
for  the  decline  of  Roman  society  have  been  suggested  by  historians,  but 
despite  all  these  causes  it  took  several  centuries  to  wreck  Roman  civiliza- 
tion. Similarly,  the  decay  of  medieval  institutions  actually  began  in 
the  late  thirteenth  century,  but  the  early  modern  age  was  hardly  com- 
plete before  1800.  Even  when  things  were  improving  in  the  past,  it  took 
a  long  time  to  create  a  new  order. 

Our  urban  industrial  world-civilization  presents  an  altogether  different 
spectacle.  «jOur  culture  is  so  complex,  so  delicately  articulated,  so  thor- 
oughly based  upon  an  elaborate  division  of  labor — between  industries, 
between  industry  and  transportation,  between  city  and  country,  between 
nations — that  the  whole  system  must  work  efficiently  if  it  is  to  work 
at  all.  . 

An  illustration  of  this  fact  was  furnished  by  the  "bank  holiday"  in 
the  opening  days  of  Franklin  D.  Roosevelt's  first  administration.  Our 
industrial  system  was  still  operating;  transportation  lines  ran  as  before; 
food  supplies  were  not  curtailed;  electric  current  was  generated  in  normal 


CULTURAL  LAC  AND  SOCIAL  CRISIS  51 

volume,  and  so  on.  There  was  merely  a  temporary  suspension  of  the 
ordinary  credit  system,  yet  the  country  was  in  a  veritable  panic.  Had 
not  a  new  and  colorful  administration  been  installed  to  give  renewed 
hope  and  confidence,  there  is  no  telling  how  serious  a  breakdown  of  the 
whole  structure  of  capitalistic  society  might  have  ensued.  One  can 
easily  imagine  what  would  happen  if  basic  industries,  transportation, 
or  food  production  were  entirely  disrupted. 

Our  economic  system,  if  it  runs  well,  can  do  more  for  man  than  any 
earlier  one,  but  it  exacts  a  price  for  this  advantage.  It  demands  rela- 
tively efficient  control  and  coordination  to  operate  at  all.  A  dynamo  can 
do  much  more  work  than  a  treadmill,  but  it  needs  more  expert  attention 
and  is  more  likely  to  get  out  of  order  if  carelessly  handled. 

The  second  major  contrast  between  our  age  and  any  previous  era  of 
transformation  is  that  the  alternatives  which  lie  ahead  are  far  more 
sharply  contrasting  than  was  the  case  in  any  previous  period.  'We  have 
today  a  mechanical  equipment  which  might  enable  us  to  attain  a  material 
Utopia  with  relatively  slight  physical  effort.,  0.  W.  Willcox  has  esti- 
mated that  we  could  produce  all  the  food  that  would  be  required  for  a 
liberal  diet  on  one  fifth  of  the  land  now  under  cultivation  in  the  United 
States  and  with  one  fifth  of  the  farmers  now  engaged  in  agriculture.  If 
we  eliminated  all  waste,  we  could  probably  produce  twice  as  great  a  vol- 
ume of  manufactured  goods  as  we  turn  out  today. 

•  We  are  the  first  generation  in  the  history  of  humanity  which  is  able, 
to  use  Plato's  phrase,  to  create  a  "city  of  happy  pigs." 2    k 

Likewise,  we  have  all  the  intelligence  and  information  necessary  to 
demonstrate  the  utter  imbecility  of  war  and  military  activities.  If  we 
could  apply  this  information  to  statecraft  and  diplomacy,  we  could  put 
an  end  to  the  menace  of  war. 

The  fact  that  we  have  Utopia  right,  at  hand,  if  we  have  intelligence 
enough  to  claim  it,  is  a  unique  experience  in  the  whole  history  of  human- 
ity. Hitherto,  the  Utopian  writers  have  had  to  dream  of  the  blessings 
of  some  future  era,  wholly  removed  from  the  realities  of  their  own  day; 
but  we  do  not  need  a  single  additional  machine  or  any  increase  of  our 
natural  resources.  Everything  which  Edward  Bellamy  dreamed  of  over 
fifty  years  ago  in  his  Looking  Backward  is  now  directly  available  for  us. 
•  If  our  generation  has  unique  capacity  to  enjoy  prosperity,  security  and 
world  peace,  it  also  faces  the  possibility  of  unprecedented  calamities  and 
misery.  If  we  do  not  succeed  in  controlling  the  new  empire  of  machines 
in  a  constructive  fashion,  there  is  every  probability  that  the  economic 
situation  will  grow  progressively  worse  until  the  whole  capitalistic  system 
ends  in  chaos.  The  breakdown  in  the  United  States  in  the  autumn  of 
1929  shows  that  unregulated  capitalism  cannot  be  trusted  to  conduct  its 
own  affairs.  There  is  as  yet  no  convincing  evidence,  except  in  a  few 
small  states,  that  capitalism  can  be  regulated  and  made  to  work  in  ade- 
quate fashion.  In  many  states  it  has  already  reached  the  condition  of 
desperation  which  invites  the  intervention  of  fascism. 

P  See  below,  pp.  795-804. 


52  CULTURAL  LAC  AND  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

Moreover,  our  unparalleled  mechanical  equipment  might  prove  only  a 
liability  to  the  human  race.  ,  If  the  second  World  War  continues  for  long, 
our  new  and  more  efficient  armaments  will  serve  only  to  make  possible 
a  more  rapid  and  certain  suicide  of  our  culture.  It  is  very  generally 
agreed  by  most  competent  observers  that  the  present  democratic  and 
capitalistic  civilization  cannot  withstand  the  impact  of  another  long- 
continued  world  war. 

In  his  Shape  of  Things  to  Come,  H.  G.  Wells,  our  most  talented  social 
prophet,  predicted  a  half-century  of  chaos  after  the  second  World  War, 
to  be  followed  by  a  new  type  of  civilization,  dominated  by  engineers  and 
internationalists.  That  this  happy  result  will  follow  is  purely  a  matter 
of  guesswork.  But  if  any  civilization  is  established  at  the  end  of  the 
current  World  War,  it  will  be  markedly  different  from  that  which  was 
known  in  most  of  the  world  in  1939. 

In  thus  facing  the  alternatives  of  a  material  Utopia  and  world  peace 
on  the  one  hand  and  economic  disintegration  and  widespread  chaos  on  the 
other,  our  generation  is  unique  in  the  experience  of  humanity.  Which 
road  we  shall  take  will  probably  be  decided  by  the  events  of  the  next 
quarter  of  a  century.  The  decision  will  tell  the  story  as  to  whether  man 
is  qualified  to  make  use  of  those  mechanical  advantages  which  the  last 
century  or  so  has  placed  at  his  disposal.  During  the  next  two  or  three 
decades,  then,  the  destiny  of  mankind  upon  the  planet  is  likely  to  be 
decided  for  many  generations  to  come. 

How  the  Gulf  Between  Machines  and 
Institutions  Came  About 

The  first  Industrial  Revolution,  which  started  in  England  about  1750, 
created  our  modern  methods  of  textile  manufacturing,  the  new  iron  and 
steel  industry,  the  steam  engine,  and  the  beginning  of  steam  navigation 
on  land  and  sea.  This  first  Industrial  Revolution  had  hardly  been  estab- 
lished in  many  countries  before  a  second  came  on  its  heels,  introducing 
the  application  of  chemistry  in  the  steel,  rubber,  oil,  and  other  industries, 
together  with  synthetic  products  of  many  kinds,  new  methods  of  trans- 
portation and  communication,  large-scale  industrial  establishments,  and 
the  like.  Today  we  are  in  the  midst  of  the  third  Industrial  Revolution — 
the  age  of  electrification,  automatic  machinery,  electric  control  ovef 
manufacturing  processes,  air  transport,  radios,  and  so  on. 

We  have  giant  turbines,  four  of  which  can  generate  more  energy  than  the 
whole  working  population  of  the  United  States.  We  possess  automatic 
machinery  of  the  most  amazing  efficiency.  One  plant  can,  for  example, 
turn  out  650,000  light  bulbs  each  day,  or  10,000  times  as  many  per  man  as 
was  possible  by  the  older  methods.  This  automatic  machinery  can  be 
controlled  by  a  photo-electric  cell,  or  "electric  eye,"  which  is  absolutely 
dependable  and  unfailing  and  all  but  eliminates  the  human  factor  in 
mechanical  production.  We  have  giant  auto  buses ;  clean,  quiet,  speedy 
Diesel-motored  trains;  safe,  swift  airplanes.  We  have  skyscrapers'.  Our 
bathrooms  would  fill  a  Roman  emperor  with  envy.  Our  system  of  com- 


CULTURAL   LAC  AND  SOCIAL  CRISIS  53 

munication  is  incredibly  extensive  and  efficient.  Our  radios  would  appear 
a  miracle  to  persons  who  died  so  recently  as  the  period  of  the  first  World 
War.  Our  modern  printing  presses  would  stagger  Gutenberg.  We  could 
thus  go  on  indefinitely  through  all  the  provinces  of  our  great  "empire  of 
machines." 

Never  before  has  there  been  any  such  discrepancy  between  the  mechani- 
cal side  of  culture  and  the  social  thinking  and  institutions  through  which 
material  life  is  controlled.  During  most  of  the  history  of  humanity, 
social  thinking  and  institutions  have  been  relatively  compatible  with  the 
science  of  technology  which  existed  in  any  age.  Only  in  the  case  of  the 
Greeks  and  Romans  and  of  ourselves  has  there  been  any  notable  gulf 
between  machines  and  institutions. 

In  the  classical  period,  particularly  among  the  Greeks  of  Athens  and 
Alexandria,  social  institutions  and  philosophy  advanced  much  further 
than  science  and  machinery,  whereas  our  machinery  is  infinitely  more 
up-to-date  and  adequate  than  our  thinking  and  institutions.  The  failure 
of  the  Greeks  and  Romans  to  promote  science  and  invention  so  as  to  keep 
pace  with  their  institutions  was  the  major  reason  for  the  collapse  of  classi- 
cal civilization.  There  is  a  grave  danger  that  our  failure  to  bring  our 
institutions  and  thinking  up  to  the  level  we  have  attained  in  science  and 
machinery  may  jeopardize  if  not  destroy  our  own  culture. 

The  reason  for  this  disparity  between  science  and  thinking  is  not  diffi- 
cult to  understand  if  we  are  familiar  with  the  history  of  the  modern  age. 
Social  thinking  and  institutional  development  since  1500  have  not  moved 
ahead  more  slowly  than  in  earlier  times.  What  has  upset  the  cultural 
balance  has  been  the  unprecedentedly  rapid  progress  of  science  and  ma- 
chinery since  1750.  .  Most  aspects  of  modern  culture  have  lent  great 
encouragement  to  the  development  of  science  and  machinery,  but  they 
have  given  no  comparable  impulse  to  the  growth  of  social  thinking  or 
institutional  changes.  • 

Considerable  opposition  was  offered  to  the  rise  of  modern  science,  par- 
ticularly by  religious  groups,  in  the  past.  The  publisher  of  Copernicus' 
great  work  was  alarmed  by  its  possible  consequences  and  wrote  a  pro- 
tective introduction  to  the  book.  Giordano  Bruno  was  sent  to  the  stake 
because  he  challenged  the  old  astronomical  scheme.  Gallileo  was  haled 
before  the  Roman  Inquisition  because  of  his  new  views  on  the  heavens. 
Vesalius  was  disciplined  because  of  his  early  work  on  comparative 
anatomy.  The  early  exponents  of  evolution  were  ridiculed  and  defamed 
by  churchmen.  But,  in  due  time,  natural  science  was  taken  over  into 
the  universities,  became  highly  respectable,  and  was  encouraged  by  busi- 
nessmen and  statesmen  alike. 

It  is  not  so  well  known  that  there  was,  once  upon  a  time,  persistent 
opposition  to  almost  every  significant  invention  of  modern  times.  In 
a  notable  chapter  on  "Resistances  to  the  Adoption  of  Technological  Inno- 
vations" in  the  important  publication,  Technological  Trends  and  National 
Policy,8  Bernhard  J.  Stern  shows  in  detail  how  popular  opposition  slowed 

3  Washington,  Government  Printing  Office,  1937,  pp.  39  ff. 


54  CULTURAL  LAC  AND  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

down  the  progress  and  adoption  of  important  mechanical  inventions. 
Laws  were  passed  to  prevent  or  to  discourage  the  use  of  stagecoaches. 
Canal  owners  carried  on  a  propaganda  against  the  introduction  of  rail- 
roads. It  was  alleged  that  the  boilers  of  the  engines  would  burst  and 
kill  passengers.  Doctors  testified  that  a  speed  of  20  miles  per  hour  would 
be  fatal  to  travelers.  The  progress  of  the  automobile  was  delayed  for 
decades  by  popular  opposition  and  ridicule,  though  a  steam  automobile 
was  actually  invented  by  Joseph  Cugnot  in  1769.  The  English  Parlia- 
ment in  1861  outlawed  horseless  carriages.  Popular  opposition  consti- 
tuted a  serious  handicap  to  the  installation  of  street  railways,  both  horse- 
drawn  and  electric.  The  public  ridiculed  and  delayed  the  introduction 
of  the  steamboat.  Even  world-famous .  scientists  ridiculed  the  early  in- 
ventors of  the  airplane.  There  was  great  difficulty  in  getting  anyone 
interested  in  the  telegraph  when  Morse  invented  it.  The  government 
refused  to  buy  his  patent  for  a  ridiculously  low  price.  At  first  the 
telephone  was  described  as  the  work  of  the  devil.  There  was  tremendous 
opposition  to  the  use  of  gas  for  lighting  purposes.  Likewise,  important 
newspapers  ridiculed  Edison's  invention  of  the  incandescent  lamp.  Wil- 
liam Kelly  encountered  ridicule  and  opposition  when  he  invented  the 
modern  method  of  making  steel.  Rioters  wrecked  the  early  textile  ma- 
chinery. The  sewing  machine  was  bitterly  fought  by  workers  in  the 
needle  trades,  and  the  early  agricultural  machinery  was  fought  rather 
than  welcomed  by  the  farmers. 

\  However,  this  hostility  and  obstruction  almost  disappeared,  and  the  cul- 
tural and  institutional  trends  of  modern  times  began,  on  the  whole,  to 
favor  developments  in  both  natural  science  and  mechanical  invention.. 
It  became  understood  that  science  protects  and  prolongs  human  life  and 
increases  the  possibility  of  financial  profit  in  business  and  ol  employ- 
ment for  workers.  Capitalism,  the  profit  system,  and  the  modern  busi- 
ness age  all  became  powerful  forces  stimulating  the,  growth  of  science  and 
machinery.  Those  whose  interests  were  tied  up  with  the  old  order  of 
production  naturally  opposed  inventions,  but  there  was  an  alert  minority 
which  in  time  discerned  the  financial  advantages  to  be  obtained  by 
accepting  them. 

When  the  inventions  became  more  technical  and  complicated  and 
tended  to  rest  more  and  more  upon  esoteric  discoveries  in  natural  science, 
business  threw  its  influence  behind  both  science  and  engineering.  The 
middle  class  owed  its  prestige  primarily  to  wealth  and  economic  success, 
and  it  inevitably  supported  those  types  of  intellectual  endeavor  which 
laid  the  material  foundations  for  efficient  manufacturing  and  the  profits 
which  flowed  therefrom.  The  progress  in  chemistry  and  in  air  navigation 
are  conspicuous  examples  of  the  way  in  which  even  war  has  promoted 
scientific  and  mechanical  progress.  Today,  though  finance  and  business 
on  the  whole,  support  and  encourage  scientific  and  mechanical  progress, 
there  are  still  striking  examples  of  business  sabotage  of  inventions  which 
threaten  to  undermine  heavy  investments  in  less  efficient  machinery. 


CULTURAL   LAC  AND  SOCIAL  CRISIS  55 

In  early  modern  times  there  was  actually  a  greater  impulse  to  institu- 
tional change  and  to  new  types  of  social  thought  than  there  was  t6  the 
progress  of  science  and  invention.  Between  1500  and  1800,  as  the  Middle 
Ages  came  to  an  end  and  modern  times  came  into  being,  these  changes 
were  mainly  the  product  of  the  middle  class.  The  middle  class  repudiated 
most  types  of  medieval  institutions  and  social  thought.  It  helped  along 
the  national  state  and  transformed  it  from  an  absolutistic  to  a  representa- 
tive basis.  It  developed  the  ideas  of  natural  law,  which  placed  juris- 
prudence behind  the  protection  of  property.  In  conjunction  with  the 
Protestant  ministers,  the  middle  class  brought  into  being  the  capitalistic 
system  and  the  eulogy  of  pecuniary  profits.  It  took  an  active  part  in 
colonialism  and  the  creation  of  modern  imperialism ;  developed  an  appro- 
priate type  of  political  and  economic  theory  to  justify  the  new  bourgeois 
system;  and  brought  into  being  the  liberal  political  philosophy,  justifying 
revolution  against  the  privileged  aristocracy  and  defending  outstanding 
civil  liberties,  such  as  freedom  of  speech,  press,  assemblage,  religion, 
and  the  like.  In  economics,  it  extolled  the  freedom  of  trade  and  the 
immunity  of  business  and  trade  from  extensive  governmental  regulation. 

Most  of  these  innovations  in  political  and  economic  philosophy  had 
been  executed  by  the  close  of  the  eighteenth  century.  The  system  thus 
created  tended  thereafter  to  crystallize  to  resist  change.  In  this  way, 
the  social  influences  which,  between  1500  and  1800,  had  strongly  encour- 
aged the  transformation  of  institutions  and  social  thought,  became  an 
insuperable  obstacle  to  such  change  in  the  nineteenth  and  twentieth  cen- 
turies. It  was  believed  that  the  interests  of  the  middle  class  were  linked 
up  with  preserving  the  status  quo  in  institutional  life  and  social  thought. 
Hence  the  business  and  financial  classes  threw  all  of  their  tremendous 
power  into  the  maintenance  of  things  as  they  were  in  institutional  life. 
This  they  did  at  the  very  time  when  they  were  becoming  most  enthusiastic 
in  the  way  of  promoting  progress  in  science  and  technology.  Therefore, 
from  about  1800  to  the  present  time,  the  dominating  economic  groups 
in  modern  society  have  tended  to  resist  social  and  institutional  change, 
while  at  the  same  time  they  have  encouraged  advances  in  science  and 
technology.  This  is  a  major  reason  for  the  strange  and  alarming  state 
of  affairs  which  we  face  today;  namely,  the  juxtaposition  of  a  thoroughly 
up-to-date  science  and  technology  and  a  heritage  of  social  institutions 
and  social  thought  which  date,  for  the  most  part,  from  around  1800  or 
earlier.  Conditions  in  our  modern  world  have,  for  more  than  a  century, 
made  strongly  for  scientific  and  mechanical  advance  and  for  institutional 
stability. 

Some  Social  and  Cultural   Implications  of  the 
Gulf  Between  Machines  and   Institutions 

One  of  the  most  conspicuous  things  about  the  mental  life  of  our  day 
is  the  contrast  in  our  attitude  toward*modernity  and  efficiency  in  science 
and  machinery,  on  the  one  hand,  and  in  institutions  and  social  thought, 


56  CULTURAL  LAC  AND  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

on  the  other.  We  desire,  if  we  have  money  enough  to  buy  them,  the  latest 
in  automobiles,  radios,  plumbing,  and  electrical  gadgets.  We  are  humili- 
ated by  any  evidence  that  we  are  behind  the  times  in  such  matters.  The 
average  American  would  be  greatly  embarrassed  to  drive  a  reconditioned 
Dodge  touring  car,  model  1920,  through  the  thoroughfares  of  any  of  our 
main  cities.  This  would  be  the  case  even  if  the  car  were  in  new  con- 
dition. The  mere  fact  that  its  model  was  two  decades  out  of  date  would 
provide  sharp  humiliation  for  the  owner. 

But  the  very  person  who  would  be  embarrassed  by  a  motor  car  two 
decades  behind  the  times  is  likely  to  demonstrate  great  enthusiasm,  if  not 
sheer  reverence,  for  a  constitution  a  century  and  a  half  old,  or  for  an 
economic  system  which  was  already  being  extolled  by  Adam  Smith  in  the 
year  1776.  The  man  who  expresses  great  contempt  for  the  transportation 
ideals  of  the  horse-and-buggy  era  usually  defends  with  gusto  and  convic- 
tion political  and  economic  ideas  which  antedate  the  stagecoach. 

This  situation  makes  it  very  difficult  to  do  anything  to  bridge  the  gulf 
between  machines  and  institutions.  So  long  as  we  are  proud  of  our 
institutions  and  ideas  in  proportion  to  the  antiquity  of  their  origin,  we 
have  less  than  any  incentive  to  bring  them  up  to  date.  Until  we  are  as 
much  embarrassed  by  an  archaic  idea  as  we  are  by  an  obsolete  gadget, 
there  is  little  prospect  of  making  any  headway  in  the  transformation  of 
our  institutional  equipment. 

Far  from  taking  steps  to  bridge  the  gulf  by  bringing  our  institutions  up 
to  date,  the  intellectual  attitudes  and  social  values  of  our  era  tend  to 
widen  the  gulf.  We  provide  all  sorts  of  prizes  for  scientists  and  engi- 
neers who  make  important  discoveries ;  yet  we  stand  in  no  great  present 
need  of  further  scientific  discoveries,  save  perhaps  in  the  field  of  medicine. 
Nor  do  we  actually  require  any  additional  mechanical  inventions.  •  What 
we  need  more  than  anything  else  today  are  the  contributions  of  the  social 
inventors — those  who  can  bring  our  institutions  and  social  thinking  up 
to  date  by  devising  new  and  better  forms  of  government,  economic  life, 
legal  practices,  moral  codes,  and  improved  educational  systems.  * 

But  we  have  few  or  no  prizes  or  rewards  for  the  social  inventor.  At 
be.st,  he  is  likely  to  be  ridiculed  as  a  crank  and  nitwit.  In  certain  coun- 
tries he  may  be  imprisoned  or  shot.  The  net  result  is  an  extension  of 
the  already  dangerous  abyss  between  our  science  and  machinery  and  our 
institutional  life  and  social -thought. 

It  is  not  surprising  to  find  a  sharp  contrast  between  the  type  of  guid- 
ance which  we  demand  in  the  field  of  science  and  technology  and  that 
with  which  we  rest  satisfied  in  regard  to  our  institutional  procedure.  We 
want  the  very  finest  medical  scientists  and  surgeons  we  can  afford.  We 
would  be  inexpressibly  shocked  at  the  suggestion  that  we  should  call  in, 
for  an  operation,  the  family  butcher,  who  might  possess  remarkable 
facility  as  a  precise  meat-cutter.  When  there  is  an  operation  to  be  per- 
formed upon  our  body,  we  wish  the  most  competent  brain  trust  we  can 
obtain.  But,  for  operations  upon  ,the  body  politic,  with  problems  far 
more  complex  and  technical  than  any  conceivable  surgical  operation  upon 


CULTURAL  LAC  AND  SOCIAL  CRISIS  57 

the  human  body,  we  let  political  butchers  hack  and  mangle  the  body 
politic  at  their  will.  Hence,  we  need  not  be  surprised  at  the  vast  amount 
of  bungling  which  goes  on  in  contemporary  political  life.  Until  we  are 
as  willing  to  call  in  experts  to  guide  us  in  our  institutional  life  as  we  are 
to  seek  their  medical  services  or  to  request  them  to  repair  our  gadgets, 
there  is  little  hope  that  we  shall  be  able  to  deal  effectively  with  the  com- 
plex problems  of  contemporary  life. 

-  The  discrepancy  which  exists  between  our  scientific  world  and  empire 
of  machines  and  our  institutions  and  social  thinking  is  of  the  greatest 
importance  in  any  attempt  to  understand  the  institutional  crisis  and 
the  social  problems  of  our  age.  •  The  latter  are,  without  exception,  inci- 
dental manifestations  of  the  gulf  between  machines  and  institutions,  no 
matter  what  type  of  social  problem  or  institutional  crisis  we  deal  with. 
While  millions  suffered,  were  on  relief,  or  were  ill-fed  and  ill-housed, 
the  government  paid  farmers  to  plow  under  wheat  and  cotton  so  that  we 
could  have  less  to  eat  and  wear.  Millions  have  been  on  relief  or  in  the 
bread-line  at  a  moment  when  the  factories  and  farms  were  well  equipped 
to  turn  out  an  abundance  of  goods  and  food.  Our  productive  potentiali- 
ties are  fitted  to  give  us  all  we  need  in  every  field  of  human  requirements. 
But  the  distributive  processes  of  society  possess  nothing  like  the  same 
facility  in  putting  goods  at  the  disposal  of  consumers. 

This  paradox  is  easily  explained.  The  productive  side  of  our  economic 
life,  based  primarily  upon  our  science  and  machinery,  is,  relatively  up-to- 
date  and  efficient;  the  ideas  and  practices  which  control  distribution  and 
consumption  are,  on  the  contrary,  a  manifestation  and  reflection  of  our 
institutional  life  and  social  thinking,  which  are  highly  retarded,  out-of- 
date,  and  ineffective.  If  we  possessed  the  same  efficiency  in  getting  goods 
to  eager  consumers  that  we  possess  in  turning  them  out  of  our  factories, 
there  would  be  no  economic  crisis  in  modern  industry.  At  present,  our 
clumsy  and  outworn  economic  system  exacts  around  $2.30  to  get  to  the 
consumers  each  dollar's  worth  of  goods  purchased  at  the  farm  or  factory 
gate.4  If  we  could  get  food  to  the  hungry  masses  as  readily  as  the  farmers 
can  provide  it,  there  would  be  no  crisis  in  agriculture,  no  millions  denied 
the  primary  necessities  of  existence. 

Take  the  example  of  war  in  contemporary  times.  -When  it  comes  to 
devising  and  manufacturing  bigger  and  better  machinery  for  the  destruc- 
tion of  humanity,  we  are  able  to  produce  ever  better  battleships,  subma- 
rines, tanks,  dive-bombers,  machine-guns,  field  and  long-range  artillery, 
and  semi-automatic  rifles.  There  seems  to  be  no  limit  to  the  intelli- 
gence which  we  apply  to  improving  our  war  machinery.  On  the  other 
hand,  we  approach  the  whole  social  and  cultural  problem  of  war  on  the 
basis  of  attitudes  which  date  back  to  the  period  of  bows-and-arrows  and 
the  battle-axe,  if  not  the  fist-hatchet.  r 

We  pool  every  intellectual  resource  of  university  laboratories  and  scien- 
tific foundations  to  discover  how  we  may  wage  war  more  efficiently.  But 
we  do  not  apply  even  sixth-grade  intelligence  in  studying  the  problem  of 

*See  Walter  Rautenstrauch,  Who  Gets  the  Money?    Harper,  1934,  pp.  29-47. 


58  CULTURAL  LAC  AND  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

how  we  might  rid  the  world  of  the  menace  of  war.  Whatever  social  serv- 
ices war  may  have  rendered  in  early  days,  it  has  now  become  a  fatal 
anachronism  and,  perhaps,  the  chief  threat  to  the  preservation  of  con- 
temporary civilization.  It  does  not  require  even  high  school  intelligence 
to  see  that  war  is  a  stupid  monstrosity.  Yet  the  very  best  brains  of  the 
world  are  still  employed  to  facilitate  its  deadly  ravages.  As  matters 
stand,  our  failure  to  bridge  the  gulf  between  war  machinery  and  our  insti- 
tutional approach  to  the  war  problem  may  ultimately  wipe  out  much  of 
our  present  civilization. 

The   Institutional   Lag   in  Contemporary  Culture 

•  The  most  advanced  knowledge  in  the  field  of  economics,  politics,  or  law 
is  as  up-to-date  and  accurate  as  that  which  dominates  the  scientific 
laboratory  and  schools  of  engineering.  But  very  little  of  this  new 
knowledge  is  brought  to  bear  upon  the  control  of  our  institutions  in  every- 
day life.  Indeed,  we  ridicule  the  very  notion  that  it  should  be.  Roose- 
velt's institution  of  a  very  limited  brain  trust  was  hooted  and  derided  by 
most  Americans — even  intellectuals.  We  may  now  take  a  few  pages  to 
document  the  assertion  that  most  of  our  institutional  life  and  social  think- 
ing dates  from  the  eighteenth  century  or  earlier. 

Our  opinions  and  institutions  have  altered  but  slightly  in  a  century 
and  a  half.  Any  person  who  was  a  member  of  the  Constitutional  Con- 
vention in  1787  would  be  completely  amazed  if  faced  by  our  modern 
material  culture,  but  he  could  discuss  economics,  politics,  law,  education, 
and  religion  with  a  contemporary  American  citizen.  Indeed,  even  the 
average  member  of  the  Constitutional  Convention  of  1787  would  be 
thought  dangerously  radical  by  a  reactionary  Democrat,  a  typical  mem- 
ber of  the  Republican  National  Committee,  a  member  of  the  Liberty 
League,  or  the  Dies  Committee. 

Anthropologists  have  described  the  primitive  mind  as  characterized 
chiefly  by  an  all-pervading  supernaturalism,  credulity,  lack  of  precise 
and  logical  thinking,  and  ignorance  of  scientific  methods  and  results. 
Judged  by  these  standards,  it  is  obvious  that  a  great  majority  of  Ameri- 
cans are  still  overwhelmingly  primitive  in  their  ways  of  thinking — as  are 
the  people  of  nearly  every  other  country.  A.  M.  Tozzer  of  Harvard  pub- 
lished some  years  ago  an  admirable  little  book  on  primitive  culture,  en- 
titled Social  Origins  and  Social  Continuities.  As  an  appendix  he  included 
an  exhibit  of  the  persistence  of  ancient  superstitions  in  the  themes  sub- 
mitted by  Harvard  freshmen  to  the  department  of  English.  He  showed 
a  striking  hang-over  of  the  primitive  belief  in  luck,  chance,  and  other 
pre-scientific  attitudes  and  devices. 

Many  still  believe  it  is  good  luck  to  see  the  new  moon  over  their  right 
shoulder,  or  to  find  a  four-leaf  clover.  Many  believe  that  it  is  a  bad 
omen  for  a  black  cat  to  cross  their  path.  Many  fear  to  light  three  ciga- 
rettes on  one  match,  or  to  start  a  journey  on  Friday  the  13th.  Many 
think  it  bad  luck  to  break  a  mirror.  Many  continue  to  attempt  to  tell 


CULTURAL  LAG  AND  SOCIAL  CRISIS  59 

fortunes  by  tea  leaves,  daisy  petals,  and  the  like.  Many  flip  a  coin  to 
determine  what  action  to  take,  and  knock  on  wood  to  avoid  bad  luck. 
Many  continue  to  pray  for  rain,  good  crops,  health,  and  the  like.  Many 
still  adopt  mascots,  which  are  reminiscent  of  the  primitive  totemic  ani- 
mals. Astrological  columns  in  the  newspapers  are  read  by  millions  with 
interest  and  respect. 

Our  fundamental  ideals  and  institutions  came  into  being  between  1500 
and  1800.  Capitalism  was  a  product  of  the  ethical  ideals  of  the  Protes- 
tants and  the  economic  ambitions  of  the  early  merchants.  Between  them 
they  elaborated  the  fundamental  notions  and  practices  of  the  capitalistic 
system.  The  virtues  and  validity  of  the  profit  motive  as  the  chief  incen- 
tive to  economic  activity  were  expounded  by  the  pastors  of  early  modern 
times,  particularly  the  Puritan  ministers.  Under  the  influence  of  Calvin 
they  emphasized  God's  approval  of  accumulating  wealth  through  business 
activity  and  extolled  the  virtues  of  thrift  and  industry.  The  persistent 
ideals  of  complete  liberty  for  economic  enterprise  and  of  the  emancipa- 
tion of  the  latter  from  governmental  interference  were  formulated  by  the 
Deists,  the  Physiocrats,  and  Adam  Smith  in  the  seventeenth  and  eight- 
eenth centuries.  The  economic  ideals  embodied  in  Herbert  Hoover's 
book,  Challenge  to  Liberty,  and  in  the  pronouncements  of  John  W.  Davis 
and  other  Liberty  League  potentates,  differ  in  no  fundamental  degree 
from  those  set  forth'  in  Adam  Smith's  Wealth  of  Nations,  which  appeared 
in  the  same  year  that  Jefferson  wrote  the  Declaration  of  Independence. 
When,  early  in  the  present  century,  the  American  coal  magnate  George  F. 
Baer  stated  that  our  modern  businessmen  are  unquestionably  "those 
Christian  men  to  whom  God  in  his  infinite  wisdom  has  given  the  control 
of  the  property  interests  of  the  country,"  he  was  only  echoing  the  senti- 
ments which  were  much  more  elaborately  expressed  by  James  Mill,  J.  B. 
Say,  and  others  in  the  first  half  of  the  nineteenth  century. 

Our  attitudes  and  usages  with  respect  to  property  are  equally  full  of 
primitive  vestiges.  The  notion  of  the  unique  sanctity  of  property  is  in 
part  an  outgrowth  of  primitive  magic,  mysticism,  and  superstition.  Our 
contemporary  view  of  property  rights  is  a  compound  of  ancient  legalism 
and  of  the  prevailing  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  century  Protestant  views 
of  God's  approval  of  thrift  and  profit.  To  these  have  been  added  the 
seventeenth  and  eighteenth  century  notion  that  the  chief  purpose  of  the 
state  and  legal  institutions  is  to  protect  private  property.  Nothing  more 
modern  than  this  is  necessary  to  explain  the  majority  decisions  of  the 
Supreme  Court  of  the  United  States  on  matters  pertaining  to  private 
property  in  the  twentieth  century.  Critical  writers,  like  Hobhouse, 
Tawney,  and  Veblen,  have  subjected  the  whole  conventional  theory  of 
property  to  searching  re-examination,  but  their  views  have  been,  for  the 
most  part,  ignored.  When  they  have  been  considered  at  all  they  have 
been  bitterly  attacked  as  un-American  or  Bolshevistic.  There  is  little 
or  nothing  in  current  American  conceptions  of  property  rights  which 
cannot  be  discovered  explicitly  or  implicitly  in  the  writings  of  John  Locke 
and  Sir  William  Blackstone. 


60  CULTURAL  LAC  AND  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

Our  political  opinions  and  institutions  represent  a  mosaic  mainly  com- 
pounded of:  (1)  veneration  of  the  state,  derived  from  the  oriental  em- 
peror worship  and  early  modern  nationalism;  (2)  the  classical  obsession 
with  the  merits  of  monarchy,  aristocracy,  and  democracy;  (3)  archaic 
views  of  representative  government,  which  developed  between  the  six- 
teenth and  eighteenth  centuries;  (4)  Rousseau's  notion  of  popular  sov- 
ereignty and  the  general  will;  (5)  the  seventeenth  and  eighteenth  century 
doctrine  of  natural  rights;  (6)  the  eighteenth  century  view  of  the  per- 
fectability  of  man,  linked  up  with  the  nineteenth  century  enthusiasm 
for  democracy. 

While  plenty  of  dynamic  and  vital  political  doctrine  is  expounded  by 
up-to-date  thinkers  in  the  field,  this  has  found  but  slight  adoption  in 
practice  and  there  has  been  singularly  little  effort  to  adapt  our  political 
institutions  to  the  needs  of  an  urban  industrial  age. 

Law  is  still  based  primarily  upon  oriental  usages  and  conceptions,  on 
the  formulations  of  the  Roman  jurists,  and  on  the  precedents  of  the  Eng- 
lish Common  Law.  Very  little  progress,  indeed,  has  been  made  in  the 
way  of  introducing  the  historical  and  sociological  point  of  view  in  the 
reconstruction  of  juristic  theory  and  practice  in  America. 

The  legal  ideals  which  have  dominated  the  conservative  majority  of 
the  United  States  Supreme  Court  in  their  decisions  upon  property  issues 
in  the  last  75  years  have  been  based  upon  the  theories  of  natural  law 
which  were  worked  out  by  Grotius,  Althusius,  Pufendorf ,  and  John  Locke 
in  the  seventeenth  century.  This  has  been  well  brought  out  by  Charles  G. 
Haines  in  The  Revival  of  Natural  Law  Concepts.5  The  rules  of  legal 
evidence  are  hopelessly  out  of  date  and  confused.  In  many  ways,  they 
are  almost  exactly  the  opposite  of  the  principles  and  processes  applied 
in  the  field  of  scientific  evidence,  which  are  designed  to  ascertain  the 
actual  truth  in  regard  to  some  specific  problem. 

The  attitude  taken  by  the  courts  towards  crime  and  criminal  responsi- 
bility is  a  composite  of  archaic  legalism,  religious  superstition,  and  meta- 
physical illusions.  With  the  exception  of  certain  advanced  work  in 
juvenile  courts,  there  is  but  the  slightest  recognition  of  the  modern  socio- 
psychological  conception  of  human  conduct  and  its  relation  to  the  causa- 
tion of  crime.  Even  in  the  field  of  insanity,  where  the  conventional  legal 
conception  of  the  free  moral  agent  is  in  part  suspended,  the  test  for  in- 
sanity is  strictly  legal  and  not  medical.  In  a  notorious  case  in  Ohio — 
that  of  Mr.  Remus — we  witnessed  the  amusing  spectacle  of  a  group  of 
learned  and  logical  physicians  branding  the  defendant  as  legally  sane 
but  medically  quite  irresponsible. 

We  have  been  especially  reluctant  to  bring  our  notions  of  sex  and  the 
family  into  harmony  with  contemporary  scientific  and  aesthetic  consid- 
erations. Our  sex  mores  and  family  institutions  embody:  (1)  a  primitive 
reaction  to  the  mystery  of  sex  and  of  women  in  particular;  (2)  Hebraic 
uxoriousness  and  conceptions  of  patriarchal  male  domination;  (3)  patris- 


8  Harvard  University  Press,  1930. 


CULTURAL  LAG  AND  SOCIAL  CRISIS  61 

tic  and  medieval  views  regarding  the  baseness  of  sex  and  sex  temptation, 
especially  as  offered  by  women;  (4)  the  medieval  esteem  for  virginity  in 
women;  (5)  the  sacramental  view  of  marriage,  which  leads  us  to  regard 
marriage  as  a  theological  rather  than  a  social  issue;  (6)  the  property 
views  of  the  early  bourgeoisie;  and  (7)  the  Kantian  rationalization  of 
personal  inadequacy  and  inexperience.  There  are  very  few  items  in  the 
sex  mores  of  a  conventionally  respectable  American  today  which  square 
with  either  science  or  aesthetics. 

Our  educational  system  has  changed  little  when  compared  with  the 
vast  alteration  of  our  ways  of  living.  •  Certain  basic  strains  in  our  edu- 
cational doctrine  are  derived  from  the  oriental  and  medieval  notion  that 
the  chief  purpose  of  education  is  to  make  clear  the  will  of  the  gods  or  of 
God  to  man.%  From  the  Greeks  and  Romans  came  the  high  esteem  placed 
upon  training  in  rhetoric  and  argumentation  as  the  prime  essential  of  a 
successful  career  in  politics.  Humanism  contributed  the  view  that  the 
classical  languages  embody  the  flower  of  secular  learning  and  represent 
the  most  exquisite  form  of  literary  expression.  The  democratic  phi- 
losophy of  the  last  century  supported  the  idea  that  everybody  is  entitled 
to  participate  in  a  complete  system  of  education,  and  that  educational 
opportunities  should  be  equal  for  all.  But  we  went  on  teaching  little 
democrats  the  same  subject-matter  that  had  been  designed,  centuries 
before,  to  fill  the  minds  of  the  children  of  the  feudal  nobility  and  the 
squirearchy — thus  strikingly  illustrating  the  fact  of  cultural  lag  in  the 
field  of  education. 

The  punitive  psychology,  which  still  dominates  the  greater  part  of  our 
educational  procedure,  was  derived  from  the  Christian  philosophy  of 
solemnity  and  of  the  need  for  exacting  discipline  of  the  will. 

Education  in  the  natural  and  social  sciences  and  in  technology  was  re- 
garded for  a  long  time  as  relatively  unimportant,  and  even  today  it 
occupies  not  nearly  so  great  a  part  in  our  educational  system  as  the  older 
currents  in  our  curriculum.  Horace  M.  Kallen  has  observed  that  educa- 
tion today  is  more  of  a  distraction  from  life  than  a  preparation  for  it. 
Few  of  the  real  problems  involved  in  living  intelligently  and  successfully 
in  an  urban  and  industrial  world-society  are  touched  upon  vitally  in  our 
educational  system,  from  the  kindergarten  to  the  graduate  school.  Nor 
has  there  been  much  effort  to  work  over  our  educational  methods  in  har- 
mony with  the  modern  psychological  truism  that  vivid  personal  interest 
is  the  only  sensible  basis  of  a  dynamic  educational  scheme.  In  the 
matter  of  social  change,  organized  education  is  overwhelmingly  lined 
up  with  conservatism  and  the  status  quo.  Indeed,  it  is  extremely  pre- 
carious for  a  teacher  even  to  advocate  in  the  abstract  that  education 
should  assume  the  responsibility  for  guiding  humanity  to  a  better  day 
and  a  more  adequate  social  order. 

Journalism  has  not  as  yet  achieved  any  considerable  success  as  a 
method  of  accurately  informing  the  public  with  respect  tofcontemporary 
issues  and  providing  general  educational  direction  in  regard  to  the  prob- 
lems of  modern  life.  It  is  still  chiefly  a  method  of  continuing  the  whole- 


62  CULTURAL  LAG  AND  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

sale  dissemination  of  the  old  brand  of  neighborhood  gossip  in  an  age 
when  the  neighborhood  has  disappeared  and  face-to-face  gossiping  has 
become  ever  more  inadequate  and  impossible.  The  same  subjects  that 
made  juicy  gossip  in  the  pre-newspaper  days  still  constitute  the  best  copy 
for  the  contemporary  newspapers.  Personalities  are  much  more  highly 
esteemed  than  principles.  'No  scientific  discovery  of  modern  times,  no 
engineering  achievement  of  our  age,  and  no  social  reform  program  enunci- 
ated in  our  day  has  received  the  same  publicity  as  was  bestowed  upon  the 
kidnapping  of  the  Lindbergh  baby  or  the  birth  and  destiny  of  the  Dionne 
quintuplets.  » No  newspaper  which  has  made  a  serious  effort  to  devote 
itself  primarily  to  public  education  on  vital  topics  of  economic,  political, 
and  sociological  import  has  been  able  to  survive. 

Religion  is  probably  the  most  archaic  element  in  our  culture,  and  the 
most  reluctant  to  take  cognizance  of  contemporary  developments  in 
knowledge  and  life.  The  fundamentalists — viewing  the  term  broadly — 
among  whom  are  numbered  the  majority  of  religious  communicants  today, 
live  under  the  domination  of  the  same  intellectual  and  emotional  patterns 
as  prevailed  in  primitive  times.  William  Jennings  Bryan  openly  de- 
clared at  the  Dayton  trial  in  1925  that  no  statement  whatever  would 
appear  to  him  preposterous  or  unsupportable,  provided  it  be  found  in 
Holy  Writ.  Even  a  majority  of  liberal  theologians  today  are  in  rebellion 
mainly  against  seventeenth  and  eighteenth  century  religious,  ethical,  and 
philosophic  views.  Probably  not  one  per  cent  of  modern  theologians  are 
really  adjusted  to  contemporary  knowledge  and  ways  of  thinking.  At 
best,  a  majority  of  them  are  attempting  to  express  archaic  views  in  con- 
temporaneous phraseology,  though  some  courageous  religious  reformers 
have  squared  their  views  with  modern  science.  tThat  religion  is  slower 
in  readjusting  itself  to  new  ways  of  living  and  thinking  than  any  other 
phase  of  human  culture  was  admirably  demonstrated  by  the  study  of  the 
relative  change  of  opinions  and  attitudes  in  American  culture  since  1890 
embodied  in  Dr.  and  Mrs.  Lynd's  book  Middletown.6  Religion  is  the 
primary  intellectual  factor  that  discourages  a  candid  and  secular  ap- 
proach to  the  reconstruction  of  human  knowledge  and  social  conduct  in 
many  other  fields. 

\The  greatest  danger  that  faces  contemporary  civilization  is  this  alarm- 
ing discrepancy  between  our  natural  science  and  technology  on  the  one 
hand  and  our  opinions  and  social  institutions  on  the  other.  *  Modern  civi- 
lization is  like  a  man  with  one  foot  strapped  to  an  ox-cart  and  the  other 
to  an  airplane — with  one  set  of  loyalties  to  a  windmill  and  another  to  a 
dynamo. 

This  sort  of  situation  cannot  continue  indefinitely.  Unless  we  can 
bring  our  thinking  and  institutions  up  to  date,  the  ultimate  collapse  of 
civilization  is  inevitable.  At  present,  far  from  closing  the  gap,  the  tend- 
ency is  for  the  divergence  to  become  ever  greater.  Our  technology  is 
progressing  with  dizzy  speed,  each  year  making  more  remarkable  strides 


6  Harcourt,  Brace,  1920. 


CULTURAL  LAG  AND  SOCIAL  CRISIS  63 

than  ever  before.    At  the  same  time,  the  forces  of  social  conservatism 
seem  to  be  getting  stronger.    The  outlook,  then,  is  not  too  optimistic. 


Are  We  Living  in  a  Scientific  Age? 

The  above  discussion  enables  us  to  comment  intelligently  upon  the 
frequent  assertion  that  we  are  living  in  a  scientific  age.  The  fact  is,  of 
course,  that  we  are  not  doing  anything  of  the  sort,  so  far  as  the  attitudes 
of  the  average  citizen  are  concerned. 

%,  The  mass  of  mankind  in  Western  civilization  was,  it  is  true,  vastly 
affected  in  an  indirect  way  by  the  progress  of  nineteenth  and  early  twen- 
tieth century  science.  New  mechanical  devices  and  conveniences  vitally 
altered  people's  lives.  >  Men  were  healed  of  diseases  more  surely  and 
more  often  and  operated  upon  by  surgeons  more  successfully  and  more 
painlessly.  In  popular  magazines  and  newspapers  they  read  superficially 
about  the  wonders  that  modern  science  had  uncovered.  They  looked 
through  bigger  and  better  telescopes,  and  through  more  powerful  micro- 
scopes, to  instruct  or  amuse  themselves  with  respect  to  the  heavens  or  the 
minute  wonders  of  the  animal  and  vegetable  worlds. 

However,  as  we  have  said  in  connection  with  technological  advance, 
the  mode  of  thinking  of  men  in  the  Western  world  was  very  slightly 
altered  by  the  direct  impact  of  science.  To  be  sure,  the  perspective  of  a 
man  who  has  traveled  across  a  continent  in  a  streamlined  railroad  train 
must  be  somewhat  different  from  that  of  one  whose  travels  have  been 
limited  to  an  ox-cart  within  a  rural  township.  But  a  transcontinental 
railroad  trip  may  not  prevent  a  person  from  thinking  about  the  funda- 
mental problems  of  life  and  society  much  as  his  grandfather  did  two  gen- 
erations before  while  jogging  along  with  a  horse  and  buggy. 

Such  is  the  situation  with  Western  civilization  as  a  whole.  In  their 
thinking  about  God,  the  world,  man,  politics,  law,  wealth  and  economics, 
education,  and  the  problems  of  right  and  wrong,  most  men  are  as  much 
dominated  by  custom,  tradition,  folklore,  and  habit  in  1942,  as  they  were 
in  1642.  The  power  of  the  supernatural  over  human  thought  has  been 
but  little  affected  by  scientific  progress.  Tradition  and  emotion,  rather 
than  fact  and  logic,  prevail.  Belief  and  conviction  are  supreme. 

Our  opinions  and  institutions  are  overwhelmingly  the  product  of  con- 
tributions from  the  pre-scientific  era.  *  In  our  age,  civilization  has  been 
profoundly  affected  in  certain  respects  by  scientific  discoveries  and  their 
application  to  our  material  cultures  Thus  mankind,  still  primarily  pre- 
scientific  in  its  thinking  and  life-interests,  has  been  able  to  appropriate 
the  results  of  the  investigations  and  achievements  of  a  few  scientifically 
minded  pioneers.  Probably  fewer  than  500  individuals  have  been  respon- 
sible for  the  changes  in  the  material  civilization  that  separate  us  from  the 
days  of  Columbus  and  Luther.  Modern  civilization  is  a  venerable  para- 
site unintelligently  exploiting  the  products  of  contemporary  science  and 
technology. 

Very  often  those  who  most  greedily  accept  and  enjoy  the  products  of 


64  CULTURAL  LAG  AND  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

modern  science  and  technology  engage  in  attacks  upon  the  scientific  ap- 
proach to  life.  Not  infrequently,  persons  who  are  most  exacting  in  their 
demands  for  the  most  recent  provisions  in  plumbing,  the  best  medical 
attention,  the  most  efficient  and  up-to-date  automobiles,  at  the  same 
time  defend  classical  or  medieval  civilization  as  the  ideal  period  of  human 
development.  Many  a  plutocrat  riding  about  in  a  Rolls-Royce  is  at  the 
same  time  disporting  an  intellect  which  could  be  matched  in  most  respects 
by  the  mental  attitudes  of  a  cave-dweller  in  the  late  Paleolithic  period, 
or  of  Tecumseh  or  Sitting  Bull. 

Many  might  gather  from  the  above  discussion  the  impression  that  our 
social  thinking,  in  being  frequently  so  archaic,  is  well-organized,  coherent, 
static,  and  clear-cut.  This  is  decidedly  not  the  case.  While  it  has  a 
common  denominator  of  antiquity,  our  conventional  social  thought  is 
often  confused,  shifting,  and  contradictory.  The  uncertainty  and  dis- 
agreement in  the  traditional  camp  is  due  in  part  to  the  clash  of  class  inter- 
ests and  the  changing  lines  of  defense  of  conventional  society.  Bankers, 
for  example,  favor  free  trade,  while  manufacturers  are  prone  to  support 
a  protective  tariff.  Employers  and  laborers,  while  they  may  both  espouse 
the  economic  principles  of  Adam  Smith  and  Ricardo,  have  radically 
different  attitudes  towards  the  wage  problem  and  collective  bargaining. 
Political  parties  rationalize  their  struggles  for  the  spoils  of  office  in  terms 
of  conflicting  ideologies,  which  may  have  only  one  point  in  common — 
their  mutual  departure  from  the  realities  of  history  and  social  science. 
Conservative  educators  may  quarrel  over  the  necessary  degree  of  intellec- 
tual discipline,  while  mutually  ignoring  the  relation  of  all  education  to 
social  change  and  social  planning.  The  New  Deal  was  devoted  to  the 
effort  to  save  capitalism,  but  it  was  regarded  by  "Economic  Royalists" 
as  dominated  by  Muscovite  ideals  and  motives.  Liberal  theologians 
attack  Fundamentalists  no  less  vigorously  than  they  do  the  formulators 
of  a  rational  theology. 

Not  only  do  all  traditionalists  frustrate  and  delay  a  scientific  attack 
on  our  social  problems;  their  differences  among  themselves  weaken  the 
efficiency  and  coherence  of  the  traditional  order  of  society. 

In  short,  the  real  problem  facing  modern  civilization  is  to  make  this 
age  actually  a  scientific  one,  in  which  we  will  insist  not  only  upon  con- 
temporaneous bathtubs  but  also  upon  intellectual  and  social  assump- 
tions harmonious  with  up-to-date  plumbing.  In  a  truly  scientific  age  a 
man  would  be  as  much  humiliated  and  disgraced  to  defend  the  literal 
inspiration  of  the  Bible  or  to  oppose  birth-control  as  he  would  be  today 
if  he  were  compelled  to  travel  daily  down  Fifth  Avenue,  New  York,  in  an 
ox-^cart,  or  to  use  stone  implements  in  eating  his  soup  at  a  metropolitan 
banquet. 

If  we  are  to  bridge  the  gulf  between  machines  and  institutions  and 
bring  our  social  life  up  to  date,  we  must  develop  and  apply  the  social 
sciences  in  our  institutional  life  to  the  same  extent  that  we  have  cultivated 
natural  science  and  technology  in  building  the  empire  of  machines. 
This  fact  has  been  amply  emphasized  by  Professor  Robert  S.  Lynd  in  his 


CULTURAL   LAC  AND   SOCIAL  CRISIS  65 

courageous  and  realistic  book,  Knowledge  for  What? 7  This  book  is,  it- 
self, a  modest  effort  to  subject  our  institutional  life  to  the  scrutiny  and 
analysis  of  social  science.  The  degree  to  which  it  has  succeeded  will  be 
measured  by  the  extent  to  which  the  reader  gains  a  better  understanding 
of,  and  a  more  dynamic  attitude  towards,  the  institutions  and  social 
problems  of  our  age. 


7  Princeton  University  Press,  1939. 


PART  II 
Economic  Institutions  in  an  Era  of  World  Crisis 


CHAPTER   IV 
Some  Phases  of  the  Evolution  of  Industry 

Some  Suggested  Stages  of   Industrial   Evolution 

ONE  OF  the  chief  institutional  efforts  of  mankind  has  been  that  related 
to  the  task  of  making  a  living — the  customs  and  institutions  that  Sumner 
and  Keller  call  the  "mores"  of  self-maintenance.  But  industry  has  long 
been  impelled  by  other  forces  than  the  sheer  quest  for  livelihood.  Greed, 
envy,  emulation,  the  quest  of  the  prestige  and  leisure  which  accompany 
wealth  and  property,  have  been  almost  as  potent  stimuli  to  industrial 
effort  as  has  been  the  material  need  for  food,  clothes,  and  shelter.  Indeed, 
within  historic  times,  those  who  have  controlled  and  directed  industry 
have  been  only  incidentally  concerned  with  satisfying  their  direct  ma- 
terial needs.  They  have  been  motivated  chiefly  by  the  prestige  and 
leisure  associated  with  wealth.  Providing  a  livelihood  for  the  masses 
would  be  a  very  easy  task  today  if  our  industrial  organization  were 
directed  to  this  end  alone,  or  even  mainly  to  this  end. 

Though  the  term  industry  is  usually  limited  to  some  form  of  manu- 
facturing, we  shall  cover  at  least  briefly  the  collection  of  herbs,  berries, 
and  nuts,  hunting  and  fishing,  pastoral  life,  agriculture,  manufacturing, 
and  trade.  But  we  shall  differentiate  manufacturing  industry  from  other 
forms  of  effort  and  treat  of  outstanding  periods  or  stages  in  its  evolution. 

A  generation  ago,  when  the  idea  of  social  evolution  dominated  social 
and  economic  thinking,  it  was  very  usual  for  economic  historians  to 
outline  so-called  stages  of  economic  evolution.  These  were  supposed  to 
'be  rather  universal  and  to  have  followed  each  other  in  uniform  sequence 
everywhere  over  the  planet.  Since  different  criteria  of  progress  and  a 
variety  of  economic  items  were  selected  for  special  emphasis  by  economic 
historians,  these  alleged  stages  of  economic  evolution  varied  widely.  We 
can  illustrate  this  more  thoroughly.  If  one  took  as  the  chief  criterion  of 
economic  development  the  dominant  type  of  economic  effort,  the  stages 
outlined  were  likely  to  be  something  like  the  following: 

The  economy  of  collectors — natural  foraging,  hunting,  and  fishing. 
The  pastoral  economy. 
The  agricultural  economy. 
The  commercial  economy. 
The  industrial  economy. 
The  financial  economy. 

The  governmental  economy — state  capitalism  or  state  socialism. 

66 


PHASES   OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF    INDUSTRY        67 

If  the  methods  by  which  industry  is  carried  on  are  singled  out  as  a 
basis  for  classification,  agriculture  is  usually  divided  into  the  periods  of 
the  hoe  culture,  the  plow  culture,  and  mechanical  agriculture.  Manu- 
facturing industry  has  been  divided  into  two  broad  stages:  the  handicraft 
or  tool  era  and  the  age  of  machines  and  the  factory  system  since  the 
Industrial  Revolution.  Another  form  of  differentiation  has  been  to  stress 
the  sequence  of  technology  in  the  use  (1)  of  natural  objects,  (2)  of  tools, 
and  (3)  of  machines.  If  the  mode  of  power  used  constitutes  the  test,  we 
find  the  sequence  of  hand  power,  water  power,  steam  power,  and  electrical 
power.  If  major  stress  is  laid  upon  the  place  where  labor  has  been 
applied  to  produce  goods,  we  often  find  the  following  sequence  suggested: 

The  home. 

The  small  shop. 

The  gild  establishment. 

The  putting-out  system  in  the  home. 

The  factory. 

The  super-factory. 

Here  is  another  classification  based  upon  the  same  general  point  of 
view: 

The  family  economy. 
The  village  economy. 
The  town  economy. 
The  city  economy. 
The  metropolitan  economy. 

If  the  economic  historian  has  been  chiefly  interested  in  the  methods  of 
applying  and  controlling  labor,  the  following  stages  are  frequently 
separated: 

The  family  system. 

The  gild  system. 

The  putting-out  system. 

The  factory  system  under  private  enterprise. 

The  factory  system  under  state  capitalism  or  state  socialism. 

Another  way  of  dividing  economic  stages  has  been  related  primarily 
to  the  evolution  of  money  and  credit.  One  familiar  classification  along 
this  line  is  that  of: 

The  natural  economy — exchange  by  barter. 
The  money  economy. 

The  credit  economy  ("the  promise  men  live  by,"  according  to  Harry  Scher- 
man). 

Another  scheme,  expanding  the  same  basis  of  differentiation  to  include  the 
pattern  of  economic  control,  is: 

Individual  production  for  one's  own  needs. 
The  exchange  economy. 
The  capitalistic  economy: 

Commercial  capitalism. 

Industrial  capitalism. 

Monopoly  capitalism. 

Finance  capitalism. 

State  capitalism. 


68        PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION  OF   INDUSTRY 

A  broad  classification,  based  upon  both  occupations  and  industrial 
technique,  is  that  proposed  by  Richard  T.  Ely: * 

The  hunting  and  fishing  stage. 
The  pastoral  stage. 
The  agricultural  stage. 
The  handicraft  stage. 
The  industrial  stage: 

Universal  competition. 

Concentration. 

Integration. 

If  one  were  to  seize  upon  the  dominant  objectives  and  activities  of 
economic  life,  one  could  discern  the  following  stages  of  development: 

The  collecting  economy. 

The  pastoral-agricultural  economy. 

The  commercial  economy. 

The  manufacturing  economy. 

The  financial  economy. 

The  state  economy. 

A  recent  and  illuminating  classification  of  economic  development, 
based  upon  the  dominating  type  of  technology,  has  been  proposed  by 
Lewis  Mumford  in  Technics  and  Civilization.2  Leaving  aside  very  early 
forms  of  economic  effort  in  the  hunting,  fishing,  pastoral,  and  agricultural 
periods,  he  divides  the  rise  of  the  machine  economy  into  three  stages: 
(1)  the  Eotechnic  or  dawn  age  of  machine  technology,  resting  on  a  fire, 
wood,  and  water  basis  and  involving  such  things  as  the  water  wheel, 
wooden  ships,  printing  machinery,  and  simple  clocks;  (2)  the  PaZeo- 
technic  or  early  machine  age,  based  on  coal  and  iron  and  embracing  the 
inventions  and  devices  we  customarily  associate  with  the  first  Industrial 
Revolution;  and  (3)  the  Neotcchnic  or  recent  machine  age,  depending  on 
electricity  and  alloys  and  embodying  the  technological  advances  we  shall 
describe  in  this  chapter  as  the  later  stages  of  the  second  Industrial 
Revolution. 

These  attempts  to  differentiate  economic  life  into  stages  of  growth  and 
change  help  to  clarify  one's  approach  to  the  evolution  of  industry  and 
provide  a  clearer  perspective  on  economic  evolution.  But  we  no  longer 
believe,  with  the  older  evolutionary  writers,  that  there  can  be  some  all- 
inclusive  scheme  of  stages  that  takes  into  consideration  all  the  outstand- 
ing factors  in  the  evolution  of  industry.  Nor  do  we  any  longer  concede 
that  these  stages,  even  when  relatively  valid,  apply  everywhere  in  the 
same  degree  and  have  always  succeeded  each  other  in  uniform  sequence 
among  civilized  peoples  in  all  parts  of  the  earth.  There  is  much  over- 
lapping in  any  scheme  of  classification  and  evolution,  however  sound 
and  suggestive.  Even  in  our  own  era,  when  manufacturing  predominates 
over  agriculture  as  the  outstanding  form  of  industrial  effort,  agriculture 


1  Studies  in  the  Evolution  of  Industrial  Society,  Macmillan,  1903. 

2  Harcourt,  Brace,  1934. 


PHASES  OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF    INDUSTRY        69 

still  remains  vitally  important  in  our  economic  life,  as  also  do  the  pastoral 
industries.  When  viewed  with  these  qualifications,  the  notion  of  eco- 
nomic stages  may  still  be  highly  useful  to  students  in  attaining  a  broad 
perspective  on  industrial  progress. 

Outstanding  Aspects  of  the  Evolution 
of  Agriculture 

The  Origins  of  Agriculture.  For  nearly  a  million  years  mankind 
had  no  formal  industrial  life,  if  industry  is  interpreted  according  to  con- 
ventional usage.  There  were  no  domesticated  animals  and  no  agricul- 
ture. There  was  no  manufacturing  industry,  save  for  making  the 
weapons  and  implements  used  in  a  hunting  and  fishing  economy.  For 
three  quarters  of  a  million  years  man  did  not  even  have  stone  weapons, 
and  he  lived  simply  by  picking  up  what  he  could  of  fruits,  grasses,  roots, 
berries,  and  nuts.  If  he  lived  on  animal  flesh  or  fish  he  could  only  use 
such  of  these  as  he  caught  in  his  hands  and  was  willing  to  consume  un- 
cooked. In  the  Paleolithic  or  Old  Stone  Age,  man  continued  to  gather 
berries,  herbs,  and  nuts  but  he  also  provided  stone  and  bone  implements 
to  aid  him  in  hunting  and  fishing,  and  he  mastered  the  art  of  making  fire, 
so  as  to  cook  some  of  his  food.  He  also  domesticated  dogs.  It  was  not 
until  the  New  Stone  or  Neolithic  Age  began,  perhaps  as  early  as  18,000 
years  ago,  that  man  domesticated  other  animals  and  took  up  early  types 
of  agriculture.  Economic  life  before  Neolithic  times  is  generally  known 
in  economic  history  as  the  era  of  collectors,  or  the  collecting  economy. 

Agriculture  dates  from  the  Neolithic  Age.  It  was  indeed  a  great  dis- 
covery when  man  found  that  he  could  plant  seeds  and  get  a  crop  in 
return.  Perhaps  man,  as  G.  Elliot  Smith  suggests,  "began  agriculture 
as  an  irrigator."  It  may  have  happened,  once  it  was  recognized  that 
the  soil  became  most  fertile  where  it  had  been  covered  by  a  flooded 
stream,  that  man  simply  imitated  the  action  of  the  river.  He  then, 
perhaps,  made  artificial  depressions,  where  water  could  gather  and  in- 
crease the  productivity  of  grain  that  still  grew  wild  and  naturally.  It 
is  also  possible  that  the  discovery  of  agriculture  was  woman's  achieve- 
ment. In  primitive  times,  women  usually  brought  the  grain  and  food 
plants  to  the  home,  and  it  may  be  that  an  alert  woman  noticed  that  where 
some  seeds  or  bulbs  had  been  dropped  the  plants  themselves  appeared  the 
following  spring.  Thereafter,  she  may  have  done  the  planting  con- 
sciously. Some  anthropologists  believe  that  not  a  sown  species  but  a 
plant  with  side  shoots,  like  a  banana,  or  a  tuber  (taromyam)y  was  the 
first  to  be  cultivated. 

The  Nile  Valley  was  blessed  with  natural  conditions  most  favorable  to 
agriculture — warm  climate,  rich  soil,  and  enough  moisture — and  there 
is  evidence  that  cereals  have  been  cultivated  there  for  some  ten  thousand 
years.  On  these  grounds,  Egypt  is  often  held  to  be  the  original  source 
of  systematic  human  agriculture. 

We  have  evidence  that  Neolithic  peoples  were  familiar  with  barley, 


70        PHASES   OF  THE  EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY 

wheat,  millet,  peas,  lentils,  beans,  apples,  and  certain  other  fruits,  and 
flax,  which  was  used  for  textile  purposes.  There  were  no  plows;  pointed 
sticks  served  at  first  to  grub  up  roots  and  dig  holes,  and  later  agriculture 
was  carried  on  in  the  crude  fashion  known  as  "hoe  culture."  While  early 
agriculture  yielded  little,  and  simply  supplemented  the  food  supply  pro- 
vided by  hunting  and  fishing,  it  did  revolutionize  the  life  of  primitive 
man.  Georges  Renard  writes  cogently  as  follows: 

A  new  civilization  arose  with  the  growth  of  agriculture.  The  peoples  who 
adopted  it,  submitted  to  endure  disciplined,  regular  daily  work  accomplished 
often  by  a  co-operative  effort  according  to  the  seasons.  They  had  a  hearth, 
a  home  lit  up  at  night  by  the  oil  lamps,  surrounded  by  a  stockade.  They 
took  root  there  where  they  were  born,  where  their  dead  were  buried.  Eaters 
of  bread,  they  had  gentler  manners  and  began  to  hold  cannibalism  in  detesta- 
tion. Within  their  villages  there  thronged  a  dense  population,  which  was 
fundamentally  peaceful  and  formed  a  whole  in  which  peasants  and  workers 
lived  amicably  side  by  side.  Every  change  of  environment  causes  a  change  in 
habits,  ideas,  beliefs,  and  the  change  that  wedded  man  to  the  soil,  fixed  him 
on  the  land  and  for  the  first  time  gave  him  a  country,  was  an  enormous  one.3 

Another  real  step  in  advance  was  achieved  during  the  Neolithic  period 
through  the  domestication  of  the  more  common  animals.  There  is  no 
agreement  as  to  whether  animals  or  plants  were  domesticated  first.  Per- 
haps the  two  processes  took  place  at  about  the  same  time.  It  may  be 
that  man  did  not  begin  to  raise  animals  until  he  had  a  relatively  fixed 
home  and  a  clearing,  or  perhaps  he  was  able  to  build  homes  because  he 
was  no  longer  fully  dependent  on  the  chase  for  meat.  Speculation  aside, 
we  know  that  the  domestication  of  cattle,  swine,  sheep,  and  goats  was 
achieved  before  the  close  of  the  Neolithic  Age.  These  animals  were  not 
bred  at  the  outset  for  drawing  the  plow  or  wheeled  vehicles,  for  these 
did  not  appear  until  well  along  in  the  metal  ages.  They  served  first  of 
all  as  a  reserve  of  food,  and  were  also  valued  for  their  milk  or  skins.  It 
was  later  that  man  "condemned  them  to  hard  labor."  No  early  use  of 
swine  is,  however,  known  to  have  existed  in  pre-literary  Egypt.  Nor 
was  beef  eaten  in  early  Egypt,  Babylonia,  or  China.  Milking,  however, 
w#s  often  a  late  practice  of  primitive  animal-breeders. 

Agriculture  in  the  Ancient  Near  Orient.  Agriculture  and  the  pas- 
toral industries  achieved  striking  advances  in  the  ancient  oriental  cultures 
of  Egypt,  Babylonia,  and  Assyria.  Additional  types  of  animals  were 
domesticated,  and  we  also  find  at  this  time  the  first  domestication  of 
fowls.  The  most  important  animals  domesticated  in  this  period  were 
the  donkey,  horse,  mule,  and  camel.  The  donkey  was  domesticated  in 
Egypt,  and  the  domesticated  horse  first  appeared  in  western  Asia  around 
2200  B.C.  The  hybrid  mule  became  common  after  the  introduction  of 
the  horse,  and  the  camel  became  popular  in  the  late  Assyrian  period  in 
western  Asia  (c.  700  B.C.)  and  in  the  Ptolemaic  period  (c.  300  B.C.)  in 
Egypt.  Further,  we  have  in  the  oriental  period  the  first  evidences  of 


3G.  F.  Renard,  Life  and  Work  in  Prehistoric  Times,  Knopf,  1929,  pp.  131-132. 


PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY        71 

the  selective  breeding  of  domesticated  animals  for  specialized  purposes. 
Also,  domesticated  animals  ceased  to  be  exploited  solely  for  their  flesh, 
skins,  or  milk,  and  many  of  them  came  to  be  utilized  for  draft  purposes. 

Agriculture  was  revolutionized.  More  and  better  cereals  were  dis- 
covered, and  the  technique  of  cultivation  was  improved,  even  to  the 
extent  of  including  a  practicable  seed-drill  hundreds  of  years  before  the 
Christian  era,  though  this  machine  did  not  enter  permanently  into  the 
agricultural  technique  of  European  civilization  until  the  eighteenth  cen- 
tury of  our  own  era.  A  crude  plow  made  its  appearance,  and  hoe 
culture  gradually  disappeared.  Likewise  the  wheeled  vehicle,  destined 
to  play  so  stupendous  a  part  in  the  subsequent  history  of  mankind,  was 
brought  on  the  scene  by  the  Sumerians  as  they  emerged  from  the  Caspian 
area,  possibly  about  4000  B.C.  The  technique  of  storing  a  water  supply, 
with  the  associated  practice  of  irrigation,  was  elaborately  developed  by 
both  the  Egyptians  and  the  Babylonians.  Among  the  Egyptians  there 
was  a  highly  centralized  governmental  control  of  the  grain  trade. 

Instead  of  the  crude  agriculture  of  the  Neolithic,  practiced  on  partially 
uncleared  lands  and  on  relatively  small  plots,  with  frequent  abandonment 
of  each  settlement  (except  for  those  associated  with  the  lake  dwellings) , 
there  arose  large,  permanently  cultivated  estates.  Slave  labor  was 
widely  applied  to  agriculture.  Another  epoch-making  transformation 
carried  agriculture  beyond  mere  production  for  family  use,  to  the  pro- 
duction of  a  surplus  of  grain  for  sale.  In  short,  the  ancient  Orient,  for 
the  first  time,  created  large-scale  agricultural  operations  on  a  permanently 
cultivated  site.  There  was  little  revolutionary  progress  in  agricultural 
technique  or  organization  beyond  these  oriental  achievements  until  the 
Agricultural  Revolution  in  western  England  in  the  seventeenth  and 
eighteenth  centuries. 

We  may  further  illustrate  the  character  of  ancient  oriental  agriculture 
by  a  description  of  how  it  was  carried  on  in  ancient  Egypt.  By  No- 
vember, the  overflowing  Nile  recedes,  and  the  land  is  dry  enough  to  work. 
The  plow  of  the  ancient  Egyptians  was  a  clumsy  implement.  One  man 
controlled  the  plow  and  the  other  drove  the  oxen  which  drew  it.  Fre- 
quently the  peasants  themselves  drew  the  plow  when  only  the  crust  of 
the  soil  had  to  be  broken  up.  A  wooden  hoe  was  used  to  pulverize  the 
soil  after  the  plow  had  turned  it  up.  Seed  was  scattered  broadcast  and 
then  trodden  in  by  herds  of  sheep.  Wheat  and  barley  were  the  usual 
grains  cultivated;  millet  was  also  sown.  Ancient  Egypt  likewise  seems 
to  have  produced  onions,  cucumbers,  peas,  beans,  lettuce,  leeks,  radishes, 
and  melons.  The  olive  was  cultivated  in  certain  parts  of  Egypt,  and 
vineyards  were  generally  plentiful.  Flax  and  cotton  were  grown  to  be 
used  in  weaving. 

The  harvest  time  of  the  ancient  Egyptians  fell  in  our  spring.  For 
cutting  grain  the  peasants  used  sickles  of  metal  or  wood  with  a  cutting 
edge  of  flint.  Wheat  and  barley  were  cut  just  above  the  middle  of  the 
stalk,  which  made  the  threshing  easier.  The  straw,  left  standing  in  the 
fields,  was  later  used  in  the  manufacture  of  bricks.  Men  usually  did 


72        PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION  OF   INDUSTRY 

the  reaping;  women  followed  them  and  gathered  the  grain.  The  grain 
was  threshed  out  on  the  ground  with  flails,  or  oxen  and  donkeys  were 
driven  over  the  straw  to  tread  out  the  grain  from  the  husks  or  hulls. 
Winnowing,  generally  the  task  of  the  women,  was  done  by  throwing 
the  grain  and  chaff  together  up  into  the  wind,  so  that  the  chaff  might  be 
blown  away.  Then  the  grain  was  stored  in  granaries,  and  a  suitable 
harvest  festival  was  celebrated. 

The  most  useful  domestic  animals  of  the  Egyptians  were  the  ox  and 
the  donkey.  The  horse  was  not  introduced  until  after  1750  B.C.,  and 
never  assumed  much  importance  in  the  cultivation  of  the  soil.  Sheep 
and  goats  were  the  other  most  common  domesticated  animals.  Geese 
(highly  regarded  by  the  Egyptians) ,  ducks,  swans,  and  doves  were  domes- 
ticated rather  early.  The  chicken,  unknown  in  early  Egypt,  was  later 
introduced  from  India.  The  camel,  the  animal  we  inevitably  associate 
with  Egypt,  was  not  used  as  a  beast  of  burden  until  the  Ptolemaic  period 
— very  late  in  Egyptian  history. 

The  agriculture  of  Egypt  was  the  source  of  its  power  and  was  by  far 
the  most  vital  occupation.  Nevertheless,  the  servile  agricultural  laborer 
was  regarded  with  social  contempt.  The  life  and  the  activities  of  the 
peasant  population  were  regimented  and  controlled  by  the  revelations  of 
the  gods  and  by  the  edicts  of  the  quasi-divine  rulers.  The  Pharaoh, 
through  his  officials,  decided  what  crops  were  to  be  cultivated  and  in 
what  fields  they  were  to  be  grown,  and  then  determined  what  percentage 
of  the  yield  would  be  given  to  the  government.  In  return,  the  rulers 
undertook  irrigation  and  reclamation  projects  on  a  large  scale,  and  gave 
the  farmers  such  police  and  military  protection  as  they  needed. 

Agriculture  in  Greece  and  Rome.  Agriculture,  in  spite  of  the  de- 
velopment of  trade  and  industry  in  Athens,  always  remained  the  basic 
occupation  in  ancient  Greece.  The  soil  was  not  well  suited  for  cultiva- 
tion, but  it  is  clear  enough  that  most  of  the  citizens  of  Athens  lived  on 
their  land,  or  at  least  on  its  products.  The  Greeks  regarded  the  culti- 
vation of  the  soil  as  the  "most  honored  profession,"  as  Xenophon  declared. 
In  Periclean  Athens  (c.  430  B.C.),  about  one  half  of  the  citizen  body 
possessed  medium-size  holdings,  another  group  almost  as  large  had  only 
tiny  fields  to  till,  and  about  one  fortieth  of  the  body  of  citizens  can  be 
described  as  large  landowners.  The  large  as  well  as  the  small  landowner 
usually  lived  on  his  land  himself.  But  the  tendency  for  the  wealthy 
landowner  to  become  an  absentee  landlord  and  leave  the  estate  to  the 
care  of  a  manager  was  present  early  and  continued  to  grow. 

Agricultural  methods  were  rather  crude.  To  enable  the  relatively  un- 
productive soil  to  recuperate,  it  was  usual  to  let  each  field  lie  fallow  in 
alternate  years.  Artificial  fertilization  was  little  used  until  the  fourth 
century  B.C.,  when  improved  methods  were  introduced  and  some  more 
advanced  cultivators  adopted  the  three-field  system  in  place  of  the  old 
two-field  system. 

The  more  common  cereals  of  Greece  were  wheat,  barley,  millet,  and 
spelt.  Wheat  could  be  grown  successfully  only  on  the  more  fertile  land. 


PHASES  OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY        73 

Among  vegetables,  peas,  beans,  onions,  garlic,  and  leeks  were  the  most 
widely  grown.  The  fruits  were  numerous — olives,  apples,  pears,  quinces, 
pomegranates,  figs,  dates,  and  grapes.  Flax  was  extensively  cultivated 
for  the  manufacture  of  Greek  clothing  and  house  linen.  Goats  and  sheep 
were  numerous,  the  former  being  the  chief  source  of  milk  and  cheese  for 
the  Greeks.  Donkeys  and  mules  were  abundant,  but  there  were  few 
cows.  Horses  were  rarely  owned  except  by  the  very  rich,  and  even  then 
chiefly  in  Boeotia  and  Thessaly.  Most  of  our  present-day  domesticated 
fowls — though  not  the  turkey — were  raised. 

The  soil  of  Greece  was  ill  adapted  to  the  production  of  cereals,  and 
the  Greek  mainland  depended  more  and  more  upon  imported  wheat  from 
Sicily,  Egypt,  and  the  Black  Sea  region.  The  common  tendency  among 
the  Greek  states  on  the  mainland  was  to  specialize  its  agricultural  pro- 
duction. Athens  concentrated  on  the  culture  of  olives  and  grapes  for 
export.  After  the  fifth  century,  B.C.,  it  is  evident  that  the  city-state 
was  rarely  able  to  be  a  self-sufficient  economic  unit.  The  problem  of  how 
to  feed  the  constantly  increasing  city  populations  became  distressingly 
difficult. 

Roman  agriculture  underwent  tremendous  changes  between  the  small 
farms  of  early  Republican  days  and  those  of  the  declining  Empire,  when 
cultivation  was  chiefly  carried  on  by  large  landowners  on  great  estates 
with  the  forced  labor  of  coloni  and  slaves.  Roman  agriculture  during 
the  late  Republican  period  is  the  most  representative  of  Roman  experi- 
ence. 

By  late  Republican  days,  cattle  and  other  domestic  animals  were 
raised  in  greater  numbers  and  pasturage  gained  in  importance  in  pro- 
portion to  the  amount  of  land  under  active  cultivation.  The  chief  cereals 
were  wheat,  barley,  and  millet.  Among  the  more  important  vegetables 
were  beans,  lettuce,  cabbage,  leeks,  onions,  carrots,  asparagus,  artichokes, 
cucumbers,  melons,  and  peas.  Turnips  were  food  for  cattle  and  slaves. 
Vineyards  provided  grapes,  raisins,  and  wine.  During  the  imperial 
period  olive  orchards  were  especially  prized  and  extensively  developed. 
Olive  oil  was  a  dressing  for  food  and  a  substitute  for  our  butter;  it  was 
also  burned  in  lamps  and  used  as  a  lubricant.  Figs  were  grown  in 
abundance.  The  Romans  did  little  artificial  fertilization  of  the  soil,  but 
they  did  practice  the  rotation  of  crops,  which  helped  to  preserve  fertility. 
The  two-field  system  was  in  general  use. 

The  plow  was  made  of  wood  with  an  iron  point,  and  it  was  often  neces- 
sary to  plow  back  at  least  once  to  turn  over  the  furrow.  Cross-plowing 
was  also  usual.  Even  so,  men  on  foot  had  to  pull  over  some  of  the  sod 
with  griib  hoes.  Crude  drags  and  harrows  constructed  of  wooden  beams 
and  iron  spikes  were  used  to  break  up  the  sod  and  prepare  the  soil.  The 
sowing  was  done  by  hand — broadcast.  Brush  was  then  dragged  over  the 
ground  to  help  cover  the  seed  or  grain.  The  ripened  grain  was  cut  with 
sickles  and  scythes,  bound  by  hand,  and  drawn  in  crude  ox-carts  to  the 
barns.  Here  it  was  threshed  with  flails,  or  by  sheep  and  other  domestic 
animals  driven  over  it.  Stone  mills,  operated  by  hand  or  water  power, 


74        PHASES   OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY 

ground  the  grain  into  flour  and  meal.  There  were  also  presses  for  making 
wine  and  olive  oil. 

The  seasonal  distribution  of  agricultural  operations  varied  somewhat 
as  between  the  northern  and  southern  portions  of  the  peninsula,  but 
roughly  it  went  about  as  follows:  Wheat  was  sown  in  the  autumn,  when 
most  of  the  plowing  was  done  for  other  crops  as  well.  Threshing  was 
also  cleaned  up  in  the  autumn.  In  the  winter  the  orchards  were  trimmed. 
In  the  spring  the  barley  and  millet  were  sown  and  the  vegetables  planted. 
Hay  was  mown  in  May  and  June.  Wheat,  barley,  and  millet  were 
harvested  in  July.  Figs  and  grapes  were  picked  in  August.  Figs  were 
dried,  the  grapes  made  into  raisins,  and  the  wine  pressed  mainly  during 
this  month. 

Agricultural  operations  were  complicated  and  delayed  by  the  many 
festivals  and  religious  holidays  connected  with  Roman  agriculture.  In- 
deed, the  religion  of  Republican  Rome  centered  about  the  rites  involved 
in  securing  adequate  supernatural  aid  and  guidance  in  agricultural 
processes  and  about  the  expressions  of  gratitude  to  the  gods  for  a  success- 
ful harvest.  There  were  forty-five  such  festival  days  in  the  Roman 
calendar. 

Domestic  animals  were  varied  and  numerous.  The  many  breeds  of 
horses  were  used  mainly  for  travel,  war,  and  races  rather  than  for  ordi- 
nary farm  draft  purposes.  Cattle  were  raised  extensively  for  milk  and 
draft  purposes  more  than  for  beef.  Beef  was  not  widely  consumed  as  a 
staple  meat  by  the  ancient  Romans  except  by  the  wealthier  classes. 
Much  cheese  was  made  but  butter  was  practically  unknown  in  Roman 
times.  Hogs  were  raised  in  great  profusion  and  pork  was  the  most 
popular  meat  consumed  by  the  Romans,  especially  by  the  middle  classes. 
Sheep  were  raised  for  wool  and  for  mutton.  Goats  were  reared  for  milk 
and  cheese.  Donkeys  were  bred  as  beasts  of  burden.  Among  the 
better-known  domestic  fowls  were  hens,  peacocks,  and  doves.  Game 
birds  were  grown  for  the  table  of  the  rich.  The  bee  industry  was  im- 
portant since  sugar  was  unknown  and  honey  was  the  chief  sweetening 
used  in  the  food  and  beverages  of  the  time. 

Medieval  Agriculture.  During  the  Middle  Ages  agriculture  was 
carried  on  according  to  an  interesting  communal  form  of  control  known 
as  the  manorial  system. 

With  the  peasant  village  inhabited  by  the  serfs  as  a  center,  there  ex- 
tended out  and  around  it  the  arable  or  cultivated  fields,  which  could  be 
reached  from  the  village  by  lanes  wide  enough  for  the  passage  of  carts. 
The  arable  land  was  divided  into  three  distinct  sections,  each  large  field 
being  subdivided  into  several  smaller  plots  called  shots,  and  these  in 
turn  divided  into  seemingly  numberless  strips  of  varying  lengths.  If  the 
manor  was  a  large  one,  the  village  might  nestle  against  the  thick  outer 
walls  of  the  lord's  castle.  In  a  smaller  one,  the  lord's  manor  house,  with 
the  adjoining  barn  and  stable,  would  be  situated  on  a  choice  site  not  far 
from,  and  perhaps  facing,  the  village.  Within  the  same  section  there 
stood  a  church,  the  dwelling  of  the  priest,  and  a  small  cemetery.  Near 


PHASES   OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY        75 

the  manor  house  lay  at  least  a  part  of  the  lord's  demesne,  which  was 
entirely  his  own  land  and  usually  the  best  of  the  farm  land  on  the  manor. 
Finally,  there  was  the  common  meadow,  woodland,  and  waste  land, 
shared  by  all  the  village  peasantry. 

In  all,  seven  different  agricultural  divisions  of  land  could  be  discovered 
on  the  typical  manor:  (1)  the  lord's  demesne,  cultivated  by  special  serfs 
of  the  demesne  and  by  the  villagers;  (2)  the  lord's  close,  which  was  that 
part  of  the  demesne  rented  to  free  or  semiservile  cultivators;  (3)  the 
tenures  or  shares  of  the  villagers,  scattered  in  strips  through  the  three 
large  arable  fields;  (4)  the  meadow  land;  (5)  the  woodlands;  (6)  the 
waste  land,  and  (7)  the  land  of  the  parish  priest,  either  in  a  compact 
area  or  scattered  in  strips  throughout  the  fields. 

The  arable  land  lay  in  two  or  three  great  open  fields — after  the  close 
of  the  eighth  century,  usually  in  three.  Each  field  was  divided  into  strips 
ranging  from  an  eighth  of  a  mile  to  a  half-mile  in  length,  separated  by 
balks  of  unplowed  land.  No  peasant  held  two  contiguous  strips.  This 
open-field  system,  so  strange  in  modern  eyes,  finds  its  reason  for  existence, 
as  well  as  its  explanation,  in  the  sharehold  principle.  The  peasants'  arable 
land  usually  did  not  change  hands,  but  was  held  by  each  household  in 
hereditary  possession.  Yet,  as  Vinogradoff  points  out,  only  when  the 
land  was  planted  did  the  villager  possess  what  we  may  call  separate  or 
private  rights  over  his  particular  strips.  For  after  the  field  had  been 
harvested,  returning  to  the  condition  of  waste  land  or  pasture  land,  it 
became  a  common,  and  thus  perpetuated  the  principle  that  the  common 
belonged  to  the  village  as  a  whole.  Furthermore,  though  each  house- 
hold in  the  manor  had  a  recognized  right  to  its  share  of  arable  land, 
which  was  usually  passed  on  by  hereditary  succession,  still  the  particular 
strips  held  might  not  always  remain  the  same  from  year  to  year.  In 
some  regions  at  least,  and  particularly  in  the  early  period,  the  house- 
holders exchanged  strips  periodically  by  lot,  so  that  each  took  his  chances 
in  getting  either  the  better  or  the  less  desirable  strips. 

The  three-field  system,  so  characteristic  of  manorial  husbandry,  divided 
the  arable  land  into  three  distinct  sections.  One  field  was  for  spring 
planting,  the  second  for  fall  planting,  and  the  third  left  fallow  to  recover 
its  fertility.  This  was  the  one  great  innovation  in  agriculture  made 
during  the  Middle  Ages.  Both  the  Germans  and  the  Romans  had  em- 
ployed the  two-field  system,  in  which  one  field  was  planted  and  one  kept 
fallow  for  recuperation.  The  discovery,  at  some  time  or  other,  that 
wheat  or  rye  could  be  planted  in  the  fall  as  well  as  in  the  spring  made  it 
possible  every  year  to  work  two  thirds  of  the  available  land  and  to 
permit  one  third  to  rest  and  regain  its  strength,  according  to  the  following 
rotation  in  each  field:  spring  planting,  autumn  planting,  fallow.  This 
remarkable  discovery  produced  two  crops  each  year,  made  use  of  two 
thirds  of  the  arable  land  instead  of  one  half,  and  even  reduced  the  labor 
in  plowing. 

The  fall  crop,  consisting  of  wheat  or  rye  or  both,  was  sown  at  the  end 
of  August  or  early  in  September  and  was  harvested  the  following  summer. 


76        PHASES   OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY 

Here  about  two  bushels  of  seed  were  sown  to  the  acre  strip,  and  the 
return  was  rarely  above  ten  bushels  to  the  acre,  indeed  a  slight  one  for 
the  labor  involved.  The  spring  plowing  and  sowing  took  place  in  Febru- 
ary or  March,  and  the  crop  was  harvested  late  in  the  following  summer. 
Oats,  barley,  peas,  and  beans  (the  last  two  were  more  common  in  the 
later  centuries,  and  only  rarely  was  a  whole  field  given  over  to  them) 
were  sown,  and  the  yield  of  the  first  two  was  usually  under  fourteen 
bushels  to  the  acre  on  four  bushels  of  seed.  Because  a  knowledge  of 
artificial  fertilization  was  lacking  in  most  cases,  one  field,  as  we  have 
seen,  had  to  be  left  fallow  so  that  nature  might  restore  its  fertility. 

The  villagers  worked  their  own  strips  and  those  of  the  lord  as  well. 
The  village  community  as  a  whole  directed  and  supplied  the  labor  for 
all  the  agricultural  processes,  including  the  crops  to  be  planted  and  the 
reclamation  of  new  land.  All  the  manorial  land,  of  both  the  lord  and 
the  villagers,  was  thus  cultivated  by  a  complex  system  of  joint  labor. 
Poor  implements  and  the  elementary  agricultural  technique  at  their  com- 
mand made  the  labor  of  the  peasants  back-breaking  and  tedious.  The 
fact  that  most  of  the  labor  was  done  in  groups  or  gangs  did  something, 
however,  to  relieve  its  wearying  monotony. 

The  plow,  a  huge,  clumsy  affair  tipped  with  iron,  had  to  be  drawn  by 
some  six  to  twelve  oxen,  required  two  or  four  men  to  operate  it,  and 
turned  up  the  soil  in  a  very  shallow  furrow.  Thorn  trees  weighted  with 
logs  constituted  far  from  adequate  harrows.  The  large  lumps  of  soil 
were  broken  with  crude  mattocks.  There  were  no  grain  drills,  so  the 
seed  was  always  sown  by  hand.  Weeding  was  done  by  hand  or  with  a 
forked  stick,  a  hook,  or  snippers.  Wheat  and  rye  were  gleaned  with  a 
sickle — a  long  and  laborious  job — and  a  scythe  was  used  to  cut  the  hay, 
barley,  oats,  peas,  and  beans.  The  grain,  threshed  with  a  flail  or  trodden 
out  by  cattle,  was  later  winnowed  by  being  thrown  up  into  the  wind. 
The  last  was  a  task  frequently  performed  by  the  women  and  children. 
Except  for  a  very  rudimentary  use  of  marl  and  lime,  and  the  informal 
manuring  of  the  land  when  it  was  used  as  pasturage,  there  was  no  attempt 
to  produce  artificial  fertilization. 

For  farm  work  oxen  were  preferred  and  were  used  far  more  than 
horses.  They  were  less  expensive  to  keep  and  less  likely  to  become  sick; 
their  harness  was  much  more  simple  and  their  shoeing  cheaper;  and 
finally,  when  they  grew  old  they  could  be  killed  and  eaten.  While  horses 
were  raised  on  the  manor — especially  for  military  service — their  use  was 
limited.  When  they  were  employed  for  farm  work,  they  were  usually 
hitched  together  with  the  oxen.  The  lack  of  scientific  breeding  and  care 
of  all  domesticated  animals  resulted  in  rangy  cattle,  much  lighter  in 
weight  and  weaker  than  the  sturdy  animals  of  today,  and  in  unimproved 
types  of  sheep  and  hogs.  The  cattle  were  valued  for  butter,  milk,  cheese, 
and  calves.  In  the  thirteenth  century  a  peasant  thought  about  one  pound 
of  butter  a  week  a  good  return  from  a  cow.  Today,  ten  or  twelve  pounds 
of  butter  is  no  unusual  production  for  a  cow  in  one  week.  The  record 
cow  in  American  dairying  averaged  approximately  thirty  pounds  per 


PHASES  OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY        77 

week  for  a  year.  At  the  opening  of  winter  it  was  customary  to  slaughter 
and  salt  down  many  cattle  not  essential  for  breeding  and  draft  purposes. 

The  sheep  were  valued  chiefly  for  their  wool.  "Rot"  and  "scab"  were 
devastatingly  frequent.  As  late  as  the  beginning  of  the  seventeenth 
century,  the  wool  was  still  partially  pulled  out  and  partially  cut  off  with 
a  knife.  Both  the  cattle  and  sheep  were  cared  for  by  the  village  cowherd 
and  shepherd,  who  took  them  out  to  pasture  in  the  morning  and  brought 
them  back  at  nightfall.  Hogs,  like  our  half-wild  Arkansas  razorbacks, 
ranged  the  woods  for  food.  Of  fowls,  chickens,  geese,  ducks,  and  pigeons 
(only  the  lord  was  permitted  to  breed  and  keep  these  last)  were  common. 
Turkey  and  guinea  fowl  were  unknown  at  this  time.  During  the  Middle 
Ages  bees  enjoyed — as  in  Roman  days — an  economic  dignity.  The  wax 
was  in  great  demand  for  seals  and  candles,  and  honey  was  almost  the 
only  form  of  sweetening  available. 

The  villagers,  as  we  have  stated,  worked  both  the  demesne  farm  of  the 
lord  and  their  own  holdings.  In  return  the  peasantry  owed  the  lord 
certain  duties  and  dues.  Besides,  from  a  practical  and  realistic  point  of 
view,  the  lords  did  and  could  exploit  the  village  communities  simply  be- 
cause they  were  strong  enough  to  do  so.  The  theory  that  the  peasants 
rendered  services  and  dues  to  the  lord  in  return  for  protection  and  the 
"privilege  of  working  their  lands"  is  at  best  no  more  than  a  legal  ration- 
alization of  a  harsh  practical  fact. 

Beyond  these  services  in  labor,  the  village  was  obliged  to  supply  the 
lord  with  carefully  stipulated  amounts,  at  regular  intervals,  of  grain, 
shoes,  eggs,  wood,  wool,  honey,  poultry,  cattle,  and  so  on.  The  lord  also 
shifted  to  his  villagers  the  economic  burden  of  financing  his  entertain- 
ment. 

Granted  that  the  lord  enjoyed  the  better  part  of  the  bargain,  he  never- 
theless did  perform  services  that  were  of  benefit  to  his  peasants.  In  the 
protection  he  offered,  in  the  food  he  frequently  distributed  in  famine 
times,  in  the  ovens  and  mills  and  bridges  he  constructed  for  general  use, 
and  in  the  superior  stock  he  sometimes  kept  for  breeding  purposes,  he 
offered  the  peasant  definite  economic  aid. 

The  medieval  monks  were  the  best  farmers  in  western  Europe.  They 
handed  down  Roman  agricultural  methods,  did  heroic  work  in  clearing 
forests  and  waste  land  for  agricultural  uses,  drained  swamps,  built  roads, 
and  made  some  start  in  introducing  crude  methods  of  fertilization  of  the 
soil.  In  the  early  Middle  Ages,  the  monks  did  most  of  the  farming  them- 
selves, but  later  on  they  both  employed  serfs  and  hired  peasant  laborers 
extensively,  and  their  technique  and  system  of  cultivation  did  not  differ 
greatly  from  the  general  manorial  procedure,  save  in  being  usually  more 
efficient  and  productive. 

The  Muslims  were  even  more  scientific  farmers  than  the  medieval 
monks.  They  cultivated  the  conventional  grain  crops  very  efficiently, 
but  they  were  especially  famous  for  their  fruits,  especially  melons, 
oranges,  dates,  figs,  apricots,  and  peaches.  They  were  also  noted  for 
their  scientific  stock-raising,  particularly  fine  horses  and  sheep  with  an 


78        PHASES  OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY 

excellent  grade  of  wool.  Muslim  agriculture  was  carried  on  both  on  great 
estates  cultivated  by  serfs  and  peasants  and  on  smaller  farms  worked  by 
free  peasant  owners. 

The  Agricultural  Revolution.  The  next  important  change  in  agri- 
culture was  the  so-called  Agricultural  Revolution  of  the  seventeenth 
and  eighteenth  centuries.  This  took  place  mainly  in  England,  though 
its  achievements  were  carried  to  the  Continent  and  to  America. 

The  manorial  system  had  been  wiped  out  in  England,  so  far  as  methods 
of  landholding  and  class  differentiation  were  concerned,  by  the  sixteenth 
century,  but  the  technique  of  agriculture,  involving  rudimentary  tools 
and  cooperative  labor,  underwent  astonishingly  slight  changes  between 
the  twelfth  century  and  the  close  of  the  seventeenth.  In  spite  of  the 
disappearance  of  the  legal  aspects  of  the  manor  and  of  many  of  its  older 
social  practices,  the  agricultural  village,  strip  ownership  of  land,  cooper- 
ative cultivation,  common  pasture,  and  wood-gathering  rights  were  still 
present  in  1700. 

A  series  of  remarkable  changes  in  technique,  with  a  sweeping  reaction 
upon  the  social  organization  of  English  agriculture,  took  place  in  the 
eighteenth  century.  These  were:  (1)  the  introduction  of  new  agricultural 
implements;  (2)  successful  experiments  with  new  crops;  (3)  improve- 
ments of  stock-breeding;  (4)  drainage  of  waste  land  and  the  development 
of  scientific  notions  of  fertilizing  the  soil;  and  finally  (5)  the  organization 
of  scientific  and  pseudo-scientific  societies  for  the  promotion  of  improved 
agricultural  technique. 

Down  to  the  seventeenth  century,  almost  nothing  new  had  been  pro- 
vided for  working  up  the  ground  about  the  roots  of  crops  that  could  be 
"cultivated"  (not  grain),  and  for  eliminating  weeds.  The  provision  of 
better  agricultural  tools  and  machinery  is  associated  chiefly  with  the 
work  of  Jethro  Tull  (1674-1740).  Tull  introduced  the  first  successful 
modern  drill  for  the  sowing  of  grain.  This  superseded  the  old  and  waste- 
ful method  of  sowing  grain  broadcast  by  hand  on  top  of  the  ground.  He 
also  stimulated  (for  England)  the  modern  practice  of  "cultivating," 
namely,  working  up  the  soil  about  the  roots  of  such  crops  as  peas,  beans, 
beets,  turnips,  and  potatoes,  and  eliminating  the  competing  weeds.  In 
the  words  of  R.  W.  Prothero:  "The  chief  legacies  which  Jethro  Tull  left 
to  his  successors  were  clean  farming,  economy  in  seedings,  drilling,  and  the 
maxim  that  the  more  irons  are  among  the  roots  the  better  for  the  crop." 

Lord  Townshend  (1674r-1738)  was  mainly  responsible  for  the  introduc- 
tion of  new  crops.  Down  to  this  time  it  had  been  difficult  to  secure  winter 
crops,  or  any  that  would  not  considerably  reduce  the  fertility  of  the  land. 
This  deficiency  had  made  it  necessary  to  leave  one  third  or  more  of  the 
ground  fallow  each  year.  An  associated  problem  had  been  to  secure 
enough  fodder  to  carry  the  horses,  cattle,  and  sheep  safely  through  the 
winter  season,  because  the  "hay"  was  chiefly  derived  from  unproductive 
natural  grasses. 

Townshend  solved  some  of  these  problems.  He  introduced,  and 
rendered  important  service  in  promoting  the  successful  cultivation  of, 


PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION  OF   INDUSTRY       79 

turnips  and  artificial  grasses,  especially  clover.  Clover  does  not  reduce 
fertility  as  do  grains,  and  it  performs  important  services  in  gathering 
nitrogen,  loosening  the  ground,  and  counteracting  the  tendency  of  many 
crops,  when  repeated,  to  render  the  soil  unfit  to  reproduce  them  until  it 
has  been  "rested,"  as  farmers  sometimes  colloquially  put  it.  The  chem- 
istry of  plant  growth  and  the  results  of  repeated  cropping  on  the  same 
spot  under  intensive  artificial  cultivation  are  so  delicate  and  complicated 
that  a  judicious  change  of  crops  is  often  as  effective  in  preventing  soil 
exhaustion  as  a  fallow  year  would  be.  After  the  introduction  of  clover 
and  the  rotation  of  crops,  the  fallow  year  was  gradually  abandoned,  and 
the  acreage  that  might  be  cropped  each  year  was  increased  by  some 
30  per  cent  or  more.  At  the  same  time,  the  appearance  of  clover  made  it 
possible  to  produce  an  adequate  supply  of  hay  to  carry  live-stock  through 
the  winter.  Turnips  as  a  new  crop  also  helped  greatly  in  the  problem  of 
getting  enough  food  for  cattle.  They  were  also  used  as  food  by  peasants. 
So  great  was  Lord  Townshend's  enthusiasm  for  turnips  that  he  was 
dubbed  "Turnip  Townshend." 

A  revolutionary  development  of  stock-breeding  was  very  largely  the 
result  of  the  efforts  of  Robert  Bakewell  (1725-1795).  Specialized  breeds 
that  would  bring  the  highest  market  prices  as  beef,  mutton,  and  pork  had 
been  impossible  under  manorial  conditions.  The  cultivators  had  used 
common  pasture  lands,  so  that  all  the  stock  ran  together,  breeding  down 
to  a  common  mongrel  type.  Something  had  been  done  in  stock-breeding 
by  monasteries  and  lay  lords  who  had  inclosed  fields,  but  the  shortage  of 
hay  for  wintering  tended  to  throw  emphasis  on  hardihood  rather  than  on 
quality  from  the  consumer's  point  of  view.  Some  progress  had  already 
been  made  in  the  Netherlands,  where  the  manor  had  disappeared  early 
or  never  existed  at  all,  and  imported  stock  from  the  Mediterranean  re- 
gion had  improved  the  breeds,  particularly  of  cattle,  horses,  and  sheep. 
In  England,  however,  as  in  northern  Europe,  it  was  usual  to  find  a  single 
type  of  horse,  cow,  sheep,  or  hog,  not  specialized,  respectively,  to  road 
or  draft  use,  milk  or  beef,  mutton  or  wool,  or  the  best  type  of  pork. 

Bakewell  understood  that  no  one  type  of  animal  could  be  adapted  to 
all  the  various  purposes.  Therefore,  he  started  to  breed  specialized 
horses  for  draft  and  for  road  use,  to  create  distinctive  breeds  of  cattle  for 
beef  or  milk,  and  to  separate  his  wool  sheep  from  his  mutton  sheep.  He 
was  opposed  to  allowing  others  to  imitate  his  methods  or  appropriate  his 
secrets,  but  his  improvements  in  stock-breeding  were  more  rapidly 
accepted  than  the  innovations  of  Tull  and  Townshend  in  their  respective 
fields.  The  Duke  of  Bedford  (1765-1802)  and  Lord  Somerville  (1765- 
1819)  carried  on  and  popularized  scientific  stock-breeding. 

Arthur  Young  (1741-1820)  made  a  contribution  of  a  different  sort. 
He  was  familiar  with  the  work  of  Tull,  Townshend,  and  B.akewell,  and 
desired  to  see  their  innovations  generally  adopted.  He  understood,  how- 
ever, that  this  would  not  be  possible  so  long  as  England  was  divided  into 
many  small  holdings,  worked  according  to  the  anachronistic  cooperative 
methods  inherited  from  the  manorial  regime,  and  without  capital  Adequate 


80        PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION  OF   INDUSTRY 

to  finance  large-scale  farming.  His  professional  life  was  devoted  mainly 
to  the  reforms  that  were  necessary  to  realize  his  aspirations.  He  was 
the  great  prophet  and  agitator,  urging  on  the  most  characteristic  agrarian 
transformation  of  his  time  in  England — the  development  of  the  enclosure 
or  engrossing  of  land.  The  consolidation  of  small  holdings  into  larger 
farms  displaced  the  English  yeomanry  and  produced  modern  capitalistic 
farming  between  1760  and  1830. 

Further  technical  advances  were  made  in  draining  land,  mixing  soils, 
and  fertilization.  The  desirability  of  mixing  soils  was  emphasized  by 
Lord  Townshend  and  carried  on  by  Thomas  Coke  and  other  early  capi- 
talistic farmers.  Scientific  fertilization  of  soils  was  made  possible  by 
the  remarkable  advances  in  chemistry  in  the  eighteenth  and  nineteenth 
centuries.  Perhaps  the  first  important  chemist  to  devote  his  attention 
to  land  fertilization  was  Sir  Humphry  Davy.  His  work  was  carried  on 
by,  among  others,  the  greatest  organic  chemist  of  his  age,  the  German 
scientist,  Justus  von  Liebig.  Chemistry  enabled  experts  to  determine  just 
what  chemicals  were  needed  in  any  particular  soil  to  insure  maximum 
fertility  and  also  made  it  possible  to  produce  these  substances  more 
surely,  speedily,  and  cheaply.  Agricultural  societies  were  organized  to 
aid  in  carrying  on  effectively  all  of  these  progressive  farming  methods. 
Such  were  the  famous  Smithfield  Club  of  London  and  the  Highland 
Society  in  Scotland. 

The  rapidity  with  which  the  reforms  were  actually  carried  out  was 
due  to  the  Commercial  Revolution  and  its  results.  Merchants  had 
greatly  increased  in  numbers  and  in  wealth,  but  social  prestige  was  still 
hard  to  achieve  without  membership  in  the  landholding  class.  Many 
who  had  become  rich  in  commerce  were  thus  glad  to  invest  their  money 
in  great  landed  estates  as  the  one  open  door  to  political  and  social  influ- 
ence. Not  altogether  by  accident,  the  technical  improvements  in  agri- 
culture added  the  possibility  of  profits  to  the  social  and  political  incen- 
tives for  building  up  the  great  estates  that  characterized  English 
agriculture  throughout  the  nineteenth  century.  Also,  the  higher  agri- 
cultural prices  that  prevailed  during  the  French  Revolutionary  and 
Napoleonic  wars  encouraged  capitalistic  farming.  The  large  landhold- 
ing&  were  created  chiefly  by  purchasing  land  held  earlier  by  the  squires 
and  tenant  farmers,  and  by  ousting  peasants  from  their  leaseholds  and 
customs  holds. 

Though  these  agricultural  transformations  as  a  whole  increased  agri- 
cultural efficiency  and  production,  they  brought  about  the  wholesale 
depression  of  the  great  mass  of  the  residents  in  the  country.  N.  S.  B. 
Gras  writes: 

To  many  students  of  our  day,  the  most  significant  result  of  the  agricultural 
revolution  was  not  economic  efficiency,  not  change  in  land  tenure,  and  not 
literary  culture,  but  the  loss  of  well-being  by  the  rank  and  file  of  country  people. 
The  proletarianizing  of  the  yeomen  and  the  customary  tenants  seems  a  great 
social  set-back.  Where  they  had  been  masters,  they  now  became  laborers,  at 
least  in  many  instances.  And  then  the  cottars  and  squatters,  the  traditional 


PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION  OF   INDUSTRY        81 

poor  and  laboring  class  of  the  village,  suffered  greatly  when  their  holdings  were 
enclosed  for  the  new  agriculture.  They  lost  their  cows,  pigs,  and  geese  when 
the  commons  were  enclosed,  and  instead  of  milk,  pork,  and  fowl,  they  lived  on 
bread  and  tea.  They  lost  their  fuel  when  the  waste  land  was  enclosed;  and  if 
they  wanted  to  keep  warm,  they  were  invited  to  use  the  stables.  Truly  it  was 
but  slight  compensation  for  such  losses  to  have  plenty  of  work  offered  to  them 
and  to  be  compelled  to  accept  it  to  keep  body  and  soul  together.  Industrial 
discipline  is  one  of  our  modern  acquisitions,  but  the  price  in  this  case  and 
commonly  is  a  very  heavy  one.  The  usual  escape  from  this  sad  dilemma  is 
to  regard  the  economic  gain  as  permanent  and  the  human  suffering  as  tem- 
porary. But  the  unescapable  reflection  is  that  the  sufferers  have  but  one  life 
to  live,  and  when  that  is  gone,  civilization  is  gone — for  them.  They  have  helped 
to  furnish  the  elegant  home  of  the  gentleman  farmer  and  they  have  submitted 
to  the  new  discipline.  They  have  built  the  poet's  palace  of  art  but  they  dwell 
not  in  it.4 

The  ruination  of  the  free  peasantry  was  a  major  cause  of  the  decline 
of  Roman  society.  The  coming  of  the  Industrial  Revolution  after  1750, 
however,  and  the  employment  of  many  of  the  landless  in  factories,  lessened 
the  immediate  social  penalty  of  dispossessing  the  English  masses  of  their 
land. 

The  agricultural  changes,  like  those  in  industry  and  commerce,  were 
not  without  a  close  relation  to  the  Industrial  Revolution.  The  new  capi- 
talistic farming,  for  the  time  being  at  least,  increased  the  productivity 
of  English  agriculture  and  made  it  possible  to  maintain  the  greatly  in- 
creased urban  population.  Further,  the  great  mass  of  peasants  were 
glad  to  take  up  employment  on  the  large  estates  or  in  the  new  factory 
towns  at  even  pitifully  inadequate  wages  and  under  the  most  exacting 
conditions  of  labor.  In  this  way  a  cheap  and  eager  industrial  proletariat 
was  provided  for  the  new  factory  towns  that  were  created  as  a  result  of 
the  inventive  genius  of  Hargreaves,  Crompton,  and  Watt,  and  the  organ- 
izing genius  of  Arkwright.  From  the  dispossessed  agricultural  laborers 
there  was  created  a  "free"  labor  market  to  facilitate  the  rapid  expansion 
of  nascent  industrialism. 

The  Mechanization  of  Agriculture.  The  most  important  recent 
changes  in  agriculture  are  those  related  to  mechanization  and  the  applica- 
tion of  chemistry  and  other  forms  of  science  to  agricultural  production. 
This  transformation  of  agriculture  has  been  most  striking  in  the  United 
States. 

The  colonists  brought  from  England  and  other  parts  of  Europe  the 
plow,  the  cultivator,  and  other  rudimentary  agricultural  machinery. 
There  were  few  further  mechanical  improvements  in  agriculture  until 
the  nineteenth  century.  In  the  first  half  of  that  century,  Thomas  Jeffer- 
son and  others  devised  better  types  of  iron  and  steel  plows.  A  workable 
seed  drill  was  invented,  better  harrows,  and  a  mechanical  mowing  ma- 
chine. Perhaps  the  most  momentous  invention  of  this  period  was  that  of 
Obed  Hussey  and  Cyrus  H.  McCormick,  who  produced  the  mechanical 


4  N.  S.  B.  Gras,  History  of  Agriculture  in  Europe  and  America,  Crofts,  1940,  2nd  ed., 
p.  328. 


82        PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY 

reaper  between  1833  and  1845.  Crude  threshing  machines,  usually  oper- 
ated by  horse  power,  appeared  about  the  middle  of  the  century. 

From  the  Civil  War  onward  agricultural  inventions  became  more 
numerous  and  impressive.  The  grain  binder  (self-binder),  invented  in 
the  'seventies,  was  at  first  rather  crude  and  bound  the  grain  with  wire. 
In  the  'seventies  and  'eighties  John  F.  Appleby  and  William  Deering  in- 
vented the  improved  twine  binder.  At  the  end  of  the  century  the  me- 
chanical header  was  introduced  and  greatly  hastened  the  harvesting 
process  in  areas  where  it  was  not  thought  worth  while  to  preserve  the 
straw  from  the  wheat  stalk.  The  steam  threshing  machine  worked  a 
revolution  in  the  separation  of  grain  from  the  husk.  At  the  turn  of  the 
century  the  corn  harvester  and  the  corn  husker  completely  transformed 
the  handling  of  the  corn  crop.  It  is  estimated  that  the  mechanical 
inventions  of  the  nineteenth  century  brought  about  a  saving  of  79  per 
cent  in  farm  labor  and  cut  down  farming  costs  by  over  46  per  cent. 

But  the  most  sweeping  and  unsettling  advances  in  agricultural  ma- 
chinery were  still  to  come.  The  improvement  of  the  internal  combustion 
engine  made  possible  an  economical  and  successful  farm  tractor,  first 
introduced  by  Benjamin  Holt  in  1903.  This  and  the  automobile  truck 
tended  to  displace  the  horse,  mule,  and  ox  in  agricultural  processes. 
Along  with  the  tractor,  the  ever  more  effective  gang-plow  and  the  disc- 
harrow  combine  revolutionized  the  preparation  of  soil  for  the  sowing  of 
crops.  Larger  grain  drills,  tractor-drawn  in  veritable  fleets,  greatly 
hastened  the  sowing.  Airplanes  are  beginning  to  be  used  for  the  sowing 
of  rice  and  of  wheat  with  an  impressive  efficiency. 

The  harvesting  of  grain  was  equally  facilitated  by  the  harvesting  com- 
bine, which  cuts,  threshes,  cleans,  and  bags  grain,  all  in  one  process. 
The  product  per  worker  in  grain  agriculture  has  been  incredibly  increased 
in  comparison  with  the  old  days  of  the  horse  plow  and  the  horse-drawn 
binder.  The  cotton-picker,  invented  by  the  Rust  brothers,  may  produce 
a  comparable  revolution  in  Southern  agriculture.  The  increase  of  effi- 
ciency brought  about  as  a  result  of  mechanized  farming,  as  well  as  the 
wide  divergence  of  the  new  from  the  old  methods  of  cultivation,  is  well 
brought  out  by  Morrow  Mayo: 

Technically,  the  machine  has  revolutionized  wheat  farming  fully  as  much  as 
it  has  revolutionized  automobile  production.  In  1900  it  required  three  hours 
of  labor  to  produce  a  bushel  of  wheat;  today  it  requires  three  minutes  of 
machine  time.  Under  horse  conditions  500  acres  was  about  all  the  land  that  a 
wheat  fanner  could  handle.  He  could  plow  only  from  two  to  four  acres  a  day. 
Even  with  a  six-horse  drill  he  could  plant  only  eighteen  or  twenty  acres  a  day. 
Today  with  a  small  tractor  he  plows  fifty  acres  a  day  and  drills  fifty  acres  a 
day.  With  a  tractor  and  combine  two  men  can  cut  and  thresh  fifty  acres  of 
wheat  in  ten  hours — an  operation  that  but  a  few  years  ago  required  twenty-three 
men  the  same  number  of  hours.  The  machine  has  reduced  10,000  acres  of  wheat 
land  to  the  size  of  500  acres,  and  500  acres  to  the  size  of  20  acres.  .  .  . 

Corporation  wheat  farming  is  a  first  step  in  that  direction  (economical  pro- 
duction). Here  is  the  way  they  do  it.  The  land  is  divided  into  blocks  of  from 
5,000  to  10,000  acres.  Each  block  is  under  a  foreman,  who  has  charge  of  the 
labor,  and  the  machinery  when  it  is  on  his  unit.  He  is  responsible  to  the  pro- 


PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION  OF   INDUSTRY       83 

duction  manager.  A  transportation  outfit  shifts  equipment  wherever  it  is  needed. 
The  Wheat  Farm  Corporation  of  Kansas  City,  which  operates  75,000  acres,  uses 
forty  caterpillar  tractors,  a  fleet  of  trucks,  thirty  combines,  and  hundreds  of 
tillage  machines,  with  an  aggregate  value  of  $250,000.  Laborers  (i.e.,  farmers) 
are  employed  when  needed,  about  sixty  or  ninety  days  a  year.  They  work  eight 
hours  a  day,  and  punch  time-clocks  on  their  tractors.  At  certain  seasons  the 
work  is  carried  on  twenty-four  hours  a  day,  with  the  laborers  working  in  three 
eight-hour  shifts  and  operating  tractors  equipped  with  search-lights  at  night.5 

When  one  reflects  that  nearly  one  half  of  our  domestic  wheat  today  is 
produced  by  tenant  farmers  on  a  sharecropping  basis,  with  nothing  like 
the  same  mechanization  which  prevails  on  the  big  corporate  farms,  it  is 
easy  to  realize  how  far  we  are  from  exploiting  all  the  advantages  of 
mechanized  efficiency.  We  can  begin  to  understand  what  tremendous 
changes  are  bound  to  take  place  in  cereal  farming  areas  if  all  possible 
mechanical  efficiency  is  ever  fully  attained  and  we  begin  to  produce  grain 
for  human  use  in  an  economy  of  plenty. 

The  contributions  of  chemistry  to  greater  agricultural  efficiency  have 
also  been  notable.  The  mechanical  inventions  and  better  fertilization 
have  created  a  potential  agricultural  production  in  the  United  States 
which  seems  almost  incredible,  even  to  scientific  students  of  the  problem. 
0.  W.  Willcox  has  made  it  clear,  in  his  Reshaping  Agriculture  and  Nations 
Can  Live  at  Home,  that  we  could  produce  all  the  food  needed  for  a  high 
standard  of  living  with  one  fifth  of  the  number  of  persons  now  employed 
in  agriculture,  working  only  one  fifth  of  the  land  now  under  cultivation. 
The  import  of  all  this  for  the  future  of  the  American  farm  and  rural  com- 
munity is  too  momentous  for  even  the  most  astute  economist  or  sociologist 
to  discern  today  or  to  forecast  with  accuracy. 

Moreover,  we  are  on  the  eve  of  remarkable  achievements  in  the  field 
of  synthetic  chemistry.  These  will  insure  a  better  utilization  of  farm 
products  and  will  also  create  foods  artificially  by  purely  chemical 
methods.  The  stages  in  the  application  of  chemistry  to  agriculture  have 
been  thus  summarized  by  Wayne  W.  Parrish  and  Harold  F.  Clark: 

1.  Primitive  stage,  still  practiced  over  wide  areas  of  the  earth,  in  which  seeds 
are  planted  in  straight  rows  in  the  soil  and  the  whole  business  is  left  to  nature. 
A  little  fertilization  is  used  but  most  unscientifically. 

2.  Intensive  stage,  gradually  coming  into  use,  in  which  large  quantities  of  syn- 
thetically produced  fertilizers  are  applied  to  the  soil  to  reap  enormous  yields. 
This  stage  is  so  perfected  that  it  is  known  with  precision  that  a  specified  quantity 
of  the  organic  chemical  matter  will  yield  a  specified  quantity  of  crop. 

3.  Control  stage,  which  eliminates  the  soil  as  being  unnecessary  to  plant  growth. 
Plants  are  grown  in  a  solution  of  necessary  organic  substances  in  trays  or  cabi- 
nets, with  a  new  crop  every  few  weeks.    This  stage  takes  agriculture  off  the  farm 
into  factories  or  kitchens  and  places  it  under  strict  man-made  control. 

4.  Synthetic  stage,  in  which  the  chemist  transfers  the  whole  agricultural  enter- 
prise to  the  factory,  eliminating  seeds,  plant,  sun,  soil,  winds,  and  rain.    He  finds 
out  wheat  a  plant  is  made  of,  duplicates  or  imitates  it,  and  provides  unlimited 
production  of  uniform  produce  by  automatic  processes.  .  .  . 


5  "Goodbye  Wheat  Farmer,"  in  The  American  Mercury,  June,  1931,  p.  193. 


84        PHASES  OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY 

Virtually  all  foods,  from  wheat  and  corn  to  beans,  can  be  made  in  the  labora- 
tory. The  problem  was  merely  to  break  down  the  natural  food  into  its  chemical 
constituents  and  rebuild  these  constituents  into  new  food  forms.  While  this  is 
not  strictly  a  synthetic  process,  it  at  least  transfers  the  making  of  foods  from 
the  farm  to  the  factory.  One  of  the  outstanding  achievements  to  date  has  been 
the  manufacture  of  butter  substitutes.6 

The  recent  agricultural  advances  have  completely  upset  the  theories 
of  Malthus,  to  the  effect  that  population  growth  was  bound  to  crowd 
hard  on  the  heels  of  food  production.  In  the  twentieth  century,  popula- 
tion has  notably  slowed  down  while  potential  food  production  has  in- 
creased at  a  most  impressive  rate.  These  inventions  have  also  altered 
some  of  the  main  problems  of  the  farmer.  In  the  old  days  his  chief 
ambition  was  to  get  a  good  crop,  which  he  could  easily  sell.  Today  the 
problem  is  often  how  to  dispose  of  a  crop  profitably,  once  it  is  harvested. 
Machinery,  fertilization,  irrigation,  and  insecticides  have  reduced  the 
tyranny  and  vicissitudes  of  nature ;  but  new  worries,  in  the  form  of  agri- 
cultural surpluses,  have  arisen. 

Agricultural  surpluses  are  not  alone  due  to  better  technological  methods 
of  production.  They  also  grow  out  of  more  efficient  modes  of  preserving 
and  transporting  food.  The  canning  industry  has  been  improved,  but 
even  more  revolutionary  have  been  the  use  of  refrigerator  cars  and  the 
construction  of  cold  storage  plants.  Electric  and  gas  refrigeration  units 
have  increased  the  popularity  of  refrigerators  in  private  homes.  This 
means  that  less  and  less  food  is  wasted  through  spoiling  and  decay.  So- 
called  dry  ice  as  a  type  of  super-refrigeration  and  the  associated  method 
of  refrigeration  employed  in  the  Birdseye  and  other  frozen  food  products 
make  possible  almost  indefinite  preservation  of  food,  with  little  loss  of 
the  original  taste  and  savor. 

Agricultural  Changes  Since  the  First  World  War.  The  first  World 
War  created  a  special  need  for  food  production  at  home,  on  account  of 
the  British  blockade  of  the  Continent  and  the  German  submarine  warfare 
directed  against  French  and  English  shipping.  Considerable  land  that 
had  hitherto  been  waste  land,  pasture  land,  hunting  land,  or  concentrated 
in  the  estates  of  the  nobility  was  brought  under  cultivation.  Improved 
agricultural  methods  were  also  introduced. 

After  the  war  there  were  sweeping  land  reforms.  In  Soviet  Russia 
the  land  was  gradually  nationalized,  collective  and  state  farms  estab- 
lished, and  agriculture  was  mechanized  with  a  speed  and  thoroughness 
unmatched  in  previous  human  experience. 

In  the  Balkan  states  and  in  the  newly-created  states  of  Poland,  Czecho- 
slovakia, Finland,  Latvia,  Estonia,  and  Lithuania,  there  were  notable 
agrarian  reforms,  consisting  mainly  of  the  redistribution  of  great  estates, 
formerly  held  by  the  nobility,  among  the  peasants.  The  Tory  landlords 
in  England,  the  feudal  landlords  in  Hungary,  and  the  Junkers  in  Prussia 


6  Parrish  and  Clark,  "Chemistry  Wrecks  the  Farm,"  Harper's  Magazine,  August, 
1935,  pp.  274-275,  278. 


PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION  OF   INDUSTRY        85 

were  able  to  resist  the  movement  for  agrarian  reform  until  the  coming 
of  the  second  World  War. 

The  second  World  War  once  more  created  a  food  crisis.  Germany, 
in  control  of  much  of  continental  Europe  outside  of  Soviet  Russia,  and 
prevented  by  the  British  blockade  from  getting  food  overseas,  made  a 
frantic  effort  to  get  enough  food  supplies  by  intensive  cultivation  of 
European  lands.  In  so  doing  she  made  much  use  of  forced  labor  on  the 
part  of  conquered  populations  and  armies.  The  prospect  was  that  the 
land  would  be  nationalized  and  agriculture  mechanized  by  the  Nazis 
almost  as  thoroughly  as  in  Soviet  Russia. 

In  the  United  States,  despite  a  so-called  surplus  of  agricultural  pro- 
duction, at  no  time  have  the  masses  been  able  to  buy  enough  food  to  enjoy 
decent  living  standards.  Even  in  1928  and  1929,  only  10  per  cent  of  the 
population  could  afford  to  buy  enough  to  eat,  according  to  government 
standards  of  a  liberal  diet  suitable  for  our  citizens. 

But  we  have  been  able  to  produce  far  more  than  the  people  can  buy 
under  a  scarcity  economy  and  the  profit  system  of  agricultural  enter- 
prise. The  condition  of  the  American  farmers  grew  progressively  worse 
from  1920  to  1933.  The  New  Deal  had  to  tackle  the  farm  problem  reso- 
lutely but  its  policy  has  been  that  of  subsidizing  agricultural  scarcity  and 
curtailed  production,  while  the  masses  of  the  people  still  continue  to  have 
too  little  to  eat.  This  is  obviously  no  solution  of  the  farm  problem,  and 
many  believe  that  it  cannot  be  solved  short  of  a  system  of  cooperative 
and  state-controlled  agriculture  which  will  produce  for  human  use  rather 
than  for  private  profits. 

Outstanding  Trends  in  the  Evolution  of 
Manufacturing 

Industry  in  Primitive  Times.  Like  those  of  most  other  phases  of 
human  culture,  the  foundations  of  manufacturing  industry  were  laid  in 
the  so-called  prehistoric  or  pre-literary  period. 

The  most  important  contribution  of  the  pre-literary  period  to  human 
material  culture  lay  in  the  origins  of  tools,  which  made  the  conquest  of 
nature  by  man  more  efficient  than  would  have  been  possible  by  his 
unaided  hands.  To  a  considerable  degree,  the  measure  of  human  progress 
lies  in  the  progressive  development  of  tools.  The  first  tools,  we  may  say, 
were  the  products  not  of  thought  but  of  accident.  Man's  tools  were 
discovered  before  they  were  invented. 

Wood,  bone,  shell,  skin,  and  the  like  were  employed  as  tools  by  early 
man,  in  addition  to  stone — that  is,  he  used  all  these  objects  as  means  to 
secure  the  desired  ends.  Implements  fashioned  of  stone  are  generally 
the  ones  that  enable  us  to  measure  early  industrial  development.  The 
fact  that  the  stone  implements  and  weapons  of  pre-literary  man  changed  . 
and  improved  in  many  ways  permits  us  to  distinguish  successive  stages 
in  his  industrial  progress. 

In  the  Eolithic  period,  man  found  his  tools  "ready-made."    The  re^ 


86        PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION  OF   INDUSTRY 

mainder  of  the  Stone  Age  is  broken  up,  as  we  have  seen,  into  the  Paleo- 
lithic and  Neolithic  periods,  classified  according  to  changes  in  the  type, 
variety,  and  fineness  of  workmanship  of  the  stone  tools  and  weapons 
manufactured.  From  then  on,  man  made  his  own  tools  instead  of  de- 
pending upon  crude  aids  provided  by  nature. 

Paleolithic  man  also  began  the  manufacture  of  clothing  to  keep  himself 
warm.  Equipped  as  he  was  with  scraper,  knife,  awl,  and  bone  needle, 
late  Paleolithic  man  cut  and  sewed  the  skins  of  animals  to  provide  crude 
clothing  for  himself  and  his  fellow  creatures. 

Probably  the  most  striking  and  far-reaching  innovation  in  the  Paleo- 
lithic period,  with  the  exception  of  the  basic  stone  industry,  was  the 
method  of  making  fire  by  rubbing  together  two  pieces  of  wood.  There  is 
good  reason  to  believe  that  fire  was  thus  artificially  produced  as  early  as 
the  middle  of  the  Paleolithic  period,  and  it  seems  certain  that  fire  was  used 
by  man  long  before  he  became  its  real  master. 

For  early  man  fire  meant  light,  heat,  protection,  and  a  multitude  of 
other  things.  That  which  once  warmed  the  bodies  of  primitive  man  in 
the  Paleolithic  rock  shelters  now  reduces  to  molten  form  the  iron  ore  in 
the  blast  furnaces  of  today,  and  in  the  acetylene  torch  it  cuts  steel  plates 
as  though  they  were  plywood. 

A.  L.  Kroeber  admirably  summarizes  the  achievements  of  the  Paleo- 
lithic Age,  also  indicating  what  still  remained  to  be  done  in  the  way  of 
creating  the  foundations  of  human  civilization  in  the  subsequent  Neo- 
lithic period: 

The  end  of  the  Paleolithic  thus  sees  man  in  possession  of  a  number  of  mechani- 
cal arts  which  enable  him  to  produce  a  considerable  variety  of  tools  in  several 
materials:  sees  him  controlling  fire;  cooking  food,  wearing  clothes,  and  living  in 
definite  habitations;  probably  possessing  some  sort  of  social  grouping,  order, 
and  ideas  of  law  and  justice;  clearly  under  the  influence  of  some  kind  of  religion; 
highly  advanced  in  the  plastic  arts;  and  presumably  already  narrating  legends 
and  singing  songs.  In  short,  many  fundamental  elements  of  civilization  were 
established.  It  is  true  that  the  sum  total  of  knowledge  and  accomplishments 
was  still  pitifully  small.  The  most  advanced  of  the  Old  Stone  Age  men  perhaps 
knew  and  could  do  about  one  thing  for  every  hundred  that  we  know  and  can  do. 
A  whole  array  of  fundamental  inventions — the  bow  and  arrow,  pottery,  domesti- 
cation of  animals  and  plants — had  not  yet  been  attempted,  and  they  do  not 
appear  on  the  scene  until  the  Neolithic.  But  in  spite  of  the  enormous  gaps 
remaining  to  be  rilled  in  the  Neolithic  and  in  the  historic  period,  it  does  seem 
fair  to  say  that  many  of  the  outlines  of  what  civilization  was  ultimately  to  be  had 
been  substantially  blocked  out  during  the  Upper  Paleolithic.  Most  of  the  frame- 
work was  there,  even  though  but  a  small  fraction  of  its  content  had  yet  been 
entered.7 

Remarkable  industrial  progress  was  made  during  the  Neolithic  Age. 
Earlier  types  of  implements  and  weapons  were  improved,  and  new  ones 
were  invented.  The  bow-and-arrow  and  the  large  stone  axe  originated 
in  the  early  Neolithic.  By  the  close  of  the  period  the  latter  had  come 
to  be  ground,  and  perforated  to  receive  a  handle.  In  the  early  Neo- 


T  A.  L.  Kroeber,  Anthropology,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1934,  pp.  178-179, 


PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION  OF   INDUSTRY        87 

lithic  there  was  also  a  marked  improvement  in  the  work  on  horn  and 
bone.  The  beauty  of  the  design  and  workmanship  evident  in  the  late 
Neolithic  stone  implements,  particularly  the  knives,  made  them  works  of 
art  as  well  as  tools.  One  more  significant  stone  implement  made  its 
appearance:  the  stone  mill  for  grinding  corn. 

Almost  as  important  as  the  domestication  of  animals  and  agriculture 
was  the  beginning  of  spinning  and  weaving  in  the  Neolithic  period. 
Earlier,  man  made  his  clothing  of  animal  skins,  using  beaten-bark  string 
as  thread.  Now  he  began  to  wear  woven  clothing,  for  which  flax  was 
the  chief  fiber  material  used.  Man  at  first  twisted  the  fibers  by  rubbing 
them  on  his  thigh  or  leg.  Later  a  weight  was  attached  to  one  end  of  a 
stick.  The  spindle-whorl  thus  evolved ;  the  yarn  could  be  spun  by  twist- 
ing the  spindle  to  which  the  fiber  was  attached.  The  weight  prevented 
the  thread  from  untwisting  or  curling.  It  seems  that  the  spindle-whorl 
answered  admirably  at  the  time,  for  there  was  only  a  slight  advance  in 
this  technique  of  spinning  until  the  spinning-wheel  was  devised  some  time 
during  the  Middle  Ages.  In  some  backward  regions  the  spindle-whorl 
is  still  used. 

The  first  suggestions  of  weaving  appeared  in  the  wattle-work  roofs  of 
the  pit  dwellings,  and  the  next  step  came  in  basketry  and  matting.  By 
the  Neolithic  period,  cloth  was  woven  on  the  hand  loom,  which  was  finally 
supplanted  only  in  the  first  quarter  of  the  nineteenth  century  of  the 
Christian  era.  As  Professor  Breasted  points  out,  the  technique  of  spin- 
ning and  weaving  linen  cloth  in  the  late  Neolithic  period  in  Egypt  was  in 
most  respects  equal  to  any  workmanship  exhibited  prior  to  the  Industrial 
Revolution  and  the  age  of  mechanical  weaving. 

For  the  introduction  of  pottery,  Neolithic  man  also  deserves  credit. 
Hollowed  chalk  vessels  were  the  only  rude  traces  of  pottery  in  the  Paleo- 
lithic period.  How  man  discovered  pottery  we  can  only  guess.  But  it 
was  indeed  a  stroke  of  good  fortune  when  he  learned  that  some  kinds  of 
earth  could  be  molded  and  dried  to  retain  a  given  shape,  and  could  also 
be  baked  and  thus  made  durable  and  waterproof.  The  invention  of  pot- 
tery meant  that  man  could  pick  his  habitation  more  freely,  because  the 
all-necessary  water  could  now  be  transported  over  a  distance.  It  opened 
up  new  possibilities  in  cooking,  and  also  brought  art  into  the  home.  Pot- 
tery was  still  hand-shaped  in  the  Neolithic;  the  potter's  wheel  did  not 
appear  until  the  metal  ages.  Kiln-baking  was  likewise  a  thing  of  the 
future. 

Manufacturing  in  the  Ancient  Near  Orient.  In  the  field  of  tech- 
nology and  manufacturing,  the  progress  made  by  the  ancient  Near 
Orient  was  striking  and  diversified.  The  Stone  Age  came  to  an  end, 
except  for  stone  knives  used  by  the  priests  for  ceremonial  purposes.  The 
metal  ages  began  at  this  time  and  before  the  close  of  the  oriental  period 
man  had  accustomed  himself  to  the  manufacture  of  most  of  the  well- 
known  metals  we  now  utilize,  with  the  exception  of  aluminum  and  alloys. 
Copper  was  the  first  metal  to  be  worked.  It  seems  that  the  Egyptians 
first  invented  the  art  of  metal  working,  as  we  find  some  copper  needles  in 


88        PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION  OF   INDUSTRY 

the  Egyptian  tombs  constructed  earlier  than  4000  B.C.,  and  copper  chisels 
in  considerable  quantities  in  graves  of  around  3500  B.C. 

A  harder  and  tougher  metal  appeared  with  the  rise  of  bronze  imple- 
ments and  weapons,  about  2500  B.C.,  on  the  islands  of  the  Aegean.  The 
first  bronze  appears  to  have  been  manufactured  from  an  ore  in  which 
copper  and  the  essential  tin  existed  in  a  natural  mixture.  Shortly  after 
this  time,  man  mastered  the  process  of  manufacturing  bronze  by  mixing 
tin  and  other  metals  with  the  copper  ore. 

Though  there  is  some  evidence  of  an  early  iron  culture  in  Africa,  it  is 
still  generally  held  that  the  manufacture  of  iron  implements  and  weapons 
originated  with  the  Hittites  of  Asia  Minor,  sometime  around  the  four- 
teenth century  B.C.  Excellent  steel  was  manufactured  in  Syria  and  else- 
where before  the  close  of  the  oriental  period. 

The  working  of  the  precious  metals  was  also  begun  in  oriental  times. 
The  Egyptians  executed  the  most  elaborate  forms  in  gold,  and  the  Baby- 
lonians specialized  in  various  kinds  of  silver  ornaments.  Likewise,  com- 
petent work  on  precious  stones  made  its  appearance  in  this  antique  age. 

The  potter's  wheel  was  first  used  in  the  oriental  period,  and  glazed  pot- 
tery began  to  be  manufactured.  Designs  became  more  ingenious  and 
artistic  and  the  ornamentation  much  more  beautiful.  The  potter's  wheel 
was  the  forerunner  of  the  all-important  lathe,  about  the  most  complicated 
mechanism  that  the  ancient  world  produced.  It  also  suggested  the  drill, 
which  was  used  by  the  Egyptian  jewelers. 

The  textile  industry  expanded  rapidly.  Finer  cloth  was  demanded  and 
quickly  produced.  The  weaving  of  tapestry  began  at  this  time.  The 
Egyptians  excelled  in  the  production  of  many  types  of  linen  cloth,  while 
the  Babylonians  carried  the  manufacturing  of  woolens  and  worsteds  to  a 
high  degree  of  technical  perfection.  Clothing  began  to  be  artificially 
dyed  in  a  variety  of  colors. 

The  improved  technology  brought  about  a  marked  increase  in  the 
volume  of  manufactured  commodities.  Better  transportation  resulted 
from  the  domestication  of  the  donkey,  horse,  and  camel.  Improved 
roads  made  it  feasible  to  travel  farther  in  search  of  raw  materials  and 
facilitated  the  shipment  of  manufactured  products.  There  was  special- 
ization by  trades,  which  made  for  better  quality  and  increased  produc- 
tivity in  manufacture.  Likewise,  in  Babylonia  we  find  the  first  appear- 
ance of  factories  or  shops,  usually  located  in  the  temples,  which  made 
possible  a  more  efficient  supervision  of  industry  than  could  be  achieved 
with  scattered  labor  in  individual  homes.  All  along  the  line  there  were 
notable  improvements  in  the  variety  and  technique  of  manufacturing. 

Greek  and  Roman  Manufacturing.  In  spite  of  their  remarkable 
contributions  to  culture,  the  Greeks  were  far  inferior  to  the  peoples  of  the 
Near  Orient  in  their  industrial  activities.  The  Greeks  did  not  distin- 
guish between  the  crafts  and  the  professions  as  we  do.  The  worker  in 
metal,  the  sculptor,  and  the  doctor  were  all  "craftsmen."  They  were  all, 
in  theory  at  least,  of  the  same  social  and  economic  rank.  The  method 
of  instruction,  whether  in  painting  or  in  cobbling,  was  by  apprenticeship. 


PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION  OF   INDUSTRY        89 

Even  before  Pericles  there  was  specialization  in  industry,  and  there  was 
specialization  within  some  of  the  crafts  themselves.  Sandals,  for  ex- 
ample, were  not  usually  cut  and  sewed  by  the  same  craftsman.  There 
was  a  similar  division  of  processes  in  the  manufacture  of  pottery.  The 
work  was  done  by  hand  with  the  aid  of  fairly  simple  tools.  Most  of  the 
Greek  craftsmen  were  free  metics  (people  of  foreign  birth)  and  slaves. 
Some,  however,  were  drawn  from  the  class  of  free  citizens. 

One  of  the  largest  Athenian  establishments  produced  shields  and  em- 
ployed 120  men,  but  a  shop  with  twenty  men  was  considered  rather  large. 
Most  craftsmen  worked  in  their  homes  or  in  small  establishments.  They 
retained  their  status  as  private  craftsmen  when  they  labored  for  the  state. 
The  free  craftsmen  were  in  no  sense  servants  of  the  state.  The  chief 
reasons  for  the  absence  of  large-scale  industrial  organization  were  the 
continued  importance  of  work  in  the  home  and  the  cheapness  of  slave 
labor.  Domestic  craftsmen  were  aided  by  the  members  of  their  family 
and  worked  side  by  side  with  the  slaves.  The  craftsman  usually  limited 
his  output  to  his  own  needs  and  actual  orders  received.  Xenophon  tells 
us  that  the  Athenian  workman  was  not  interested  in  increasing  the  num- 
ber of  his  employees,  since  his  production  was  limited  by  a  definite  market 
and  he  knew  exactly  how  many  employees  he  needed.  There  was  some 
production,  however,  for  a  hypothetical  general  market.  The  shoemaker, 
for  instance,  produced  a  number  of  ready-made  shoes. 

Though  industry,  as  well  as  commerce,  ran  well  behind  agri-culture  in 
economic  importance  in  ancient  Rome,  the  limited  evidence  we  possess 
indicates  considerable  industrial  development  between  the  third  century 
B.C.  and  the  rule  of  Augustus.  The  growth  of  the  population  of  Rome 
and  other  urban  communities  increased  the  demand  for  manufactured 
goods  and,  despite  heavy  imports,  stimulated  industry.  War  needs  en- 
couraged shipbuilding  and  metal-working,  while  the  reconstruction  of 
Rome  in  the  last  years  of  the  Republic  must  have  caused  considerable 
activity  in  the  building  trades.  The  tendency  toward  specialization  in 
industry  in  urban  centers  was  progressing  rapidly,  even  though  many 
needs  in  the  rural  districts  were  still  supplied  by  domestic  manufacture 
on  the  part  of  the  family.  On  the  largest  estates,  most  of  the  necessities 
were  provided  for  by  the  labor  of  slaves. 

The  chief  industries  of  Italy  appear  to  have  included  the  manufacture 
of  pottery,  textiles,  metal  ware,  leather  goods,  and  articles  of  wood.  The 
metal  mines,  both  in  the  peninsula  and  in  Spain  and  Gaul,  were  exten- 
sively worked.  Several  cities,  such  as  Capua,  Gales,  and  Puteoli,  became 
notable  for  their  production  of  metal  goods.  Puteoli,  with  its  busy  iron 
works,  was  most  important,  while  Capua  was  a  center  for  copper  and 
bronze  manufacture.  Puteoli  was  also  notable  for  its  extensive  pottery 
works.  Rome  was  a  manufacturing  center  for  bricks,  pottery,  tiles,  and 
articles  made  from  precious  metals.  The  great  number  of  goldsmiths 
and  jewelers  in  that  city  was  indicative  of  a  growing  class  of  wealthy 
people  and  of  luxurious  tastes.  Our  knowledge  of  the  textile  industries 
is  rather  scanty,  but  it  seems  that  spinning  and  weaving,  characteristi- 


90        PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY 

cally  domestic  tasks,  were  becoming  specialized  occupations  or  were 
done  by  the  slaves  in  the  wealthier  families. 

Small-scale  organization  and  the  simplest  of  mechanical  devices  were 
typical  of  Roman  industry.  Large-scale  production  and  organization 
were  to  be  found  only  in  such  industries  as  pottery  and  brick-making. 
Some  comparatively  large  workshops  were  established  by  wealthy 
Romans,  in  which  a  goodly  number  of  slaves  were  employed  under  the 
management  of  a  freedman  or  a  slave.  Many  smaller  shops  were  simi- 
larly organized,  of  several  types.  The  free  craftsman  working  with  his 
family  and  one  or  two  slaves  was  common,  as  were  the  shops  started  by 
freedmen  on  borrowed  money.  The  ready  availability  of  cheap  labor, 
slave  and  free,  discouraged  interest  in  mechanical  invention  and  labor- 
saving  devices. 

Medieval  Industry.  In  the  early  Middle  Ages,  two  forms  of  indus- 
trial production  generally  prevailed — domestic  and  manorial.  In  the 
first,  also  known  as  house  industry,  the  family  within  its  own  household 
produced,  so  far  as  possible,  all  the  necessaries  of  life  for  its  own  uses.  In 
manorial  industry,  manufactured  goods  were  produced  by  workers  on  the 
manor,  who  were  attached  to  their  work  as  the  villeins  were  bound  to  the 
soil.  Likewise,  they  rendered  dues  and  rents,  not  in  agricultural  pro- 
duce, but  in  work  on  manufactured  articles.  Residing  within  the  town 
proper  or  in  its  suburbs,  there  existed  what  we  may  call  an  embryonic 
class  of  urban  artisans,  who  too  were  under  the  dominion  of  lay  or 
eccelsiastical  lords.  As  a  rule,  most  of  the  goods  produced  by  domestic 
and  manorial  industry  were  destined  for  local  consumption,  and  the 
variety  of  goods  was  narrow.  Yet  historians  have  lately  proved  that 
in  the  larger  towns  there  was  considerable  manufacturing,  some  of  it  for 
a  luxury  trade. 

During  and  after  the  eleventh  century,  the  revival  of  commerce  pro- 
vided three  stimuli  that  had  hitherto  been  lacking — broader  markets,  raw 
materials,  and  capital.  The  contact  with  the  Near  East  not  only  intro- 
duced new  articles  into  western  Europe,  but  also  brought  in  the  more 
advanced  industrial  technique  and  organization  of  the  Muslims  and 
Byzantines.  Before  long,  Europe  learned  not  only  to  reproduce  the  arti- 
cled of  the  East  but  also  to  improve  at  times  upon  the  borrowed  tech- 
nique. 

The  characteristic  urban  industrial  establishment  was  the  small  work- 
shop of  the  free  artisan — the  gild  master.  He  was,  apart  from  the  restric- 
tions that  encircled  him,  a  small  entrepreneur.  He  provided  the  tools, 
frequently  the  raw  materials,  always  the  labor — his  own,  and  that  of  his 
family  and  apprentices  and  journeymen — and  finally  disposed  of  the 
completed  article.  Since  he  was,  in  part,  a  merchant,  it  is  understandable 
why  the  merchant  gild  at  first  included  craftsmen. 

As  the  artisan  worked  on  the  orders  of  individual  customers  or  produced 
for  the  town  or  regional  market,  he  rarely  ran  the  risk  of  overproduction. 
Though  his  gain  was  circumscribed,  he  alone  enjoyed  the  income  from 
his  labor.  The  element  of  profit  entered,  however,  where  hired  workers 


PHASES   OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF    INDUSTRY        91 

were  involved.  There  the  master  craftsman  received  a  return  also  on 
their  labor. 

An  incentive  to  produce  goods  of  high  quality  lay  in  the  fact  that 
he  sold  directly  to  the  consumer.  It  was  thus  difficult  to  escape  personal 
responsibility  for  articles  of  poor  quality.  The  gilds  regulated  the 
hours  and  conditions  of  labor  in  the  effort  to  maintain  uniform  stand- 
ards of  excellence.  As  a  rule,  the  artisan  had  a  long  working-day,  run- 
ning from  eight  and  a  half  to  as  many  as  sixteen  hours  in  some  trades 
during  the  summer.  But  he  was  forbidden  to  work  at  night  principally 
because  the  poor  artificial  light  at  his  disposal  made  it  almost  impossible 
to  do  good  work  after  dark.  The  gild  craftsman  was  enjoined  to  do  his 
work  before  his  shop  window,  where  he  could  be  plainly  seen  by  the  public. 
The  fact  that  all  the  members  of  a  craft  lived  in  the  same  street  or  quarter 
of  a  town  facilitated  inspection  of  working  conditions  and  manufactured 
products,  and  enhanced  the  sense  of  corporate  unity  among  the  gild 
members. 

Despite  the  many  regulations  by  the  gilds,  the  standards  of  excellence 
were  not  always  maintained  as  well  as  is  often  supposed.  Contemporary 
records  show  the  types  of  fraud  practiced.  Material  supplied  by  cus- 
tomers was  sometimes  cunningly  stolen  from  under  their  very  noses ;  pots 
melted  when  placed  on  the  fire;  cloth  was  stretched;  inferior  goods  were 
substituted  for  those  of  better  quality  after  the  sale  had  been  made. 
"Falsework"  was  punished — first  offenses  by  a  fine,  which  the  gild  and 
the  town  divided.  Third  or  fourth  offenses  might  draw  expulsion  from 
the  gild. 

The  craft  gilds  also  regulated  the  remuneration  of  apprentices  and 
journeymen.  The  latter  were  the  true  wage-earners,  although  the  for- 
mer sometimes  received  wages  towards  the  close  of  their  training  period. 
The  regulation  of  wages  was  made  to  equalize  conditions  and  destroy 
competition  among  gild  members.  Prices  were  fixed  on  the  assumption 
that  all  members  of  a  gild  possessed  about  the  same  skill.  When  a  great 
variety  of  goods  with  a  diversity  of  grades  began  to  be  manufactured,  the 
success  of  price  regulation  became  uncertain,  for  it  depended  upon  the 
uniformity  of  the  goods  being  produced.  To  check  both  variety  and 
diversity,  all  the  gilds  discouraged  technical  improvements.  A  change 
in  tools,  material,  or  method  would  destroy  the  principle  of  gild  equality 
as  well  as  the  uniformity  of  the  type  and  grade  of  product.  Innovations 
did  creep  in,  regardless  of  prohibitions,  and  complete  equality  and  uni- 
formity was  lost  with  the  resulting  breakdown  in  the  rigid  control  of 
prices. 

AVhile  agriculture  was  the  main  activity  carried  on  by  the  monks, 
nevertheless  they  fostered  an  extensive  development  of  the  ordinary  medi- 
eval industries,  and  were  surpassed  in  production  only  by  the  gilds.  Most 
of  this  manufacturing  activity  was  carried  on  by  serfs.  This  servile  labor 
greatly  reduced  manufacturing  costs.  The  monks  therefore  could  com- 
pete to  great  advantage  with  the  free  and  better-paid  gild  labor.  Hence 
the  gilds  endeavored  to  protect  themselves  by  anti-cleric  economic  legis- 


92   PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION  OF  INDUSTRY 

lation  in  the  medieval  towns.  The  monks,  however,  continued  to  manu- 
facture utensils,  clothing,  leather  goods,  and  so  on.  They  were  noted  for 
the  high  quality  of  their  beer,  and  had  a  virtual  monopoly  on  beer-brew- 
ing until  well  along  in  the  twelfth  century.  Their  industrial  organization 
attained  such  efficiency  that  they  might  be  described  as  forerunners  of 
our  modern  division  of  labor.  Among  the  monastic  serfs  were  smiths, 
masons,  carpenters,  carders  and  weavers,  millers  and  bakers,  and  skilled 
workers  In  precious  metals. 

The  Muslims  were  far  more  advanced  than  the  Christians  of  western 
Europe  hi  their  manufacturing  industry.  They  turned  out  goods  unique 
for  their  day  in  both  variety  and  volume.  According  to  Charles  Seig- 
nobos,  the  West  owes  to  the  Muslims  "the  greater  part  of  our  manufac- 
tured articles  of  luxury — linen,  damask,  morocco,  silk  stuffs  embossed 
with  gold  and  silver,  muslin,  gauze,  taffeta,  velvet  (later  brought  to  such 
perfection  in  Italy),  crystal  and  plate  glass  imitated  in  Venice,  paper, 
sugar,  confectionery,  and  syrups." 

Early  Modern  Industry.  Industrial  developments  following  the  ex- 
pansion of  Europe  and  the  Commercial  Revolution  after  1500  were  more 
impressive  than  any  others  which  had  taken  place  since  the  industrial 
developments  in  ancient  Egypt  and  Babylonia. 

The  new  oversea  markets  called  for  increased  quantities  of  European 
manufactured  products,  and  the  governments,  particularly  England, 
stressed  the  production  of  those  to  be  exchanged  for  raw  materials.  No 
doubt  the  flow  of  goods  was  checked  somewhat  by  monopoly  and  Mer- 
cantilism,8 but  the  increased  production  was,  nevertheless,  unprecedented. 

The  textile  industry  was  one  of  the  first  to  be  profoundly  affected  by 
the  new  demand  for  goods.  The  manufacture  of  woolens  had  been  highly 
developed  in  Flanders  in  the  Middle  Ages  and  had  been  introduced  into 
England  after  the  middle  of  the  fourteenth  century.  The  silk  industry 
had  also  grown  to  some  proportions  in  Italy  and  France,  and  to  a  lesser 
degree  in  England.  Not  only  was  silk  manufactured,  but  raw  silk  was 
successfully  produced  in  both  Italy  and  France. 

Most  of  the  oversea  demand  for  European  textiles  came  from  colonists. 
Among  the  old,  established  industries  to  profit  by  the  new  situation  were 
English  woolens  and  French  silks.  The  fact  that  some  of  this  textile 
trade  was  with  tropical  or  subtropical  regions  led  in  time  to  a  remarkable 
development  of  the  cotton  trade,  in  spite  of  the  opposition  of  the  vested 
interests  in  the  woolen  and  silk  industries.  As  early  as  the  latter  half 
of  the  sixteenth  century,  the  English  began  to  manufacture  for  export  to 
the  Indies  a  coarse  cloth  known  as  fustian.  At  the  outset,  it  was  prob- 
ably not  cotton,  certainly  not  all  cotton,  but  it  soon  became  a  mixture  in 
which  cotton  figured  more  and  more  as  the  importation  of  raw  cotton  in- 
creased. A  considerable  cotton  industry  also  developed  in  the  manu- 
facturing of  calico,  chintz,  and  underclothing,  but  the  woolen  interests 
effectively  restrained  the  full  expansion  of  the  new  rival  for  a  long  period. 


8  See  below,  p.  110. 


PHASES   QF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF    INDUSTRY        93 

Cotton  began  to  dominate  English  textile  industry  only  after  the  onset 
of  the  Industrial  Revolution  of  the  eighteenth  century.  As  the  ancient 
traditions,  craft  skill,  and  the  vested  interests  of  the  workers  in  the  woolen 
industry  offered  much  greater  resistance  to  technological  changes,  English 
production  of  a  rough,  staple  cotton  cloth  was  of  great  importance  in 
facilitating  the  later  introduction  of  textile  machinery. 

The  revolution  in  dyestuffs  improved  the  quality  as  well  as  increased 
the  quantity  of  English  colored  fabrics.  The  most  important  of  these 
new  vegetable  dyes  from  overseas  were  indigo,  logwood,  and  cochineal. 
The  wide  use  of  pottery  in  Europe  came  mainly  from  the  contact  of 
Europeans  with  China.  During  the  Middle  Ages  dishes  had  been  made 
of  wood,  pewter,  or  brass.  The  Europeans  now  began  to  manufacture 
imitations  of  the  Chinese  goods,  and  such  well-known  products  as  Meissen 
and  Delft  ware  were  beginning  to  be  made. 

Various  types  of  glass  products  and  glazed  ware  were  produced  in 
Europe  on  a  considerable  scale  from  the  seventeenth  century  onward. 
During  the  Middle  Ages  there  had  been  little  use  of  glass,  except  for 
windows  in  the  dwellings  of  the  rich  and  the  notable  development  of 
stained  glass  for  cathedral  windows.  The  glass  industry  in  the  Orient 
had  been  important  since  the  days-  of  the  ancient  Egyptians,  and  Euro- 
pean contacts  with  the  East  led  to  the  large-scale  introduction  of  glass 
and  glazed  products.  Not  only  did  the  expansion  of  Europe  encourage 
the  use  of  glass  and  glazing  for  such  purposes  as  windows  and  dishes,  but 
also  increased  the  use  of  spectacles,  burning  glasses,  mirrors,  and  other 
devices  brought  forth  as  a  result  of  the  progress  in  the  science  of  optics. 

The  leather  industry  increased  to  a  marked  degree,  particularly  notable 
being  the  enormous  colonial  demand  for  shoes.  In  the  year  1658  no  less 
than  24,000  pairs  of  shoes  were  sent  to  Virginia  alone. 

There  was  a  large  market  for  various  types  of  hardware  in  the  colonies, 
particularly  for  muskets,  swords,  hoes,  nails,  various  types  of  tools,  lead, 
pewter,  and  tinware.  The  development  of  the  hardware  industry  in  turn 
stimulated  mining,  particularly  the  mining  of  iron,  lead,  and  tin. 

Shipbuilding  was  immediately  affected  by  the  new  commerce.  The 
improvement  in  the  construction  of  vessels  had  been  one  of  the  most 
important  influences  making  possible  oversea  expansion.  Progress  in 
physics  and  mathematics  made  it  possible  to  apply  scientific  rules  in  the 
technique  of  navigation,  which  tended  to  keep  pace  with  the  demand  for 
more  and  better  vessels.  In  1560  the  total  tonnage  of  English  merchant 
ships  was  7,600.  By  1691  it  had  increased  to  500,000.  This  was  accom- 
panied by  a  remarkable  growth  in  the  tonnage  of  war  vessels.  The  Eng- 
lish naval  tonnage  in  1607  was  23,000,  while  a  century  later  it  reached 
over  120,000. 

Much  of  this  new  industry  was  carried  on  in  the  homes  of  workmen 
under  the  so-called  putting-out  system,  which  replaced  the  gild  system  of 
the  Middle  Ages.9 


9  See  below,  p.  105. 


94        PHASES  OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF    INDUSTRY 

The  First  Industrial  Revolution.  The  most  sweeping  changes  that 
ever  took  place  in  manufacturing  industry  were  those  launched  by  the 
"Industrial  Revolution,"  which  began  in  England  in  the  first  half  of  the 
eighteenth  century.  While  there  had  been  considerable  mechanical  in- 
vention from  the  close  of  the  Middle  Ages,  machine  manufacturing  did 
not  become  general  until  after  the  Industrial  Revolution. 

The  first  important  mechanical  changes  came  in  the  manufacture  of 
cloth,  an  industry  in  which  England  led  the  world.  Before  cotton  and 
wool  can  be  made  into  cloth,  the  fibers  must  be  spun  into  threads.  The 
medieval  spinning  wheel,  which  spun  one  thread  at  a  time  and  was  run 
by  foot  power,  was  still  in  use  everywhere  until  after  the  middle  of  the 
eighteenth  century.  In  1764,  James  Hargreaves,  an  English  weaver, 
succeeded  in  making  a  "spinning  jenny,"  which  was  run  by  horsepower 
and  spun  eight  threads  instead  of  one.  Some  five  years  later,  Richard 
Arkwright  provided  a  roller  water-frame  spinning  machine  which  spun  a 
firmer  yarn  than  Hargreaves'  machine.  Ten  years  later  (1779),  Samuel 
Crompton  invented  the  "mule  spinner,"  which  spun  even  more  rapidly 
and  efficiently.  By  around  1785  the  "mule  spinner"  was  in  general  use 
in  England.  Better  looms  to  weave  cloth  were  now  needed.  In  1738, 
John  Kay  had  invented  a  flying  shuttle  which  made  hand  weaving  about 
twice  as  easy  as  it  had  been  before.  In  1787  Edmund  Cartwright  in- 
vented a  power  loom,  which  soon  replaced  the  hand  loom.  The  invention 
of  the  cotton-gin  by  Eli  Whitney  in  the  United  States  in  1793  enormously 
facilitated  mechanical  production  of  cotton  goods.  It  removed  the 
seeds  from  raw  cotton  by  mechanical  methods,  thus  making  cotton  avail- 
able in  quantities  suitable  for  mechanical  manufacture. 

Between  1750  and  1825,  mechanical  methods  of  spinning  and  weaving 
were  thus  successfully  devised  and  practically  applied.  These  inventions 
rendered  necessary  new  types  of  power  for  driving  the  machinery.  Water 
power,  which  had  been  utilized  since  primitive  times,  was  cheap  and  ade- 
quate where  it  could  be  found,  but  it  was  not  available  in  all  places  where 
men  desired  to  build  factories.  Hence  it  was  supplemented  by  the  steam 
engine. 

The  steam  engine  had  been  invented  as  a  sort  of  mechanical  toy  in  the 
Greek  period,  and  in  the  form  of  a  steam-propelled  atmosphere  engine 
it  had  been  in  use  in  the  early  part  of  the  eighteenth  century  for  the  pur- 
pose of  pumping  water  out  of  mines.  It  remained  for  a  Scottish  me- 
chanic, James  Watt,  to  invent,  in  1769,  the  true  steam  engine  and  thus 
provide  the  basic  type  of  power  long  used  in  modern  industry  and  trans- 
portation. The  steam  engine  has  since  been  supplemented  by  the  steam 
turbine,  the  internal  combustion  engine,  and  the  increasingly  popular 
and  efficient  electric  motor. 

The  new  machines  and  engines  required  stronger  materials  than  wood. 
Iron  and  steel,  as  produced  by  the  crude  methods  of  the  mid-eighteenth 
century,  were  too  expensive.  The  first  problem  in  the  production  of 
cheaper  iron  products  was  to  find  more  suitable  fuel  than  charcoal  for 
smelting  ore.  In  the  early  eighteenth  century  Abraham  Darby  learned 


PHASES  OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF  .INDUSTRY        95 

how  to  use  coke  in  his  furnaces  in  England.  About  1760,  John  Smeaton 
invented  the  air-blast  furnace.  On  the  basis  of  these  innovations,  Peter 
Onions  and  Henry  Cort  invented  the  puddling  process  for  making  malle- 
able iron  relatively  cheaply  and  in  large  quantities.  Their  methods  were 
improved  upon  by  Joseph  Hall  about  1830,  and  at  the  same  time  James 
Neilson  invented  the  hot-blast  furnace.  Cort  and  Purnell  invented  the 
rolling  mill,  and  John  Wilkinson  and  John  Roebuck  combined  efficient  fac- 
tory methods  with  these  new  processes  for  making  iron.  In  the  1840's 
Sir  Henry  Bessemer  extended  the  methods  used  by  Cort  and  Onions  to 
the  manufacture  of  low-cost  steel.  The  Bessemer  process  is  still  em- 
ployed for  making  low-grade  steel  products,  but  it  has  been  supplemented 
by  the  Siemens-Martin,  or  open-hearth  process  for  a  better  grade  of  steel. 

The  need  for  a  greater  volume  and  a  wider  diversity  of  raw  materials, 
together  with  the  vast  increase  of  finished  products  produced  by  the  new 
machinery,  made  extensive  improvements  desirable  in  methods  of  trans- 
portation. Better  roads  were  devised  by  Telford,  Macadam,  and  others, 
early  in  the  nineteenth  century.  These  first  achievements  were  followed 
by  success  in  making  asphalt  and  concrete  highways.  A  great  network 
of  canals  was  constructed  in  the  wake  of  the  initial  activities  of  the  Duke 
of  Bridgewater  and  his  chief  engineer,  James  Brindley,  in  England,  fol- 
lowing 1760.  The  steam  locomotive  was  invented  by  George  Stephenson, 
and  the  modern  railroad  and  steam  transportation  on  land  came  into 
being  after  1825.  Fitch,  Symington,  Fulton,  and  others  successfully 
applied  the  steam  engine  to  water  navigation  through  the  invention  of  the 
steamboat.  The  new  methods  of  manufacturing  iron  and  steel  soon  made 
possible  greatly  improved  types  of  ocean-going  boats.  The  screw  pro- 
peller invented  by  John  Ericsson  notably  increased  the  efficiency  of  the 
steamboat. 

The  Second  and  Third  Industrial  Revolutions:  Mass  Production. 
These  inventions  in  the  realms  of  textiles,  iron  and  steel,  manufacturing, 
and  transportation  are  usually  regarded  as  constituting  the  essence  of  the 
Industrial  Revolution.  But,  in  reality,  they  constituted  only  the  first 
industrial  revolution.  A  second  industrial  revolution  followed  closely 
upon  its  heels.  We  are  already  entering  upon  a  third,  and  perhaps  more 
momentous,  one.  The  second  Industrial  Revolution  fell  mainly  between 
the  periods  of  our  Civil  War  and  the  World  War.  The  third  began  to 
make  its  appearance  at  the  close  of  the  World  War. 

The  second  Industrial  Revolution  brought  into  existence  bigger  and  bet- 
ter machinery  in  those  fields  where  there  had  been  notable  inventions 
during  the  first  industrial  revolution.  For  example,  the  manufacture  of 
textiles  and  of  iron  and  steel  products  became  ever  more  efficient.  Rail- 
road trains  and  steamboats  became  larger  and  speedier.  There  have 
been,  however,  many  novel  developments  which  were  anticipated  only 
faintly,  if  at  all,  during  the  first  Industrial  Revolution.  Especially  im- 
portant has  been  the  application  of  chemistry  to  industrial  processes. 
It  brought  about  more  efficient  methods  of  making  steel.  It  also  laid 
the  basis  for  the  enormously  important  rubber  industry,  which  today  ex- 


96        PHASES  OF.  THE   EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY 

tends  from  automobile  tires  to  the  most  varied  articles  of  clothing  and 
sanitary  devices.  The  discoveries  of  Charles  Goodyear,  about  1840, 
made  possible  the  further  development  of  the  rubber  industry.  It  was 
chemistry  which  taught  us  how  to  refine  petroleum  and  to  produce  more 
cheaply  the  gasoline  which  is  essential  for  the  internal  combustion  engine. 
Organic  chemistry  has  enabled  us  to  manufacture  a  vast  variety  of  syn- 
thetic products  and  to  utilize  many  by-products  which  were  formerly 
wasted.  For  example,  it  requires  two  pages  of  a  large  book  merely  to 
tabulate  the  by-products  derived  from  cottonseed,  running  all  the  way 
from  explosives  and  camera  films  to  soap  and  cosmetics. 

Power  and  transportation  were  also  revolutionized.  The  steam  tur- 
bine and  the  internal  combustion  engine  made  their  appearance  in  the 
last,  third  of  the  ninteenth  century,  the  Diesel  engine  and  the  electric 
motor  in  the  twentieth.  The  bicycle,  the  automobile,  and  the  airplane 
have  followed  in  rapid  succession.  Streamlined  and  Diesel-motored 
railroad  trains  are  competing  effectively  with  increasing  airplane 
transport. 

The  revolutions  in  the  communication  of  information  have  paralleled 
those  in  power  and  transport.  Marconi  gave  us  the  wireless  telegraph, 
and  within  less  than  two  decades  the  wireless  telephone,  or  radio,  made 
its  appearance.  We  stand  on  the  eve  of  practical  television.  Improved 
printing  presses  and  typsetting  machinery,  more  efficient  methods  of 
making  stereotyped  plates,  the  use  of  cables  and  wireless,  and  the  appear- 
ance of  radio  pictures  have  made  news  more  comprehensive  and  instan- 
taneous. 

The  second  Industrial  Revolution  brought  about  a  vast  increase  in  the 
volume  of  production.  The  larger  factories  and  better  machines  made 
mass  production  feasible.  Industrial  units  became  ever  larger.  There 
are  today  in  the  United  States  over  a  score  of  billion-dollar  industrial 
enterprises.  Industry  has  also  tended  to  become  localized  in  such  a 
manner  as  to  realize  the  maximum  advantages  in  the  assembling  of  raw 
materials  and  the  distribution  of  finished  products. 

The  greater  difficulties  of  administering  these  vast  industrial  organiza- 
tions have  given  rise  to  the  science  of  business  management  and  personnel 
administration.  Efficiency  has  increased  and  wastes  are  eliminated  to 
an  ever  greater  degree.  More  abundant  production  has  brought  to  the 
fore  the  necessity  of  improving  salesmanship,  to  dispose  of  the  increased 
volume  of  products.  To  meet  this  need,  commercial  advertising  has 
developed  on  an  unprecedented  scale. 

Impressive  though  the  achievements  of  the  second  Industrial  Revolu- 
tion may  be,  we  are  entering  an  even  more  amazing  industrial  era  in 
what  is  coming  to  be  known  as  the  third  Industrial  Revolution,  or  "the 
power  age."  The  most  remarkable  addition  to  manufacturing  efficiency 
already  in  common  use  is  the  so-called  "speed-up"  process  which  underlies 
contemporary  mass  production.  This  has  been  made  possible  by  the 
wholesale  manufacture  of  interchangeable  parts  and  the  development 
of  the  conveyor-belt. 


PHASES   OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF    INDUSTRY        97 

The  introduction  of  the  photo-electric  cell  or  "electric  eye"  for  the  auto- 
matic control  of  mechanical  processes  has  brought  about  an  increase  in 
productive  efficiency.10  For  example,  the  manufacture  of  electric  light 
bulbs  is  no  less  than  ten  thousand  times  more  efficient  in  terms  of  produc- 
tion per  man  power  than  were  methods  previously  employed.  On  the 
basis  of  carefully  compiled  statistics,  it  has  been  shown  that  production 
per  man-hour  has  more  than  tripled  since  1900.  Using  the  production  of 
1900  as  100,  man-hour  production  in  1919  was  136;  in  1939  it  was  325; 
and  in  1940  it  was  330. 

The  onset  of  the  third  Industrial  Revolution  is  characterized  by  the 
increased  use  of  electricity.  Formerly  generated  mainly  by  water  power, 
it  is  now  coming  to  be  produced  more  and  more  by  gigantic  steam  tur- 
bines. Four  of  the  largest  turbines  known  in  the  United  States  can 
produce  more  energy  than  the  entire  working  population  of  the  country. 
The  location  of  turbines  close  to  the  site  of  use  saves  the  expense  of  build- 
ing transmission  lines  and  the  large  waste  of  current  incident  to  long- 
distance transmission. 

The  introduction  of  automatic  machinery  and  the  greater  utilization  of 
more  cheaply  produced  electricity  threatens  mankind  with  technological 
unemployment  to  an  extent  unknown  in  human  experience.  It  is  believed 
by  many  that  the  third  Industrial  Revolution  is  rapidly  producing  tend- 
encies quite  incompatible  with  the  ideals  and  practices  of  a  democratic 
and  capitalistic  culture. 

As  the  brilliant  French  sociologist,  Gabriel  Tarde,  pointed  out  in  his 
ingenious  system  of  social  philosophy,  inventions  are  the  chief  source  of 
innovations  in  modern  culture.  Only  by  inventions  can  culture  be 
changed  in  any  very  fundamental  way.  In  addition  to  local  inventions, 
there  is  also  the  borrowing  by  one  group  of  the  inventions  which  another 
community  has  produced.  Above  all,  the  spirit  of  invention  is  a  denial 
of  the  repetition  and  stability  that  characterized  pastoral  and  agricultural 
society. 

Inventions  were  few  and  relatively  infrequent  down  to  the  middle  of 
the  eighteenth  century.  In  fact,  the  condition  of  technology  was  rela- 
tively static  for  thousands  of  years  prior  to  1700.  At  the  present  time, 
a  single  year  often  witnesses  a  number  of  inventions  far  in  excess  of 
those  produced  in  a  thousand  years  previous  to  1700.  Furthermore,  with 
the  progress  of  modern  technology,  they  are  no  longer  the  chance  product 
of  a  unique  genius.  They  are  becoming  the  natural  and  inevitable  result 
of  scientific  research  and  experimentation.  Given  a  definite  need,  an 
invention  is  well-nigh  inevitable,  as  William  F.  Ogburn  and  others  have 
proved  by  citing  numerous  inventions  arrived  at  independently  and 
almost  synchronously  by  a  number  of  different  inventors.  It  is  not  now 
so  much  a  question  whether  it  is  possible  as  whether  it  will  pay  to 
produce  and  market  it. 


10  Qn  the  photo-electric  eye,  see  Atlantic  Monthly,  December,  1940. 


98        PHASES  OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY 

However,  the  great  productive  capacity  of  our  modern  industrial  plants 
has  never  been  realized  except  in  war  time.  Our  economic  system  is  based 
upon  scarcity  and  curtailed  production,  while  our  technology  is  adjusted 
to  plenty.  Until  we  are  able  to  create  an  economic  order  which  sanctions 
and  encourages  full  productive  efficiency  we  are  never  likely  to  realize 
anything  like  our  actual  productive  capacity  in  peace  time.  Our  business 
order  even  deliberately  holds  back  technological  advances  through  fre- 
quent suppression  of  inventions  and  patents  which  would  upset  invest- 
ments in  obsolete  equipment.  Harold  Loeb  estimates  that  we  waste 
between  30  and  50  billion  dollars  each  year  in  potential  production  of 
goods  as  a  result  of  the  anti-social  and  non-economic  practices  associated 
with  the  scarcity  economy.  And  we  probably  waste  an  equal  amount  in 
the  inefficient  handling  of  the  problems  of  distribution  and  consumption 
of  food  and  goods.11 

The  most  important  recent  developments  working  against  the  prevail- 
ing economy  of  scarcity  have  been  the  rationalization  of  industry  and 
economic  planning.  These  have  taken  place  mainly  in  Germany  and 
Russia.  In  rationalizing  industry  both  the  state  and  private  producers 
cooperate  in  planning  production,  in  eliminating  waste,  in  abandoning 
inferior  plants,  and  in  stimulating  invention  and  engineering  efficiency. 
This  program  was  first  elaborately  developed  in  Germany  after  the  first 
World  War.  It  was  used  as  a  method  of  enabling  Germany  to  recover 
from  the  industrial  losses  sustained  during  the  war. 

In  Soviet  Russia  a  planned  economy  with  no  restriction  of  production 
has  been  achieved.  It  rests  upon  three  comprehensive  five-year  plans, 
the  first  set  up  in  October,  1928,  the  second  in  January,  1933,  and  the 
third  in  January,  1938.  The  utmost  possible  efficiency  is  aimed  at. 
However,  the  Russians  have  not  yet  been  able  to  develop  the  same  degree 
of  mechanical  expertness  that  has  been  attained  in  Germany  and  the 
United  States. 

A  less  resolute  effort  at  a  planned  economy  was  made  in  Nazi  Germany, 
where  four-year  plans  were  announced  in  1934  and  in  1937.  The  Nazi 
four-year  plans  had  in  part  a  military  goal — to  make  the  country  inde- 
pendent, so  far  as  possible,  of  imports.  The  result  was  an  increase  of 
efficiency  in  production,  though  much  of  it  went  into  armament  and  did 
not  bring  about  any  marked  increase  in  the  welfare  of  the  people. 

Leading  Periods  in  the  Development  of 
Trade  and  Commerce 

In  treating  the  rise  and  growth  of  commerce,  we  should  recall  what  has 
been  said  earlier  concerning  the  development  of  transportation  facilities, 
upon  which  commerce  so  closely  depends.  Inventive  genius  in  manu- 


The  Social  Frontier,  November,  1938,  pp.  44-46. 


PHASES  OF  THE   EVOLUTION  OF   INDUSTRY        99 

f acturing  and  transportation  has  been  mainly  responsible  for  the  existence 
of  trade,  both  local  and  foreign. 

There  seems  to  have  been  some  trade  on  a  barter  basis  in  flint  and  bone 
implements,  skins,  grains,  and  a  few  other  rudimentary  commodities  by 
early  man,  but  systematic  trade  over  a  considerable  area  began  in  ancient 
Egypt  and  Babylonia.  Egypt  carried  on  an  extensive  trade  across  the 
desert  of  northern  Africa,  down  the  Nile  to  Nubia  and  the  Sudan,  eastward 
to  the  peninsula  of  Sinai  and  Arabia,  and  into  Syria.  Not  only  did  the 
Egyptians  create  a  large  overland  trade,  but  they  seem  to  have  been  the 
first  to  conquer  the  sea  and  to  launch  commerce  on  the  Red  and  Mediter- 
ranean Seas.  The  land  trade  of  the  Egyptians  was  carried  on  chiefly  by 
means  of  donkey  caravans.  We  usually  associate  camels  with  desert 
commerce,  but  they  were  not  introduced  in  ancient  Egypt  until  very 
late. 

The  Babylonians  built  up  a  large  overland  trade,  which  followed  the 
Tigris  and  Euphrates  rivers,  and  then  went  west  through  the  mountain 
passes  to  the  Syrian  coast.  The  government  gave  security  to  Babylonian 
commerce  by  sending  portions  of  the  army  to  police  the  trade  routes. 

But  the  great  land  traders  of  the  ancient  East  were  the  Arameans  of 
Syria.  From  their  cities,  like  Damascus,  they  established  control  over 
the  rich  land  commerce  of  western  Asia.  Their  language  became  the 
universal  language  of  the  area  for  commercial  and  cultural  purposes. 

The  first  important  people  that  founded  their  culture  and  power  mainly 
on  the  basis  of  sea  trade  were  the  inhabitants  of  ancient  Crete.  By  2500 
B.C.  the  Cretans  had  created  a  prosperous  commercial  civilization,  which 
lasted  until  about  1500  B.C. 

The  next  great  sea  traders  of  the  Near  East  were  the  Phoencians,  who 
carried  their  commerce  and  culture  throughout  the  Mediterranean,  and 
even  skirted  the  coasts  of  western  Africa  and  western  Europe. 

Greece  replaced  the  Phoenician  cities  as  the  leader  in  Mediterranean 
commerce  after  600  B.C.  In  the  fifth  century  B.C.,  Athens  became  the 
great  commercial  state  of  the  Mediterranean  and  for  a  time  dominated 
its  commerce.  Greek  products  were  sent  abroad  in  exchange  for  the 
wheat  which  was  so  sorely  needed.  Even  after  Athens  lost  its  political 
independence  it  still  carried  on  a  good  deal  of  sea  trade. 

Athenian  dominion  was  followed  by  that  of  Alexandria,  which  built 
larger  ships  than  the  Athenians  were  ever  able  to  float  and  for  a  time 
conducted  an  extremely  prosperous  commercial  activity.  Carthage,  a 
Phoenician  colony  in  northern  Africa,  dominated  much  of  the  trade  of 
the  Mediterranean  from  400  B.C.  until  it  was  destroyed  by  the  Romans; 
two  centuries  later. 

Rome  utilized  the  maritime  genius  of  its  conquered  peoples,  such  as  the 
sailors  of  Athens  and  Alexandria,  to  assist  in  carrying  on  the  Roman  trade 
which  was  necessary  to  supply  Rome  with  both  the  luxuries  and  necessi- 
ties— especially  wheat.  Indeed,  Rome  was  a  parasitic  economy  which 
lived  mainly  on  the  imported  resources  of  the  Near  East  and  Gaul. 


100      PHASES   OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY 

From  the  time  of  the  Egyptians  to  that  of  the  Muslims,  Mediterranean 
trade  was  seriously  handicapped  by  the  lack  of  the  compass.  Ships  had 
to  keep  in  sight  of  land  and  hence  the  hazard  of  shipwreck  was  greatly 
increased.  The  misfortunes  of  St.  Paul  on  his  famous  trip  to  Rome  were 
not  unusual  for  a  sea  voyage  in  ancient  times. 

During  the  early  Middle  Ages  the  trade  of  the  Mediterranean  was 
divided  between  the  merchants  of  the  Greek  Empire  in  Constantinople 
and  the  Muslim  traders.  The  Muslims  were  unquestionably  the  leading 
traders.  They  ranged  from  India  and  China  to  northern  Africa  and 
Spain,  carrying  with  them  Muslim  products  and  culture. 

Medieval  trade  in  Christian  Europe  did  not  reach  large  proportions 
until  after  the  Crusades  had  brought  western  Europe  in  contact  with  the 
riches  of  the  East.  Then  the  Italian  cities  dominated  European  foreign 
trade.  They  brought  the  much  desired  products  of  the  Near  East — 
especially  the  spices  needed  to  preserve  meat — to  the  cities  of  western 
Europe,  where  they  were  disposed  of  mainly  during  the  course  of  great 
national  or  local  fairs.  Overland  trade  in  Europe  in  the  Middle  Ages 
operated  under  great  handicaps  as  a  result  of  poor  roads  and  rudimentary 
conveyances.  In  addition,  there  was  the  danger  of  being  ravished  and 
murdered  by  the  robber  barons  that  preyed  on  the  merchant  trains. 
Much  of  the  medieval  trade  in  northern  Europe  was  sea  trade  controlled 
by  great  organizations  of  merchants  like  the  London  Hanse  and  the 
Hanseatic  League,  the  latter  made  up  chiefly  of  cities  in  northern  Ger- 
many. 

Down  to  the  time  of  Columbus  the  trade  of  the  world  was  carried 
either  on  the  land  or  on  rivers  and  inland  seas.  After  the  beginning  of 
the  sixteenth  century,  trade  for  the  first  time  became  oceanic,  as  the 
result  of  the  expansion  of  Europe  and  the  Commercial  Revolution. 

Medieval  travelers  like  Marco  Polo  had  brought  back  stories  of  the 
immense  riches  of  the  Far  East.  Overland  trade  with  the  Far  East  was 
established  across  Asia,  but  the  Italian  cities  were  able  to  monopolize 
most  of  this.  The  northern  and  western  European  countries  were  jealous 
of  this  Italian  monopoly  and  sought  to  break  it  down  by  discovering  a 
sea  route  to  Asia.  This  led  to  the  period  of  exploration  'and  discovery 
and  brought  about  the  Commercial  Revolution  which  created  early 
modern  civilization. 

Between  1500  and  1800  larger  ships  were  built  and  commerce  attained 
a  volume  and  variety  never  before  known  in  the  experience  of  mankind. 
A  great  number  of  new  commodities  were  brought  to  Europe,  and  Euro- 
pean states  found  a  new  market  for  their  commodities  in  oversea  areas 
and  in  the  colonies  established  in  the  New  World.  The  Portuguese,  the 
Spaniards,  the  Dutch,  the  French  and  the  English  participated  in  this 
trade,  but  by  the  close  of  the  eighteenth  century  England  had  become 
the  dominant  trading  and  naval  country  of  the  Old  World. 

Some  elementary  statistics  will  emphasize  how  the  Industrial  Revolu- 
tion and  machine  production  stimulated  the  growth  of  commerce.  The 
total  trade  of  the  world  had  already  increased  sixfold  between  1750  and 


PHASES  OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF    INDUSTRY      101 

1800.    The  following  table  will  reveal  the  degree  to  which  world  trade 
was  further  increased  by  the  first  Industrial  Revolution: 12 

Year  Gross  Commerce  Commerce  Per  Capita 

1800  $1,400,000,000  $2.31 

1820  1,600,000,000  2.13 

1830  1,900,000,000  2.34 

1840  2,700,000,000  2.93 

1850  4,000,000,000  3.76 

1860  7,200,000,000  6.01 

1870  10,000,000,000  8.14 

As  we  have  seen,  the  second  Industrial  Revolution  greatly  increased 
the  output  of  mechanical  industries  through  increased  efficiency  of 
machinery,  the  concentration  of  industry,  the  building  of  giant  factories, 
and  the  greater  economies  of  mass  production.  All  this  is  reflected  in 
the  growth  of  world  trade  from  1880  to  the  first  World  War: 13 

Year  Gross  Commerce  Commerce  Per  Capita 

1880  $14,700,000,000                                                 $10.26 

1890  17,500,000,000                                                   11.80 

1900  20,100,000,000                                                     13.02 

1910  33,600,000,000                                                   20.81 

1913  40,400,000,000                                                   24.47 

After  the  first  World  War  the  more  efficient  production  of  goods  brought 
about  by  the  third  Industrial  Revolution,  the  reconstruction  of  Europe, 
and  the  development  of  the  automobile  industry  resulted  in  a  figure  of 
$69,000,000,000  for  the  total  world  trade  in  1929,  as  against  $40,000,000,- 
000  in  1913.  The  world  depression  after  1929  brought  the  total  world 
trade  down  to  less  than  $24,000,000,000  in  1933  and  1934.  The  concen- 
tration upon  armament  production  rather  than  production  for  export 
helped  to  prevent  world  trade  from  recovering  completely  after  the  worst 
years  of  the  depression.  In  1938  the  total  world  trade  amounted  to 
about  $47,000,000,000.  This  figure  has  been  greatly  reduced  by  the 
second  World  War. 

Though  most  discussions  of  trade  and  commerce  concentrate  upon 
foreign  trade,  the  exchange  of  commodities  within  groups,  whether  tribes 
or  great  national  commercial  states,  has  always  been  greater  than  the 
foreign  trade  between  these  groups. 

Primitive  men  produced  commodities  primarily  for  family  or  com- 
munity use;  but  with  industrial  specialization,  local  trade  began. 
Farmers,  for  example,  exchanged  their  products  for  manufactured  stone 
implements  and  weapons. 

Local  trade  on  a  large  scale  began  in  ancient  Egypt.  At  first,  the 
craftsmen  sold  their  products  directly  to  consumers,  but  by  the  imperial 
period  a  distinct  merchant  class  had  arisen  which  handled  much  of  the 


12Clive  Day,  A  History  of  Commerce,  Longmans,  Green,  1922,  p.  271, 
is  Ibid. 


102      PHASES  OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY 

retail  trade.  Much  the  same  situation  existed  in  Babylonia  and  Assyria. 
A  merchant  class  arose  in  due  time  to  control  local  trade ;  many  of  them 
clustered  about  the  temples.  The  Aramean  merchants  controlled  the 
local  and  foreign  trade  of  the  Syrian  city-states  in  western  Asia. 

In  ancient  Athens  there  was  much  production  by  craftsmen  for  a 
custom  trade,  and  some  retail  trade  was  carried  on  by  merchants  in  stalls 
in  the  public  market-place. 

In  ancient  Rome  there  was  less  retail  trade  than  in  Athens,  since  many 
of  the  commodities  used  by  the  rich  were  made  on  their  estates  by  slaves. 
But  there  was  a  considerable  retail  trade  which,  as  in  Athens,  was  divided 
between  craftsmen  and  merchants. 

In  the  Middle  Ages,  local  trade  centered  in  the  public  markets  situated 
just  outside  of  a  town  or  adjoining  a  monastery"  or  castle.  There  were 
definite  market  days  specified,  usually  once  or  twice  a  week.  Here, 
merchants,  craftsmen,  and  peasants  exchanged  their  wares  and  products. 
Local  trade  on  a  larger  scale  was  usually  carried  on  through  local  or 
regional  fairs  and  commodities  were  gathered  from  many  towns.  During 
much  of  the  Middle  Ages  both  the  town  markets  and  the  fairs  were  con- 
trolled by  the  merchant  gilds,  though  in  the  later  Middle  Ages  a  good 
deal  of  control  of  local  trade  was  taken  over  by  the  craft  gilds. 

When  the  gild  system  disappeared  in  early  modern  times,  local  and 
domestic  trade  fell  chiefly  into  the  hands  of  merchant  capitalists,  who 
conducted  the  putting-out  system,  and  small  shopkeepers  who  handled 
the  retail  trade  through  private  stores.  This  latter  system,  with  notable 
improvements  in  the  construction  and  the  administration  of  stores,  con- 
tinued until  the  beginnings  of  the  second  Industrial  Revolution. 

Towards  the  close  of  the  nineteenth  century  the  increased  production 
brought  about  by  the  second  Industrial  Revolution,  the  growth  of  popula- 
tion, and  the  improvement  of  transportation  facilities  promoted  the 
growth  of  chain  stores.  These  sought  to  profit  by  the  same  large-scale 
operations  which  had  prompted  the  concentration  of  industry  and  the  rise 
of  the  super-factory.  The  first  chain-store  company  was  the  Great 
Atlantic  and  Pacific  Tea  Company,  established  in  1858.  The  next  im- 
portant addition  to  chain  stores  were  the  five-and-ten-cent  stores  opened 
in  the  70's  and  80's.  After  1900  there  was  a  tremendous  growth  of  chain 
stores.  In  1929,  these  chain  stores  had  gross  sales  of  about  $11,000,000,- 
000,  some  22  per  cent  of  all  retail  trade.  These  chain  stores  have  brought 
many  economies  to  consumers.  But  local  jealousy  and  rivalry,  exploited 
by  politicians,  has  led  to  attacks  upon  the  chain  stores,  especially  in  the 
effort  to  tax  them  out  of  existence. 

Mail-order  houses,  especially  Sears,  Roebuck  &  Co.,  and  Montgomery, 
Ward,  were  aided  by  the  creation  of  the  parcel-post  system  in  1913. 
Recently  they  have  created  chain  stores  for  local  trade  in  leading  cities. 
All  in  all,  the  agencies  for  retail  trade  are  better  adapted  to  serving  the 
public  than  are  the  factories,  dominated  by  the  policy  of  curtailing  pro- 
duction to  maintain  high  prices. 


PHASES  OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY      103 


Leading   Forms  of  Control   Over   Industry 

Control  of  Agriculture.  In  early  times,  agriculture  was  controlled 
mainly  by  the  family  and  the  clan.  Production  was  for  local  use. 
Ownership  of  lands  and  tools  was  communal,  family,  or  both. 

In  ancient  Egypt  we  have  the  first  conspicuous  example  of  the  rigorous 
control  of  agriculture  by  the  state.  In  theory,  the  Pharaoh  owned  all 
the  land.  Even  over  lands  granted  to  nobles  the  government  exercised 
complete  control — specifying  crops,  inspecting  production,  and  demand- 
ing taxes  in  kind.  The  officials  of  the  Pharaoh  made  detailed  and  fre- 
quent reports  on  the  state  of  agricultural  operations.  The  government 
also  exercised  strict  supervision  over  the  irrigation  system.  The  estates 
of  the  priests  were  about  the  only  Egyptian  lands  that  were  not  under 
governmental  control. 

The  governments  of  Babyloniq,  and  Assyria  exercised  considerable 
control  especially  over  irrigation  projects,  but  they  never  went  as  far  as 
the  Egyptian  government  in  the  control  of  agriculture.  Great  landlords, 
often  using  many  slaves,  were  very  prominent  in  Babylonian  agriculture, 
while  a  free  peasantry  under  government  protection  dominated  the 
situation  in  Assyria. 

In  Athens,  the  clan  and  the  family  long  controlled  lands  and  agricul- 
ture; but  private  enterprise  grew,  and  eventually  in  Attica  great  land- 
lords built  up  their  estates  at  the  expense  of  impoverished  peasants.  In 
Sparta  the  extensive  state  control  over  agriculture  was  a  phase  of  the 
military  socialism  which  dominated  the  life  of  that  state. 

Ancient  Roman  agriculture  was  at  first  mainly  a  family  affair,  but  the 
state  soon  intervened  in  seizing  and  distributing  conquered  lands.  By 
the  end  of  Republican  days  Roman  agriculture  was  dominated  chiefly 
by  great  landlords  and  their  Latifundia,  cultivated  in  part  by  slave  labor. 
In  the  later  Empire  the  landlords  defied  the  government  and  created  a 
system  of  political  and  economic  anarchy,  which  was  an  important  cause 
of  the  break-up  of  the  Empire  in  the  West.  In  the  Eastern  Roman 
Empire  of  the  early  Middle  Ages  we  find  a  system  of  state  control  over 
agriculture  which,  in  certain  regions,  almost  rivaled  that  of  ancient 
Egypt. 

In  the  feudal-manorial  system  of  western  Europe,  the  lord's  demesne 
was  a  private  agricultural  enterprise,  while  the  lands  of  the  serfs  were 
cultivated  under  a  complex  system  of  communal  control. 

In  England,  after  the  manorial  system  broke  up,  we  have  the  period  of 
the  Squirearchy,  in  which  the  medium-sized  farms  of  the  country  squires 
were  cultivated  mainly  by  hired  peasant  workers.  There  were  also  some 
free  small  farmers.  After  the  middle  of  the  eighteenth  century,  English 
agriculture  came  more  and  more  under  the  control  of  great  landlords, 
who  pushed  out  the  squires  and  peasants  and  created  vast  estates  worked 
by  hired  peasants.  In  France,  the  estates  remained  in  the  hands  of 


104      PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION  OF   INDUSTRY 

great  landlords  until  the  French  Revolution.  The  agrarian  and  legal 
reforms  of  that  period  converted  France  into  a  country  of  small  farmers. 
In  Prussia,  the  Junker  class  carved  out  great  estates  and  held  them  down 
to  the  present  time.  In  eastern  Europe,  a  quasi-feudal  system  of  great 
estates  dominated  the  scene  until  the  agrarian  reforms  after  the  first 
World  War.  In  Hungary,  the  feudal  landlords  were  able  to  escape  even 
these  reforms  and  continued  to  hold  great  estates. 

Since  the  first  World  War,  Soviet  Russia  has  introduced  the  state 
ownership  of  land  and  complete  state  control  of  farming.  In  Fascist 
countries,  the  state  has  controlled  agriculture,  though  formal  private 
ownership  of  land  still  continues. 

In  the  United  States,  the  system  of  private  control  of  agriculture  and 
small  farming  has  prevailed  from  colonial  times.  But  the  farm  crisis 
since  the  first  World  War  compelled  the  government  to  intervene  more 
and  more  in  behalf  of  the  stricken  farmers. 

The  Control  of  Industry.  In  primitive  times,  manufacturing  in- 
dustries were  controlled  mainly  by  the  family.  Women,  as  Otis  T.  Mason 
has  pointed  out,  carried  on  many  of  the  manufacturing  activities,  leaving 
the  men  free  for  hunting  and  fighting. 

The  craftsmen  in  ancient  Egypt  belonged  chiefly  to  the  free  middle 
class.  They  paid  a  tax  to  the  Pharaoh  or  to  the  nobles  for  the  privilege 
of  carrying  on  their  industrial  activities.  There  was  no  such  systematized 
gild  control  over  Egyptian  craftsmen  as  we  find  in  the  Middle  Ages  in 
Europe. 

In  Babylonia  and  Assyria,  control  of  industry  was  varied  and  com- 
plicated. The  free  craftsmen  in  the  cities  were  not  unlike  those  in  Egypt. 
There  was  also  slave  labor,  especially  in  shops  on  the  estates  of  the 
priests.  Then  there  were  a  large  number  of  slave  workers  employed  by 
the  kings,  the  great  nobles,  and  in  the  temple  workshops. 

In  Athens,  industrial  control  was  also  complex.  There  were  some  free 
craftsmen  of  the  citizen  class,  but  most  Greek  craftsmen  were  free 
foreigners  or  slaves.  The  craftsmen  worked  at  home  or  in  small  estab- 
lishments, and  there  was  a  fairly  elaborate  system  of  organization  and 
specialization.  The  apprenticeship  system  was  well  developed.  The 
craftsmen  maintained  their  professional  independence  even  when  in  state 
employ. 

In  early  Rome  most  craftsmen  were  free,  and  were  dominated  by  the 
family  system.  In  late  Republican  days  most  industrial  production 
was  carried  on  by  freedmen  and  slaves.  The  large  proportion  of  slave 
labor  in  industry  tended  to  drive  free  craftsmen  out  of  industry.  Many 
of  them  joined  with  the  dispossessed  peasants  to  create  the  city  mob.  that 
was  supported  under  the  system  of  bread-and-circuses.  The  status  and 
operations  of  such  free  craftsmen  as  existed  in  the  Roman  Republic  and 
Empire  did  not  differ  widely  from  the  situation  in  Athens. 

In  the  Middle  Ages,  as  we  have  seen,  industrial  operations  were  con- 
trolled by  the  craft  gilds,  where  we  find  masters,  apprentices,  and  journey- 
men. 


PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY      105 

In  addition  to  the  generally  thorough  technical  preparation  that  the 
apprentice  received,  he  was  also  given  a  moral  education,  apprenticeship 
being  designed  to  make  him  socially  useful  as  well  as  industrially  skilled. 

The  period  of  apprenticeship  ranged  from  three  to  as  high  as  twelve 
years,  depending  on  the  difficulty  of  the  trade.  A  seven-year  period  was 
most  common  in  England.  In  some  crafts  apprentices  received  regular 
wages  towards  the  close  of  their  service.  Runaway  apprentices  were 
returned  to  their  masters  and  punished.  If  the  offense  became  habitual, 
the  apprentice  was  debarred  from  the  craft  for  all  time.  On  the  other 
hand,  masters  guilty  of  harsh  or  ill  treatment  of  their  apprentices  might 
be  punished  by  the  gild.  In  England,  one  to  four  apprentices  to  a  master 
seems  to  have  been  usual.  The  number  of  apprentices  was  further  re- 
stricted, especially  in  the  later  days  of  the  gild,  by  the  desire  of  both 
masters  and  journeymen  to  avoid  competition. 

When  his  term  of  service  was  over,  the  apprentice  became  a  journey- 
man, and  was  employed  by  a  master  workman  at  specified  wages.  The 
journeyman  was  a  candidate  for  mastership.  At  an  earlier  period  in 
France,  the  apprentice,  having  completed  his  training  and  proved  his 
fitness,  was  eligible  to  mastership  if  he  possessed  the  necessary  capital. 
In  time,  several  years'  employment  as  a  journeyman  became  customary 
before  a  craftsman  could  become  a  master.  In  England,  as  a  rule,  the 
journeyman  set  himself  up  as  a  master  when  he  was  at  least  twenty-three 
years  old,  possessed  sufficient  capital,  and  had  given  the  gild  officials  some 
proof  of  his  skill  as  a  workman. 

Following  the  gild  system  came  what  we  call  the  domestic  or  putting- 
out  system,  which  had  first  developed  in  Italy  in  the  Middle  Ages  and 
had  spread  to  the  Low  Countries  in  early  modern  times.  It  was  intro- 
duced into  England  in  the  fifteenth  century,  after  the  gild  system  had 
lost  its  grip.  It  was  at  first  limited  mainly  to  the  woolen  and  worsted 
industries.  Following  are  some  differences  between  the  putting-out 
system  and  the  gild  system. 

Instead  of  collecting  in  the  household  of  a  gild  master,  the  workers 
under  this  system  lived  in  their  own  dwellings  in  the  towns  or  in  the 
adjacent  countryside.  The  person  who  controlled  all  phases  of  this 
manufacturing  process  was  known  as  a  merchant-capitalist,  or  more 
N technically,  in  the  woolen  industry,  as  a  clothier.  He  furnished  the 
original  capital  with  which  to  establish  the  business  and  sent  out  the  raw 
materials  to  be  worked  up  by  the  laborers  at  a  rate  agreed  upon.  The 
representatives  of  the  merchant-capitalist  could  then  go  to  the  homes  of 
the  contract  workers,  leave  more  raw  material,  and  collect  the  finished 
work.  This  merchant-capitalist  was  not  merely  superimposed  upon  a 
single  craft — his  group  was  the  organizing  center  of  the  whole  grotip  of 
crafts  in  the  industry.  For  example,  the  clothier  bought  raw  wool  in 
the  market  or  from  the  raisers,  sent  it  in  turn  to  spinners,  weavers,  fullers, 
and  dyers,  and  finally  marketed  the  finished  product. 

The  most  important  differences  between  the  gild  and  the  putting-out 
systems  were  those  which  helped  to  develop  a  capitalistic  tendency  on 


106      PHASES  OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY 

the  part  of  the  merchant,  the  dominant  figure  in  the  process.  Inciden- 
tally, in  some  ways  the  workers,  who  owned  their  own  tools,  were  for  a 
while  more  independent  than  under  the  old  gild  order.  Later,  however, 
the  workers  lost  their  independence  to  the  merchants,  who  often  supplied 
them  with  both  materials  and  tools.  In  this  phase,  some  of  the  worst 
evils,  later  associated  with  modern  industrialism,  put  in  appearance: 
woman  and  child  labor,  low  wages,  and  the  "sweating"  of  the  workers. 

Some  disadvantages  of  the  putting-out  system  were  the  impossibility 
of  continuous  supervision,  the  tendency  of  workers  to  get  drunk  on  pay- 
day and  stay  intoxicated  until  their  wages  were  used  up,  dishonesty  on 
the  part  of  workmen,  and  waste  of  time  in  distributing  raw  materials  and 
picking  up  finished  products. 

These  difficulties  led  to  the  appearance  of  some  large  central  shops- 
many  writers  call  them  factories — before  the  modern  mechanical  tech- 
nique had  been  introduced.  Here  men  were  kept  at  work  by  foremen 
who  were  representatives  of  the  merchant-capitalists.  From  the  stand- 
point of  personnel  organization,  this  arrangement  had  all  the  advantages 
to  the  employer  of  the  factory  system,  as  we  know  it,  except  one — the  cost 
of  the- tools  was  still  so  slight  that  the  craftsman  in  most  trades  still  had 
som.6  chance  to  work  for  himself  if  he  thought  the  employers  were  unjust. 

'If  it  had  become  general,  there  is  every  reason  to  suppose  that  the 
central  shop  would  have  exhibited  most  of  the  defects  and  inconveniences 
of  the  factory  system,  such  as  crowded  living  conditions  and  the  central- 
ization of  control  in  the  hands  of  a  few  persons.  Its  slow  growth  and  its 
restriction  to  a  few  industries  suggest  that  the  disadvantages  of  central- 
ization before  machines  came  in  must  have  just  about  balanced  the 
advantages  until  the  Industrial  Revolution  threw  an  overwhelming  weight 
into  the  scales  on  the  side  of  the  factory. 

The  impressive  so-called  factory  system  grew  up  out  of  the  Industrial 
Revolution  as  an  inevitable  aftermath  of  mechanical  production.  Many 
regard  the  factory  system  as  identical  with  the  machine  technique. 
However,  the  machine  technique  comprehends  our  modern  method  of 
manufacturing  and  the  like,  while  the  factory  system  represents  the 
method  of  organizing  and  applying  labor  to  productive  processes.  Fac- 
tories of  a  crude  sort — central  shops — not  only  could  but  did  exist  long 
before  machinery  was  provided ;  but  it  was  difficult,  if  not  impossible,  to 
introduce  the  new  machinery  without  setting  up  the  factory  system.  It 
was  impractical  to  introduce  machinery  into  the  homes  of  workers  be- 
cause of  the  lack  of  space  and  of  power. 

Improvements  in  transportation  so  enlarged  the  manufacturers'  possi- 
ble market  that  they  could  sell  a  great  number  of  articles  exactly  alike. 
Each  process  could  now  be  broken  up  into  many  routine  operations,  per- 
formed chiefly  by  machines  and  merely  supervised  by  the  workers. 
Before  the  development  of  electrical  appliances,  power  to  run  machines 
was  transmitted  directly  by  shafts  and  belts,  which  meant  that  it  must 
be  used  fairly  close  to  its  source.  Other  elements  determining  the  loca- 
tion of  factories  were  the  existence  of  natural  resources  (such  as  coal, 


PHASES   OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF    INDUSTRY      107 

iron  ore,  and  petroleum),  ease  of  transportation,  and  markets.  All  these 
considerations  made  the  factory  system  inevitable. 

The  most  striking  characteristic  of  the  factory  system  is  that  it  brought 
together  in  one  establishment  a  larger  number  of  workmen  than  had  ever 
been  assembled  in  any  earlier  type  of  industrial  operation.  While  a 
factory  may  employ  only  a  score  or  so  of  workmen,  the  characteristic 
modern  factory  has  hundreds  or  thousands  of  employees. 

The  factory  system  provided  a  greater  opportunity  for  the  close 
control,  supervision,  and  discipline  of  labor.  The  modern  factory  worker 
is  normally  more  at  the  mercy  of  the  employing  class  than  was  the  gild 
journeyman,  who  might  himself  become  a  master,  since  the  tools  he  used 
were  relatively  inexpensive.  Discipline  in  the  factory  system  is  more 
rigorous  than  in  the  putting-out  system,  under  which  the  capitalist  or 
his  representative  visited  the  employees  only  to  distribute  raw  materials 
or  to  collect  finished  products.  Before  the  development  of  labor  organ- 
izations, factory  workers  were  almost  entirely  dependent  upon  the  will  of 
their  employers,  and  their  daily  presence  in  the  plant  was  made  obligatory 
upon  penalty  of  discharge. 

The  factory  rendered  such  discipline  and  regimentation  absolutely  in- 
evitable. A  loose  supervision  based  upon  personal  contacts  might  have 
been  sufficient  for  the  small  gild  establishment;  but,  with  hundreds  of 
factory  workers  under  one  roof,  it  became  necessary  to  issue  certain  rules 
defining  the  hours  of  labor,  the  assignment  of  individual  tasks,  the  atti- 
tude of  the  employee  in  his  relations  with  the  employer,  details  of  conduct 
within  the  factory,  and  even  the  matter  of  orderly  entering  and  leaving. 
So  elaborate  are  some  of  these  codes  of  factory  discipline  that  their  com- 
plete and  literal  execution  would  paralyze  the  operation  of  the  plant. 

The  first  adequate  code  of  factory  discipline  was  worked  out  by  Sir 
Richard  Arkwright  in  England  after  1770.  Arkwright's  own  factories 
proved  so  successful  and  his  code  seemed  so  adequate  that  it  was  widely 
adopted  in  Europe  and  was  the  parent  of  the  later  and  more  perfect  ones 
of  the  nineteenth  century. 

Lately,  these  conventional  codes  of  factory  discipline  have  been  criti- 
cized for  sacrificing  to  order  and  regimentation  most  of  the  normal 
human  impulses  toward  creative  effort — or,  for  that  matter,  toward  any 
effort  whatever  beyond  that  compulsory  for  holding  a  job.  One  result 
was  the  development  of  the  modern  sciences  of  personnel  management 
and  industrial  psychology  and  of  attempts  to  humanize  the  factory. 

The  machine  technique  itself  tends  to  mechanize  the  workman,  who 
often  carries  on  a  narrowly  specialized  routine  operation  throughout  most 
or  all  of  his  active  life.  In  this  way,  all  those  advantages  of  special 
training  and  the  repetition  of  familiar  simple  motions  may  be  easily 
realized.  Ad^m  Smith  pointed  out  long  ago  the  great  advantages  in- 
herent in  this  subdivision  of  industrial  processes,  but  he  could  not  foresee 
the  elaborate  and  intricate  development  of  the  division  of  labor  in  the 
modern  factory. 

The  gains  in  productivity  are  partly  offset  by  the  indolence  and  the 


108      PHASES  OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY 

indifference  to  craftsmanship  growing  out  of  the  highly  regimented  factory 
system.  The  machine  technique  itself  is  charged  with  producing  un- 
necessary fatigue  and  various  occupational  nervous  disorders.  Industrial 
and  abnormal  psychology  has  been  trying  to  get  at  the  exact  causes  of 
such  human  wastage,  in  order  to  suggest  better  means  of  adapting  our 
manufacturing  processes  to  the  human  beings  by  and  for  whom  they 
are  carried  on. 

A  striking  factory  development  was  the  speed-up  system,  first  introduced 
by  Henry  Ford.  It  rests  upon  two  major  mechanical  principles:  (1)  that 
of  interchangeable  parts,  first  devised  by  Eli  Whitney  in  the  manufacture 
of  muskets,  and  (2)  the  endless  conveyor  belt,  which  brings  around  the 
parts  to  be  assembled.  This  was  first  used  by  the  Chicago  meat  packers, 
who  used  an  overhead  trolley  to  bring  carcasses  of  beef  along  the  line  of 
butchers.  The  results  were  astonishing.  In  1914,  the  Ford  plants  were 
turning  out  about  700  cars  daily;  on  November  4,  1924,  7,500  cars  were 
turned  out  in  a  single  day.  The  nature  of  work  under  the  speed-up 
system  has  thus  been  described  by  a  workman  in  the  Ford  plant: 

As  a  result  of  the  conveyor  system,  upon  which  the  whole  plant  is  operated, 
the  men  have  no  time  to  talk  to  each  other;  have  no  rest  except  for  fifteen  or 
twenty  minutes  at  lunch  time;  and  can  go  to  the  toilet  only  when  substitutes  are 
ready  to  relieve  them  at  the  "belt."  One  operation  upon  which  I  worked  re- 
quired that  I  be  on  the  job,  ready  to  work,  just  as  soon  as  the  preceding  shift 
went  off;  work  up  to  the  exact  minute  for  lunch  time;  take  a  couple  of  minutes 
to  clean  up  and  get  my  lunch  kit  and  be  back  thirteen  minutes  later  to  work. 
There  was  never  a  moment  of  leisure  or  opportunity  to  turn  my  head.  .  .  ,14 

Under  such  conditions  the  average  man  risks  a  nervous  or  physical 
breakdown,  or  both,  after  two  or  three  years  of  steady  employment.  But 
eager  and  hungry  men  are  standing  in  line  to  take  the  place  of  the 
discarded  human  wreckage. 

Nevertheless  the  speed-up  process  has  a  great  economic  appeal.  Ford 
made  the  country  "mass-production  conscious,"  and  mass  production 
spread  from  his  plant  in  Dearborn  to  other  industries  throughout  the 
country. 

t  A  more  humane  method  of  realizing  industrial  efficiency  is  that  of 
scientific  management  in  our  leading  factories.  Its  foremost  figures 
were  three  American  engineers  and  industrialists:  Frederick  W.  Taylor 
(1856-1915),  Henry  L.  Gantt  (1861-1919),  and  Frank  B.  Gilbreth 
(1868-1924).  The  moving  spirit  was  Taylor.  A  Taylor  Society  has 
been  formed  in  his  honor,  devoted  to  the  principles  of  scientific  factory 
management.  The  movement  centers  around  the  elimination  of  waste 
and  the  introduction  of  more  efficient  standards  of  production,  based 
upon  a  careful  study  of  factory  methods  and  improvements  in  technology. 

Both  mass  production  and  scientific  management  have  been  embodied 
in  the  rationalization  of  industry  adopted  by  Germany  since  the  first 
World  War. 


i*New  Republic,  March  16,  1932,  p.  117. 


PHASES  OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY      109 

In  Fascist  countries,  the  state  controls  industry,  though  ownership 
remains  mainly  in  private  hands.  In  Soviet  Russia,  the  state  not  only 
controls  industry  but  owns  and  operates  the  means  of  producing  and 
distributing  goods.  Russia  has  introduced  a  speed-up  system  divorced 
from  the  profit  system.  The  first  such  experiment,  started  in  1928,  was 
the  so-called  Shock-Brigade  movement,  in  which  workers  banded  together 
and  declared  their  determination  to  keep  machines  working  constantly 
at  the  highest  degree  of  efficiency.  More  recently  the  Stakhanov  move- 
ment offered  rewards  to  workers  who  turned  out  the  greatest  possible 
volume  of  products.  It  took  its  name  from  a  miner,  Alexey  Stakhanov, 
who,  in  1935,  increased  coal  production  in  his  gang  five-fold.  This  Rus- 
sian speed-up  system  rests  upon  an  appeal  to  the  competitive  spirit  of 
man  and  to  devotion  to  the  country  and  its  policies. 

Even  in  capitalistic  and  democratic  countries,  depression,  preparedness, 
and  war  have  brought  about  increasing  trends  toward  state  control  of 
industry.  It  would  seem  that  we  are  moving  toward  a  system  in  which 
the  dominant  type  of  industrial  control  will  be  the  factory  under  state 
management  and  perhaps  under  state  ownership. 

The  most  recent  and  promising  proposal  for  industrial  control  is  what 
has  been  called  Technocracy,  under  which  economic  life  would  be  directed 
by  industrial  engineers  who  would  produce  for  human  service  rather  than 
for  private  profit.  Those  who  favor  this  plan  tell  us  that  Technocracy 
will  prove  far  more  efficient  than  the  speed-up  system  and  will  be  much 
more  humane  than  the  best  managed  factory  today.  They  assert,  for 
example,  that  a  high  standard  of  living  can  be  maintained  with  our  pres- 
ent industrial  plant  without  working  more  than  ten  to  fifteen  hours  a 
week. 

The  Control  of  Trade.  In  primitive  times,  such  trade  as  existed  was 
controlled  by  the  community  and  the  family.  It  was  mainly  an  exchange 
of  goods  resulting  from  the  specialization  of  industry  in  the  local  com- 
munity. 

In  Egypt,  local  trade  was  controlled  mainly  by  the  craftsmen  and 
merchants,  who  purchased  concessions  from  the  government.  Foreign 
trade  was  partially  in  the  hands  of  merchants  and  their  caravans  and 
partly  in  the  hands  of  commercial  expeditions  sent  out  by  the  Pharaoh. 
Even  private  foreign  trade  was  carefully  regulated  by  the  government, 
and  merchants  had  to  surrender  part  of  their  profits  to  the  crown.  In 
return,  the  government  protected  trade  routes  on  land  and  sea.  The 
situation  was  not  greatly  different  in  Mesopotamia,  though  the  govern- 
ment did  not  regulate  and  exploit  foreign  trade  quite  so  much  as 
did  the  Egyptian  government.  But  it  did  impose  restrictions,  penal- 
ize dishonesty,  and  levy  tribute.  In  return,  it  also  policed  the  trade 
routes. 

In  Athens,  local  trade  was  controlled  by  free  merchants  and  craftsmen. 
The  state  intervened  to  regulate  market  conditions,  to  inspect  weights 
and  measures,  and  to  fix  the  prices  of  the  necessities  of  life.  Foreign 
trade  was  chiefly  in  private  hands,  though  there  was  considerable  state 


110      PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION   OF   INDUSTRY 

regulation  of  the  grain  trade  in  order  to  secure  an  adequate  supply  of 
wheat. 

Domestic  trade  in  Rome  was  mainly  in  the  hands  of  free  merchants. 
The  foreign  trade  was  more  thoroughly  regulated  and  controlled  by  the 
state  in  order  to  secure  an  adequate  grain  supply  and  keep  the  rabble 
contented.  Foreign  trade  in  Greece  and  Rome  was  generally  free  and 
private,  as  compared  with  the  degree  of  state  regulation  in  the  ancient 
Orient. 

In  the  Middle  Ages,  both  domestic  and  foreign  trade  were  chiefly  con- 
trolled by  the  merchant  gilds,  which  essentially  governed  the  medieval 
towns.  They  dominated  the  fairs  and  imposed  penalties  for  dishonest 
practices.  Since  industry  was  mainly  town  industry  and  since  the 
merchant  gilds  usually  dominated  town  government,  medieval  control 
of  commerce  was  essentially  a  system  of  government  regulation,  though 
it  was  by  the  local  rather  than  the  central  government.  Foreign  trade 
in  the  later  Middle  Ages  was  also  controlled  by  great  organizations  of 
merchants,  the  so-called  Hanses,  such  as  the  Hanse  of  London,  and  the 
Hanseatic  League. 

When  the  gild  system  broke  down  and  commerce  expanded  as  the  result 
of  the  Commercial  Revolution,  there  developed  an  extreme  form  of  gov- 
ernment control  over  trade,  generally  known  as  Mercantilism  Under 
this  system  the  government  attempted  complete  regulation  of  foreign 
trade,  especially  the  foreign  trade  of  colonies,  in  order  to  increase  the 
wealth  and  the  supply  of  precious  metals  in  the  mother  country.  It  was 
a  commercial  form  of  state  capitalism. 

After  the  Industrial  Revolution,  the  manufacturers  and  merchants  were 
for  a  time  able  to  reduce  the  degree  of  governmental  interference  and  to 
encourage  free  trade.  But,  following  1870,  the  system  of  protective 
tariffs,  which  constitute  the  modern  form  of  governmental  control  of 
trade,  became  ever  more  prevalent.  After  the  first  World  War  the  pro- 
tective system  became  most  extensive  and  rigid. 

In  totalitarian  states  the  government  controls  domestic  and  foreign 
trade,  though  it  may  allow  certain  freedom  in  domestic  trade.  The 
Nazis  in  Germany  especially  concentrated  on  the  control  of  foreign  trade, 
and*  worked  out  an  ingenious  system  of  barter  in  foreign  commerce.  Even 
where  money  was  used,  a  special  monetary  system  was  employed  in 
foreign  trade. 

In  Soviet  Russia,  the  state  assumed  control  over  both  domestic  and 
foreign  trade.  In  country  districts  the  cooperatives  were  allowed  to 
participate  in  retail  trade,  but  they  were  checked  in  the  cities ;  there  the 
state  stores  dominate.  The  foreign  trade  of  Russia  is  a  governmental 
monopoly. 

The  tense  conditions  produced  by  rearmament  and  the  second  World 
War  brought  about  an  increasing  degree  of  state  control  over  trade  which 
extended  even  to  the  democratic  states  now  engaged  in  the  second  World 
War.  We  seem  to  be  headed  for  a  revival  of  #  new  Merc.antiUsna — really 


PHASES  OF  THE  EVOLUTION  OF   INDUSTRY      111 

state  capitalism  and  social  planning — more  sweeping  and  far-reaching 
than  anything  known  in  the  seventeenth  and  eighteenth  centuries. 

The  Motives  of  Industrial   Effort 

So  habitual  and  firmly  entrenched  is  the  profit  system  that  we  usually 
take  it  for  granted  that  man  has  always  produced  mainly  for  private 
profit.  In  fact,  however,  man  has  made  goods  for  profit  during  only 
about  one  per  cent  of  the  time  he  has  been  on  the  planet.  Down  to  the 
dawn  of  history  among  the  Egyptians  and  Babylonians,  productive  effort 
was  devoted  exclusively  to  providing  materials  for  the  direct  and  imme- 
diate use  of  the  family  or  community.  Tli^ere  was  little  or  no  sale  of 
goods  for  gain. 

The  profit  system  grew  slowly  and  did  not  get  under  full  headway  until 
modern  times.  It  had  little  standing  in  the  civic  ethics  of  Greece  and 
Rome  and  even  less  in  the  religious  ethics  of  the  medieval  Catholic 
Church.  It  was  first  given  prestige  and  respectability  by  commercial 
capitalism  and  Protestant  ethics  in  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  cen- 
turies. Protestant  preachers  used  such  texts  as  "Seest  thou  a  man 
diligent  in  business?  He  shall  stand  before  kings" — later  the  favorite 
biblical  quotation  of  John  D.  Rockefeller. 

After  1600,  the  opportunity  to  make  profits  out  of  industry  offered  a 
great  impulse  to  industrial  effort.  Since  the  corporate  revolution  of  the 
present  century,  however,  this  has  been  less  true.  Those  who  control 
and  manage  industry  today  get  only  a  small  part  of  the  profits  of  in- 
dustry. Hence  they  are  encouraged  to  exploit  industry  rather  than 
to  run  it  efficiently.15 

It  is  also  true  that  the  profit  system  greatly  handicaps  productive 
enterprise,  because  it  is  closely  linked  up  with  an  economy  of  scarcity. 
It  is  thought  that  only  by  keeping  goods  scarce  can  prices  be  kept  high 
and  profits  made.  Hence,  there  is  an  effort  through  monopoly  and  other 
"bottle-necks  of  business"  to  restrict  production  if  it  threatens  to  reduce 
prices. 

Another  motive  of  industry  which  has  been  significant  since  early  times 
has  been  the  "instinct  of  workmanship,"  more  accurately  described  as 
pride  in  excellent  workmanship.  We  find  this  among  primitive  peoples 
who  exhibit  special  gratification  in  a  fine  piece  of  work.  Greek  work- 
men, especially  on  public  enterprises,  took  a  special  pride  in  excellence 
of  workmanship.  In  the  medieval  craft  gilds,  pride  of  workmanship  was 
a  powerful  force.  Nearly  a  century  ago,  John  Ruskin  and  William 
Morris  made  an  effort  to  revive  the  pride  of  workmanship  within  the 
framework  of  industrial  society. 

It  must  be  admitted  that  pride  of  workmanship  today  is  limited  mainly 
to  the  fine  arts.  Employers  are  chiefly  concerned  with  security  specula- 


is  See  below,  pp.  127  ff. 


112      PHASES   OF  THE   EVOLUTION   OF    INDUSTRY 

tion,  clipping  coupons,  and  cashing  dividend  checks,  while  the  workers 
have  their  eyes  mainly  on  the  pay  envelope. 

With  the  current  breakdown  of  private  capitalism  and  the  profit  system 
and  the  evident  inadequacies  of  the  scarcity  economy,  there  is  a  trend 
towards  state  control  of  industry  for  the  purpose  of  direct  human  use  and 
human  service  instead  of  private  profit.  To  get  the  populace  to  coop- 
erate, much  stress  is  laid  on  the  possibility  of  securing  plenty  and  a  high 
standard  of  living  with  a  minimum  of  work.  An  appeal  is  also  made  to 
pride  in  workmanship.  But  thus  far  it  has  been  found  necessary  also 
to  appeal  to  less  noble  motives,  such  as  the  competitive  spirit  and  special 
rewards  for  unusual  productive  effort. 

Whatever  the  possible  adequacy  of  industrial  motives  other  than  the 
profit  system,  it  is  evident  that  the  world  is  going  to  be  in  a  difficult 
economic  situation  unless  additional  incentives  can  be  found.  The  eco- 
nomic order  which  gave  birth  to  and  nourished  the  profit  system  is  now, 
however  much  we  may  regret  it,  on  its  last  legs.  Other  industrial  motives 
must  be  found  if  we  are  to  create  a  permanent  and  better  economic 
order.16 


10  Cf.  J.  A.  Hobson,  Incentives  in  the  New  Industrial  Order,  Seltzer,  1925;  and 
H.  F.  Ward,  In  Place  of  Profit,  Scribner,  1933. 


CHAPTER  V 
Capitalism  and  the  Economic  Crisis 

The  Fundamental   Nature  of  Economic   Problems 

IT  DOES  not  require  any  Marxian  dogmatism  or  any  fanatical  adher- 
ence to  the  economic  interpretation  of  history  to  lead  one  to  the  conclusion 
that  the  crisis  in  contemporary  capitalism  and  the  economic  problems 
related  thereunto  are  fundamental  to  most  of  the  other  social  problems 
of  the  twentieth  century.  The  remaining  ones  grow  out  of  the  economic 
situation,  or  their  solution  must  be  held  up  until  the  economic  crisis  is 
satisfactorily  resolved.  We  can  easily  illustrate  this  by  a  few  ready 
examples. 

It  is  obvious  that  the  question  of  poverty  is  closely  linked  to  our  eco- 
nomic system.  There  had  been  poverty  in  earlier  economic  systems,  but 
its  causes  and  nature  were  quite  different  from  poverty  in  the  twentieth 
century  among  civilized  peoples.  In  earlier  ages,  poverty  was  due  pri- 
marily'to  the  fact  that  there  were  not  goods,  wealth,  and  food  enough 
to  provide  high  living  standards  for  the  whole  population.  Today,  we 
would  be  able  to  produce  with  great  ease  all  the  goods  and  food  required 
for  a  Utopian  living  standard.  But  the  profit  system,  as  administered, 
greatly  reduces  potential  productive  capacity.  We  could  probably  pro- 
duce more  than  twice  as  many  goods  as  we  do  with  the  existing  national 
industrial  plant  if  we  operated  it  in  terms  of  engineering  efficiency.  Even 
more,  we  do  not  seem  able  to  put  enough  income  in  the  hands  of  the  mass 
of  purchasers  to  enable  them  to  buy  even  the  restricted  product  which 
we  turn  out.  We  could  produce  all  the  food  required  for  a  very  high 
standard  of  living  on  one  fifth  of  the  land  now  under  cultivation,  and 
with  one  fifth  of  the  personnel  now  engaged  in  agriculture.  We  are  tech- 
nologically set  up  to  realize  Utopia  almost  overnight.  But  our  economic 
system  prevents  us  from  taking  full  advantage  of  labor-saving  machinery 
in  the  interests  of  social  well-being.  Rather,  the  most  important  tech- 
nological advances  today  threaten  the  very  existence  of  our  economic 
order  by  creating  an  ever  larger  volume  of  unemployment,  which  private 
capitalism  either  cannot  or  will  not  assume  the  responsibility  for  making 
a  realistic  effort  to  avert.  Our  overcrowded  cities,  the  massing  of  popu- 
lation, and  the  defective  housing  of  most  urban  dwellers  are  tied  up 
directly  with  the  system  of  private  profit  in  real  estate  activities.  If  we 

113 


114       CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

take  steps  to  reorganize  and  distribute  urban  populations  in  suburban 
areas,  this  will  be  due  primarily  to  the  fact  that  business  has  discovered 
the  economic  advantages  of  smaller  urban  units  in  an  age  of  electrical 
power. 

Our  population  problems  are  serious  mainly  because  of  the  economic 
factors  directly  involved.  Our  present  productive  capacity,  if  used 
efficiently,  would  enable  us  to  rise  superior  to  population  fluctuations. 
We  are  today  able  to  take  care  of  any  prospective  population,  so  far  as 
the  necessities  of  life  are  concerned.  Under  a  system  of  production  for 
use,  we  would  not  have  to  worry  about  any  decrease  in  the  number  of 
customers  in  the  case  of  a  rapidly  falling  birth-rate.  We  could  simply 
produce  for  the  needs  of  those  who  exist  at  any  given  time.  The  fact 
that  population  is  increasing  most  rapidly  among  poverty-stricken  farm- 
ers and  the  working  classes  in  the  cities  is  a  serious  matter  mainly  because 
the  income  of  these  groups  does  not  enable  them  to  provide  adequate 
living  standards  and  suitable  education  for  their  children.  Crime  and 
vice  are  caused  to  a  very  considerable  extent  by  poverty.  The  organized 
criminality  of  our  day  is  motivated  mainly  by  greed,  and  has  imitated 
in  an  exaggerated  degree  the  ideals  and  practices  of  big  business  and 
finance. 

The  traditional  family  is  breaking  down  chiefly  because  of  influences 
contributed  by  the  rise  of  modern  industrialism.  A  major  reason  for 
family  friction  and  disintegration  is  inadequate  income  and  the  worries 
created  by  a  sense  of  economic  insecurity.  Race  problems  and  the  Negro 
question  in  this  country  are  as  much  economic  in  character  as  physiologi- 
cal and  psychological.  Our  contemporary  Negro  problem  rests  on  an 
economic  basis,  though  a  somewhat  different  one,  just  as  the  Negro  prob- 
lem did  in  the  era  of  slavery.  The  impending  collapse  of  democracy 
arises  primarily  out  of  the  fact  that  we  attempt  to  handle  our  complicated 
economic  problems  through  politics  and  the  party  system  rather  than 
by  means  of  engineering  science.  We  have  carried  over  into  our  tech- 
nological era  the  political  methods  and  ideals  which  prevailed  in  a  rural 
and  handicraft  epoch.  Our  rural  or  farm  problem  is  chiefly  a  manifesta- 
tion of  the  paradoxes  created  by  the  effort  to  control  an  economy  of 
abundance  by  notions  which  have  come  down  from  the  era  of  scarcity. 
The  agrarian  policies  of  Diocletian  hang  over  in  an  age  of  combines  and 
gasoline  tractors. 

The  agencies  of  communication  are  thoroughly  contaminated  by  vari- 
ous manifestations  of  our  economic  problems.  The  press  and  the  radio 
are  devoted,  to  a  large  extent,  to  propaganda  in  favor  of  contemporary 
business  and  financial  ideals.  But  such  radical  journals  and  radio  sta- 
tions as  exist  show  an  equal  bias  in  their  very  vigorous  opposition 
to  the  existing  economic  order.  Objective  opinion  is  difficult  to  secure 
and  ever  harder  to  express  in  effective  fashion.  The  greater  part  of 
education  reflects  the  ideals  of  leisure-class  psychology.  It  is  more 
concerned  with  transmitting  the  reputable  economic  tradition  than  with 
discovering  the  realities  of  present-day  life  and  using  these  as  the  basis 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS        115 

of  preparation  for  a  new  and  better  social  system.  The  great  interna- 
tional crisis  of  our  age  directly  reflects  the  underlying  economic  crisis. 
In  countries  where  capitalism  is  breaking  down,  the  economic  debacle  is 
handled  by  a  dictatorship  of  the  Right  or  the  Left.  The  former  we  call 
Fascism  and  the  latter  expresses  itself  today  mainly  in  the  form  of 
Russian  "communism."  One  works  towards  state  capitalism  and  the 
other  follows  the  method  of  state  socialism,  but  both  repudiate  private 
business  enterprise  as  we  know  it  in  the  United  States. 

While  modern  wars  are  something  more  than  a  simple  struggle  between 
the  "haves"  and  the  "have-nots,"  no  realistic  student  of  the  international 
scene  in  our  day  doubts  the  fundamental  character  of  the  economic  fac- 
tors underlying  the  international  line-up  and  the  second  World  War. 
We  could  go  on  indefinitely  with  such  illustrations,  but  the  foregoing 
summary  is  sufficient  to  demonstrate  the  validity  of  our  thesis  that  eco- 
nomic problems  are  basic  to  most  other  social  problems  in  the  second 
third  of  the  twentieth  century. 

The   Historical    Background  and  the   Rise  of  Capitalism 

While  the  conditions  essential  to  the  complete  realization  of  a  capital- 
istic economy  did  not  all  come  into  existence  until  the  late  eighteenth 
century,  various  contributions  to  the  capitalistic  complex  came  from 
earlier  ages,  and  to  these  we  may  now  devote  our  attention  very  briefly. 

In  ancient  Egypt,  while  the  extensive  degree  of  state  control  over  all 
forms  of  economic  life  prevented  the  rise  of  anything  like  free  capitalism, 
there  was,  nevertheless,  some  private  business  and  commercial  enterprise, 
and  the  first  great  private  fortunes  were  accumulated.  In  Babylonia, 
there  was  much  more  progress  towards  the  capitalistic  system.  More 
private  enterprise  was  permitted  and  many  of  the  business  forms  and 
practices  upon  which  phases  of  capitalism  later  rested  had  their  origins 
here.  Business  life  was  founded  upon  a  remarkably  wide  contractual 
basis.  The  importance  of  formal  contracts  was  made  manifest  by  the 
provision  that  a  purchase  consummated  without  a  contract  or  without 
witnesses  could  be  punished  even  by  death.  Deeds  of  settlement  and 
wills,  partnership  agreements,  the  relationship  of  principal  and  agent, 
the  forms  of  land  deeds  and  house  leases — all  these  were  elaborately 
regulated  by  law.  Witnessed  and  sealed  documents  were  prescribed  for 
all  economic  transactions.  Promissory  notes  were  provided  for,  and  the 
attitude  towards  interest  was  surprisingly  modern.  The  high  interest 
rates — normally  running  from  20  to  25  per  cent — were  regulated  by  law. 
However,  debtors  received  rather  considerate  treatment,  and  oppressive 
creditors  were  dealt  with  harshly. 

Babylonia  was  thus  the  motherland  of  our  modern  commercial  usages 
and  commercial  paper.  The  mercantile  Arameans  carried  these  achieve- 
ments even  further.  Western  Europe  did  not  surpass  their  forms  and 
processes  until  the  rise  of  modern  commerce  and  capitalism  after  1500 
A.D.  The  departure  from  a  pure  barter  economy  also  took  place  at  an 


116       CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

early  date  in  Babylonia.  A  real  money  economy  came  into  being,  involv- 
ing both  the  theory  and  practice  of  productive  capital,  though  there  was 
no  coined  money  until  the  very  close  of  the  late  Babylonian  epoch.  The 
precious  metals  were  used  by  weight.  Gold,  which  was  fifteen  times  as 
valuable  as  silver,  was  little  used.  This  was  in  marked  contrast  to  Egypt, 
where  gold  was  used  almost  exclusively. 

Some  of  the  traits  of  capitalism,  such  as  the  use  of  money,  the  accumu- 
lation of  large  fortunes,  the  prevalence  of  private  property,  and  some 
tendency  to  reinvest  savings  in  business  expansion,  thus  existed  in  the 
ancient  Near  East.  But  two  basic  institutions  of  capitalism,  the  free 
market  and  free  competition,  were  very  slightly  developed,  owing  to  the 
extensive  degree  of  state  control  over  economic  life. 

The  Phoenicians  were  the  great  sea-traders  of  antiquity,  and  in  their 
commercial  practices  we  find  some  of  the  first  rudimentary  origins  of 
commercial  capitalism,  especially  the  mercantile  control  of  business. 
Since  one  vital  phase  of  the  capitalistic  economy  is  the  use  of  money  and 
the  creation  of  a  money  economy,  mention  should  be  made  of  the  intro- 
duction of  coined  money  by  the  Lydians  in  western  Asia  Minor  around 
800  B.C.  The  fundamentals  of  a  money  economy  had  existed  before 
this  time,  monetary  values  being  determined  by  weight.  Coining  made 
monetary  designations  and  circulation  more  convenient.  But  the  value 
of  money  still  was  based  upon  the  weight  of  the  precious  metals  con- 
tained in  each  coin. 

Though  the  Athenians  engaged  in  extensive  industrial  and  com- 
mercial enterprise,  the  Greek  state  exerted  considerable  supervision  over 
both  trade  and  industry.  The  Greeks  never  understood  the  fundamental 
notion  of  capitalism,  namely,  the  accumulation  of  savings  for  reinvest- 
ment in  business.  Alfred  E.  Zimmern  once  acutely  observed  that 
"the  Greek  states  passed  with  difficulty  beyond  the  schoolboy  stage  at 
which  every  bit  of  money  that  comes  in  is  regarded  as  a  windfall,  to  be 
spent  gaily  as  the  mood  will  have  it,  without  thought  of  the  morrow." 
Hence  the  Greek  economy  has  been  called  a  "napkin  economy."  This 
term  is  used  by  some  economic  historians  to  describe  the  primitive  eco- 
nomic system  in  which  man  has  not  learned  to  reinvest  capital  for  addi- 
tional profits.  The  term  is  derived  from  the  parable  of  the  three  stewards 
in  the  New  Testament,  where  the  poor  steward,  with  only  one  talent, 
refused  to  take  the  risk  of  investment  and  wrapped  his  single  talent  in  a 
napkin.  The  fact  that  Greek  philosophers  looked  askance  upon  interest- 
taking  and  ranked  trade  on  almost  the  same  ethical  plane  as  brigandage 
shows  how  far  Greece  was  from  attaining  capitalistic  attitudes  and  prac- 
tices. Other  obstacles  to  the  development  of  capitalism  in  ancient  Greece 
were  the  absence  of  bankers  with  connections  extending  throughout 
Greece,  and  the  lack  of  exchanges  for  the  circulation  of  credit,  claims 
and  goods. 

In  ancient  Rome,  while  more  progress  was  made  towards  capitalism 
than  in  Greece,  business  was  held  in  disrepute  by  the  aristocracy  who 
believed  that  agriculture  was  the  only  truly  noble  occupation.  Cicero's 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS        117 

opinion  on  this  point  is  representative  of  the  Roman  disdain  for  money- 
making: 

All  gains  made  by  hired  labourers  are  dishonourable  and  base,  for  what  we 
buy  of  them  is  their  labour,  not  their  artistic  skill:  with  them  the  very  gain 
itself  does  but  increase  the  slavislmess  of  the  work.  All  retail  dealing  too  may 
be  put  in  the  same  category,  for  the  dealer  will  gain  nothing  except  by  profuse 
lying,  and  nothing  is  more  disgraceful  than  untruthful  huckstering.  Again,  the 
work  of  all  artisans  (opifices)  is  sordid;  there  can  be  nothing  honourable  in  a 
workshop.1 

Keeping  in  mind  this  prevailing  attitude  of  the  aristocratic  Romans 
towards  business  and  money-making,  we  may  briefly  survey  certain 
economic  developments  in  Rome  between  the  third  century  B.C.  and  the 
Christian  era,  which  brought  about  a  marked  increase  in  movable  wealth 
and  the  appearance  of  a  quasi-capitalistic  class.  The  chief  source  of 
this  new  type  of  wealth  was  neither  commerce  nor  industry,  but  the 
tribute  and  booty  of  conquest  and  the  supervision  of  public  works  and 
imperial  finances.  Imperialism,  in  other  words,  was  the  chief  contribu- 
tor to  the  new  wealth  of  Rome — a  diluted  form  of  state  capitalism. 
Tax-farming  accounted  for  a  great  deal  of  the  money  that  flowed  into 
Rome.  In  addition,  Rome's  practice  of  utilizing  middlemen  in  undertak- 
ing public  works,  the  collection  of  rents,  the  working  of  state  lands,  and 
many  other  business  activities  also  accounts  for  the  growth  of  a  moneyed 
class.  Collective  financial  enterprises  in  the  form  of  joint-stock  com- 
panies also  aided  in  the  creation  of  a  quasi-capitalistic  class.  Share- 
holders in  such  companies,  however,  were  drawn  from  almost  every 
class  except  the  poor. 

In  consequence,  there  was  a  notable  increase  of  capital  in  Rome,  and 
great  fortunes  made  their  appearance.  This  accumulation  of  wealth  was 
dramatized  by  the  suddenness  with  which  it  took  place.  Rudimentary 
banking  was,  naturally,  stimulated,  and  money-changing  became  an  im- 
portant source  of  income.  An  exceptionally  profitable  business  was  the 
lending  of  money  at  high  interest  by  the  new  class  of  bankers.  The  high 
maximum  legal  rate  of  12  per  cent  was  only  too  often  exceeded.  Specu- 
lation became  common,  and  there  are  records  of  financial  crises  in  Rome. 
The  wealthy  men  of  business  formed  a  separate  class,  called  the  eques- 
trian order  (ordo  equester) ,  the  members  of  which  were  called  knights 
(equites).  Their  wealth  was  "movable"  rather  than,  landed,  and  this 
fact  among  others  served  to  distinguish  them  from  the  senatorial  plutoc- 
racy. Towards  the  close  of  the  Republic,  even  though  real  estate  retained 
its  position  of  supremacy,  both  capital  and  the  class  that  possessed  it 
Assumed  greater  importance  in  the  Roman  state. 

Three  important  factors,  however,  served  to  hold  back  Roman  indus- 
trial and  commercial  development  from  anything  like  the  heights  which 
it  might  otherwise  have  attained.  All  grew  out  of  the  process  of  conquest. 
In  the  first  place,  conquest  poured  slaves  into  Rome  and  allowed  Italy 


W.  W.  Fowler,  Social  Life  of  Rome,  Macmillan,  1909,  pp.  43-44. 


118       CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

to  lean  upon  a  slave  economy  without  any  strong  incentive  to  mechani- 
cal invention  or  shrewd  business  management.  In  the  second  place,  there 
was  the  vast  tribute  from  the  provinces  which,  for  a  long  time,  offset  the 
losses  resulting  from  the  rudimentary  type  of  economic  life.  In  the  third 
place,  the  constant  opening  up  of  new  lands  for  exploitation  as  a  result 
of  conquest  diverted  capital  and  energy  from  Italian  commerce  and 
industry.  What  there  was  of  Roman  capitalism  disappeared  as  the 
society  of  the  Empire  went  into  decline.  City  life  and  business  fell  away 
and  the  economy  reverted  to  an  agrarian  basis.  Great  landlords  rose  to 
a  position  of  supremacy,  defied  the  law,  created  an  agricultural  anarchy 
and,  in  this  way,  led  Roman  civilization  into  feudalism,  which  offered 
no  opportunity  for  the  development  of  capitalistic  institutions  and  prac- 
tices. 

In  a  general  way  the  civilization  and  institutions  of  the  Christian 
Middle  Ages  were  anti-capitalistic.  The  Christian  theologians  and  law- 
makers revived  the  Greek  opposition  to  interest-taking,  and  both  ethics 
and  commercial  law  condemned  what  are  today  fundamental  bulwarks  of 
capitalistic  enterprise:  namely,  monopoly,  cornering  the  market,  and  the 
exchange  of  goods  purely  for  monetary  profit.  That  fundamental  eco- 
nomic concept  of  the  Middle  Ages,  the  just  price,  was  anti-capitalistic  in 
character. 

Nevertheless,  important  foundations  of  early  modern  capitalism  were 
laid  during  the  Middle  Ages.  The  Jews  assumed  an  important  place  as 
money-lenders,  and  they  introduced  the  use  of  letters  of  credit  and  rudi- 
mentary bills  of  exchange.  In  time,  a  considerable  number  of  Christian 
money-lenders  and  bankers  came  into  existence,  especially  in  connection 
with  handling  the  vast  resources  and  extensive  financial  operations  of  the 
Catholic  Church.  The  businessmen  of  the  north  Italian  city-states  in 
the  later  Middle  Ages  not  only  brought  into  existence  rudimentary  bank- 
ing and  credit  institutions  but  also  standardized  the  currency.  Banker- 
merchants  began  to  appear  in  the  latter  part  of  the  twelfth  century,  and 
a  hundred  years  later  the  first  banks  of  deposit  were  coming  into  being. 
These  were  at  first  private  banks,  but  early  in  the  fifteenth  century 
public  banks  of  deposit  sprang  up,  particularly  in  Spain  and  Italy.  In 
these  credit  operations  of  the  so-called  Lombard  bankers  in  Italy  and 
Caursine  money-lenders  in  southern  France,  we  find  the  origins  of  ideals 
and  practices  that  contributed  notably  to  the  rise  of  modern  capitalism. 

A  survey  of  the  contributions  of  the  Italians  to  banking  in  the  thir- 
teenth and  fourteenth  centuries  shows  that  they  were  developing  new 
forms  of  credit,  from  business  necessity  and  from  the  attempt  to  circum- 
vent the  prohibitions  of  the  Church.  Loans  on  mortgages,  on  a  limited 
partnership  basis,  on  the  security  of  bank  deposits,  or  on  specie  were  com- 
ing into  rather  general  use.  At  the  same  time  the  Italians,  copying  from 
the  Near  East,  introduced  into  the  West  letters  of  credit  and  payment, 
and  bills  of  exchange.  These  dispensed  with  cash  payments,  and  they 
also  meant  the  introduction  of  what  may  be  regarded  as  paper  currency 
into  Europe.  With  the  dawn  of  modern  times  in  the  sixteenth  century, 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS        119 

the  bank  check  and  double-entry  bookkeeping  made  their  appearance. 

A  powerful  philosophical  and  ethical  impetus  to  capitalism  came  from 
the  Protestant  Revolt  of  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries.  Look- 
ing at  the  matter  in  the  broad  perspective  of  the  history  of  civilization, 
the  most  important  contribution  of  the  Protestant  Revolt  to  economic 
theory  and  practice  was  the  sanction  and  respect  it  gave  to  the  profit- 
seeking  motive  in  man.  Not  even  in  the  period  of  oriental  antiquity  had 
the  acquisitive  instinct  been  so  frankly  blessed.  We  have  already  seen 
how  the  Greeks  looked  down  upon  economic  life,  when  compared  to  the 
glories  of  philosophy,  art,  and  athletics,  and  how,  in  the  scale  of  economic 
activities,  they  rated  commerce  much  lower  than  landholding — one  step 
above  brigandage.  The  Roman  aristocracy  had  this  same  general  out- 
look. Social  respectability  of  the  highest  order  was  associated  with 
agriculture  and  the  cultivation  of  rural  estates.  We  quoted  from  Cicero, 
gome  pages  back,  to  illustrate  the  contempt  of  the  cultivated  Roman  for 
both  commercial  pursuits  and  the  workshop. 

The  medieval  Christians  brought  a  revolution  in  human  attitudes 
towards  work  and  industry  by  upholding  the  worthy  character  of  manual 
labor  and  especially  blessing  competent  craftsmanship.  The  skilled 
worker  was  no  longer  contemptible.  But  the  medieval  Church  empha- 
sized the  penitential  nature  of  work,  looked  askance  upon  the  profit 
system,  and  tried  to  eliminate  from  trade  those  things  which  today  would 
be  regarded  as  the  very  essence  of  shrewd  business — selling  at  a  profit  with 
no  social  service,  cornering  the  market,  monopolizing  products,  and  inter- 
est-taking. Christians  involved  in  medieval  trade  may  have  engaged  to 
some  degree  in  all  these  prohibited  practices,  but  the  Church  never  for- 
mally gave  its  approval  to  such  conduct. 

The  Protestant  Revolt  fully  removed  the  stigma  from  personal  enrich- 
ment through  commercial  pursuits,  glorified  trade  and  monetary  profits, 
and  laid  the  foundations  for  our  present  near-deification  of  the  business- 
man. Protestantism,  especially  Calvinism,  decisively  encouraged  indi- 
vidualism in  economics  as  well  as  in  religion.  It  promoted  the  spirit  of 
thrift  and  economic  ambition,  the  acquisition  of  wealth  through  shrewd 
dealings,  and  increased  freedom  in  all  forms  of  economic  operations. 
The  modern  theory  and  practice  of  "business  enterprise"  found  a  power- 
ful initial  support  in  Protestant  morality  and  economic  doctrine.  This 
helped  along  the  rise  of  the  new  bourgeoisie  or  middle  class. 

The  true  origins  of  capitalism  are  to  be  found  in  the  expansion  of 
Europe,  the  Commercial  Revolution,  and  the  rise  of  a  new  volume  of 
trade  and  industry  in  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries.  We  will 
now  summarize  the  more  salient  points  of  capitalism  and  then  indicate 
the  way  in  which  these  essentials  of  capitalism  came  into  being  in  the 
two  or  three  centuries  after  Columbus. 

The  outstanding  traits  and  practices  of  capitalism  are  the  following: 
(1)  The  desire  for  private  profit  rather  than  the  service  of  the  com- 
munity or  mankind;  (2)  the  rise  of  a  money  economy,  which  promoted 
the  freedom  of  partners  in  all  kinds  of  economic  relations,  the  dissocia- 


120       CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

tion  of  objects  from  the  person  of  the  owner,  the  depersonalization  and 
rationalization  of  economic  relations,  and  the  habit  of  calculation  in 
economic  affairs;  (3)  the  estimation  of  social  status  and  success  in  terms 
of  relative  monetary  resources;  (4)  the  evaluation  of  goods  and  services 
in  terms  of  prices  set  by  bargaining  in  the  market  rather  than  by  con- 
siderations of  justice  or  intrinsic  worth;  (5)  the  accumulation  of  large 
monetary  resources  for  investment  in  business  ventures;  (6)  the  exist- 
ence of  a  free  market  for  the  sale  of  goods;  (7)  the  presence  of  a  sufficient 
labor  market  to  produce  the  needed  laborers;  (8)  a  credit  system  ade- 
quate to  the  needs  of  the  economic  era;  (9)  a  reasonably  thorough  devel- 
opment of  commercial  and  industrial  life;  and  (10)  unrestricted  dominion 
of  private  property  in  lands  and  goods.  Viewed  broadly,  capitalism  has 
as  its  purpose  the  gaining  of  private  profit,  its  method  is  that  of  free 
competition,  its  spirit  that  of  private  initiative,  and  its  field  of  operation, 
the  free  market. 

We  have  already  noted  how  the  Protestant  Revolt  broke  down  the 
medieval  emphasis  on  the  social  use  of  wealth  and  extolled  the  economic 
and  ethical  virtues  of  accumulating  private  profits  through  business  en- 
terprise. 

For  a  long  time,  social  status  reflected  former  agrarian  values,  and  the 
newly-rich  as  a  social  class  did  not  have  the  same  prestige  as  the  old 
agrarian  aristocracy.  But  by  the  eighteenth  century  wealth  had  come 
to  bestow  not  only  economic  power  but  social  prestige,  especially  when 
the  wealthy  business  and  commercial  classes  bought  up  great  landed 
estates.  By  the  nineteenth  century  one's  place  in  society  was  pretty 
directly  related  to  his  monetary  holdings,  and  high  social  position  de- 
pended upon  capacity  to  make  a  lavish  display  of  wealth. 

The  Protestant  Revolt  and  early  modern  business  and  commercial 
practices  wiped  out  the  medieval  limitations  upon  the  free  purchase  and 
sale  of  goods  and  encouraged  free  bargaining  in  the  market.  It  became 
one's  ethical  and  legal  privilege  to  buy  as  cheaply  as  possible  and  to  sell 
for  as  much  as  he  could  get,  even  though  nothing  was  added  to  the  value 
of  the  commodity.  The  idea  of  the  "just  price"  withered  away. 

In  early  modern  times,  great  fortunes  were  accumulated  by  families 
which  had  engaged  for  years  in  money-lending  and  rudimentary  bank- 
ing. Such  were  the  Peruzzi  and  Medici  of  Italy,  and  the  Fuggers  of 
South  Germany.  The  financial  resources  accumulated  by  these  and 
other  less  well-known  families  provided  a  material  basis  for  the  more 
extensive  investments  required  after  the  growth  of  overseas  trade  and 
the  expansion  of  industry  needed  to  support  this  trade. 

The  market  for  goods  in  the  Middle  Ages  had  been  rigidly  controlled 
by  many  practices  and  groups.  The  gilds  and  local  market  regulations 
sharply  restricted  the  operations  of  the  local  markets.  The  regional  and 
national  market,  provided  by  the  medieval  fairs,  was  also  subjected  to 
strict  regulations  imposed  by  Church  ethics,  gild  regulations,  the  law 
merchant,  and  royal  ordinances.  In  early  modern  times,  these  restric- 
tions of  the  market  were  slowly  but  surely  swept  away  and  relative  free- 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS        121 

dom  was  given  in  the  sale  of  goods.  Under  the  Mercantilist  system,  the 
main  restrictions  upon  a  free  market  were  the  limitations  imposed  upon 
sales  of  goods  by  colonies,  but  in  home  countries  a  free  market  generally 
prevailed,  though  not  so  absolute  as  it  became  in  the  nineteenth  cen- 
tury, when  laissez-faire  principles  had  fully  triumphed. 

The  destruction  of  the  medieval  manor  and  the  ousting  of  the  serfs 
therefrom  provided  a  large,  mobile,  and  helpless  labor  supply,  which 
provided  all  the  workers  necessary  to  produce  goods  under  the  new 
putting-out  system.  The  gradual  breaking-down  of  the  gild  system  put 
an  end  to  this  medieval  monopoly  over  the  labor  market. 

The  growth  of  large  fortunes,  the  extension  of  business  enterprise,  the 
opportunity  for  more  extensive  investment  and  profits,  together  with  the 
growing  experience  with  credit  institutions  and  banks  in  the  late  Middle 
Ages,  gave  an  enormous  impetus  to  the  improvement  of  banking  in  early 
modern  times  and  created  a  system  of  money  and  credit  adequate  to  the 
needs  of  the  expanding  business  and  commerce.  The  conventional  com- 
mercial paper,  such  as  promissory  notes,  drafts,  checks,  and  bills  of  ex- 
change, came  into  wider  use  and  facilitated  new  business  ventures. 

The  opportunities  for  gain  which  were  revealed  by  exploration  and 
colonization  led  to  a  notable  expansion  of  commerce.  New  commodities 
were  brought  into  Europe  from  overseas,  while  colonials  and  natives  pro- 
vided a  new  market  for  European  manufacturers.  This  expansion  of 
business  activity  laid  a  substantial  foundation  for  the  growth  of  modern 
capitalism  and  encouraged  its  practices  and  policies.  The  latter  were 
blessed  by  Protestanism,  especially  by  calvinists,  who  denounced  idle- 
ness, praised  industry,  and  regarded  business  as  a  divine  calling. 

During  the  Middle  Ages,  property  had  been  in  part  communal  and 
was  based  upon  a  complex  system  of  personal  and  legal  relationships.2 
With  the  breakdown  of  the  manors  and  the  gilds  and  the  destruction  of 
feudalism,  there  gradually  came  into  being  an  unrestricted  system  of 
private  property.  This  was  praised  by  religion,  defended  by  law,  and 
nourished  by  business.  In  early  modern  times,  the  direct  responsibility 
of  private  ownership  for  business  profits  tended  to  make  private  prop- 
erty a  dynamic  impulse  to  industrial  development. 

We  have  now  briefly  listed  some  of  the  more  important  contributions 
to  the  rise  of  capitalism  through  the  ages.  By  the  seventeenth  century, 
the  capitalistic  system  had  come  into  existence.  It  was  a  late  arrival 
on  the  human  scene.  Over  99  per  cent  of  man's  existence  on  the  planet 
had  been  passed  through  before  capitalism  appeared.  Further,  capital- 
ism did  not  come  into  full  bloom  until  the  nineteenth  century.  Not  until 
then  were  private  fortunes  large  enough  to  give  capitalism  full  reach  or 
was  economic  freedom  sufficient  to  provide  fully  for  that  cornerstone  of 
capitalism — the  free  market.  The  strong  and  extensive  state  control 
which  characterized  the  Mercantilist  system  of  politics  and  economics 
held  over  until  the  nineteenth  century. 


2  See  below,  pp.  174-176. 


122       CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS 


The  Evolution  of  Capitalism 

It  is  misleading  to  describe  capitalism  exclusively  in  terms  of  any 
single  stage  of  its  development,  to  envisage  as  a  unified  whole  a  system 
of  economic  life  covering  the  period  from  the  Fuggers  of  the  fifteenth 
century  to  the  Morgans  of  the  twentieth.  Capitalism  can  be  intelli- 
gently understood  only  when  analyzed  according  to  its  periods  of  evolu- 
tion, each  of  which  had  distinctive  characteristics.  The  most  accurate 
portrayal  of  the  evolution  of  modern  capitalism  conceives  of  it  as  having 
already  passed  through  four  main  successive  stages:  (1)  mercantile  or 
pre-industrial  capitalism;  (2)  early  industrial  capitalism;  (3)  monopolis- 
tic industrial  capitalism;  and  (4)  finance  capitalism.  State  capitalism 
may  be  the  next  stage. 

Pre-industrial  capitalism  developed  between  the  Commercial  and  In- 
dustrial revolutions — between  1500  and  1750,  Society  was  still  primarily 
agricultural,  and  the  rising  capitalistic  activities  were  chiefly  associated 
with  the  growing  world  trade  following  the  overseas  discoveries,  and 
with  the  small  manufacturing  units  operating  under  either  the  gild  or 
the  putting-out  system.  The  merchants  were  the  masters  of  capitalism 
in  this  era.  Their  fortunes  were  built  up  chiefly  out  of  the  new  trade, 
and  capitalistic  institutions  and  practices  were  created  mainly  to  serve 
commerce. 

Early  industrial  capitalism  prevailed  during  the  preliminary  stages  of 
the  first  Industrial  Revolution,  and  was  associated  with  the  rise  of  the 
machine  technique,  the  factory  system,  urban  industrial  life,  and  im- 
provements in  transportation  resulting  from  the  application  of  the  steam 
engine.  The  industrialists  were  the  chief  capitalists;  they  owned  and 
operated  their  own  plants  and  kept  finance  subordinate  to  industry. 
Absentee  ownership  was  not  important. 

Monopolistic  industrial  capitalism  was  primarily  associated  with  the 
earlier  phases  of  the  second  Industrial  Revolution,  which  demonstrated 
the  superior  efficiency  of  large  industrial  establishments  and  mass  pro- 
duction. It  was  greatly  aided  by  the  development  of  the  corporate  form 
of  business  organization  and  the  rise  of  trusts.  Bold  and  unscrupulous 
men  attempted  to  obtain  control  of  entire  industries,  to  profit  by  the 
introduction  of  labor-saving  devices  and  large-scale  production,  and  to 
fix  prices  at  a  high  level.  Ownership  was  not,  however,  even  yet  di- 
vorced to  any  great  extent  from  management.  The  industrial  giants  of 
those  days  still  maintained  an  active  personal  control  over  their  expand- 
ing empires  of  industry.  Railroad  development  was,  however,  thoroughly 
shot  through  with  financial  chicanery  and  speculative  enterprise.  It  was 
here  that  finance  capitalism  bored  from  within. 

In  finance  capitalism,  the  investment  banker  replaced  the  industrialist 
as  the  controlling  figure  in  economic  life.  The  process  of  industrial 
consolidation  launched  by  monopoly  capitalism  continued,  but  was  di- 
rected by  investment  bankers  rather  than  by  industrialists.  The  holding 
company  replaced  the  outlawed  trusts.  Control  and  management  were 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS        123 

both  increasingly  divorced  from  ownership,  and  absentee  ownership  be- 
came all  but  universal.  This  has  been  one  of  the  outstanding  revolutions 
produced  by  finance  capitalism.  Productivity  and  human  service,  as 
dominating  economic  motives,  were  supplanted  by  the  desire  for  large 
and  immediate  financial  profits  through  speculative  manipulations,  the 
latter  often  being  definitely  opposed  to  the  permanent  welfare  of  the 
industries  and  transportation  systems  involved. 

It  is  now  pretty  generally  conceded  by  impartial  students  of  economic 
and  social  history  that  finance  capitalism  is  drawing  to  an  end  and  that 
the  next  stage — perhaps  the  final  stage — of  capitalism  will  be  state  capi- 
talism, in  which  the  government  will  furnish  most  of  the  credit,  will 
own  many  basic  industries  and  transportation  agencies,  and  will  exert 
extensive  control  over  all  forms  of  economic  life.  In  Europe  today,  state 
capitalism  dominates  nearly  every  country  except  the  Soviet  Union. 
It  has  attained  its  most  extreme  development  in  such  Fascist  states  as 
Italy  and  Germany.  But  in  a  less  complete  form  it  had  become  well 
established  in  the  Scandinavian  states  and  Finland  before  the  second 
World  War  broke  out.  As  the  result  of  the  emergency  created  by  the 
second  World  War,  France  and  Britain  had  to  adopt  a  complete  system 
of  state  capitalism,  while  German  conquests  brought  a  number  of  new 
countries  under  the  dominion  of  the  Nazi  form  of  state  capitalism.  In 
some  ways  it  is  a  misnomer  to  call  such  a  system  "state  capitalism,"  for 
it  suppresses  the  most  conspicuous  element  in  capitalism,  namely,  the  free 
market,  and  it  also  greatly  restricts  private  property. 

Many  historians  believe  that  when  state  capitalism  becomes  well  de- 
veloped it  will  bring  an  end  to  all  forms  of  capitalism  and  will  pass  over 
naturally  into  a  system  of  state  socialism,  like  that  which  exists  in  Soviet 
Russia.  The  Nazi  economic  order  today  has  moved  ahead  towards  col- 
lectivism to  such  an  extent  that  it  does  not  differ  markedly  from  the 
Russian  economic  system,  so  far  as  the  state  control  of  economic  life  is 
concerned. 

If  we  apply  this  conception  of  the  stages  of  capitalistic  evolution  to  the 
United  States,  for  example,  the  era  of  mercantile  or  pre-industrial  capi- 
talism falls  between  the  period  of  settlement  and  the  first  quarter  of  the 
nineteenth  century.  Dominated  by  colonial  merchants,  this  period  had, 
as  its  outstanding  figures  in  commercial  capitalism,  John  Hancock, 
Peter  Faneuil,  the  Whartons  of  Philadelphia,  the  Livingstons  of  New 
York,  and  the  Browns  of  Providence. 

Beginning  around  1800,  machine  methods  were  introduced  into  the 
New  England  cotton  textile  industry  by  Samuel  Slater  and  others ;  trans- 
portation was  revolutionized  by  canals,  river  steamboats,  and  railroads; 
modern  methods  of  making  iron  and  steel  were  developed  by  William 
Kelley  and  others ;  and  the  factory  system  became  rather  general.  Lead- 
ing figures  in  this  stage  of  capitalism  were  the  textile  barons,  Nathan 
Appleton,  Francis  Cabot  Lowell,  and  William  Crompton;  the  ironmasters, 
William  Kelley  and  Thaddeus  Stevens;  the  manufacturer,  Cyrus  McCor- 
miak;  the  railroad  promoter,  J.  M.  Forbes;  and  Philip  Armour,  the  meat- 
packer. 


124       CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

Industrial  capitalism  was  tremendously  stimulated  by  the  Civil  War. 
Andrew  Carnegie,  the  ironmaster,  was  the  outstanding  representative  of 
well-developed  industrial  capitalism.  No  definite  date  marks  the  deci- 
sive end  of  this  stage  of  capitalism.  Henry  Ford  may  probably  be  re- 
garded as  motivated  by  the  ideals  of  industrial  capitalism,  equipped  with 
the  technique  afforded  by  the  second  Industrial  Revolution,  and  operat- 
ing somewhat  defiantly  in  a  world  generally  dominated  by  finance  cap- 
italism. The  anomalous  character  of  Ford's  ideals,  however  commend- 
able, have  often  been  commented  upon  by  historians  and  economists. 
What  we  have  just  said  offers  the  explanation. 

The  last  two  decades  of  the  nineteenth  century  witnessed  a  sweeping 
transformation  in  capitalistic  processes  and  ideals.  The  chief  objective 
was  to  concentrate  industrial  power,  in  order  to  obtain  the  advantages 
of  large-scale  production  and  monopoly  prices.  The  most  representative 
figure  of  this  period  was  John  D.  Rockefeller,  Sr.,  and  the  Standard  Oil 
Company  was  the  most  conspicuous  and  successful  product  of  monopoly 
capitalism  in  this  country.  Other  examples  were  the  United  States  Steel 
Corporation,  the  International  Harvester  Company,  and  the  American 
Tobacco  Company.  Monopolistic  capitalism  was  at  first  brought  about 
through  the  use  of  trusts,  but  these  were  outlawed  by  the  Sherman 
Act  of  1890.  After  this  date  the  holding  company  was  invented.  It  has 
been  fairly  successful  in  keeping  beyond  the  reaches  of  the  law. 

In  the  United  States  the  age  of  finance  capitalism  overlaps  the  terminal 
period  of  monopoly  capitalism.  Indeed,  the  finance  capitalists  continued 
monopolistic  practices.  The  holding  company,  the  most  spectacular 
product  of  finance  capitalism,  became  the  main  instrument  of  monopolis- 
tic control  and  exploitation.  The  formation  of  the  United  States  Steel 
Corporation  at  the  opening  of  the  twentieth  century  was  as  much  the 
work  of  a  banker,  J.  P.  Morgan,  as  of  the  industrialists,  Carnegie, 
Schwab,  Frick,  and  others.  In  the  era  of  finance  capitalism,  great  bank- 
ing combines  were  created  and  investment  banks  assumed  increasing 
control  over  the  origin  and  operation  of  manufacturing  industries,  min- 
ing, transportation,  electric  utilities,  and  insurance  companies.  If  the 
elder  Rockefeller  was  typical  of  the  period  of  monopoly  capitalism,  J.  P. 
Morgan,  Sr.,  was  the  outstanding  figure  in  the  triumph  of  finance  capi- 
talism. Other  leading  banking  concerns  were  Kuhn,  Loeb  &  Co.,  Dillon, 
Read  &  Co.,  Lee  Higginson  &  Co.,  and  great  metropolitan  national  banks 
such  as  the  Chase  National  Bank  and  the  National  City  Bank  of  New 
York.  Descendants  of  monopoly  capitalists  often  assumed  a  prominent 
position  in  the  age  of  finance  capitalism.  For  example,  the  younger 
Rockefeller  has  a  controlling  interest  in  the  Chase  National  Bank,  the 
greatest  public  banking  establishment  in  the  United  States. 

It  must  not  be  supposed  that  the  financiers'  control  of  legitimate  busi- 
ness was  limited  to  the  giant  investment  houses  and  manipulators  we 
have  just  enumerated.  There  were  lesser  J.  P.  Morgans,  Samuel  Insulls, 
Albert  Wiggins,  Charles  E.  Mitchells,  and  Clarence  Dillons  in  every 
sizable  city  and  town  who,  in  a  small  way,  attempted  to  do  what  these 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS        125 

men  did  on  a  national  scale.  Moreover,  they  were  aided  by  the  big 
metropolitan  financial  houses,  which  unloaded  on  the  smaller  banks  their 
less  desirable  securities.  The  latter  in  turn  sold  them  to  trusting  clients 
with  disastrous  results  to  both  the  American  masses  and  to  our  banking 
system. 

The  growth  of  great  banking  institutions,  together  with  the  vast  wealth 
which  they  concentrated,  naturally  made  them  the  pivots  of  finance 
capitalism.  We  must  keep  in  mind  the  fact  that  the  banks  themselves, 
like  industries  and  transportation  lines,  have  been  combined  into  gigantic 
institutions  and  have  accumulated  immense  deposits. 

In  order  that  finance  capitalism  might  reach  full  expression,  it  was 
necessary  that  the  banks  should  gain  control  over  industry,  transporta- 
tion, mining,  and  electric  utilities.  All  of  these  require  extensive  credit, 
and  the  banks  dominated  the  credit  facilities  of  the  country.  Moreover, 
newly  formed  companies  must  have  banking  aid  to  underwrite  and  float 
their  securities.  Established  companies  need  similar  help  when  they 
plan  activities  requiring  the  flotation  of  new  issues  of  corporate  paper. 
When  a  company  goes  into  a  receivership,  a  great  banking  house  may 
supervise  the  reorganization,  usually  emerging  with  fairly  complete  con- 
trol of  the  reorganized  company.  In  these  ways  nearly  all  forms  of 
American  business  and  transportation  have  fallen  into  the  grip  of  the 
great  American  banks,  private  and  public. 

The  Ascendency  of  Finance  Capitalism 

The  actual  character  of  finance  capitalism  in  the  United  States 
today  can  best  be  illustrated  by  a  brief  summary  of  the  relevant  facts. 
The  total  national  wealth  of  the  country  before  the  1929  slump  amounted 
to  some  367  billion  dollars.  Of  this  total,  business  wealth  may  be 
assigned  around  210  billions.  Some  78  per  cent  of  all  business  wealth — 
165  billions — was  corporate  wealth.  This  was  divided  among  some 
300,000  non-financial  corporations  (that  is,  excluding  banks  and  the  like) . 
The  concentration  of  this  corporate  wealth  under  the  management  of  a 
few  individuals  is  almost  incredible  to  all  except  students  of  recent  Amer- 
ican economic  history.  Two  hundred  of  the  largest  corporations,  repre- 
senting only  0.7  per  cent  of  the  total  number  of  corporations,  in  1932 
controlled  81  billion  dollars — namely,  about  half  of  all  corporate  assets, 
35  per  cent  of  all  business  wealth,  and  nearly  20  per  cent  of  our  total 
national  wealth.8 

Within  each  of  these  great  corporations  there  is  a  high  degree  of  con- 
centration of  control.  This  literal  control  is  rarely  based  upon  the 
actual  ownership  of  a  majority  of  the  stock.  In  fact,  only  ten  of  these 
200  super-corporations  are  controlled  by  owners  of  a  majority  of  the 
stock.  And  these  are  relatively  small  corporations,  since  the  ten  control 


3  The  concentration  of  control  is  even  greater  today,  and  the  formal  assets  of  the 
200  super-corporations  are  larger. 


126       CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

only  2  per  cent  of  the  total  assets  of  the  200  corporations.  This  divorce 
of  control  from  investment  and  ownership  is  at  times  amazing.  The 
Van  Sweringens  gained  control  over  eight  Class  A  railroads,  with  assets 
of  more  than  2  billion  dollars,  on  the  basis  of  an  original  investment  of 
only  2  million,  nearly  all  of  which  was  borrowed  from  a  Cleveland  bank. 
This  was  then  expanded  to  20  million  dollars  by  various  subsequent 
manipulative  transactions.  Henry  L.  Doherty  and  his  associates  con- 
trolled the  Cities  Service  utility  interests,  with  about  one  billion  dollars 
in  paper  assets,  through  the  unbelievably  small  investment  of  one  mil- 
lion in  preferred  voting-stock.  Likewise,  an  investment  of  one  million 
dollars  has  given  control  over  the  one  billion  paper  assets  of  the  Stand- 
ard Gas  and  Electric  Company. 

This  is  only  part  of  the  story.  Among  these  200  corporations  there 
were  43  with  assets  of  more  than  500  million  dollars  each  at  the  begin- 
ning of  1932.  These  are  controlled  by  166  individuals,  who  serve  as 
interlocking  directors  between  the  43  corporations,  ten  leading  banks, 
and  three  great  insurance  companies.  In  fact,  the  ten  banks  and  three 
insurance  companies  control,  in  practice,  not  only  the  43  corporations, 
but  all  one  billion  dollar  corporations  of  the  country,  with  but  one  ex- 
ception: the  Ford  Motor  Company,  which  is  controlled  through  the 
ownership  of  a  majority  of  the  stock. 

The  pivotal  organization  in  this  growth  of  financial  concentration  and 
dominion  is  the  firm  of  J.  P.  Morgan  &  Co.  This  company  directly 
influences,  through  interlocking  directorates,  enterprises  with  more  than 
20  billion  dollars  in  assets.  We  shall  shortly  consider  the  effect  of  this 
financial  dominion  on  economic  life. 

While  we  must  point  out  the  defects  in  the  philosophy  of  irresponsible 
business  enterprise,  we  must  also,  to  be  fair  and  accurate,  indicate  that 
the  greater  part  of  such  sound  business  as  we  once  had  has  been  under- 
mined by  the  methods  of  finance  capitalism. 

Most  attacks  on  the  modern  industrial  order  are  lacking  in  discrimina- 
tion and  emphasis.  We  frequently  assault  modern  "business,"  lumping 
in  the  term  not  only  actual  business  pursuits  but  also  speculative  finance, 
which  is  really  the  major  enemy  of  legitimate  business.  It  is  quite  true, 
as  we  shall  see  later  on,  that  modern  business  enterprise  leaves  much  to 
be  desired.  Nevertheless,  it  has  provided  those  products  which  enable 
us  to  live  in  a  manner  quite  different  from  primitive  man.  Modern 
business  may  be  unscientific,  and  harsh  with  labor,  and  may  have  ex- 
ploited the  inventors,  but  after  all,  its  creations,  even  though  their 
quality  might  be  improved  in  most  cases,  are  the  most  impressive  of 
man's  economic  achievements.  That  they  may  prove  self-destructive  is 
another  matter. 

Modern  finance  is  a  different  story.  But  even  here  we  are  in  danger 
of  indiscriminate  abuse.  Legitimate  banking,  which  supplies  our  invest- 
ment and  credit  machinery,  renders  an  indispensable  service  to  modern 
industrial  life.  Without  it,  large-scale  business,  with  its  increased  ef- 
ficiency and  productivity,  could  not  exist.  Banking  and  finance,  which 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS        127 

should  be  the  servants  of  business,  have  unfortunately  become  its  master 
in  the  United  States.  The  investment  and  credit  functions  have  be- 
come incidental  to  speculative  exploitation. 

In  the  United  States  there  has  been  no  such  extreme  development  of 
state  capitalism  as  we  find  in  Europe.  But  the  depression  of  1929  and 
thereafter  has  headed  this  country  definitely  in  the  direction  of  state 
capitalism.  The  government  has  adopted  extensive  control  over  bank- 
ing and  credit  and  has  imposed  restrictions  upon  the  operations  of 
finance  capitalism.  It  has  put  the  force  of  the  state  behind  labor  organi- 
zations. It  has  tended  to  fix  prices  and  to  attack  monopoly.  It  has 
asserted  extensive  control  over  agriculture.  Great  sums  have  been 
raised  to  care  for  the  needy  through  relief  and  public  works,  the  total 
cost  amounting  to  about  fourteen  billion  dollars  during  Mr.  Roosevelt's 
first  two  administrations.  With  the  adoption  of  the  vast  preparedness 
program  of  1940-1941,  the  government  asserted  even  more  extensive 
control  over  finance  and  business,  with  the  prospect  of  complete  state 
capitalism  after  our  entry  into  the  second  World  War.  The  vast  ex- 
penditures for  defense — upwards  of  a  hundred  billion  dollars — are  likely 
to  encourage  an  ever  more  complete  system  of  state  capitalism  to  deal 
with  the  difficult  economic  problems  which  lie  ahead.  Nine  weeks  of  war 
subjected  American  business  to  a  greater  degree  of  state  control  than  nine 
years  of  the  New  Deal  were  able  to  accomplish. 

Some  Defects  in  the  System  of  Finance  Capitalism 

Though  the  net  effect  of  financial  dominion  over  capitalism  has  been 
disastrous,  as  we  shall  make  clear  in  some  detail,  one  should  not  over- 
look the  fact  that  investment  bankers  can  render  a  real  service  to  busi- 
ness and  have  at  times  actually  done  so  in  some  respects  and  cases.  In 
ideal  theory,  as  N.  S.  B.  Gras  has  explained,  investment  bankers  may 
render  the  following  services  to  the  business  world:  4  They  make  possible 
the  expansion  of  business  and  the  creation  of  new  companies  by  under- 
writing the  sale  of  securities  needed  to  finance  plant  expansion  or  the 
establishment  of  new  business.  They  arrange  long-term  loans  for  busi- 
ness, in  the  same  way  that  commercial  banks  provide  for  short-term 
loans.  Since  businesses  could,  before  recent  innovations,  be  started  and 
expanded  only  through  the  aid  of  the  investment  banks,  the  latter  can 
exert  a  restraining  influence  upon  wild  investment  in  new  plants  or  upon 
unwise  expansion  of  existing  plants.  Further,  through  their  domination 
over  business,  they  can  select  corporate  officers  and  managers  of  busi- 
ness enterprises  and  thus  bring  about  wise  and  efficient  business  manage- 
ment for  the  benefit  of  stockholders  and  the  public  alike.  In  these  ways, 
investment  banks  and  financial  capitalists  might  have  a  benevolent  and 
efficient  control  over  all  modern  business. 


4  See  Gras,  "Do  We  Need  Private  Bankers?"  New  York  Times  Current  History, 
August,  1933.  Professor  Gras'  apology  for  finance  capitalism  is  elaborated  in  his 
Business  and  Capitalism,  Crofts,  1939. 


128       CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

In  practice,  these  benefits  have  been  very  imperfectly  realized.  The 
investment  banks  have,  indeed,  financed  new  enterprises  and  plant  expan- 
sion, though  usually  at  enormous  profits  to  themselves.  But  they  have 
rarely  exerted  any  other  beneficial  effects  upon  business.  Instead  of 
restraining  unwise  and  unneeded  enterprise  and  plant  expansion,  they 
have  all  too  often  encouraged  such  rashness,  in  order  to  get  the  profits 
connected  therewith.  They  have  chosen  corporate  directors  and  man- 
agement, but  usually  for  the  purpose  of  having  docile  puppets  who  will 
aid  in  looting  business  rather  than  administer  it  with  integrity  and 
efficiency.  Instead  of  increasing  the  efficiency  of  corporate  administra- 
tion, the  investment  banks  have  more  frequently  demoralized  it  through 
internal  financial  manipulations.  To  facilitate  and  extend  this  pro- 
cedure they  have  created  great  holding  companies,  which  loot  and  drain 
the  profits  from  manufacturing  enterprise,  railroads,  utility  companies, 
and  the  like. 

That  this  is  not  an  exaggeration  can  be  seen  from  a  careful  reading  of 
Max  LowenthaPs  The  Investor  Pays,5  a  not  extreme  case  history  of 
finance  capitalism  at  its  best  in  operation — the  case  of  the  Chicago, 
Milwaukee  &  St.  Paul  Railroad.  This  describes  the  experience  of  the 
St.  Paul  Railroad  under  the  domination  of  one  of  the  best  investment 
banking  houses,  that  of  Kuhn,  Loeb  &  Company.  Indeed,  Mr.  Otto 
Kahn  of  this  company  testified  before  an  investigating  committee  in 
Washington  that  he  and  his  company  dealt  with  the  St.  Paul  as  a  kindly 
family  physician  would  deal  with  the  sick  wife  of  a  personal  friend.  The 
ravishing  carried  on  by  more  ruthless  investment  banking  houses  has 
often  been  quite  incredible  to  those  not  familiar  with  the  practices  and 
policies  of  finance  capitalism. 

A  brief  summary  of  some  characteristic  operations  of  finance  capital- 
ism will  illustrate  its  fundamental  antagonism  to  honest  practice.  The 
formula  and  technique  of  finance  capitalism,  with  minor  variations  in 
individual  cases,  seem  to  be  essentially  the  following: 

A  new  enterprise  is  proposed,  either  to  or  by  a  great  investment  bank- 
ing house.  Little  or  no  concern  is  shown  for  the  community's  need  of 
this  enterprise,  be  it  a  power  plant,  a  shoe  factory,  or  a  transcontinental 
railroad.  Rather,  the  question  is  wholly  whether  the  securities  of  the 
proposed  corporation  can  be  floated  profitably.  If  they  can,  the  invest- 
ment bankers  market  the  securities  at  a  handsome  profit  to  themselves 
and  with  little  conscience  about  the  amount  of  water  thrown  into  the 
initial  capitalization. 

Then  the  actual  plant,  transportation  system,  or  utility,  as  the  case 
may  be,  is  built  at  an  unnecessarily  high  cost,  the  financiers  almost  al- 
ways profiting  through  their  connections  with  construction  and  supply 
companies. 

When  the  plant  is  built  and  business  starts,  there  is  a  period  of  gross 


0  Knopf,  1933.    See  the  excellent  review  by  G.  C.  Means  in  The  New  York  Times, 
June  25,  1933. 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS        129 

mismanagement  and  extravagance.  Much  of  this  is  due  to  the  control 
of  the  corporation  by  directors  who,  in  one  way  or  another,  can,  as  we 
shall  make  clear  later,  make  greater  profits  for  themselves  by  such  mis- 
management than  by  earning  large  dividends  for  stockholders.  They 
own  only  a  small  portion  of  stock,  so  they  get  only  a  fraction  of  the 
dividends,  but  they  get  all  of  the  proceeds  from  their  inside  exploitation. 
Not  even  the  insistence  of  the  stockholders  upon  getting  dividends  suf- 
fices adequately  to  check  this  tendency.  Moreover,  the  stockholders 
are  usually  kept  in  the  dark  about  corporate  finances  until  a  receivership 
is  inevitable.  As  Alden  Winthrop  has  pointed  out:  "It  is  no  exaggeration 
to  say  that  it  is  difficult  to  find  one  out  of  ten  corporate  reports  which 
is  complete,  clear  and  fundamentally  honest;  and  probably  there  is  not 
one  out  of  five  which  is  not  misleading,  ambiguous,  vague,  or  evasive."8 

Mismanagement  eventually  leads  to  a  receivership.  The  controlling 
insiders  and  their  bankers  get  together  and  decide  upon  the  steps  to  be 
taken.  Security  holders  are  usually  lulled  into  a  false  sense  of  con- 
fidence by  optimistic  rumors,  lest  they  become  panicky  and  take  action 
which  would  delay  or  frustrate  the  reorganization  plans  of  the  controlling 
clique.  A  friendly  judge  is  found  who  will  appoint  receivers  and  com- 
mittees favorable  to  those  directing  the  reorganization.  The  mass  of 
small  investors  are  then  saddled  with  great  losses,  while  the  insiders  gain 
control  of  the  reorganized  concern  at  relatively  small  cost.  The  stock 
holder  has  only  a  substantial  or  a  total  loss  to  show  for  the  hard-earned 
funds  he  invested.7 

In  the  meantime,  the  company's  service  to  the  public  is  an  incidental 
matter  compared  to  the  financial  profit  which  the  insiders  make  from 
underwriting,  construction,  mismanagement,  and  reorganization.  Like- 
wise, the  market  value  of  the  stock — which  should  be  determined  by 
prudent  investment  and  earning  power — is  often  controlled  by  stock  ex- 
change manipulations,  the  stock  exchange  itself  being  supported  and 
managed  by  speculative  bankers. 

Launch,  mismanage,  wreck,  and  reorganize  are,  then,  quite  literally, 
the  slogan  of  finance  capitalism.  Between  the  first  and  last  of  these 
processes,  as  many  speculative  gains  as  possible  are  extracted  from  the 
company.  Hence,  wage  cuts  and  other  savings  at  the  expense  of  mass 
purchasing  power  are  favored.  Professor  Ripley  has  trenchantly  sum- 
marized the  results: 

A  multitude  of  people — a  horde  of  bewildered  investors — has  little  left  in 
the  world  but  ashes  and  aloes.  These  are  all  that  remain  of  the  precious  fruits 
of  years  of  pelf-denial  and  of  hard  labor.  A  raid  upon  the  thrift  and  industry, 
which  lie  at  the  very  roots  of  our  orderly  civilization  and  culture,  has  been,  and 


«  Are  You  a  Stockholder?    Covici-Friede,  1937,  p.  13. 

7  That  this  analysis  of  the  operations  of  finance  capitalism  is  not  overdrawn  is 
evident  from  the  careful  works  of  Lowenthal,  Berle  and  Means,  Flynn,  Wormser, 
and  others.  But  even  more  cogent  is  the  reported  observation  of  Paul  D.  Cravath, 
one  of  the  greatest  of  corporation  lawyers,  that  in  twenty  years  he  has  witnessed 
over  half  of  the  important  American  corporations  pass  through  receivership. 


130       CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

still  is,  under  way.    This  is  becoming  steadily  more  and  more  apparent  as  we 
set  about  clearing  up  the  slash  after  the  great  timber  cut  of  1929.8 

The  speculative  and  exploitive  policies  of  finance  capitalism  are  made 
possible  by  absentee  ownership,  the  divorce  of  control  from  ownership, 
and  the  mechanism  of  the  holding  company,  which  enables  a  few  insiders 
to  gain  control  of  great  corporations  with  a  small  investment  of  capital. 
As  John  T.  Flynn  has  cogently  observed,  "The  holding  companies  are  the 
machine  guns  of  the  financial  racketeers/1 

We  have  moved  a  great  distance  from  the  days  when  the  individual 
manufacturer  owned  his  plant  and  managed  his  property,  thoroughly 
disciplined  by  a  sense  of  personal  responsibility.  Today,  those  who 
manage  our  industrial  enterprises  are  usually  two  degrees  removed  from 
actual  ownership.  The  owners  are  the  stockholders,  usually  extremely 
numerous  and  widely  scattered.  Those  who  control  the  ultimate  policy 
of  industrial  enterprises  and  of  particular  plants  are  the  corporate  of- 
ficers and  directors.  As  we  shall  see,  they  rarely  own  more  than  an 
insignificant  fraction  of  the  total  stock  of  the  corporation.  They  get 
control  of  the  concern  by  owning  a  small  and  coherent  block  of  voting 
securities,  by  issuing  non-voting  stock,  and  by  other  methods  of  legal 
legerdemain.  While  this  group  controls  corporations,  it  usually  has  little 
to  do  with  the  actual  management  of  manufacturing  plants  and  other 
business  details.  These  duties  and  responsibilities  are  handed  over  to 
technically  trained  business  managers,  usually  graduates  of  our  ever 
improving  schools  of  business  administration.  But  these  business  man- 
agers find  that  their  scientific  ideals  and  efficiency  precepts  are  all  too 
often  violated  by  the  policies  of  the  officers  and  directors,  who  succumb 
to  speculative  impulses  and  exploitive  ambitions. 

Today,  it  is  unusual  for  the  governing  clique  of  a  great  corporation  to 
own  as  much  as  5  per  cent  of  its  stock.  But  suppose  we  grant,  for  the 
sake  of  illustration,  that  they  do  own  5  per  cent.  Let  us  assume  that 
they  are  industrious,  work  hard  and  do  everything  they  can  to  increase 
legitimate  dividends.  What  do  they  get  as  their  reward?  They  obtain 
5  per  cent  of  the  total  dividends,  since  they  own  only  5  per  cent  of  the 
stock.  On  the  other  hand,  if  they  hire  an  eminent  corporation  lawyer  to 
tell  them  how  they  can  increase  their  profits  through  financial  manipula- 
tion and  still  keep  out  of  jail,  what  is  their  reward?  They  get  100  per  cent 
of  the  profits,  since  the  whole  manipulative  process  is  exclusively  in  their 
hands.  At  the  worst,  they  will  be  saddled  with  only  5  per  cent  of  the 
losses,  since  they  own  only  5  per  cent  of  the  stock,  and  any  assessment 
would  be  limited  to  that  amount. 

Therefore,  honesty  and  industry  are  rewarded  at  the  best  by  5  per 
cent  of  the  income,  while,  at  the  very  worst,  chicanery  is  repaid  with 
95  per  cent  of  its  profits.  Hence,  it  is  no  wonder  that,  human  nature 
and  the  profit  motive  being  what  they  are,  the  governing  cliques  under 


8  W.  2.  Ripley,  "Our  Corporate  Revolution  and  Its  Perils/'  The  New  York  Times, 
July  24.  1932. 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS        131 

the  regime  of  finance  capitalism  prefer  dishonesty  and  95  per  cent  of 
the  manipulative  profits  rather  than  honesty  and  industriousness  and 
5  per  cent  of  the  dividends.  Such  abuses  are  almost  inevitable  when 
people  handle  things  which  do  not  belong  to  them.  It  is  the  penalty  we 
pay  for  allowing  our  corporate  directors  to  use  "other  people's  money," 
to  employ  Mr.  Justice  Brandeis*  phrase,  without  proper  restrictions  and 
safeguards. 

In  addition  to  financial  manipulation  and  deliberate  mismanagement, 
another  way  in  which  the  governing  clique  of  insiders  enrich  themselves 
at  the  expense  of  stockholders  is  through  excessive  salaries  and  bonuses.0 
Salaries  running  from  $100,000  to  $300,000  a  year  are  not  uncommon. 
One  special  form  of  salary  graft  is  the  creation  of  a  number  of  perfunc- 
tory vice-presidents  who  often  do  little  or  nothing  and,  yet,  receive  large 
salaries.  Even  more  reprehensible  is  the  bonus  system  when  carried  to 
the  excesses  which  have  been  revealed.  During  the  first  ten  years  that 
the  bonus  system  was  in  force  in  one  large  corporation,  bonuses  were  paid 
to  officials  to  the  amount  of  approximately  $32,000,000,  as  againsjb  only 
$41,000,000  paid  out  to  all  the  common  stockholders  during  this  period. 
Indeed,  in  1925-28,  when  not  a  cent  of  dividends  was  paid  to  common 
stockholders,  nearly  $7,000,000  was  paid  out  in  bonuses  to  officials. 

Finance  capitalism  also  accustoms  the  public  to  regard  the  securities 
of  corporations  as  paper,  to  be  used  in  institutionalized  gambling  on  the 
stock  exchange.  Attention  is  concentrated  on  the  possibility  of  specula- 
tive profits  in  financial  manipulation  rather  than  on  the  assurance  of 
steady  earnings  on  bona-fide  capitalization.  Industry  has  been  further 
jeopardized  through  the  tendency  of  finance  capitalism  to  encourage  ex- 
cessive investment  in  plants.  Money  may  be  made  for  a  time  through 
floating  the  securities  of  new  companies,  in  spite  of  an  overcrowding  of 
producers  in  a  particular  industry.  The  ultimate  result,  however,  is 
overproduction,  glutted  markets,  and  finally  factories  abandoned  or  run- 
ning on  part  time,  and  other  symptoms  of  industrial  decline.  In  real 
estate,  finance  capitalism  encourages  building  out  of  all  proportion  to 
actual  needs.  Investment  companies  may  earn  large  immediate  profits 
by  selling  mortgage  bonds  on  new  structures,  even  though  these  build- 
ings, when  erected,  may  have  few  or  no  tenants  and  will  soon  pass  into 
bankruptcies  and  receiverships,  saddling  the  owners  of  these  bonds  with 
heavy  or  total  losses. 

Finance  capitalism  has  all  but  wrecked  our  transportation  and  electric 
utility  systems.  In  its  earliest  phases,  it  encouraged  overinvestment  in 
canals.  Then  came  the  fifty-year  period  in  which  railroads  were  viewed 
by  men  like  Jay  Gould  and  Daniel  Drew  more  as  gambling  machines 
than  as  transportation  systems.  But  little  or  nothing  was  learned  from 
the  disastrous  experience  of  the  railroads  with  finance  capitalism.  The 
same  methods  were  applied  on  a  grander  and  more  disastrous  scale  in 
our  electric  utility  industry.  The  results  were  fully  illustrated  by  the 


9  See  J.  T.  Flynn,  Graft  in  Business,  Vanguard,  1931,  Chapter  VIII. 


132       CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

collapse  of  the  Insull  empire  in  1932  and  the  Associated  Gas  and  Electric 
Company  in  1940.  Insull  and  Hopson  were  only  conspicuous  examples. 
Most  fundamental  of  all  the  evils  of  finance  capitalism,  probably,  is 
the  antagonism  of  finance  capitalism  to  the  provision  of  that  mass  pur- 
chasing power  upon  which  the  very  existence  of  our  economic  system 
depends.  The  speculative  profits  of  finance  capitalism  are  almost  in- 
variably derived  by  methods  which  deplete  mass  purchasing  power. 
Finance  capitalism  takes  the  cream  of  the  profits  off  every  enterprise 
that  it  finances,  "siphons  out"  the  earnings  and  resources  of  these  busi- 
nesses, and  drains  the  proceeds  into  the  pockets  of  the  bankers,  under- 
writers, and  security  manipulators,  to  the  disadvantage  of  wage  earners 
in  these  industries.  It  also  gouges  their  security-holders  and,  all  too 
frequently,  leaves  the  industry  or  organization  "financed"  unable  to  func- 
tion efficiently  for  any  considerable  period  of  time.  It  need  hardly  be 
pointed  out  that  those  who  get  the  profits  are  the  least  needy  class  in 
society  and  they  contribute  almost  nothing  to  mass  purchasing  power. 
Conspicuous  also  has  been  the  depression  of  the  farmers,  aggravated  in 
many  cases  by  financial  control  over  farm  mortgages  and  markets: 

It  is  only  beginning  to  be  dimly  recognized  that  in  a  plenty  economy  there  is 
and  must  be  between  the  interests  of  business  and  those  of  finance  an  irrepres- 
sible conflict.  The  normal  processes  of  finance  are  poisonous  to  business. 
Finance  causes  instability.  One  way  to  make  financial  profits  is  to  wait  until 
business  starts  to  be  profitable,  and  then  lend  money  to  someone  to  set  up  a 
competing  plant.  Then  when  everybody  naturally  goes  bankrupt,  the  lender  gets 
the  property,  and  if  recovery  ever  docs  take  place,  he  is  in  on  the  ground  floor. 
Business  pays  the  cost.  Another  way  is  to  buy  securities  when  they  threaten 
to  go  up,  and  hold  them  so  that  they  will  go  up,  and  sell  them  when  they 
threaten  to  go  down,  and  sell  short  so  as  to  help  them  go  down.  Business  pays 
the  cost.  A  third  way  to  get  financial  profits  is  to  set  up  an  investment  trust  or 
a  holding  company  that  is  so  complicated  that  the  small  investor  cannot  see  just 
how  he  is  to  be  rooked.  When  his  investment  is  gone,  he  becomes  a  poor  cus- 
tomer for  legitimate  business.  A  fourth  way  is  to  take  a  commission  from  a 
foreign  government  for  selling  bonds  to  people  who  ask  their  banker  for  dis- 
interested advice.  In  any  case,  business  pays  the  costs  either  in  rising  overhead 
or  falling  sales  or  both.  Businass  needs  stability  to  prosper,  finance  gets  its 
profits  from  instability  .  .  .  Over  this  conflict  of  interest  there  must  be  a  battle, 
because,  so  long  as  finance  dominates  business,  both  are  headed  for  the  precipice, 
and  finance  will  not  loose  its  grip  without  a  fight.  The  question  whether  they 
will  go  over  the  edge  together  will  be  settled  by  whether  business  has  the  vitality 
to  rouse  itself  and  muster  the  power  to  reduce  finance  to  its  proper  place  as 
the  servant  of  production.  .  .  . 

About  one  more  shot  of  that  kind  of  thing  (the  poison  administered  by  finance 
to  business  before  1929),  and  it  is  hard  to  see  how  it  will  be  possible  to  avoid 
the  final  collapse  of  our  social  order.  The  crossroads  of  history  will  be  the  place 
where  we  do  or  do  not  develop  means  for  keeping  money  out  of  Wall  Street  and 
making  it  travel  up  and  down  Main  Street  where  it  belongs.  No  country  has 
ever  got  out  of  a  depression  without  some  kind  of  expansion.  The  important 
thing  to  keep  in  mind  now  is  that  if  the  expansion  is  applied  to  the  buying  end 
it  will  not  necessarily  kill  the  patient.10 


10  David  Cushman   Coyle,   The   Irrepressible   Conflict:   Business   versus  Finance, 
privately  printed,  pp.  37  ff. 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS        133 

These  are  relevant  observations,  if  we  remember  that  when  Mr.  Coyle 
speaks  of  finance  he  means  present-day  speculative  finance.  No  sane 
person  can  question  the  enormous  service  rendered  by  legitimate  finan- 
cial institutions  to  business. 

There  have  been  a  number  of  other  disastrous  results  from  the  policies 
and  practices  of  finance  capitalism  that  deserve  at  least  passing  mention 
in  this  place.  In  the  first  place,  we  may  mention  the  undermining  of 
the  stability  of  American  banks,  as  the  result  of  the  domination  of  bank 
practices  by  speculative  ideals.  Between  1920  and  the  beginning  of 
1933,  there  were  about  11,000  bank  failures  in  the  United  States,  leaving 
only  18,800  banks  open  to  do  business  on  the  eve  of  the  bank  holiday. 
The  deposits  involved  in  these  bank  failures  amounted  to  approximately 
5  billion  dollars.  There  are  fewer  valid  reasons  for  bank  failures  in  the 
United  States  than  in  any  other  civilized  country.  This  is  so  because 
of  our  vast  wealth  and  resources  and  the  possibility  of  making  large 
bank  profits  through  legitimate  forms  of  banking  enterprise.  Had  our 
bankers  been  willing  to  accept  reasonable  profits,  there  would  have  been 
no  reason  whatever  for  them  to  take  such  chances  as  they  did  on  highly 
speculative  ventures.  Their  responsibility  for  our  bank  failures  is  well 
illustrated  by  comparison  with  conditions  in  Canada  and  Great  Britain. 
In  Canada,  the  difficulties  of  banking  are  far  greater  than  in  the  United 
States  because  of  the  smaller  population,  its  scattered  character,  and  the 
vast  area  involved.  There  is  no  such  opportunity  for  legitimate  bank- 
ing gains  in  Canada  as  there  is  in  this  country.  But  Canadian  bankers 
stuck  to  banking,  and  there  has  been  only  one  bank  failure  in  Canada 
since  1914,  and  this  was  a  relatively  small  one  involving  liabilities  of  not 
more  than  $20,000,000.  There  has  not  been  a  bank  failure  in  England 
in  contemporary  times.  Some  improvement  in  our  shaky  banking  sys- 
tem was  brought  about  by  the  New  Deal  legislation  of  1933-34,  but  the 
system  was  patched  up  rather  than  thoroughly  overhauled. 

Extremely  ominous  and  difficult  to  reduce  is  the  staggering  burden  of 
debt  that  finance  capitalism  has  piled  up  as  a  result  of  its  encourage- 
ment of  overconstruction,  its  promotion  of  installment  buying,  and  its 
backing  of  wildcat  speculation.  It  is  quite  possible  that  these  lines  of 
action  will  pull  down  the  whole  capitalistic  system  unless  a  very  exten- 
sive "write-off"  is  effected — something  that  our  finance  capitalists  will 
resist  to  the  last. 

The  long-term  public  and  private  debts  in  the  United  States  amounted 
to  134  billions  at  the  end  of  1932.  The  short-term  debts  amounted  to 
approximately  104  billions.  This  made  a  total  of  238  billion  dollars. 
Obviously  there  was  only  a  very  slight  margin  between  debts  and  total 
national  wealth,  which  is  variously  estimated  by  experts  today  as  some- 
where between  200  and  300  billion  dollars.  It  is,  therefore,  quite  ap- 
parent that  far  the  greater  proportion  of  our  national  wealth  is  pledged 
to  meet  credit  obligations  incurred  in  the  past. 

The  debt  menace  still  hangs  over  us.  The  Roosevelt  policies  have 
only  postponed  the  day  of  reckoning.  The  public  debt  has  developed  by 


134       CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

leaps  and  bounds  since  1932.  And  the  methods  of  finance  capitalism 
which  have  created  and  rapidly  extended  the  current  debt  structure  have 
not  been  altered  in  any  fundamental  way.  The  national  debt  increased 
from  14.4  billions  in  1930  to  over  100  billions  in  1942.  State  and  local 
debts  increased  from  16.9  billions  in  1929  to  17.8  billions  in  1937.  The 
total  debt  burden  of  the  country  in  1937  was  estimated  to  be  over  250 
billion  dollars.  It  is  far  over  300  billions  today. 

Another  important  item  to  be  considered  is  the  relationship  of  debt  to 
production.  The  capitalistic  system  is  relatively  safe  only  when  there 
is  a  definite  and  fixed  one-to-one  relationship  between  the  growth  of 
debt  and  the  growth  of  production.  In  his  ultra-scientific  volume  on 
Debt  and  Production,  an  able  engineer,  Bassett  Jones,  points  out  that 
this  safe  relationship  has  not  existed  in  the  United  States  since  1910. 
The  curve  of  production  growth  has  fallen  off  ever  since  that  time,  while 
the  curve  of  debt  growth  has  increased  at  an  alarming  rate.  The  re- 
sult is  that  today  our  productive  system  cannot  support  more  than  one 
sixth  of  the  capital  claims  that  have  been  piling  up  against  it  for  the  last 
twenty  years.  The  implications  of  this  situation  are  staggering. 

A  very  disastrous  influence  of  finance  capitalism  upon  business  in  the 
way  of  lessening  the  relative  income  of  productive  business,  cutting  down 
the  income  of  producers — farmers  and  industrialists  alike — decreasing 
the  income  going  into  wages  and  salaries,  increasing  living  costs  and  thus 
reducing  mass  purchasing  power,  is  to  be  detected  in  the  amazing  in- 
crease of  overhead  costs  since  the  first  World  War.  Overhead  costs  com- 
prise all  charges  of  any  sort  involved  in  moving  goods  from  the  producers 
— factories  or  farms — to  the  ultimate  consumers,  and  in  distributing 
them  to  the  latter.  The  total  cost  of  operating  all  of  our  national  in- 
dustrial plant  in  1917  was  approximately  equal  to  the  cost  of  operating 
it  in  1932.  Yet  the  cost  of  overhead  increased  by  no  less  than  230  per 
cent  during  those  fifteen  years.  In  1917,  when  producers  received  $1 
for  raising  food  or  manufacturing  consumers'  goods,  those  who  were 
engaged  in  the  various  overhead  operations  received  $1  also.  Today, 
for  every  dollar  that  goes  to  producers  no  less  than  $2.30  goes  into  over- 
heatf  charges.  For  example,  every  consumer  pays  62  cents  out  of  every 
dollar  of  living  costs  for  overhead  charges  on  his  necessities  of  life. 
This  increase  of  overhead  has  been  due,  in  part,  to  the  creation  of  hold- 
ing companies,  and  the  like,  that  render  little  or  no  practical  service  in 
producing  goods  or  in  moving  them  to  the  consumers,  but  which  do 
impose  a  vast  charge  upon  society  in  order  to  pay  dividends  to  these 
companies.  Advertising  is  another  source  of  large  overhead  costs. 

Walter  Rautenstrauch  has  indicated  the  enviable  condition  that  would 
exist  if  overhead  costs  had  not  been  inflated  in  the  period  since  1917: ll 

1.  We  would  need  12,300,000  more  producers; 

2.  And  no  more  overheaders ; 


Who  Gets  the  Money t    Harper,  1934,  p.  48. 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS        135 

3.  And  an  increase  in  the  producers'  income  of  56  per  cent  over  its 
1932  level; 

4.  And  an  increase  in  the  fanners'  income  of  216  per  cent  over  its 
1932  level 

It  is  obvious  that  this  inordinate  increase  of  overhead  charges  played 
a  large  role  in  causing  the  economic  depression  of  1929,  decreasing  the 
purchasing  power  of  the  mass  of  Americans,  and  bringing  capitalistic 
society  to  its  knees.  There  will  be  little  chance  of  rehabilitating  capital- 
ism until  this  condition  is  corrected.  It  is  true  that  there  are  many 
engaged  in  overhead  services  who  receive  modest  incomes  and  contribute 
to  the  purchasing  power  of  the  country.  But  most  of  the  overhead  goes 
to  relatively  parasitic  super-corporations  and  holding  companies  and 
the  rich  at  the  top  of  the  economic  pyramid,  who  neither  can  nor  will 
spend  any  large  proportion  of  their  incomes. 

The  operations  of  American  finance  capitalism  outside  of  our  own 
country  have  been  just  about  as  disastrous  to  the  mass  of  American 
investors.  These  operations  are  usually  known  as  financial  imperialism. 
After  the  first  World  War,  American  investments  abroad  increased 
greatly.  In  1913,  our  foreign  investments  amounted  to  about  2.5  bil- 
lion dollars.  We  owed  abroad  nearly  twice  this  amount.  After  1914, 
the  situation  changed  markedly.  A  large  part  of  our  foreign  indebted- 
ness was  canceled  against  payments  for  war  materials.  The  American 
public  bought  widely,  optimistically,  and  indiscriminately  almost  any 
foreign  securities  offered,  and  American  companies  made  heavy  invest- 
ments in  plant  and  equipment,  particularly  in  the  South  American 
countries.  By  the  end  of  1929,  our  investments  abroad  had  reached  the 
astonishing  total  of  nearly  18  billion  dollars.  Since  1929  the  day  of 
reckoning  has  come,  and  the  United  States  is  beginning  to  count  the 
cost  of  becoming  banker  to  the  world.  In  excess  of  6  billion  dollars  of 
our  foreign  investments,  exclusive  of  war  debts,  were  in  default  in  1933. 
No  small  part  of  this  loss,  the  bulk  of  which  falls  on  the  innocent  and 
helpless  individual  investor,  must  be  counted  a  cost  of  our  imperialistic 
tendencies. 

Despite  the  heavy  losses  sustained  by  individual  investors,  financial 
imperialism  has  paid  the  great  investment  banks  handsomely.  They 
quickly  unloaded  the  foreign  bonds  on  lesser  banks,  and  made  a  good 
profit  on  the  operation.  The  lesser  banks,  in  turn,  unloaded  the  foreign 
securities  on  their  clients,  the  latter  of  whom  ultimately  held  the  bag 
and  bore  the  losses  resulting  from  the  avarice  and  irresponsibility  of 
the  great  investment  banks  in  the  field  of  financial  imperialism. 

Not  only  has  finance  capitalism  undermined  the  capitalistic  system  as 
a  whole  by  its  speculative  practices,  and  not  only  is  it  being  challenged 
by  the  growth  of  state  capitalism,  but  it  also  appears  to  be  on  the 
decline  because  even  capitalistic  business  is  gradually  escaping  from  its 
control.  Indeed,  it  is  not  unfair  to  say  that  finance  capitalism  has  now 
reached  its  twilight  period,  even  if  private  capitalism  continues  to  be 
powerful  for  some  time  in  the  United  States. 


136       CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

These  rather  startling  facts  were  demonstrated  by  voluminous  evidence 
given  before  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  in  Washing- 
ton in  1938-39.  This  is  analyzed  and  summarized  with  characteristic 
insight  and  clarity  by  Stuart  Chase  in  two  brilliant  articles  in  Harper's 
Magazine  for  February  and  March,  1940. 

In  the  old  days,  finance  capitalism  prospered  and  enjoyed  a  strangle 
hold  on  industry  because  many  new  industries  were  being  established 
and  older  industries  were  expanding  their  capital  plant  to  produce  more 
goods.  The  investment  bankers  loaned  the  money  for  plant  expansion 
and  sold  bonds  for  this  and  for  the  new  industries,  as  well  as  marketing 
the  stocks  which  were  issued.  It  was  difficult  to  build  a  new  plant  or 
to  expand  an  old  one  unless  the  investment  banks  would  make  the  loans 
and  underwrite  the  sale  of  securities. 

In  the  1920's,  business  expansion  was  kept  up  by  some  five  main  factors 
or  influences:  (1)  housing  construction  after  the  first  World  War;  (2) 
extensive  investments  in  foreign  countries  and  the  expansion  of  financial 
imperialism;  (3)  the  growth  of  consumer  credit  and  installment  buying; 
(4)  tolerance  of  large  inventory  accumulations;  and  (5)  government 
construction,  especially  in  the  way  of  automobile  highways  and  school 
buildings. 

Since  the  depression,  business  expansion  and  the  demand  for  loans 
from  investment  bankers  have  fallen  off  markedly  for  a  number  of 
reasons:  (1)  technological  improvements,  leading  to  increased  efficiency 
of  capital  plants  and  lessening  the  need  for  plant  expansion;  (2)  over- 
production, as  a  result  of  inadequate  mass  purchasing  power;  (3)  the 
disastrous  experience  with  foreign  investments  and  the  closing  of  many 
areas  to  foreign  financial  penetration,  as  a  result  of  economic  nationalism, 
totalitarian  economics  and  war;  (4)  the  decline  in  the  rate  of  popula- 
tion growth;  and  (5)  the  fear  of  New  Deal  policies  and  other  current 
trends  by  business  and  finance — i.e.  lack  of  confidence.  Though  business 
profits  in  1936-37  were  about  what  they  were  in  1928-29,  the  re- 
investment in  business  enterprise  was  only  about  one  third  of  what  it 
was  in  1928-29.  Most  of  the  business  expansion  since  1929  has  been 
due  to  government  investments  and  enterprise  under  the  New  Deal,  such 
as  P.W.A.,  W.P.A.,  and  other  federal  projects. 

Hence,  the  demand  for  the  services  of  investment  banks  in  granting 
loans  and  floating  securities  has  fallen  off  to  an  amazing  extent.  On 
top  of  this  is  the  impressive  and  ominous  fact  that,  even  when  plants 
are  expanded  or  new  plants  built,  the  great  corporations  finance  this 
expansion  from  their  own  funds.  These  funds  are  drawn  mainly  from 
three  sources:  (1)  depreciation  reserves,  (2)  depletion  reserves,  and 
(3)  undistributed  corporate  profits  and  surpluses.  Between  1925  and 
1940,  American  business  put  aside  some  63  billion  dollars  in  depreciation 
reserves  and  6  billion  dollars  in  depletion  reserves.  Between  1922  and 
1929,  some  15  billion  dollars  were  laid  by  in  undistributed  profits,  and 
this  fund  has  since  been  increased,  in  spite  of  its  temporary  taxation 
by  the  federal  government. 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS        137 

We  may  give  some  examples  of  this  financing  of  plant  expansion  by 
business  itself,  independent  of  investment  banks.  The  United  States 
Steel  Corporation  raised  $1,130,000,000  out  of  a  total  of  $1,222,000,000 
required  for  plant  expansion  and  reconditioning.  The  General  Motors 
Corporation  financed  a  gigantic  expansion  program  wholly  by  its  own 
funds.  Even  on  Class  I  railroads,  between  1921  and  1938,  less  than 
20  per  cent  of  the  capital  outlay  was  provided  by  Wall  Street  and  in- 
vestment bankers. 

Even  more  striking  as  evidence  of  the  decaying  power  of  finance 
capitalism  and  investment  banks  is  the  fact  that  business  concerns  re- 
quiring long-term  loans  for  expansion  and  other  purposes  no  longer 
invariably  go  to  the  investment  banks.  There  is  a  growing  tendency  to 
short-cut  the  process,  and  go  directly  to  the  great  insurance  companies, 
which  have  a  vast  reserve  to  lend.  In  1938,  for  example,  some  37  per 
cent  of  all  bonds  and  notes  were  handled  through  loans  by  insurance 
companies  and  other  large  savings  institutions.  That  the  trend  is 
upward  here  may  be  seen  from  the  fact  that  in  1936  only  11  per  cent 
of  loans  were  made  outside  of  the  investment  banks. 

Even  though  not  nearly  so  much  money  is  made  by  the  investment 
banks  through  loans  for  plant  expansion  and  in  floating  securities  as 
was  the  case  before  1929,  yet  the  great  investment  bankers  do  still 
control,  not  only  the  corporations  which  have  ceased  to  need  their  loans 
but  also  the  insurance  companies  which  make  many  loans  that  invest- 
ment banks  formerly  made.  This  they  do,  as  already  explained,  by 
interlocking  directorates,  whereby  the  great  investment  bankers  domi- 
nate industries,  railroads,  utilities,  and  insurance  companies.  It  will 
require  more  than  a  falling  off  in  their  loan  market  to  dislodge  them 
from  this  vantage-point  and  the  controlling  power  that  it  gives. 

Industrial   Capitalism,   Industrial  Waste,  and 
Inadequate  Mass  Purchasing   Power 

Attempts  have  been  made,  especially  by  Carl  Snyder  in  his  Capitalism 
the  Creator,12  to  attribute  the  remarkable  developments  in  industry 
and  transportation  during  the  last  two  centuries  to  capitalism.  It  is 
difficult  to  know  just  how  much  of  this  impressive  industrial  evolution 
can  be  attributed  to  businessmen,  dominated  by  capitalistic  outlook, 
and  how  much  it  was  due  chiefly  to  scientists  and  engineers,  who  brought 
about  the  great  inventions.18  It  so  happened  that  these  inventions  took 
place  at  a  time  when  capitalism  dominated  our  economic  order.  Cer- 
tainly, remarkable  economic  expansion  has  taken  place  under  such 
capitalistic  auspices,  but  it  cannot  be  demonstrated  that  this  has  been 
due  to  capitalism.  If  another  type  of  economic  system  had  been  in 
existence,  industrial  expansion  might  have  done  as  well  or  better.  Cer- 
tainly, the  state-controlled  economy  of  Prussia  in  the  eighteenth  century 


12  Macmillan.  1940. 

13  See,  F.  W.  Taussig,  Inventors  and  Money-Makers,  Macmillan,  1915. 


138       CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

demonstrated  far  greater  economic  efficiency  than  the  free  capitalistic 
system  in  England  during  the  same  period.  Or,  again,  the  develop- 
ment of  German  railroads  under  Bismarckian  and  later  German  state 
capitalism  was  far  more  efficient  and  sound  than  American  railroad 
development  after  1870  under  unrestricted  capitalism  and  wildcat  in- 
vestment enterprise. 

The  remarkable  economic  expansion  attributed  to  capitalism  took 
place  during  the  ascendency  of  industrial  capitalism.  This  came  to 
an  end  shortly  after  the  beginning  of  the  present  century,  and  finance 
capitalism  has  surely  done  little  to  stimulate  industrial  development. 
Such  industrial  development  as  has  taken  place  in  the  last  decades  has 
been  due  to  the  momentum  of  the  earlier  industrial  capitalism,  to  the 
impulse  from  the  first  World  War,  to  the  work  of  the  few  industrial 
capitalists  who  have  survived  into  the  present  century,  such  as  Henry 
Ford,  and  to  greatly  increased  governmental  expenditures  since  1933. 
Therefore,  even  if  we  concede  that  capitalism  was  once  a  "creator"  of 
industrial  enterprise  and  business  expansion,  it  can  hardly  be  maintained 
that  it  is  such  in  the  present  stage  of  finance  capitalism. 

Many  critics  of  capitalism  regard  it  as,  at  present,  two  stages  removed 
from  efficiency  and  vigor.  Industrial  capitalism  is  today  under  the 
dominion  of  finance  capitalism,  which  is  more  concerned  with  financial 
speculation  than  with  industrial  production.  For  this  reason,  repre- 
sentatives of  industrial  capitalism  and  their  economic  defenders  lay 
stress  upon  the  antagonism  between  speculative  finance  and  sound  busi- 
ness. It  is  alleged  that  if  the  octopus  of  finance  were  raised  from  busi- 
ness, industrial  capitalism  could  once  more  operate  in  an  efficient  and 
dynamic  manner.  But  the  industrial  engineers  contend  that  even  business 
and  industrial  capitalism  are  notoriously  inefficient  and  laggard,  judged 
by  engineering  standards.  They  contend  that  only  well-trained  indus- 
trial egineers  can  give  us  a  truly  efficient  economy  in  these  times. 

Though  finance  capitalism  dominates  all  forms  of  large  capitalistic 
enterprise  today,  industrial  capitalism  is  still  a  powerful  factor  in  modern 
economic  life.  Its  two  most  serious  weaknesses  are  economic  waste  and 
the  failure  to  turn  back  enough  profits  in  terms  of  wages  and  salaries 
to  provide  for  the  mass  purchasing  power  upon  which  industrial  capitalism 
depends.  Of  course,  the  domination  of  finance  capitalism  over  industrial 
capitalism  is  responsible  for  much  of  the  waste  and  concentration  of 
wealth  which  are  too  often  laid  wholly  at  the  door  of  industrial  capital- 
ism. Moreover,  finance  capitalism  usually  determines  what  shall  be 
done  with  the  earnings  of  industrial  capitalism  and  makes  it  impossible 
for  enlightened  employers  to  return  more  to  the  public  in  the  form  of 
higher  wages,  even  if  they  desire  to  do  so. 

The  vast  amount  of  waste  in  our  productive  and  consumptive  proc- 
esses has  been  made  the  subject  of  an  interesting  study  by  Stuart 
Chase.  He  holds  that  at  least  half  the  available  man  power  of  America 
is  wasted  as  a  result  of  the  unscientific  methods  of  our  competitive 
order: 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS        139 


An  aeroplane  view  of  America  would  disclose  a  very  large  fraction  of  the  avail- 
able man-power  worklcss  on  any  given  working  day;  would  disclose  another 
large  fraction  making  and  distributing  things  which  are  of  no  real  use  to  any- 
body; and  a  third  fraction  taking  two  hours  to  do  a  job  which  engineers  have 
found  can  be  done  in  one — and  which  some  men  are  actually  doing  in  one.  .  .  . 

Half  and  more  of  our  man-power  counting  for  nothing;  half  and  more  of  the 
yearly  output  of  natural  resources  heedlessly  scattered  and  destroyed  ...  a 
billion  slaves  of  energy  turning  useless  wheels,  dragging  unneeded  loads.  Motion, 
speed,  momentum  unbounded — to  an  end  never  clearly  defined,  to  a  goal  unknown 
and  unseen.  If  there  be  a  philosophy  of  waste,  it  lies  in  the  attempt  to  clarify 
that  goal,  to  turn  men's  eyes  towards  the  whyfore  of  the  sweat  of  their  bodies 
and  of  their  brains.1* 

In  1921,  a  Committee  of  the  Federated  American  Engineering  Societies 
published  a  comprehensive  report  on  Waste  in  Industry.  The  introduc- 
tion to  this  report  was  written  by  Herbert  Hoover.  Commenting  on  this 
report,  Raymond  T.  Bye  and  W.  W.  Hewett  conclude  that  Mr.  Chase's 
estimate  of  total  waste  is  "very  conservative."  These  authors  present 
the  following  tabular  summary  of  the  conclusions  of  the  1921  report: 


PERCENTAGE  OF  WASTE  IN  INDUSTRY 


Points  Assayed 

Against  the  Best 

Industry  Plants  Studied 

Men's  Clothing  Mfg 26.73 

Building  Industry    30.15 

Printing 30.50 

Boot  and  Shoe  Mfg 12.50 

Metal  Trades   6.00 

Textile  Mfg 28.00 


Points  Assayed 

Against  the  Average  of 

All  Plants  Studied 

63.78 

53.00 

57.61 

40.83 

28.66 

49.20 


Ratio  of 
the  Best  to  the 
Average  Plant 
1:2 
1:1% 
1:2 
1:3 
1 :4% 
1:1% 


A  plant  in  which  all  possible  forms  of  waste  were  present  would  be  charged 
with  a  hundred  points  in  this  table.  As  no  plant  is  entirely  wasteful  in  every 
respect,  the  number  of  points  in  any  one  case  would  be  less  than  a  hundred. 
In  the  men's  clothing  industry,  for  example,  out  of  a  hundred  per  cent  possible 
waste,  the  best  plant  shows  26.73  as  the  actual  waste  found.  The  average 
clothing  manufacturing  concern  runs  almost  three  times  that,  or  63.78.  It  will 
be  noticed  that  the  average  efficiency  of  industry  is  very  far  below  that  achieved 
by  the  best  plant  in  each  of  the  industries  listed.  The  ratio  of  the  best  plant  to 
the  average  is  approximately  one  to  two.  .  .  . 

The  following  table,  taken  from  the  Hoover  Report,  shows  the  relative  respon- 
sibility for  waste  in  industry  as  assayed  against  management,  labor  and  other 
factors  • 

Responsibility  As- 
sayed Against  Outside 
Responsibility      Contacts  (the  Public, 
Assayed  Against     Trade  Relationships , 
Labor  and  Other  Factors) 

16%  9% 

21  14 

28  9 

11  16 

9  10 

10  40 


Responsibility 
Assayed  Against 
Industry  Management 

Men's  Clothing  Mfg 75% 

Building  Industry 65 

Printing    63 

Boot  and  Shoe  Mfg 73 

Metal  Trades   81 

Textile  Mfg 50 


Tragedy  of  Waste,  Macmillan,  1925,  pp.  269,  274-275. 


140       CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

The  table  indicates  that  more  than  half  the  waste  in  industry  is  due 
to  faulty  management,  while  less  than  one  quarter  of  the  total  waste  is 
due  to  labor.  The  remaining  waste  caused  by  outside  contacts  of  a 
plant  is,  with  the  exception  of  the  textile  business,  apparently  of  little 
importance.  If  we  are  to  eliminate  waste  and  increase  the  efficiency  of 
production,  it  is  apparent  that  management  must  take  the  lead,  for 
management  has  the  greater  part  of  the  responsibility.15 

These  figures  deal  mainly  with  wastes  in  our  industrial  order  between 
the  first  World  War  and  the  depression.  The  waste  has  been  even 
greater  since  1929.  Isidor  Lubin  estimates  that  we  lost  140  billion  dol- 
lars in  potential  national  income  between  1930  and  1938.  Lewis  Corey 
puts  the  loss  for  these  years  as  high  as  200  billions,  and  says  it  is  300 
billion  dollars  if  we  take  into  consideration  unused  potential  plant 
capacity  for  production. 

Not  only  has  business  enterprise  been  wasteful  in  actual  production; 
it  has  also  squandered  disastrously  the  natural  resources  of  the  world 
— forests,  ores,  oil,  land,  waterpower.  This  had  become  a  national 
scandal  as  early  as  the  administration  of  Theodore  Roosavelt. 

The  growth  of  the  super-corporation  and  big  business  has  had  many 
important  results  for  industrial  capitalism.  The  most  beneficial  result 
of  industrial  consolidation  and  big  business  is  greater  efficiency  in  both 
production  and  distribution: 

Not  only  does  big  business  pay  its  workers,  both  salaried  and  wage  workers, 
more  per  hour  than  either  of  the  other  categories;  not  only  are  the  conditions 
of  work  more  favorable  and  the  hours  shorter,  but  also  the  consumer  is  best 
served  by  big  business.  He  receives  more  for  his  money  than  he  does  from  either 
of  the  other  producing  divisions. 

In  sum,  where  big  business  operates,  Americans  have  a  great  advantage  over 
citizens  in  other  societies;  where  little  business  operates,  Americans  may  or  may 
not  have  an  advantage,  and  where  the  old  atomic  individual  enterprise  persists, 
the  various  societies  are  more  or  less  on  a  par.  .  .  . 

Thus  big  business  not  only  gives  the  consumer  more  for  his  money  than  the 
consumer  receives  in  other  societies,  but  big  business  pays  out  in  the  process 
higher  wages  than  little  business  and  much  higher  wages  than  the  profits  the 
average  farmer  succeeds  in  realizing. 

If  the  above  presentation  is  roughly  accurate,  the  higher  living  standard  in 
America  is  to  a  large  extent  the  product  of  big  business.  And,  in  reverse, 
wherever  the  American  standard  of  living  is  unduly  low,  where  labor  is  sweated, 
the  consumer  cheated,  and  the  enterprise  wrecked  by  non-profitable  operation, 
we  usually  find  either  little  business  or  some  older  form  of  production,  such  as 
sharecropping  or  mixed  subsistence  farming.16 

Unfortunately,  along  with  these  advantages,  there  are  adverse  aspects 
of  big  business.  While  absolute  monopoly  can  rarely  be  attained,  suf- 
ficient control  over  production  can  be  secured  so  that  it  can  be  curtailed 
and  prices  can  be  maintained  at  a  fairly  stable  level,  in  spite  of  changes 


15  R.  T.  Bye  and  W.  W.  Hewett,  Applied  Economics,  Crofts,  1928,  pp.  45-46. 
18  Harold  Loeb,  "Twelve  Trust-Busters  in  Search  of  Monopoly,"  Common  Sense, 
January,  1939. 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS        141 

in  general  business  conditions.  This  enables  big  business  to  control 
production  in  the  interest  of  corporate  profits  rather  than  the  service  of 
the  public.  It  also  enables  business  to  keep  prices  high,  in  spite  of 
general  business  depression,  unemployment,  low  wages,  and.  wide-spread 
lowering  of  mass  purchasing-power.  By  applying  drastically  these 
methods,  big  business  can,  as  E.  D.  Kennedy  has  shown  in  his  Dividends 
to  Pay/7  make  itself  relatively  independent  of  economic  fluctuations 
and  the  business  cycle,  so  far  as  profits  are  concerned.  By  curtailing 
expenditures,  big  concerns  can  make  almost  as  much  money  in  depression 
periods  as  in  good  times.  And,  through  accumulation  of  corporate  sur- 
pluses and  undistributed  dividends,  they  can  pay  high  dividends  in  de- 
pression periods,  even  if  earnings  fall  off  greatly.  This  can  be  strikingly 
illustrated  from  the  facts  drawn  from  the  depression  after  1929.  In  1932, 
total  wage  payments  in  the  United  States  were  only  45  per  cent  of  what 
they  were  in  1929,  and  even  real  wages  in  1932  were  only  49  per  cent 
of  the  1929  level.  On  the  other  hand,  dividend  and  interest  payments 
declined  but  slightly  from  1929  to  1932— from  173  to  160  (using  1926  as 
100).  Indeed,  in  1931,  when  employment  and  wages  had  both  slumped 
alarmingly,  dividend  and  interest  payments  were  above  the  1929  level — 
187,  as  against  173  in  1929.18  Another  disadvantage  lies  in  the  usual 
divorce  of  ownership  from  control  in  big  business.  This  makes  it  pos- 
sible for  the  controlling  clique  to  govern  business  policies  in  the  interest 
of  the  corporate  insiders  rather  than  the  stockholders  or  the  public. 

Attacks  upon  big  business,  just  because  it  is  big — a  hangover  of  radical 
frontier  economic  philosophy — are  to  be  deplored.  The  advantages  of 
big  business  should  be  emphasized  and  conserved.  The  disadvantages 
should  be  explored,  exposed,  and  terminated.  What  we  need  to  know 
is  why  the  obvious  productive  advantages  of  big  business  are  usually 
associated  with  anti-social  policies  and  results,  such  as  curtailing  pro- 
duction, reducing  the  income  of  the  masses,  and  crippling  mass  purchas- 
ing-power: 

The  fundamental  questions  in  regard  to  our  economic  procedures  are:  Why 
does  the  United  States  fail  to  utilize  part  of  its  productive  facilities?  Why  are 
ten  million  men,  more  or  less,  not  to  speak  of  equipment  resources  and  knowl- 
edge, prevented  from  creating  needed  wealth?  Why  must  an  undersupplied 
society  support  men  in  idleness,  when  the  idle  men  would  prefer  to  correct  the 
deficiency  in  supplies  ?  19 

And,  while  we  investigate  the  real  evils  of  big  business,  we  should  not 
ignore  the  defects  of  little  business  and  the  inefficiency  of  current  Amer- 
ican farming.  These  should  also  be  investigated  and  exposed.  But 
there  is  little  probability  of  such  action,  because  it  is  politically  un- 
popular. It  is  easy  to  get  popular  support  for  attacks  upon,  and  in- 


17  Reynal  &  Hitchcock,  1940. 

is  See  P.  H.  Douglas,  "Whose  Depression?"  The  World  Tomorrow,  December  28, 
1932. 
19Loeb,  loc.  cit. 


142       CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

vestigations  of,  big  business,  but  it  is  politically  risky  to  question  the 
practices  of  little  business  and  the  farming  groups. 

Before  we  proceed  to  take  up  the  distribution  of  wealth  and  its  effect 
upon  mass-purchasing  power,  we  may  well  present  the  following  table, 
which  indicates  the  distribution  of  national  income  on  a  so-called  func- 
tional basis  in  the  years  before  the  great  depression  of  1929. 

AGGREGATE   NATIONAL   INCOME  SHOWING 
BROAD  FUNCTIONAL  DIVISIONS   1917-1929 

(In  Millions  of  Dollars) 

Individual  Ratio  of 

&  Interest  Wages  & 

Wages  &           Corporate  Dividends  Salaries 

Year                 Totals                Salaries*               Profits  &  Rent  to  Total 

1929 $95,188                 $53,350                 $22,626  $18,804  56% 

1928 94,247                   50,617                  25,242  17,985  54 

1927  87,863                   49,724                  20,523  17,235  56 

1926 87,193                   49,245                   20,671  16,904  56 

1925 86,757                   46,855                   23,432  16,102  54 

1924 77,973                  44,493                  18,168  14,976  51 

1923 75,608                  42,893                   17,968  14,426  56 

1922 66,592                  37,700                   15,071  13,536  57 

1921   58,387                  36,214                    9,034  12,871  62 

1920 73,094                  42,283                  17,831  12,665  58 

1919 69,016                   35,399                   21,823  11,510  51 

1918 60,679                   32,324                   17,875  10,222  53 

1917 55,041                  25,802                  19,038  9,980  51 

*  Maurice  Leven,  Harold  O.  Moulton,  and  Clark  Warburton,  America's  Capacity  to  Cow- 
an we  (The  Brooking*  Institution,  1934),  p.  157. 

Industrial  capitalism  depends  for  its  vitality  and  prosperity  primarily 
upon  mass  purchasing-power.  The  goal  of  industrial  capitalism  is  to 
manufacture  goods,  which  will  be  sold  in  large  quantities  for  relatively 
high  prices,  so  that  a  considerable  profit  can  be  made  in  the  process. 
It  is  obvious  that  no  such  volume  of  goods  can  profitably  be  sold  unless 
the  mass  of  the  population  has  a  sufficient  income  to  buy  them.  In 
other  words,  there  must  be  steady  employment,  good  wages  and  salaries, 
and  a  decent  income  for  the  agricultural  classes.  Only  in  this  way  can 
there  be  sales  which  are  adequate  to  keep  industrial  capitalism  in 
active  and  healthy  operation.  This  is  so  clear  and  simple  that  it 
might  almost  be  regarded  as  sixth-grade  logic.  But  the  captains  of 
finance  and  industry  seem  unable  to  grasp  this  elementary  truth.  We 
have  had  an  amazing  concentration  of  wealth  which  has  destroyed  mass 
purchasing  power  and  brought  capitalism  to  the  very  verge  of  collapse. 
This  fact  may  be  illustrated  from  familiar  American  material. 

The  enormous  income  from  financial  and  industrial  enterprises  since 
the  Industrial  Revolution  has  produced  personal  fortunes  which  would 
have  been  almost  incomprehensible  in  the  days  of  Alexander  Hamilton. 
Concomitant  with  the  growth  of  private  wealth  is  its  unprecedented  con- 
centration in  the  hands  of  a  few  persons.  The  Brookings  Institution 
study,  America's  Capacity  to  Consume,20  illustrated  this  dismal  fact. 


20  By  Leven  Moulton,  and  Warburton,  Brookings  Institution,  1934. 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS        143 

In  1929,  some  6  million  families,  or  21  per  cent  of  the  total,  had  incomes 
of  less  than  $1,000  per  family.  About  12  million  families,  or  42  per  cent 
of  the  total,  had  incomes  of  less  than  $1,500.  Twenty  million  families, 
or  71  per  cent  of  the  total,  had  incomes  of  less  than  $2,500  per  family. 
The  0.1  per  cent  of  the  families  at  the  top  of  the  economic  pyramid, 
with  family  incomes  in  excess  of  $75,000  each,  received  as  much  of  the 
total  national  income  as  the  poorest  42  per  cent  of  the  families  at  the 
bottom  of  the  income  group. 

Contrary  to  general  impression,  the  situation  was  worse  during  the 
New  Deal  period,  though  this  was  the  result  of  the  depression,  and  New 
Deal  aid  produced  a  far  better  situation  than  existed  in  1932.  The 
National  Resources  Committee  studied  family  incomes  in  the  year  from 
July,  1935,  to  July,  1936.  It  was  found  that  the  lowest  third  of  the 
families  received  $780  or  less  per  family,  with  an  average  family  income 
of  $471.  The  middle  third  of  the  families  received  between  $780  and 
$1,450  each,  with  an  average  family  income  of  $1,076.  The  upper 
third  of  the  families  received  incomes  between  $1,450  and  several  mil- 
lions each,  with  an  average  family  income  of  $3,000.  Over  70  per 
cent  of  the  poorest  third  of  the  families  received  no  relief  or  other  aid, 
though  their  average  income  was  only  $471 — a  fact  that  emphasizes 
the  paralysis  of  mass  purchasing-power  through  the  maldistribution  of 
income. 

We  may  emphasize  these  facts  further  by  a  few  figures  taken  from 
income  statistics  in  1928.  The  average  income  of  all  wage  earners 
gainfully  employed  in  1928  in  the  United  States  was  $1,205.  The  un- 
skilled wage  earners  averaged  less  than  $1,000,  and  the  agricultural 
workers  only  slightly  more  than  $500.  More  than  60  per  cent  of  all 
American  families  received  less  than  the  $2,000  a  year  needed  to  main- 
tain health  and  decency.  This  poorest  60  per  cent  received  only  a 
quarter  of  the  national  income,  while  the  richest  1.2  per  cent  actually 
received  just  about  the  same  amount.  In  order  further  to  emphasize 
the  fact  that  the  general  situation  did  not  markedly  change  under  the 
New  Deal,  we  may  reproduce  Walter  B.  Pitkin's  picture  of  how  the 
American  people  fared  in  an  economic  sense  in  1935.21 

INCOME  CLASSES  IN  1935 

Number  in  Each  Class  How  Much  They  Receive  per  Capita 

1.  Upper  class,  very  rich,  about 500,000        $10,000  each,  or  $  5,000,000,000 

2.  Middle  class  12,000,000  1,000  each,  or    12,000,000,000 

3.  Self-suporting     workers,     farmers, 

small  businessmen 34,500,000  500  each,  or    17,250,000,000 

4.  Marginals,  earning  most  of  living, 

but  receiving  some  aid  15,000,000  300  each,  or      4,500,000,000 

5.  Submerged  idle,  mostly  on  relief      65,000,000  75  each,  or      4,875,000,000 

Total   127,000,000  $43,625,000,000 


21  Adapted  from  Pitkin,  Capitalism  Carries  On,  McGraw-Hill,  1935,  pp.  180-181. 


144       CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

That  these  inadequacies  in  mass  income  had  a  disastrous  influence  in 
restricting  purchasing-power  is  self-evident,  but  we  may  illustrate  the 
matter  by  some  relevant  examples.  To  be  very  practical,  one  may  ex- 
amine the  figures  for  1928.  The  approximately  28  million  families, 
made  up  of  persons  with  incomes  under  $5,000,  had  a  total  money  income 
of  about  65  billions.  On  a  fair  budget  computation,  the  most  they  could 
spend  for  manufactured  goods  was  38  billions.  Yet,  in  1928,  we  manu- 
factured goods  (not  including  those  exported)  to  the  value  of  55  billions. 
The  slightly  more  than  1,000,000  persons  with  incomes  over  $5,000  an- 
nually could  hardly  buy  up  the  surplus  of  17  billion  dollars  worth  of 
manufactured  goods. 

Another  demonstration  of  the  inadequacy  of  mass  purchasing-power 
is  afforded  by  the  following  statistics.  Between  1923  and  1929,  the 
value  of  manufactured  products  increased  by  some  10  billion  dollars. 
The  workers,  salaried  classes,  and  farmers  were  supposed  to  buy  up  this 
10  billion  dollars  worth  of  new  goods.  But  wages  during  this  period 
advanced  by  only  600  millions.  The  workers  could  not  buy  the  in- 
creased volume  of  goods  with  only  600  million  more  at  their  disposal; 
the  salaried  classes  had  made  gains  in  income  only  slightly  greater  than 
those  in  wages;  while  the  farmers  were  getting  much  less  in  1929  than 
in  1923. 

How  many  more  goods  could  be  sold  if  income  were  more  equitably 
divided  has  been  indicated  by  Leven,  Moulton,  and  Warburton.  In 
1929,  over  70  per  cent  of  American  families  had  incomes  of  less  than 
$2,500.  If  these  20  million  families  had  all  had  their  incomes  raised 
to  $2,500  each,  they  would,  by  the  spending  standards  of  that  year,  have 
spent  40  per  cent  more  for  food,  65  per  cent  more  for  homes  and  living 
quarters,  65  per  cent  more  for  clothing,  and  115  per  cent  more  for  other 
consumers'  goods  and  services.  Such  additional  expenditures  would  have 
prevented  the  depression. 

There  is  every  evidence  that  the  American  masses  spend  liberally 
for  essential  goods  and  services  when  they  have  the  income  with  which 
to  make  such  purchases.  The  following  table  gives  the  relative  propor- 

PERIOD  FROM  1922  TO  1929 22 

Per  Cent  Per  Cent     Per  Cent  Spent  for 

Income  Classes                                                Saved  Taxes       Goods  and  Services 

$1,000  and  under  33  94 

1,000,  under  $2,000  5  2  93 

2,000,  under  $3,000  11  2  87 

3,000,  under  $5,000  16  2  82 

5,000,  under  $10,000   14  3  83 

10,000,  under  $25,000   22  4  74 

25,000,  under  $50,000  30  8  62 

50,000,  under  $100,000   31  13  56 

100,000,  under  $150,000   35  15  50 

150,000,  under  $300,000   44  16  40 

300,000,  under  $500,000  67  17  16 

500,000,  under  $1,000,000  71  17  12 

Over  $1,000,000 77  17  6 

22  M.  P.  Taylor,  Common  Sense  About  Machines  and  Unemployment,  Winston, 
1933,  p.  97. 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS        145 

tion  of  income  spent  and  saved  by  the  various  income  classes  in  the 
United  States.  It  shows  that  the  rich  can  spend  only  a  small  fraction 
of  their  income  for  goods  and  services. 

If  those  who  control  and  direct  our  financial  and  industrial  life  do 
not  voluntarily  provide  for  a  just  and  efficient  distribution  of  the  social 
income,  there  is  one  way  of  attacking  the  problem  which  does  not  involve 
any  revolutionary  radicalism.  This  is  to  tax  high  incomes  heavily,  turn 
the  money  over  to  the  public  treasury,  and  put  men  to  work  on  govern- 
ment enterprises.  A  considerable  start  has  been  made  in  this  direction 
as  the  result  of  the  income  tax,  which  was  made  constitutional  by  the 
Sixteenth  Amendment  after  many  years  of  patient  effort  by  reformers. 
But  the  income  tax  in  the  United  States  is  still  far  lower  than  that  on 
comparable  incomes  in  Great  Britain  before  1939.  The  following  table 
will  indicate  the  relative  payments  made  on  gross  income  by  the  aver- 
age married  man  without  children  in  England  and  the  United  States  in 
1934,  before  preparedness  costs  boosted  the  English  tax  rate: 

INCOME  TAX  SCHEDULES  IN  THE  UNITED  STATES  AND 
GREAT  BRITAIN   1934  23 

Gross  Income  United  States  Tax  British  Tax 

$       3,000    $         20  $       311 

5,000    100  711 

10,000    480  1,862 

25,000    2,520  7,369 

50,000    8,600  19,654 

100,000    30,100  48,101 

500,000    263,600  307,910 

1,000,000    571,000  639,160 

It  has  been  estimated  that,  if  we  adopted  the  British  income  tax  rates 
(as  they  were  in  1939)  in  this  country,  it  would  yield  our  Federal 
Treasury  in  excess  of  3  billion  dollars  a  year.  As  it  was,  the  total  indi- 
vidual income  tax  return  in  1934  was  $511,399,778.  Until  the  New 
Deal  reforms  there  were  also  various  loopholes,  such  as  the  deductions 
for  capital  losses,  through  taking  advantage  of  which  even  J.  P.  Morgan 
himself  was  able  to  avoid  paying  any  income  tax  in  1931  and  1932. 
Our  estate  and  inheritance  taxes  are  also  far  lower  than  in  Great 
Britain.  It  is  calculated  that,  if  the  British  estate  and  inheritance  taxes 
were  adopted  here,  they  would  yield  an  additional  income  of  750  mil- 
lion dollars. 

The  federal  and  state  governments  are  in  part  responsible  for  our 
failure  to  collect  as  much  as  we  might  from  both  incomes  and  estates. 
Rather  more  than  40  billion  dollars  of  wealth  is  able  to  hide  from  the  tax 
collector  through  the  system  of  issuing  tax-exempt  securities.  At  the  end 
of  1932,  there  were  outstanding  wholly  tax-exempt  federal  issues  of  ap- 
proximately $22,250,000,000,  and  state  and  local  issues  free  from  federal 
taxation  to  the  amount  of  about  $16,500,000,000.  However,  the  issuance 
of  tax-exempt  securities  was  abandoned  in  part  in  1941.  President 
Roosevelt  has  at  times  proclaimed  his  intentions  to  introduce  a  program 


23  See  also  below,  p.  197. 


146       CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

of  taxation  in  proportion  to  capacity  to  pay,  but  aside  from  plugging  the 
holes  in  the  income  tax,  placing  a  tax  on  undistributed  corporation  sur- 
pluses, and  some  minor  changes,  there  was  no  substantial  change  in  the 
federal  taxation  policy  under  the  New  Deal  until  the  preparedness  activ- 
ity of  1941.  That  crushing  taxation  lies  ahead  is  now  certain. 

Is  Capitalism  Worth  Saving? 

The  capitalistic  system  is  certainly  not  worth  saving  if  we  could  get 
a  better  system  without  paying  a  price  for  the  change  which  would  be 
greater  than  the  advantages  brought  about  by  the  new  system  of  economic 
life.  To  deal  with  this  question  intelligently,  we  must  make  our  meaning 
more  precise.  If  one  asks  whether  it  is  worth  while  to  save  the  type  of 
capitalism  which  existed  from  1921  to  1933,  the  answer  must  be  in  the 
negative.  We  could  not  save  it  if  we  wished  to  do  so. 

Appraised  against  the  background  of  our  present  stage  of  technological 
evolution  and  our  vast  natural  resources,  the  capitalistic  system  in  the 
United  States  from  1921  to  1933  did  not  make  a  sufficiently  impressive 
showing  to  justify  any  serious  wish  to  retain  it,  even  if  it  could  be  re- 
vived. As  we  have  seen,  over  70  per  cent  of  our  families  did  not  have 
income  enough  to  buy  sufficient  food  to  enable  them  to  live  in  a  truly 
healthy  fashion.  Ninety  per  cent  of  the  families  could  not  purchase 
for  themselves  a  liberal  diet,  such  as  any  self-respecting  person  should 
have  available  in  this  day  and  age.  Ninety-eight  per  cent  of  the  popula- 
tion received  less  than  $5,000  a  year,  whereas  a  system  of  production 
for  use,  in  conjunction  with  our  existing  technology,  could  certainly 
have  produced  an  income  of  $5,000  a  year  for  all  American  adults. 
Forty  per  cent  of  our  American  families  unquestionably  lived  in 
poverty,  misery  and  extreme  economic  insecurity  in  192&-29,  the  most 
prosperous  years  which  the  old  capitalistic  system  ever  boasted.  Taking 
into  account  the  potentialities  for  the  production  and  distribution  of 
wealth  in  this  country  since  1920  and  the  showing  which  capitalism 
actually  made  in  the  years  when  it  was  most  free  to  demonstrate  its 
powers,  we  may  safely  say  that  it  failed  to  justify  its  existence.  This 
verdict  may  be  rendered  without  the  slightest  infection  with  Marxian 
dogma  or  any  passion  for  economic  revolution.  In  passing  a  verdict 
upon  the  contributions  and  virtues  of  capitalism  in  the  United  States,, 
one  must  consider  not  only  what  it  did  but  what  it  might  have  done,, 
if  it  had  produced  the  utmost  possible  within  the  limits  of  our  tech- 
nology and  resources  and  had  distributed  these  products  in  a  reasonably 
equitable  fashion. 

Indeed,  one  may  go  even  further  and  state  that  the  question  of 
whether  we  should  save  the  old-line  capitalism  of  the  period  prior  to 
1933  is  today  a  purely  academic  question,  in  any  event.  It  could  not 
be  saved  in  the  form  in  which  it  existed  from  1921  to  1933.  In  the 
decade  after  1921,  capitalism  was  not  interfered  with  to  any  marked 
degree  by  political  agencies.  The  Harding  and  Coolidge  administrations 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS       147 

believed  thoroughly  in  the  doctrine  that  the  less  government  in  business 
the  better.  Capitalism  was  as  unimpeded  as  it  ever  can  expect  to  be 
in  the  present  stage  of  social  and  economic  evolution.  It  had  every 
opportunity  to  prove  its  worth  and  to  make  its  achievements  permanent. 
As  an  actual  matter  of  fact,  it  folded  up  in  the  terrific  financial  crash 
of  October,  1929,  through  its  own  weaknesses  and  defects.  There  was 
no  governmental  interference  or  threat  of  interference  to  cause  uncer- 
tainty or  fear.  Indeed,  there  was  every  governmental  encouragement  of 
the  theories  and  practices  which  were  being  followed. 

After  1929  Mr.  Hoover,  for  four  years,  attempted  to  rehabilitate  and 
restore  this  capitalism  by  strictly  orthodox  deflationary  capitalistic  pol- 
icies. His  administration  ended  in  the  most  abysmal  depth  of  depression 
and  despondency  which  the  American  economic  system  has  ever  known. 
These  facts  indicate  that  capitalism,  even  under  the  most  favorable 
conditions,  could  not  of  itself  maintain  economic  health  nor  could  it 
be  restored  to  health  by  traditional  methods.  It  is  quite  possible  that, 
by  the  most  drastic  deflationary  methods  after  1929,  at  the  cost  of 
tremendous  suffering  to  the  masses,  the  system  might  have  staggered  to 
its  feet  again  for  a  few  years.  But  the  events  of  the  Hoover  administra- 
tion, together  with  many  other  evident  considerations,  have  thoroughly 
demonstrated  that  we  can  no  longer  rely  upon  the  fiction  of  the  auto- 
matic business  cycle  to  restore  capitalism  to  prosperity.  There  is  little 
evidence  that,  in  our  day,  there  can  be  any  automatic  recovery  from 
serious  depressions. 

We  may,  therefore,  fairly  conclude,  Wendell  Willkie  to  the  contrary 
notwithstanding,  that  the  essentially  laissez-faire  capitalism  of  Coolidge 
days,  to  which  so  many  of  our  economic  royalists  look  back  with  a 
sentimental  nostalgia,  would  not  be  worth  saving,  and  could  not  be 
saved  if  we  wanted  to  preserve  it.  Such  steps  as  will  be  necessary  to 
rehabilitate  it  would  require  fundamental  changes  in  its  character. 

Much  more  to  the  point  is  the  question  of  whether  or  not  we  would 
find  it  worth  while  to  preserve  a  form  of  capitalism  which  is  capable  of 
preservation.  In  other  words,  can  any  form  of  capitalism  be  made  to 
work,  and  would  its  achievements  justify  us  in  cherishing  and  continu- 
ing it?  This  is  a  question  upon  which  there  may  be  legitimate  differ- 
ences of  opinion,  and  one  which  only  a  cock-sure  dogmatist  would  dare 
to  answer  definitively  at  the  present  time. 

In  certain  countries,  an  economic  system  which  is  basically  capitalistic 
has  operated  fairly  well,  considering  the  resources  and  financial  burdens 
of  the  states  involved.  In  England  from  1919  to  1939,  capitalism 
weathered  passably  well  difficulties  far  greater  than  those  met  with  in 
the  United  States.  England's  technology  is  inferior  to  ours,  her  natural 
resources  are  far  more  limited,  and  her  financial  burdens  are  infinitely 
greater.  In  the  Scandinavian  countries,  in  Finland,  in  Czechoslovakia, 
in  Holland,  and  in  certain  other  small  states,  the  capitalistic  system 
ran  along  fairly  smoothly  until  invaded  by  Germany.  Whether  capital- 
ism in  these,  countries  possessed  sufficient  strength  to  have  made  its 


148       CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

existence  permanent,  had  it  not  been  for  the  second  World  War,  is  a 
question  which  no  sensible  person  would  presume  to  answer  today. 

In  the  case  of  all  the  states  which  we  have  mentioned  above,  the 
capitalism  which  existed  bore  little  resemblance  to  that  of  the  Coolidge 
era  in  the  United  States.  In  England,  finance  capitalism  was  limited 
in  extent  and  closely  regulated  by  the  state.  Not  a  bank  has  failed  in 
England  in  modern  times.  Half  the  families  in  England  are  members  of 
some  cooperative  enterprise.  Even  the  Tory  government  began  the 
nationalization  of  the  coal  mines  late  in  1937.  Labor  unionism  had 
been  fully  accepted  in  England  for  more  than  half  a  century.  An 
elaborate  system  of  social  insurance  had  been  in  operation  in  England 
for  upwards  of  thirty  years.  There  arc  competent  economists  who 
believe  that,  if  the  United  States  were  run  on  the  social  and  economic 
lines  of  Tory  England  in  1938,  the  result  would  be  so  marked  and  bene- 
ficial that  the  Coolidge  era  would  appear,  by  comparison,  like  the  bot- 
tom of  a  severe  depression.  The  author  of  this  book  shares  this  view 
most  heartily.  In  the  Scandinavian  countries,  there  was  a  marked  de- 
velopment of  both  cooperation  and  state  capitalism,  which  seemed  to  add 
materially  to  the  prosperity  and  permanence  of  the  economy.  If  the 
Swedish  procedure  could  be  applied  wholesale  to  the  United  States,  it 
is  probable  that  the  results  would  be  even  more  impressive  than  the 
operation  of  the  American  economy  after  the  English  model, 
tern  are  introduced  in  this  country,  the  system  will  neither  be  worth 
preserving  nor  capable  of  preservation. 

In  normal  times,  approximately  three  quarters  of  the  federal  budget 
is  devoted  to  paying  for  past  wars  and  getting  ready  for  future  wars. 
In  an  extended  war,  costing  more  than  200  billion  dollars  and  bringing 
about  wartime  socialism,  there  is  no  reasonable  prospect  of  the  survival 
of  private  capitalism  as  a  major  factor  in  American  economic  life. 

Radicals  are  inclined  to  sneer  at  the  very  suggestion  of  saving  capital- 
ism in  the  United  States.  They  believe  that  it  cannot  be  saved,  and 
they  maintain  that  its  abuses  far  outrun  its  benefits.  If  the  radicals 
could  offer  us  any  practical  alternative  to  capitalism  which  stands  any 
reasonable  chance  of  being  introduced  at  any  immediate  time  in  the 
future  and  would  be  clearly  superior  to  capitalism,  there  would  be  little 
ground  for  refusing  to  follow  their  lead.  It  cannot  be  assumed  that 
capitalism  is  the  sole  type  of  economy  upon  which  the  Deity  has 
bestowed  divine  approval. 

The  plain  fact  is,  however,  that  there  seems  to  be  no  immediate  or 
practical  alternative  to  capitalism  in  the  United  States.  A  collectivistic 
economy,  producing  solely  for  use,  a  Technocracy,  or  an  extended  de- 
velopment of  cooperative  enterprise  seems  out  of  the  question  as  any- 
thing more  than  a  benevolent  dream  in  this  country  for  some  decades  or 
generations.  Wartime  socialism  may  be  followed  by  post-war  fascism. 

Perhaps  the  most  forceful  argument  against  the  possibility  of  economic 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS        14$ 

planning  under  capitalism  was  presented  by  Abraham  Epstein.-4  He 
argues  that  economic  planning  and  business  stabilization  under  a  system 
of  competitive  capitalism  is  self-contradictory  and  utterly  hopeless: 

The  prospect  of  any  well-managed  corporation  introducing  a  stabilization 
program  at  a  financial  sacrifice  for  the  benefit  of  its  employees  is  really  fantastic. 
The  rare  individual  who  may  be  so  philanthropically  inclined  will  not  remain 
in  business  very  long.  .  .  .  Were  any  corporation  to  embark  on  a  program 
embodying  any  considerable  number  of  these  suggestions,  its  management  would 
be  driven  into  insanity  and  its  stockholders  into  bankruptcy.24 

Furthermore,  successful  stabilization  in  one  industry  might  mean  ruin 
for  others: 

The  success  of  the  B.V.D.  Co.  spells  disaster  for  the  heavy  underwear  concerns, 
while  increased  consumption  of  macaroni  strikes  at  the  potato  farmers. 

Third,  Dr.  Epstein  contends  that  no  real  success  has  ever  been  at- 
tained by  important  business  concerns  in  any  fundamental  type  of 
stabilization.  Even  the  most  humane  employers  cannot  guarantee  em- 
ployment to  more  than  a  fraction  of  their  whole  labor  force. 

Finally,  Epstein  maintains  that  stabilization  seems  particularly  diffi- 
cult in  large  business  establishments,  which  employ  the  majority  of 
American  workers: 

A  check  of  the  various  companies  which  are  reported  to  have  introduced 
stabilized  production  reveals  that  they  are  all  primarily  small  corporations, 
manufacturing  things  which  easily  lend  themselves  to  regularized  production. 
They  produce  soaps,  macaroni,  noodles,  package  tea.  .  .  .  The  total  number 
of  workers  engaged  in  these  industries  does  not  exceed  more  than  a  fraction  of 
1  per  cent  of  the  wage-earners  in  the  United  States. 

Some  Problems  of  Capital  and  Labor 

The  United  States  has  been  notoriously  backward  in  accepting  the 
principle  of  organized  labor  and  collective  bargaining.  Such  policies  as 
these  were  publicly  accepted  and  protected  by  legislation  in  the  civilized 
countries  of  Europe  a  half  century  or  more  ago.  Even  the  German  Em- 
pire fully  recognized  the  principle  of  labor  organization  in  the  last  decade 
of  the  nineteenth  century.  The  United  States  took  no  effective  steps  to 
legalize  real  collective  bargaining  until  the  National  Industrial  Recovery 
Act  was  passed  in  1933.  Even  then  the  government  was  loath  to  enforce 
this  legislation  in  resolute  fashion.  E.  T.  Weir,  Tom  Girdler,  and  other 
steel  men  successfully  defied  the  government  with  respect  to  the  en- 
forcement of  the  collective  bargaining  clause  of  the  NRA.  After  the 
latter  was  set  aside  by  the  Supreme  Court,  more  comprehensive  and 
sweeping  protection  of  collective  bargaining  was  embodied  in  the  Na- 


24  Abraham  Epstein,  "The  Stabilization  Nonsense,"  The  American  Mercury,  Jan- 
uary, 1932. 


150       CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

tional  Labor  Relations  Act,  passed  in  the  summer  of  1935.  Employers 
fought  it  vigorously,  but  the  Supreme  Court  upheld  the  constitutionality 
of  the  act  in  1937.  But  it  has  required  great  courage  and  fortitude  on 
the  part  of  the  National  Labor  Relations  Board  to  enforce  the  Wagner 
Act,  even  with  the  backing  of  the  United  States  Supreme  Court.  Its 
courageous  enforcement  of  the  law  was  attacked  through  a  vicious 
propaganda  on  the  part  of  both  employers  and  reactionary  senators 
and  congressmen.  The  integrity  and  fairness  of  the  Labor  Board  was 
confirmed  by  the  federal  courts,  which  upheld  the  decisions  of  the  Board 
with  amazingly  few  exceptions. 

No  fair-minded  person  would  deny  that  there  were  many  defects  in 
the  older  types  of  labor  organization,  such  as  the  American  Federation 
of  Labor,  Such  things  as  limitation  of  output,  labor  racketeering,  and 
selfish  concentration  upon  the  interests  of  highly  paid  skilled  labor  were 
only  the  more  notorious  of  the  common  abuses.  The  employers  had 
a  case  against  such  deficiencies  in  labor  unionism,  for  the  latter  offered 
to  the  employer  little,  if  anything,  except  the  prospect  of  paying  higher 
wages  for  less  or  poorer  work.  But  the  employers  amply  revealed 
the  bad  faith  in  their  criticisms  of  these  weaknesses  of  the  old-line  labor 
unionism.  Just  as  soon  as  new  and  more  aggressive  unions  appeared, 
like  the  Congress  of  Industrial  Organizations,  relatively  free  from  labor 
racketeering,  repudiating  the  limitation-of-output  policy,  and  providing 
for  the  organization  of  both  skilled  and  unskilled  labor,  most  employers 
began  to  show  a  new  and  unusual  affection  for  the  American  Federation 
of  Labor,  with  all  of  its  defects  which  employers  had  been  denouncing 
for  years.  Their  strange  new  enthusiasm  for  the  latter  was  obviously 
based  on  the  fact  that  it  was  less  aggressive  and  dangerous  to  reactionary 
employers  than  the  new  industrial  unions  under  the  banner  of  the  CIO. 
In  other  words,  what  the  employers  desired  was  not  so  much  reforms 
in  labor  organization  as  relatively  weak  and  non-aggressive  unions. 
The  same  bad  faith  was  evidenced  in  the  persistent  demand  of  em- 
ployers that  labor  unions  incorporate  and  become  responsible.  Yet 
the  employers  have  done  their  best  to  weaken,  wreck,  or  crush  unions, 
thus  making  it  impossible  for  them  to  give  any  true  effect  to  responsi- 
bility, even  if  they  were  willing  to  assume  it.  Responsibility  means 
little  unless  accompanied  by  strength. 

One  may  state  with  considerable  assurance  that  there  is  little  prospect 
for  the  persistence  of  capitalism  unless  the  principle  of  collective  bar- 
gaining is  willingly  accepted  by  the  great  majority  of  employers  and 
strong  and  aggressive  labor  unions  are  legalized  and  tolerated.  Capi- 
talism cannot  endure  without  adequate  mass  purchasing  power,  founded 
upon  high  wages  and  salaries  and  relative  steady  employment.  Em- 
ployers have  repeatedly  and  amply  demonstrated  that  they  cannot  be 
trusted  to  pay  high  wages  and  salaries  of  their  own  accord.  Only 
strong  labor  unionism  and  effective,  collective  bargaining  can  assure 
steady  employment  and  permanent  high  wages.  The  vigorous  labor 
leader  is  the  truest  friend  of  the  enlightened  employer  under  the  capi- 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS        151 

talistic  system.  At  the  same  time,  one  may  reasonably  demand  that 
labor  be  efficient  and  earn  its  wages.  But  studies  of  waste  in  industry 
have  shown  that  employers  have  a  very  slight  case  against  labor  unions 
on  this  ground.  Even  in  the  era  when  the  older  and  more  wasteful 
unions  dominated  the  labor  field,  the  waste  attributable  to  employers1 
policies  and  practices  far  outran  the  waste  which  could  be  attributed  to 
labor.  Indeed,  the  famous  Hoover  report  of  1920  showed  that  the 
waste  due  to  management  was  more  than  double  the  waste  which  was 
attributable  to  labor. 

Some  of  our  best  economists  believe  that  collective  bargaining  might 
be  made  to  work  effectively  if  we  could  bring  about  some  modicum  of 
common  sense,  good-will,  and  information  on  both  sides.  A  powerful 
case  is  made  out  for  this  thesis  by  Sumner  H.  Slichter  of  Harvard 
University  in  his  article  "Collective  Bargaining  at  Work."25  He  gives 
a  very  interesting  actual  case  history  of  an  employer  who  had  been 
maintaining  orderly  relations  with  a  national  labor  union  during  the 
previous  four  years.  Though  he  had  not  previously  believed  in  collec- 
tive bargaining,  he  felt  that  the  NRA  was  introducing  a  new  era  in 
American  industrial  life,  making  collective  bargaining  a  permanent 
feature  of  our  economy.  So  he  signed  up  with  organized  labor  in  August, 
1933,  and  adjusted  his  business  policy  to  the  new  dispensation. 

This  employer  had  nothing  to  guide  him  except  horse-sense,  but  he 
had  a  considerable  stock  of  this.  He  decided  that,  if  he  was  going  to 
get  along  with  organized  labor,  there  were  two  basic  things  which  he  must 
do:  (1)  he  must  give  his  union  employees  some  clear  notion  of  the 
nature  of  his  business  and  the  policies  he  was  following,  and  (2)  he 
must  convince  his  employees  of  his  basic  honesty  and  his  intention  to 
be  fair  to  them  in  his  relations  with  labor. 

Our  employer  knew  that  it  would  be  impossible  to  take  the  rank 
and  file  of  his  employees  into  his  confidence  with  respect  to  business 
methods.  So  he  talked  these  matters  over  in  detail  with  the  business 
agent  of  the  union,  leaving  it  to  the  latter  to  carry  on  as  much  education 
as  possible  with  the  union  workers.  In  his  effort  to  promote  a  sense 
of  fairness,  he  put  a  ban  upon  the  former  procedure  of  easy  and  arbitrary 
discharge  of  workers,  cautioned  his  foremen  to  show  some  consideration 
to  employees,  and  exercised  far  greater  care  in  hiring  new  workers. 
Further,  he  ordered  his  foremen  to  investigate  carefully  the  alleged 
grievances  of  workers.  The  union  officials  were  carefully  consulted 
in  all  matters  of  labor  policy,  and  they  were  found  willing  to  cooperate 
with  the  employer  in  first  warning  and  then  disposing  of  inefficient 
workers. 

The  net  result  was  the  development  of  a  satisfactory  philosophy  of 
industrial  relations.  Moreover,  the  productive  efficiency  of  the  plant 
was  notably  increased  after  collective  bargaining  was  adopted.  The 
workers  had  a  better  spirit  than  before.  Many  of  their  grievances  re- 


25  Atlantic  Monthly,  January,  1938. 


152       CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

lated  to  inefficient  operations  which  cut  down  their  income  from  piece- 
work. When  these  were  remedied,  greater  labor  income  was  assured  and 
with  it  more  efficient  production.  The  one  thing  which  remained  was  to 
convince  the  employees  that  it  is  futile  to  strike  unless  the  employer 
can  afford  to  pay  higher  wages.  Only  a  prosperous  industry  can  raise 
wages.  If  strikes  destroy  the  prosperity  of  an  employer,  labor  is  killing 
the  goose  that  lays  the  golden  egg.  But  the  first  thing  which  is  neces- 
sary here  is  for  the  employers  to  accept  collective  bargaining  as  a 
matter  of  course.  Laborers  will  not  show  too  appreciative  an  interest 
in  the  need  for  a  prosperous  industry  so  long  as  they  have  to  fight  for 
their  very  existence: 

They  would  appreciate  the  need  far  more  keenly  if  American  unions  were 
not  kept  so  busy  fighting  for  such  elementary  rights  as  the  right  to  exist  and  to 
represent  their  members  in  collective  bargaining.  Naturally,  as  long  as  unions 
are  treated  as  outlaw  organizations  by  a  considerable  part  of  industry,  they  can 
scarcely  be  expected  to  have  a  proper  sense  of  their  interest  in  the  employer's 
prosperity.1'0 

An  opinion  opposed  to  that  of  Professor  Schlichter  is  upheld  with 
much  vigor  and  vehemence  by  Marxists  and  other  radicals  who  accept 
the  class-struggle  theory  of  economic  relationships.  They  contend  that 
the  fundamental  interests  of  the  employer  and  the  workers  are  basically 
and  eternally  antagonistic.  Neither  can  make  any  concessions  to  the 
other  without  being  the  loser.  They  contend  that  labor  unions  should 
frankly  accept  the  principle  of  the  class  conflict  and  should  regard  their 
activities  as  simply  a  preliminary  phase  of  that  industrial  warfare  and 
economic  revolution  which  will  ultimately  overthrow  capitalism  and  the 
employers  and  install  the  proletariat  in  control  of  modern  industrial 
society. 

Some  reactionary  employers  have  attempted  to  justify  their  opposition 
to  labor  unionism  on  the  ground  that  unions  are  dominated  by  Marxists. 
This  charge  is  particularly  leveled  at  CIO  unions.  It  has  repeatedly 
shown,  however,  that  Marxists  and  Communists  constitute  only  a  small 
proportion  of  those  under  the  banners  of  the  CIO.  Moreover,  the  em- 
ployers who  made  most  use  of  the  red  herring  of  Communism  showed 
little  enthusiasm  for  the  American  Federation  of  Labor  before  the 
CIO  appeared  on  the  scene.  And  the  Federation  has  been  even  no- 
toriously anti-Communistic.  It  held  out  against  the  recognition  of 
Russia  longer  than  the  arch-reactionary  National  Security  League. 

Labor  organization  and  collective  bargaining  have  unquestionably  made 
greater  progress  under  the  Roosevelt  administrations  than  in  any  other 
comparable  period  in  American  history.  The  legal  status  of  collective 
bargaining  now  seems  firmly  established.  But  a  great  deal  of  statesman- 
ship on  the  part  of  labor  leaders  and  far  more  tolerance  and  understand- 
ing on  the  part  of  employers  will  be  required  before  collective  bargaining 


26  Schlichter,  loc.  cit. 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS        153 

and  high  wages  can  exert  their  due  and  necessary  influence  upon  the 
restoration  and  maintenance  of  American  economic  prosperity  under 
the  capitalistic  system. 

The  Problem  of  Industrial   Unemployment 

The  problem  of  industrial  unemployment  is  probably  the  most  des- 
perate problem  with  which  American  capitalism  will  have  to  reckon. 
There  is  little  prospect  that  American  capitalism  will  be  overthrown  by 
radical  opponents;  but  there  is  very  grave  danger  that  capitalism  will 
be  devoured  from  within  by  the  unprecedented  inroads  of  unemployment. 

There  has  been  a  large  volume  of  unemployment  throughout  the 
modern  world  in  the  last  half  century,  and  particularly  between  the  first 
and  second  World  Wars.  The  amount  of  unemployment  has  varied. 
In  Soviet  Russia,  the  feverish  effort  to  carry  through  the  nationaliza- 
tion of  agriculture  and  an  ambitious  industrialization  program  under 
state  auspices  brought  about  a  labor  shortage,  in  spite  of  the  great 
population.  In  the  fascist  states  the  volume  of  unemployment  was  re- 
duced through  elaborate  public  works  projects  and  the  extensive  arma- 
ment program.  In  France,  with  a  large  peasant  population,  and  with 
what  had  long  been  a  stationary  population,  it  was  rare  that  enough 
man-power  could  be  mustered  at  any  given  place  to  operate  factories 
on  two  shifts.  In  some  of  the  lesser  states  of  Europe,  where  there  was 
considerable  cooperative  enterprise  and  state  capitalism,  unemployment 
was  kept  down  to  a  low  figure.  In  England  there  was  much  unemploy- 
ment after  the  first  World  War,  but  the  problem  was  handled  fairly 
well  as  a  result  of  the  unemployment  insurance  system.  The  latter  was 
also  useful  to  states  on  the  continent  of  Europe  whenever  unemploy- 
ment was  extensive. 

In  the  United  States,  a  natural  population  increase  and  the  vast 
volume  of  immigration,  especially  between  1900  and  1914,  have  pro- 
vided a  large  industrial  population.  Further,  the  United  States  has 
taken  the  lead  in  introducing  labor-saving  machinery,  thus  cutting  down 
the  demand  for  man-power.  For  example,  automatic  machinery  for 
rolling  mills  in  the  steel  industry — the  so-called  hot  strip  mill — wherever 
it  was  introduced,  brought  about  a  97  per  cent  reduction  in  the  man- 
power required.  Throughout  the  steel  industry,  this  reduction  would 
amount  to  about  85,000  of  the  highest-priced  steel  workers.  This  is 
only  one  example  and  by  no  means  the  most  impressive. 

An  important  but  less  sweeping  cause  of  unemployment  is  the  "ra- 
tionalization of  industry" — the  introduction  of  standards  of  efficiency 
which  endeavor  to  eliminate  the  great  waste  revealed  by  the  Hoover 
report  and  similar  studies.  As  a  result,  the  same  volume  is  turned  out 
with  a  smaller  working  force,  even  if  there  is  no  change  in  machinery. 
In  agriculture,  there  has  been  a  comparable  introduction  of  labor-saving 
machinery  and  efficiency. 

In  addition  to  the  steady  unemployment  (as  a  result  of  defects  in 


154       CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

capitalism  and  technological  advances),  there  have  been  fluctuations  in 
employment  by  the  operation  of  the  so-called  "business  cycle."  In 
periods  of  maximum  prosperity,  unemployment  is  at  a  minimum.  When 
the  cycle  slumps  into  depression,  unemployment  becomes  abnormally 
high.  Then  there  has  been  the  less  serious  variation  in  the  volume  of 
unemployment  due  to  highly  seasonal  industries  or  to  seasonal  variations 
in  industries  which  operate  on  a  year-round  basis.  But  all  other  phases 
of  the  unemployment  problem  have  been  dwarfed  by  the  growth  of  an 
ever  larger  body  of  chronically  unemployed  workers  who  are  thrown  out 
of  their  jobs  as  a  result  of  technological  changes. 

Paul  H.  Douglas  estimates  that,  from  1897  to  1926,  an  average  of  10 
per  cent  of  American  workers  were  unemployed  all  the  time.  According 
to  a  Russell  Sage  Foundation  study,  a  10  to  12  per  cent  average  of  un- 
employment is  a  conservative  estimate  for  the  twentieth  century.  Un- 
employment reached  its  height  at  the  beginning  of  1933,  when  the  figure 
was  placed  between  12  and  17  millions.  The  New  Deal  policies  con- 
siderably reduced  the  number  by  priming  the  pump  of  industry.  But 
even  before  the  recession  of  the  summer  of  1937,  there  were  about  7 
million  unemployed  by  private  industry.  The  unemployment  census 
conducted  in  the  latter  part  of  1937  included  over  10  million  workers. 
Since  labor-saving  machines  are  being  introduced  in  more  frequent  and 
impressive  fashion,  we  may  assume  that  the  condition  will  become  even 
more  aggravated  and  distressing  in  the  future. 

War  industries  and  conscription  reduce  unemployment  for  a  time,  but 
at  the  close  of  the  war  the  spectre  of  unemployment  will  be  even  larger 
and  more  grim.  Abraham  Epstein  has  suggested  the  ten  essential  points, 
listed  below,  in  any  effective  program  to  reduce  and  alleviate  unemploy- 
ment. The  New  Deal  legislation  made  a  start  along  all  ten  of  these  lines 
of  reform,  but  it  did  not  go  far  enough  to  much  more  than  offset  the  in- 
crease of  unemployment  due  to  technological  advances  since  1932: 

1.  A  careful  survey  of  unemployment  giving  all  the  facts  about  the  actual 
extent  of  unemployment  and  its  industrial  and  regional  distribution. 

3.  A  sufficient  number  of  efficient  employment  exchanges  to  bring  together 
employers  and  potential  employees. 

3.  Increased  stabilization  of  such  industries  as  can  be  at  least  partially 
stabilized. 

4.  An  expansion  of  public  works  projects  to  provide  employment  for  those 
who  cannot  or  will  not  be  absorbed  by  private  industry. 

5.  Adequate  old-age  pensions  to  remove  the  aged  from  both  employment 
agencies  and  the  bread-lines. 

6.  The  raising  of  the  age  limit  at  which  children  may  be  employed,  thus  tak- 
ing out  of  employment  at  once  the  large  number  of  children  under  sixteen  now 
employed  and  restricting  the  employment  of  those  between  sixteen  and  eighteen. 

7.  The  reduction  of  the  working  week,  as  rapidly  as  possible  and  feasible. 

8.  The  raising  of  wages,  so  as  to  produce  that  mass  purchasing-power  which 
is  essential  to  full  operation  of  our  factory  plant. 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS        155 

9.  The  institution  of  a  nation-wide  housing  program,  which  would  provide 
a  vast  amount  of  employment  on  the  75  billion  dollars'  worth  of  construction 
needed  to  house  the  United  States  decently. 
10.  The  establishment  of  a  national  system  of  unemployment  insurance.27 

Certain  spokesmen  for  private  capital  have  attempted  to  free  employers 
from  responsibility  for  unemployment  by  alleging  that  the  great  majority 
of  the  unemployed  are  really  unemployable — that  they  are  loafers,  de- 
generates, feeble-minded,  or  incapable  of  holding  a  good  job.  But  this 
alibi  was  shattered  by  an  elaborate  survey  by  Fortune  of  WPA  workers, 
against  whom  this  charge  of  industrial  incompetence  was  particularly 
leveled.  The  survey  found  that  the  WPA  workers  were  eminently  em- 
ployable and  only  too  glad  to  get  work  when  the  opportunity  arose. 

Certain  writers,  such  as  Simeon  Strunsky,  Walter  Lippmann,  and 
W.  J.  Cameron,  minimize  the  importance  of  the  increasing  technological 
unemployment.  They  hold  that,  in  the  past,  workers  thrown  out  of  work 
by  machines  have  always  been  able  to  find  employment  in  new  forms 
of  industry  and  that  this  will  continue  indefinitely.  Their  views,  how- 
ever, are  shared  by  few  competent  students  of  industrial  history  and 
contemporary  economic  life. 

Workers  thrown  out  of  employment  by  new  machines  may  be  ab- 
sorbed in  other  lines  of  occupation  only  in  a  new,  dynamic,  and  expand- 
ing economy.  But  in  mature  economies,  like  that  of  the  United  States, 
any  large  number  of  persons  thrown  out  of  employment  by  new  machines 
have  no  prospect  of  finding  work  in  new  industries,  save  in  war  industries. 
While  novel  enterprises  will  appear  from  time  to  time,  even  in  the  present 
stage  of  American  economic  evolution,  they  will  certainly  utilize  the 
latest  forms  of  labor-saving  devices,  and  some  of  them  may  actually  be 
devoted  to  the  manufacturing  of  labor-saving  machinery.  We  are  liter- 
ally on  the  eve  of  a  new  era  in  technological  unemployment.  Within 
another  decade  or  so,  it  would  probably  require  a  15-hour  week  to  pro- 
vide steady  work  for  all  adults  in  private  industry. 

The  importance  of  all  this  for  the  future  of  capitalism  is  apparent  to 
any  thoughtful  reader.  If  private  capital  will  not,  or  cannot,  shorten 
the  working  week  and  spread  employment  sufficiently  to  absorb  the 
unemployed,  the  only  other  solution  under  the  capitalistic  system  is  for 
the  state  to  provide  employment  on  public  work  projects.  If  this  goes 
far  enough,  the  number  employed  by  the  government  may  exceed  the 
number  employed  by  private  industry,  and  state  capitalism  will  gradually 
supersede  private  capitalism.  If  the  state  refuses  to  assume  responsi- 
bility for  the  unemployed,  the  result  is  likely  to  be  revolution,  which 
would  end  both  private  and  state  capitalism. 

Nor  can  any  form  of  unemployment  insurance  deal  successfully  with 
the  volume  of  unemployment  which  is  likely  to  exist  in  this  country. 
Nothing  except  an  ever-increasing  volume  of  state  enterprise  can  take 


27  "Faith  Cures  for  Unemployment,"  The  American  Mercury,  January,  1931. 


156       CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

care  of  the  problem.  Hence  it  is  not  surprising  to  find  even  distinguished 
economists,  drawn  from  the  conservative  camp,  who  are  predicting  today 
that  private  capitalism  is  doomed  in  the  United  States  because  of  the 
volume  of  unemployment  which  it  faces  but  does  not  handle  frankly  or 
effectively  in  peacetime. 

Old  Age  as  an   Industrial  and  Social   Problem 

The  problem  of  old  age  is  closely  related  to  that  of  unemployment, 
for  the  aged  make  up  a  constantly  increasingly  group  of  chronically  and 
unavoidably  unemployed  persons.  The  number  of  Americans  over  65 
years  of  age  has  been  steadily  increasing  since  1880,  when  it  was  3.4 
per  cent.  In  1890,  it  had  increased  to  4.0  per  cent;  in  1920,  to  4.6  per 
cent;  in  1930,  to  5.4  per  cent.  P.  K.  Whelpton  predicts  that,  when  the 
American  population  stabilizes  itself  around  1975,  the  proportion  65 
years  of  age  and  over  will  reach  13  per  cent,  or  in  excess  of  20  million 
persons.  Therefore  the  problems  of  old  age  are  likely  to  become  far  more 
extensive  and  serious  as  time  goes  on. 

Next  to  children,  the  aged  are  the  most  notably  dependent  group  in 
the  population.  At  the  present  time,  about  25  per  cent  of  those  65  years 
or  older  in  our  population  are  dependent  upon  relief  from  private  or 
public  agencies.  Moreover,  about  65  per  cent  of  those  aged  persons  who 
are  not  receiving  relief  through  public  or  private  charity  are  being  sup- 
ported in  whole  or  in  part  by  relatives  and  friends.  Hence  we  may 
regard  ourselves  as  safe  in  contending  that  more  than  half  of  the  aged 
in  the  United  States  fall  into  the  class  of  actual  dependents.  As  they 
increase  in  number,  they  are  bound  to  augment  our  problems  of  private 
and  public  relief. 

Those  over  65  constitute  a  literal — or  biological — old-age  group.  But 
an  even  more  serious  situation  is  arising  from  the  presence  of  a  sort 
of  pseudo-old-age  group — the  occupationally  aged — those  who  are  over 
the  age  of  35,  and  especially  over  40,  who  find  it  ever  more  difficult, 
except  in  a  period  of  extraordinary  industrial  activity,  to  secure  employ- 
ment solely  because  of  their  age.  A  few  years  ago  Walter  Pitkin  created 
a  sensation  by  writing  a  suggestive  book  entitled  Life  Begins  at  Forty. 
But  those  who  better  their  condition  after  40  are  rare  and  fortunate 
individuals  in  American  society.  A  survey  of  employment  conditions 
in  New  York  State  showed  that  very  few  firms  in  any  important  form 
of  private  economic  enterprise  were  willing  to  hire  workers  over  35  years 
of  age.  Forty  was  found  to  be  an  upper-age  deadline  for  taking  on  new 
employees,  which  no  important  industry  failed  to  respect.  Some  banks 
actually  had  an  upper  age  limit  of  20  years  for  bank  clerks  who  were 
to  be  taken  in  and  trained. 

Many  persons  over  35  or  40  do  retain  their  jobs  until  far  past  this  age. 
But,  if  they  lose  their  positions,  they  find  it  almost  impossible  to  get 
new  jobs.  Moreover  it  has  been  repeatedly  shown  that  they  are  more 
likely  to  be  discharged  if  they  are  over  forty.  Appalling  as  it  may  seem, 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC  CRISIS        157 

therefore,  the  great  majority  of  Americans  face  the  prospect  of  being 
unable  to  secure  new  employment  after  40,  and  many  of  them  after  35, 
except  in  periods  of  unusual  industrial  activity  or  unless  they  are  given 
various  forms  of  relief  jobs  by  local,  state,  or  federal  agencies.  Chan- 
ning  Pollock  states  the  economic  implications  of  this  outrageous  situa- 
tion: 

One-third  of  our  population  is  over  40  years  old;  no  work  for  anyone  over 
40  would  mean  pensioning  or  starving  as  many  people  as  live  in  the  States  of 
New  York,  New  Jersey,  Massachusetts,  Maine,  Connecticut,  Ohio,  and  Penn- 
sylvania— almost  the  entire  commonwealth  of  France.  Only  31.75  per  cent  of  us 
are  between  20  and  40,  so  that  anything  approaching  a  universal  decision  that 
this  is  the  span  of  industrial  usefulness  involves  the  requirement  that  38,000,000 
of  us  shall  feed,  clothe  and  house  the  remaining  87,000,000. 

The  whole  idea  is  as  fantastic  as  it  is  inhumanly  cruel  and  economically 
unsound.  Common  sense  tells  us  that,  with  ordinary  care  of  his  body  and 
cultivation  of  his  intelligence,  the  average  man  should  be  at  his  best  around  40. 
For  labor  requiring  skill,  judgment,  and  competence,  those  first  40  years  might 
well  be  regarded  as  preparatory — 20  years  of  schooling,  20  years  of  apprentice- 
ship, and  graduation  into  fitness  to  cope  with  the  perplexities  of  breadwinning.28 

At  the  very  moment  when  persons  over  35  or  40  are  being  thrown  out 
of  work  because  of  their  age,  and  when  many  thousands  of  others  are 
unemployed  because  of  labor-saving  machinery,  the  gainful  employment 
of  hundreds  of  thousands  of  children  in  industry  is  particularly  repre- 
hensible. At  the  present  time,  46  states  have  a  nominal  minimum 
age  of  14  for  full-time  employment  in  industry,  but  8  of  these  states 
provide  exemptions  which  nullify,  in  practice,  the  14-year-old  limit. 
Some  of  the  states,  like  Ohio,  have  admirable  protection  against  child 
labor.  Ohio  prescribes  a  16-year  minimum  for  all  occupations.  In 
only  two  states  is  child  labor  legislation  practically  absent.  Since 
public  opinion  in  the  culprit  states  will  not  bring  about  remedial  legisla- 
tion, there  has  been  strong  pressure  for  federal  legislation  against  child 
labor.  So,  a  federal  law  was  passed  in  1916  excluding  from  interstate 
commerce  goods  produced  by  child  labor.  The  Supreme  Court  declared 
the  law  unconstitutional.  Then  another  law  was  passed  by  Congress 
in  1919,  proposing  to  tax  the  profits  of  establishments  employing  chil- 
dren. But  this  was  declared  unconstitutional  in  1922. 

Despairing  of  getting  adequate  legislation  through  the  gauntlet  of  the 
Supreme  Court,  Congress  adopted  a  constitutional  amendment  in  April, 
1924,  giving  Congress  the  power  to  "limit,  regulate,  and  prohibit  the 
labor  of  persons  under  18  years  of  age."  Ratification  by  the  states 
proceeded  very  slowly.  By  1938  only  28  states  had  ratified  it.  The 
strongest  force  opposing  ratification  has  been  the  reactionary  element 
within  the  Roman  Catholic  Church,  which  appears  to  fear  the  possible 
political  influence  on  children  under  18  which  the  amendment  might  con- 
fer upon  public  authorities.  Liberal  Catholics,  like  Father  John  A. 
Ryan,  have,  however,  been  among  the  most  ardent  supporters  of  the 


28  "Death  Begins  at  Forty,"  The  Forum,  November,  1937. 


158       CAPITALISM  AND  THE  ECONOMIC  CRISIS 

amendment.  However,  if  there  should  not  be  sufficient  liberal  and  re- 
form pressure  in  the  country  to  bring  about  the  ratification  of  the 
amendment,  the  Supreme  Court,  now  that  it  has  taken  on  a  more  liberal 
cast,  may  approve  a  really  effective  federal  law  suppressing  child  labor. 
The  Wages  and  Hours  Act  of  1938  outlaws  child  labor  on  goods  sold  in 
interstate  commerce. 

The  Outlook  for  Capitalism  in  the  United  States 

It  is  symptomatic  of  the  present  weaknesses  in  the  terminal  stages  of 
capitalism  that  various  students  of  the  system  find  a  number  of  defects, 
each  one  regarded  by  the  particular  school  of  criticism  as  adequate  to 
undermine  capitalism.  Thurman  Arnold,  in  his  Bottlenecks  of  Business, 
finds  that  monopolistic  practices,  the  restriction  of  output,  and  the 
maintenance  of  high  price  levels  are  ruining  capitalism.  Other  econ- 
omists, notably  J.  M.  Keynes  and  Alvin  H.  Hansen,  contend  that  capital- 
ism is  being  undermined  because  too  much  profit  is  saved,  as  depreciation 
reserves,  to  be  reinvested  in  the  capital  plant,  which  can  already  turn 
out  more  goods  than  can  be  purchased  by  the  masses.  They  advocate 
great  public  works  projects  and  a  greater  diversion  of  business  profits 
into  wages.  Another  school,  mainly  critics  of  finance  capitalism,  con- 
tend that  capitalism  is  being  hurried  to  extinction  through  speculative 
manipulations  by  corporate  management  at  the  expense  of  absentee 
owners.  Among  these  writers  are  Berle  and  Means,  Lewis  Corey,  John 
T.  Flynn,  and  Max  Lowcnthal.  They  stress  the  fundamental  antagonism 
between  current  financial  practices  and  sound  business  policies. 

Another  group  of  writers,  including  such  strange  bedfellows  as  Stuart 
B.  Chase  and  Herbert  Hoover,  find  that  the  chief  evil  of  capitalism  is 
the  enormous  waste  of  the  system,  both  in  production  and  distribution. 
If  we  could  stop  waste,  capitalism  might  endure  for  generations.  Other 
writers,  notably  socialist  critics,  hold  that  capitalism  is  doomed  mainly 
by  the  hogging  of  the  national  income  by  the  rich  at  the  top  of  the 
economic  pyramid.  This  results  in  the  restriction  of  mass  purchasing 
power,  leading  to  so-called  overproduction  and  threatening  a  general 
breakdown  of  the  capitalistic  system.  Technocratic  critics  like  Walter 
Rautenstrauch  believe  that  capitalism  is  incompetent  today  because  it 
is  directed  by  the  archaic  outlook  and  technique  of  the  money-maker 
rather  than  by  the  efficient  and  economical  procedure  of  the  industrial 
engineer.28 

The  problems  of  capitalism  seemed  to  be  temporarily  solved  as  a  result 
of  the  stimulation  of  industrial  enterprise  by  the  preparedness  program 
and  our  entry  into  the  second  World  War.  But,  in  Buenos  Aires,  back 
in  1936,  President  Roosevelt  himself  warned  against  trusting  to  arma- 
ment industries: 


29  Probably  the  most  comprehensive  criticism  of  the  capitalistic  economic  system 
in  a  single  volume  is  John  Blair's  Seeds  of  Destruction,  Covici,  Friede,  1938. 


CAPITALISM  AND  THE   ECONOMIC   CRISIS        159 

We  know  too  that  vast  armaments  are  rising  on  every  side  and  that  the  work 
of  creating  them  employs  men  and  women  by  the  millions.  It  is  natural,  how- 
ever, for  us  to  conclude  that  such  employment  is  false  employment;  that  it 
builds  no  permanent  structures  and  creates  no  consumers'  goods  for  the  main- 
tenance of  a  lasting  prosperity.  We  know  that  nations  guilty  of  these  follies 
inevitably  face  the  day  when  either  their  weapons  of  destruction  must  be  used 
against  their  neighbors,  or  when  an  unsound  economy,  like  a  house  of  cards,  will 
fall  apart. 

Whatever  temporary  stimulus  to  industry  and  capitalism  may  come 
from  preparedness  and  war,  it  must  end  when  the  war  ceases,  accom- 
panied by  greatly  increased  debts  and  the  problem  of  demobilizing  mil- 
lions of  soldiers  and  reabsorbing  them  in  industrial  enterprise.  More- 
over, there  is  the  grave  danger  that  wartime  regimentation  may  hold 
over  indefinitely  into  peacetime  and  give  us  a  permanent  system  of 
state  capitalism  which  will  bring  to  an  end  the  system  of  private 
capitalism.. 


CHAPTER  VI 

The  Institution  of  Property  in  the  Light 
of  Sociology  and  History 

Basic  Definitions  and  Concepts 

PROPERTY  is  a  complicated  legal  concept  and  social  usage,  involving 
both  things  which  are  owned  and  the  right  of  ownership  thereof.  And 
there  are  a  multiplicity  of  types  of  property  and  modes  of  property  hold- 
ing. The  Universal  Dictionary  thus  defines  property  in  the  sense  of  the 
right  of  possession: 

The  exclusive  right  of  possessing,  enjoying,  and  disposing  of  anything;  owner- 
ship. It  may  be  a  right  unlimited  in  point  of  duration,  and  unrestricted  in  point 
of  disposition,  or  a  right  limited  in  duration,  as  a  life  interest. 

One  of  the  most  famous  definitions  of  property  as  the  right  of  posses- 
sion is  given  by  Sir  William  Blackstone  in  his  Commentaries  on  the  Laws 
of  England: 

The  third  absolute  right,  inherent  in  every  Englishman,  is  that  of  property; 
which  consists  in  the  free  use,  enjoyment,  and  disposal  of  all  his  acquisitions, 
without  any  control  or  diminution,  save  only  by  the  laws  of  the  land,  which  are 
extremely  watchful  in  ascertaining  and  protecting  this  right. 

Another  way  of  looking  at  property  is  to  regard  it  as  a  thing  which  is 
oWned,  according  to  well  established  property  rights.  Viewed  in  this 
sense,  property  is  defined  in  the  Universal  Dictionary  as  follows: 

That  which  is  held  by  such  a  right;  that  which  is  owned;  that  to  which  a 
person  has  the  legal  title,  whether  it  is  in  his  possession  or  not. 

A.  G.  Keller  has  pointed  out  that  nearly  all  forms  of  property  emerge, 
in  practice,  only  when  there  is  competition  for  possession.  For  example, 
Robinson  Crusoe  had  no  property  until  Friday  appeared  on  the  scene. 
As  Stephen  Pfeil  observes,  "The  relation  of  ownership  is  not  a  relation 
between  the  man  and  the  thing  but  between  him  and  other  men,  whom 
he  excludes  from,  and  to  whom  he  gives,  possession.  Property  is  an 
'exclusive1  right  and  where  there  are  no  people  to  exclude,  the  right  cannot 
exist." 

160 


THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY  161 

The  great  diversity  of  property  concepts  and  holdings  has  been  well 
indicated  by  Walton  H.  Hamilton: 

Property  is  a  euphonious  collocation  of  letters  which  serves  as  a  general  term 
for  the  miscellany  of  equities  that  persons  hold  in  the  commonwealth.  A  coin, 
a  lance,  a  tapestry,  a  monastic  vow,  a  yoke  of  oxen,  a  female  slave,  an  award  of 
alimony,  a  homestead,  a  first  mortgage,  a  railroad  system,  a  preferred  list  and  a 
right  of  contract  are  all  to  be  discovered  within  the  catholic  category.  Each  of 
these  terms,  meaningless  in  itself,  is  a  token  or  focus  of  a  scheme  of  relationships ; 
each  has  its  support  in  sanction  and  repute;  each  is  an  aspect  of  an  enveloping 
culture.  A  Maori  claiming  his  share  of  the  potato  crop,  a  Semitic  patriarch 
tending  his  flock,  a  devout  abbot  lording  it  vicariously  over  fertile  acres,  a  Yankee 
captain  homeward  bound  with  black  cargo,  an  amateur  general  swaggering  a 
commission  he  has  bought,  an  adventurous  speculator  selling  futures  in  a  grain 
he  has  never  seen  and  a  commissar  clothed  with  high  office  in  a  communistic 
state  are  all  men  of  property.  In  fact,  property  is  as  heterogeneous  as  the 
societies  within  which  it  is  found,  in  idea,  it  is  as  cosmopolitan  as  the  systems  of 
thought  by  which  it  is  explained.1 

One  fundamental  division  of  property  is  that  between  tangible  and 
intangible.  Tangible  property  is  made  up  of  concrete  things — land  or 
movable  chattels  of  any  type,  such  as  livestock,  tools,  implements, 
jewelry,  or  money.  Intangible  property  is  constituted  mainly  of  legal 
rights  to  certain  uses  and  privileges,  such  as  copyrights,  patent  rights, 
or  good-will. 

Property  is  also  divided  into  real  property  and  personal  property. 
Real  property  includes  land,  buildings,  and  other  immovable  objects, 
while  personal  property  is  made  up  mainly  of  movable  chattels,  such  as 
goods,  or  money.  In  a  broad  way,  the  distinction  between  real  and  per- 
sonal property  is  that  between  immovable  and  movable  objects.  As 
Blackstone  observes,  "Things  personal  are  goods,  money,  and  all  other 
movables  which  may  attend  the  owner's  person  wherever  he  thinks  proper 
to  go."  In  a  large  view  of  the  subject,  intangible  property  is  an  attenu- 
ated and  legalistic  phase  of  personal  property. 

We  ordinarily  think  of  property  as  possessed  by  an  individual,  in  other 
words,  private  property.  But  property  concepts  and  practices  are  far 
wider  than  this.  Property  may  be  owned  not  only  by  individuals  but 
also  by  groups.  In  fact,  during  the  greater  part  of  man's  existence,  prop- 
erty was  owned  by  groups  of  different  sizes  and  types  rather  than  by 
private  persons.  We  ordinarily  look  upon  the  various  emotions  connected 
with  property  as  being  of  a  highly  personal  sort,  but  primitive  clans  and 
tribes,  ancient  city-states,  or  contemporary  fraternal  organizations,  may 
have  just  as  specific  and  passionate  notions  of  property  rights  as  any 
individual  miser. 

The  average  layman  regards  ownership  and  possession  as  essentially 
the  same  thing,  but  they  are  quite  different  legal  concepts.  Even  lawyers 
fall  into  error  when  they  hold  that  ownership  is  a  relation  of  law  and 


1  Article,  "Property,"  Encyclopedia  of  the  Social  Sciences,  Macmillan,  Vol.  12,  pp. 
528-529. 


162  THE  INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY 

possession  a  relation  of  fact.  Ownership  means  that  a  person  has  all 
the  legal  rights  which  relate  to  the  object  owned  and  that  all  necessary 
facts  exist  to  support  this  right  of  ownership.  In  other  words,  ownership 
is  a  complex  of  rights  supporting  possession,  whether  actual  or  not. 
In  modern  law  possession  means  a  direct  physical  relation  to  the  object 
possessed,  power  over  this  object,  and  intent  to  exclude  others  from  any 
similar  contact  and  power.  Viewed  broadly,  ownership  and  possession 
are  both  legal  relations,  but  ownership  is  more  the  passive  right  while 
possession  is  both  a  legal  right  and  an  active  physical  fact. 

It  is  often  assumed  that  property  is  a  creature  of  law  but,  in  reality, 
laws  have  grown  out  of  pre-existing  property  practices  and  usages  and 
constitute  a  rationalization  and  perpetuation  of  social  customs  relating 
to  use  and  possession.  At  the  same  time,  law  has  tended  to  legalize  and 
stabilize  such  social  usages. 

In  primitive  times,  property  rights  were  controlled  primarily  by  custom 
and  usage  rather  than  by  written  law.  But  this  did  not  prevent  property 
rights  from  being  often  very  precise  and  supported  with  vigor.  In  the 
ancient  Near  East,  private  property  became  well  developed,  and  prop- 
erty rights  and  usages  were  embodied  in  written  law  as  well  as  in  custom 
and  convention.  In  the  Code  of  Hammurabi,  the  great  king  of  Babylonia 
about  2000  B.C.,  we  find  a  most  elaborate  legal  recognition  and  regulation 
of  many  kinds  of  property,  with  special  protection  given  to  various  forms 
of  contracts.  There  seems  to  be  good  evidence  that  the  Egyptians  may 
have  had  a  comparable  legal  code. 

Many  of  our  more  important  legal  concepts  in  regard  to  property  grew 
out  of  Roman  law.  Fundamental  in  early  Roman  law  was  the  distinc- 
tion between  res  mancipiae,  or  a  Roman  farm  and  its  equipment,  even 
including  slaves,  and  other  property,  such  as  merchandise.  The  res 
mancipiae  was  regarded  as  more  dignified  and  important  property  than 
other  holdings,  and  could  only  be  disposed  of  by  means  of  a  ceremonial 
contract  or  mancipium.  By  including  in  the  basic  concept  of  res  man- 
cipiae both  real  property  and  movable  chattels,  Roman  law  tended  to 
blur  the  distinction  between  real  and  personal  property.  Roman  law 
also  created  the  distinction  between  ownership,  or  proprietasy  and  pos- 
session, or  dominium.  Roman  law  envisaged  many  other  subtle  legal 
concepts  and  rights  relating  to  property  holdings. 

In  medieval  law,  the  distinction  between  possession  and  ownership  was 
less  distinct,  but  the  differentiation  between  real  property  and  chattels 
was  made  more  thorough  and  decisive  than  it  had  been  in  Roman  law. 
Real  property  could  be  acquired  in  most  places  only  by  inheritance  or 
investiture,  both  of  which  were  closely  controlled  by  feudal  law.  Investi- 
ture was  an  elaborate  feudal  rite,  both  legal  and  religious.  The  inherit- 
ance of  property  in  the  Middle  Ages  usually  followed  the  principle  of 
primogeniture,  or  inheritance  by  the  eldest  male  heir.  The  possession 
of  real  property  in  England  in  the  Middle  Ages  was  guaranteed  by  the 
right  of  seisin,  which  was  then  regarded  as  the  possession  of  such  an 
estate  in  land  as  was  believed  worthy  to  be  held  by  a  free  man.  In 


THE  INSTITUTION  OF  PROPERTY  163 

England  today  the  possession  of  a  freehold  is  frequently  regarded  as  the 
right  of  seisin. 

Perhaps  the  outstanding  development  in  property  law  since  the  dawn 
of  modern  times  has  been  that  which  clearly  distinguishes  between  real 
and  personal  property: 

The  main  differences  between  real  and  personal  property  which  still  exist  in 
England  are  these.  (1)  In  real  property  there  can  be  nothing  more  than  limited 
ownership;  there  can  be  no  estate  properly  so  called  in  personal  property,  and 
it  may  be  held  in  complete  ownership.  There  is  nothing  corresponding  to  an 
estate-tail  in  personal  property;  words  which  in  real  property  would  create  an 
estate-tail  will  give  an  absolute  interest  in  personalty.  A  life-interest  may, 
however,  be  given  in  personalty,  except  in  articles  quae  ipso  usu  consummuntur. 
Limitations  of  personal  property,  equally  with  those  of  real  property,  fall  within 
the  rule  against  perpetuities.  (2)  Personal  property  is  not  subject  to  various 
incidents  of  real  property,  such  as  rent,  dower  or  escheat.  (3)  On  the  death  of 
the  owner  intestate  real  property  descends  to  the  heir;  personal  property  is 
divided  according  to  the  Statute  of  Distributions.  (4)  Real  property  as  a 
general  rule  must  be  transferred  by  deed;  personal  property  does  not  need  so 
solemn  a  mode  of  transfer.  (5)  Contracts  relating  to  real  property  must  be 
in  writing  by  the  Statutes  of  Frauds,  29  Car.  II.c.3,s.4;  contracts  relating  to 
personal  property  need  only  be  in  writing  when  it  is  expressly  so  provided  by 
statute  as,  for  instance,  in  the  cases  falling  under  s.17  of  the  Statute  of  Frauds. 
(6)  A  will  of  lands  need  not  be  proved,  but  a  will  of  personalty  or  of  personal 
and  real  property  together  must  be  proved  in  order  to  give  a  title  to  those  claim- 
ing under  it.  (7)  Devises  of  real  estate  fall  as  a  rule  within  the  Mortmain 
Acts;  bequests  of  personal  property,  other  than  chattels  real,  are  not  within  the 
act.  (8)  Mortgages  of  real  property  need  not  generally  be  registered;  mortgages 
of  personal  property  for  the  most  part  require  registration  under  the  Bills  of 
Sale  Acts.2 

In  the  last  half-century  there  have  been  revolutionary  alterations  in 
both  the  law  and  concepts  of  property  rights,  especially  in  the  United 
States.  These  have  been  associated  chiefly  with  the  rise  of  corporations, 
the  holding-company,  and  the  speculative  practices  of  finance  capitalism. 
As  a  result  of  these  developments,  ownership  of  much  of  American  business 
has  been  divorced  from  control  and  management,  and  those  who  have 
been  vested  with  control  through  legal  legerdemain  have  been  able  to 
ride  roughshod  over  the  owners  of  securities. 

During  this  recent  period — chiefly  since  1870 — a  sweeping  legal  revo- 
lution also  took  place  with  respect  to  property.  Property  rights  have 
come  to  be  looked  upon  as  sacred.  Therefore,  those  who  had  any  special 
vested  practice,  interest,  or  privilege  attempted  to  identify  it  with  prop- 
erty and  thus  secure  for  it  impregnable  legal  defense.  This  led  to  an 
enormous — indeed,  absurd — extension  of  the  property  concept  in  law. 
Such  things  as  monopoly,  factory  codes,  sales  practices,  working  condi- 
tions, the  open-shop,  immunity  from  taxation,  and  so  on,  were  taken  un- 
der the  cloak  of  property  and  were  given  special  protection  by  the  courts. 

2  James  Williams,  article,  "Personal  Property,"  Encyclopedia  Britannica,  llth  Ed., 
Vol.  21,  p.  256.  See  also  Charles  Gore  (Ed.),  Property:  Its  Duties  and  Rights, 
Macmillan,  1932,  Chap.  VIII. 


164  THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY 


Some  Psychological   Foundations  of  Property 

A  wide-spread  notion  prevails-  even  among  some  professional  psycholo- 
gists that  the  property  emotions  and  practices  of  mankind  rest  upon  a 
definite  acquisitive  or  property  instinct,  which  not  only  dominates  man- 
kind but  is  also  to  be  found  among  lower  forms  of  life,  such  as  insects, 
birds,  rodents,  and  apes.  Such  psychologists  as  William  McDougall, 
W.  H.  R.  Rivers,  and  others  have  supported  this  theory  by  citing  the 
foraging  activities  of  the  bees,  wasps  and  ants,  their  accumulation  of  food, 
and  their  building  of  nests.  Similar  traits  among  birds  and  rodents  are 
further  adduced  to  support  the  instinct  theory  of  the  origins  of  property. 

Perhaps  the  most  convincing  exposure  of  this  instinct  hypothesis  is  the 
book,  Property:  A  Study  in  Social  Psychology,  by  Ernest  Beaglehole,  an 
able  English  psychologist.  He  investigated  thoroughly  all  the  evidence 
usually  brought  forth  to  support  the  idea  of  a  so-called  property  or 
acquisitive  instinct  among  insects,  birds,  and  animals  and  concludes  that 
this  evidence  does  not  vindicate  any  such  interpretation.3  With  respect 
to  the  insects,  Beaglehole  concludes  that: 

If  such  accumulating  activity  (in  one  case,  to  repeat,  the  provisioning  of  the 
individual  nest,  in  the  other  case,  foraging  for  food  and  other  objects  of  value 
to  the  hive  and  nest)  must  be  fitted  into  a  limited  classification  of  instincts  of 
the  McDougall  type  it  is  far  more  reasonably  and  scientifically  subsumed  by  an 
instinct  of  'nutrition'  or  'food-gathering'  than  by  an  instinct  of  'acquisition/  or 
even,  perhaps,  as  a  modification  or  extension  of  an  'instinct  of  hunting/  4 

Among  birds,  food  accumulation  is  the  exception  rather  than  the  rule, 
and  the  collection  of  materials  other  than  those  used  for  food  or  nests  is 
found  only  among  rare  and  very  intelligent  birds.  The  defense  of  a  mate, 
young,  or  a  nest  is  related  more  closely  to  sex,  nutrition,  building  drives, 
and  parental  impulses  than  to  any  acquisitive  instinct.  Beaglehole  con- 
cludes: "These  facts  take  on  a  legitimate  and  larger  meaning  only  when 
they  are  considered  within  a  configuration  which  comprise  a  total  activity 
directed  towards  the  satisfaction  of  sexual  and  parental  impulses." 5 

The  same  sort  of  reasoning  applies  to  the  evidence  with  respect  to  an 
acquisitive  instinct  among  animals.  Insofar  as  animals  accumulate  and 
defend,  it  is  only  because  the  objects  that  they  do  accumulate  and  defend 
satisfy  general  life  desires.  As  Beaglehole  puts  it:  "The  psychological 
origin  of  property  is  based  on  the  mental  and  material  appropriation  of 
those  objects  which  are  necessary  for  the  satisfaction  of  those  specific 
instincts  subserving  the  more  fundamental  needs  of  the  organism."6 

In  short,  the  tendency  to  acquire  and  defend  objects  by  insects,  birds, 
and  animals  rests  upon  a  complex  set  of  drives  to  satisfy  life  needs  rather 
than  upon  any  specific  instinct  of  acquisition.  Beaglehole  concludes  then 


8  Loc.  cit.t  Macmillan,  1932,  Chaps."  ii-iv. 
*  Ibid.,  p.  62. 
*Ibid.,  p.  93. 
*lbid.,  p.  123 


THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY  165 

that  there  is  no  instinct  of  acquisition  -to  be  found  in  forms  of  organic 
life  lower  than  man  and  that  the  resemblance  between  the  acquisitive 
behavior  of  man  and  of  other  lower  forms  of  life  is  wholly  superficial. 
There  is  no  organic,  psychological,  or  historical  link  between  the  accumu- 
lating tendencies  of  lower  forms  of  animal  life  and  the  acquisitive  be- 
havior of  man.  This  is  also  the  opinion  of  Professor  Hamilton,  who  says 
that  "a  suspicious  analogue  alone  enables  man  to  find  property  in  the 
animal  kingdom." 

After  investigating  the  rise  of  property  drives  among  men  Beaglehole 
is  also  convinced  that  what  we  find  in  mankind  is  socially  conditioned 
acquisitive  behavior  and  not  an  acquisitive  instinct: 

The  roots  of  acquisitive  behaviour  are  to  be  found  in  the  primitive  impulse 
to  grasp  and  to  handle  in  the  interests  of  the  fundamental  needs;  collecting 
behaviour  is  a  habit  complex  whereby,  on  the  one  hand,  the  undisciplined  and 
non-regimented  character  of  the  child's  impulses  is  organized  into  a  compact 
body  of  interests  through  play  activities  and  participation  in  a  social  group;  and 
on  the  other  hand,  in  conformity  with  group  values,  with  developing  intellectual 
interests.7 

With  adults  in  well  developed  society  acquisitive  behavior  is  motivated 
not  only  by  the  immediate  needs  of  the  -organism  but  by  many  complex 
factors  of  a  psychological  and  cultural  nature: 

The  dominant  motives  to  wealth  accumulation  would  thus  seem  to  be  prudence, 
the  love  of  family,  the  desire  for  social  esteem  and  invidious  distinctions  founded 
on  wealth,  and  lastly,  desire  for  power,  and  the  aggressive  control  of  others. 
The  desire  for  economic  goods,  therefore,  the  response  to  the  bribe  of  wealth,  is 
always  complex.  It  is  a  value  supported  by  a  strongly  organized  system  of 
sentiments  and  interests,  the  joint  product  of  the  interaction  of  impulse  and 
emotion  with  the  economic  culture  patterns  of  the  material  and  social  environ- 
ment. So  important,  however,  is  this  group  patterning  that  it  is  hardly  unfair 
to  say  that  man  is  acquisitive  because  his  environment  makes  him  so.8 

We  may,  therefore,  conclude  that  the  drive  to  accumulate  property  is 
a  complex  one,  which  does  not  rest  on  any  simple  instinct  of  acquisition. 
There  seems  no  valid  support  for  the  existence  of  any  such  instinct  in  man 
or  other  living  beings.  The  impulse  to  accumulate,  use,  and  own  things 
is  a  complicated  sentiment,  involving  everything  from  the  grasping  of 
the  babe  at  warm  and  familiar  objects  to  the  lust  for  emulation  and 
prestige  on  the  part  of  "economic  royalists"  in  our  era  of  finance  capi- 
talism. 

Property  Drives   in  the  Light  of  Psychology, 
Ethnology,  and  Sociology 

In  addition  to  satisfying  some  basic  requirements  of  life,  property 
values  are  conditioned  by  the  social  and  cultural  setting.  Things  are 
valuable  in  proportion  to  the  esteem  placed  upon  them  in  any  culture. 


7  Beaglehole,  op.  dt.,  p.  281. 
*Ibid.,  p.  308. 


166  THE   INSTITUTION  OF  PROPERTY 

'  When  culture  changes,  property  usages  and  values  are  likely  to  undergo 
a  comparable  transformation: 

From  the  point  of  view  of  social  theory,  after  allowance  is  made  for  this  con- 
ception of  the  psychological  minimum,  one  must  argue  that  property  is  neither 
unchanging  nor  indefeasible.  It  is,  in  reality,  an  instrument,  expedient  or  con- 
vention, adaptable  and  changing  in  accordance  with  varying  needs  (just  as  is  any 
expedient),  and  must  be  so  changed,  if  needs  are  to  be  satisfied,  in  conformity 
with  the  requirements  of  a  dynamic  society.  The  truth  of  this  statement  gains 
support  from  even  the  most  cursory  glance  at  the  history  of  Western  Europe. 
This  history  shows  very  clearly  a  gradual  development  in  the  culture  patterning 
of  property  values.9 

A.  G.  Keller  also  emphasizes  the  fact  that  the  property  interest  is 
sharply  conditioned  by  the  relative  group  esteem  for  the  objects  in  ques- 
tion and  by  the  utility  which  these  objects  possess  in  any  particular  cul- 
ture: 

Certain  things  may  be  desirable  as  property  to  some  people  and  not  to  others; 
for  instance,  the  iron  and  coal  deposits  in  America  did  not  interest  the  Indians 
at  all,  though  they  now  form  properties  of  great  desirability  and  value.  The 
Eskimo  who  traded  some  fine  furs  for  a  handful  of  wet  matches  with  red  sticks, 
was  eager  to  own  what  the  white  man  was  just  about  to  throw  away  as  useless.10 

A  particularly  brilliant  and  impressive  statement  of  the  cultural  de- 
termination of  property  values  is  provided  by  Professor  Hamilton  : 

The  mark  of  a  particular  society  always  attaches  to  a  property.  An  owner 
is  concerned  with  trinket,  vineyard  or  power,  not  for  what  it  is  in  itself,  but  for 
what  the  community  allows  him  to  extract  from  it.  In  one  society  a  string  of 
scalps  are  a  badge  of  honor,  in  another  a  mere  reminder  of  the  ways  of  savages. 
The  touch  of  superstition  gives  value  to  a  rabbit's  foot,  the  bone  of  a  reputed 
saint  and  Dr.  Wiseman's  Panacea-for-Everyill ;  at  the  coming  of  science  their 
places  are  taken  by  the  test  tube  and  the  guinea  pig.  The  march  of  invention 
subdues  waste  land  with  dry  farming,  converts  a  flash  of  lightning  into  a  great 
industry,  and  keeps  the  catalogue  of  natural  resources  in  perpetual  flux.  In  one 
age  a  moral  revolution  outlaws  the  theater,  in  another  it  consigns  the  traffic  in 
alcoholic  beverages  to  oblivion.  Under  industrialism  the  fact  of  property  is  as 
fresh  as  the  morning  newspaper,  the  ticker  tape  and  the  latest  judicial  utterance.11 

The  powerful  social  and  cultural  conditioning  of  property  values  may 
be  illustrated  in  greater  detail.  Vanity  is  a  very  important  source  of  the 
property  desire.  In  primitive  society,  most  things,  from  personal  orna- 
ments to  wives,  are  likely  to  be  esteemed  not  only  for  their  utility  or  magic 
potency  but  also  for  the  prestige  which  they  may  confer.  This  vanity 
drive  has  continued,  and  in  its  modern  manifestation  it  has  been  made 
the  subject  of  sardonic  analysis  by  Thorstein  Veblen  and  other  writers 
interested  in  the  social  psychology  of  our  contemporary  leisure  classes. 
One  of  our  present  day  plutocrats  may  get  much  the  same  satisfaction 
out  of  a  marble  castle  on  Long  Island  that  the  savage  secures  from  his 


8  Beaglehole,  op.  cit.,  p.  317. 

10  A.  G.  Keller,  Starting  Points  in  Social  Science,  Ginn,  1925,  p.  82. 

11  Hamilton,  loc  cit.t  p.  529, 


THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY  167 

string  of  shells.  "Diamond  Jim"  Brady  was  motivated  by  much  the 
same  sentiments  which  promoted  the  lavish  personal  adornment  of  King 
Luernus  of  the  ancient  Gauls. 

The  possessiveness  exhibited  by  males  with  respect  to  their  women 
arises  from  psychologically  complex  motives.  The  desire  for  women  is 
supported  not  only  by  sex  requirements  and  by  their  utility  in  the  house- 
hold, but  also  by  sentiments  of  affection,  fear  of  loss,  jealousy,  self-love 
or  egotism.  Even  polygyny,  or  the  possession  of  many  wives,  rests  as 
much  upon  vanity  and  prestige  as  upon  the  lasciviousness  of  the  sheik. 

Property  is  accumulated  and  prized  as  much  because  it  bestows  power 
and  prestige  upon  the  possessor  as  for  its  practical  utility.  This  applies 
even  to  a  utilitarian  matter  such  as  the  accumulation  of  food.  It  is  com- 
mon among  primitive  peoples  to  find  food  accumulated  and  displayed 
beyond  any  capacity  for  consumption,  because  this  display  of  excess  food 
demonstrates  prestige  and  superior  rank.  Even  ornaments  are  as  defi- 
nitely related  to  the  desire  for  social  prestige  as  to  any  aesthetic  impulse 
or  personal  pride  of  the  wearer.  Expensive  and  unusual  adornment  gives 
evidence  that  the  wearer  is  a  person  of  social  importance  and  high  rank. 

The  possession  of  land  is  usually  regarded  as  a  preeminent  example 
of  utilitarian  motivation,  but  it  is  a  far  more  complex  matter  than  this. 
It  rests  also  upon  tradition,  association  with  the  family  past,  and  aesthetic 
achievement.  Indeed,  considered  in  the  large,  the  desire  to  possess  land 
is  a  complex  sentiment  rather  than  a  direct  utilitarian  impulse: 

Over  and  above  means  of  subsistence  and  the  fulfilment  of  social  obligations 
one  must  recognize  the  large  part  that  other  psychological  factors  play  in  the 
formation  of  values  in  land.  Aesthetic  appreciation,  memories  of  former  years, 
tribal  battles,  sacred  practices,  memories  of  home  and  family — in  fact  all  those 
interests  which  are  the  resultant  of  the  interplay  of  social  sympathy  with  tradi- 
tional teaching  and  aesthetic  emotion  combine  to  create  a  sentiment  of  ownership 
for  the  land.12 

Religion  has  been  a  profound  influence  in  creating  property  values 
and  sentiments.  Primitive  magic  has  an  especially  powerful  effect.  Not 
only  is  magic  force  supposed  to  reside  in  various  amulets  and  other  ob- 
jects, giving  rise  to  that  religious  concept  we  know  as  fetishism,  but 
one's  personality  is  supposed  to  project  itself  into  the  objects  he  pos- 
sesses and  uses.  Hence  it  is  unsafe  to  seize  or  use  the  possessions  of 
others,  lest  this  magic  potency  do  one  harm.  It  was  this  notion  which, 
in  part,  underlay  the  idea  of  burial  with  one's  possessions.  This  elimi- 
nated the  danger  of  having  any  survivor  use  them  with  disastrous  results. 
Wealth  also  enabled  the  possessor  to  feel  more  certain  of  a  satisfactory 
existence  in  the  world  to  come,  for  it  enabled  him  to  gain  the  assistance 
of  medicine  men  and  priests  in  utilizing  the  aid  of  supernatural  powers. 
Benefactions  for  holy  causes  were  supposed  to  be  particularly  potent  in 
assuring  immortal  bliss.  Indeed,  in  the  later  Middle  Ages,  wealthy  per- 
sons were  assumed  to  be  able  to  purchase  partial  immunity  from  damna- 


12  Beaglehole,  op.  cit.,  pp.  154-155. 


168  THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY 

tion.  This  stimulated  the  notorious  sale  of  indulgences.  The  power  of 
wealth  over  contemporary  religion  has  stimulated  many  sociological  and 
economic  studies  and  powerful  social  novels,  an  example  of  which  is 
Winston  Churchill's  The  Inside  of  the  Cup. 

One  can  multiply  indefinitely  these  illustrations  of  the  way  in  which 
social,  psychological,  and  ethnographical  factors  influence  property  values 
and  usages,  but  those  we  have  given  will  suffice  to  demonstrate  the 
assertion  that  property  motives  are  extremely  complex  and  are  sweep- 
ingly  altered  in  the  course  of  social  evolution.  Those  who  wish  further 
information  may  consult  the  third  and  fourth  chapters  of  Sumner's  Folk- 
ways, and  the  more  detailed  treatment  in  the  Science  of  Society  by 
Sumner  and  Keller.18 

Some  Outstanding  Phases  of  the  History  of  Property 

Property  in  Primitive  Society.  The  nature  of  property  usages  and 
holdings  in  primitive  society  has  been  a  subject  of  much  controversy.1* 
One  school  of  ethnology  and  sociology  has  sought  to  demonstrate  that  in 
primitive  society  we  always  find  a  system  of  communism,  where  all  prop- 
erty is  held  in  common  by  various  social  groups,  such  as  clans  and  tribes. 
Another  school  of  thought,  chiefly  concerned  with  upholding  the  dogma 
of  the  sanctity  of  private  property,  has  combatted  this  notion  of  primi- 
tive communism  by  contending  that  private  property  has  been  the  rule 
in  primitive  as  well  as  in  historic  cultures. 

Neither  the  thesis  of  complete  communism  in  primitive  society  nor  the 
opposed  dogma  of  the  universality  of  private  holdings  among  primitive 
men  accords  with  the  facts.  While  communal  holdings  certainly  pre- 
dominated in  primitive  life,  there  was  plenty  of  private  property,  extend- 
ing even  to  abstruse  types  of  intangible  rights.  Often  in  the  case  of 
what  passes  for  communal  ownership  it  was  communal  possession  and 
use  rather  than  strict  communal  ownership.  There  was  a  rather  general 
trend  during  primitive  times  from  communal  to  family  holding,  and 
movable  objects  usually  became  private  property: 

Although  it  is  difficult  to  find  among  primitive  peoples  complete  approach  to  a 
communistic  grouping  of  society,  yet  it  is  equally  evident  that  various  factors 
converge  to  bring  about  a  fairly  equable  distribution  of  wealth  within  the  enlarged 
family  group,  the  clan,  or  the  tribe.  Even  in  the  higher  grade  agricultural 
societies,  where  we  first  find  the  phenomena  accompanying  the  differentiation  of 
classes,  the  rise  of  nobles  and  chiefs,  we  find  evidence  for  the  existence  of  group 
patterns  which  stress  the  social  approval  of  generosity,  of  giving  rather  than 
keeping,  and  which  thus  promote  equality  of  wealth.  Culture  patterns  may 
stress  the  virtue  of  liberality;  or  the  glory  accruing  to  the  group  through  tempo- 
rary possession  of  Kula  objects  of  incalculable  value.  And  human  nature  does 
not  rebel.  It  moulds  its  individualism  into  conformity  with  social  ways  of  acting, 
its  sentiments  of  ownership  to  group  patterns  of  behaviour.  The  result  is  society 
without  abnormal  acquisitiveness,  without  clear-cut  communism  but  co-operative, 


«  Especially  Vol.  I,  Part  I. 

14  On  the  evolution  of  property,  see  Gore,  op.  cit.,  Chap.  I. 


THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY  169 

combining,  through  its  customs,  individual  initiative  with  a  not  unequal  dis- 
tribution of  wealth.15 

This  general  point  of  view  is  supported  by  the  eminent  ethnologist, 
Professor  Robert  H.  Lowie,  in  his  chapter  on  "Property"  in  his  notable 
Primitive  Society: 

It  follows  from  the  foregoing  that  we  cannot  content  ourselves  with  a  blunt 
alternative:  communism  versus  individualism.  A  people  may  be  communistic  as 
regards  one  type  of  goods,  yet  recognize  separate  ownership  with  respect  to  other 
forms  of  property.  Further,  the  communistic  principle  may  hold  not  for  the 
entire  political  unit  of  however  high  or  low  an  order  but  only  within  the  con- 
fines of  a  much  smaller  or  differently  constituted  class  of  individuals,  in  which 
case  there  will  be  indeed  collectivism  but  not  communism  in  the  proper  sense 
of  the  term.  These  points  must  be  kept  in  mind  when  surveying  successively 
the  primitive  law  of  immovable  and  movable  property,  of  immaterial  wealth 
and  of  inheritance.16 

In  dealing  with  property  in  primitive  society  one  must  remember  that 
we  have  no  evidence  of  property  usages  among  any  very  early  type  of 
men.  Existing  savages,  and  peoples  who  lived  just  before  the  dawn  of 
history,  represent  relatively  recent  stages  of  human  culture.  Man 
had  passed  through  nearly  a  million  years  of  experience  before  he  reached 
the  stage  of  culture  represented  by,  let  us  say,  the  American  Indians  at 
the  time  of  the  discovery  of  America.  So,  when  we  talk  about  property 
among  primitive  peoples,  we  do  not  mean  early  primitive  peoples  but 
those  living  in  a  relatively  late  and  advanced  state  of  primitive  culture. 

In  a  rough  way,  the  extent  and  fixity  of  private  property  increased  as 
man  passed  from  the  hunting  period,  through  pastoral  life,  to  agriculture. 
But  there  were  plenty  of  private  property  rights  in  the  hunting  period 
and  a  good  deal  of  communal  control  and  use  of  property  after  agriculture 
appeared. 

In  the  so-called  hunting  and  fishing  stage  of  culture — the  economy  of 
collectors — hunting  and  fishing  lands  were  normally  owned  or  controlled 
by  the  whole  social  group,  while  individuals  owned  their  own  weapons 
and  tools.  The  ownership  of  the  latter,  rested,  as  we  have  seen,  on  magi- 
cal as  well  as  ultilitarian  grounds.  But  not  even  hunting  grounds  were 
always  communally  owned.  Among  the  Veddas  of  Ceylon,  for  example, 
private  property  rights  in  hunting  lands  were  so  specific  that  a  man  did 
not  dare  to  hunt  even  on  his  brother's  land  without  permission. 

Among  peoples  living  in  the  pastoral  period,  what  we  usually  find  is 
communal  ownership  of  the  pasture  land  and  private  ownership  of  live- 
stock, though  often  this  ownership  of  livestock  is  vested  in  the  family 
rather  than  in  the  individual  members. 

The  appearance  of  agriculture  promoted  a  marked  development  of 
private  ownership.  This  was  due  to  the  fact  that  land  had  to  be  cleared 


is  Beaglehole,  op.  cit.,  p.  237. 

16  Lowie,  op.  cit.,  Liveright  Publishing  Corporation,  1920,  p.  210.  For  more  detail 
on  primitive  property,  see  M.  J.  Herskovits,  The  Economic  Life  of  Primitive  Peoples, 
Knopf,  1940,  Part  IV. 


170  THE   INSTITUTION   OF  PROPERTY 

for  tilling,  and  those  who  cleared  and  cultivated  it  were  loath  to  sur- 
render the  product  of  their  effort  to  the  community: 

It  is  when  we  come  to  tillage  that  the  typical  property-system  as  respects  land 
undergoes  a  decided  change.  .  .  .  Under  agnculture  the  whole  situation  as 
respects  land  is  altered.  It  is  still  the  product  of  the  land  rather  than  the  land 
itself  that  is  the  object  of  desire;  but  now  some  small  areas  of  land  are  better 
than  others,  \vhereas  on  the  hunting  and  herding  stages  there  was  small  choice 
between  limited  plots.  One  piece  of  tillage-land  is,  perhaps,  naturally  more 
fertile  than  another,  even  though  the  two  are  small  and  lie  side  by  side.  But 
tillage-land  must  generally  have  been  improved,  by  being  cleared  of  trees  a-nd 
underbrush  and  otherwise  prepared  for  cultivation,  and  sometimes  enriched  with 
ashes,  fish,  or  other  fertilizer.  When  this  has  been  done,  the  holder  of  such  land 
is  not  willing  to  give  it  up  for  any  other  piece;  especially  if  the  ground  contains 
seed  which  lie  has  planted,  does  it  become  a  special  and  individual  thing,  of 
which  he  wants  the  private  monopoly.17 

With  the  coming  of  agriculture  the  old  communal  system  of  ownership 
did  not  wholly  disappear.  Waste  land,  used  for  pasturage,  almost  always 
remained  under  communal  ownership.  There  was  also  often  a  communal 
control  of  tilled  land,  though  there  was  a  definite  tendency  towards  the 
growth  of  family  or  individual  ownership  of  cultivated  plots.  In  the 
agricultural  period,  private  property  in  animals  and  tools  was  the  usual 
thing.  Among  advanced  primitive  peoples  we  often  find  that  the  land 
is  regarded  as  the  "chief's  land"  or  the  "king's  land."  In  this  way,  the 
ground  was  prepared  for  the  transition  from  primitive  to  historical  cul- 
ture. In  the  early  stages  of  the  latter  we  usually  find  that  the  land  was, 
in  legal  theory,  in  the  possession  of  the  monarch  and  distributed  among 
his  followers. 

In  primitive  society  we  find  that  movable  objects  of  real  or  supposed 
utility,  such  as  weapons,  tools,  and  animals,  were  most  frequently  owned 
by  families  or  individuals.  Private  property  was  the  rule  in  this  area  of 
human  possession.  The  elements  of  magic,  utility,  convenience,  and 
pride  all  combined  to  stimulate  the  growth  of  private  ownership: 

In  general  it  may  be  said  that  among  primitive  peoples  in  regard  to  the 
ownership  of  implements,  weapons  and  land,  what  is  acquired  or  made  by  a 
m'an  or  woman  by  personal  exertion  is  regarded  as  his  or  her  private  property. 
Similarly  what  is  acquired  or  made  through  combined  labour  of  a  group  is  usually 
the  common  property  of  the  individuals  forming  the  group. 

The  psychological  elements  involved  in  a  sentiment  of  ownership  supporting 
property,  the  acquisition  of  which  has  involved  the  mixing  of  labour,  are  not  far 
to  seek.  In  the  making  of  a  tool  or  weapon  or  a  house  there  is  the  satisfaction 
of  the  impulse  to  construction;  in  the  decoration  or  carving  of  the  implement 
there  is  aesthetic  pleasure  and  joy  in  good  craftsmanship.  Memory  of  the  energy, 
time  and  labour  spent  in  fashioning  the  tool  from  raw  materials  strengthens  the 
feelings  of  satisfaction  at  having  produced  something  of  this  that  is  useful  or 
beautiful  and  perhaps  both,  Since  an  object  of  this  nature  may  be  envied  or 
praised  by  other  members  of  the  group,  the  sentiments  grouped  round  the  self 
are  proportionately  strengthened  and  reinforce  in  their  turn  those  feelings 
centred  about  the  newly  created  object.  .  .  . 


n  Keller,  Starting  Points  in  Social  Science,  Ginn,  pp.  86-87. 


THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY  171 

Factors  of  utility,  rarity,  durability  and  incorporation  of  skill  are  by  no  means 
the  sole  and  only  determinants  of  value  and  desire  for  possession.  Other,  and 
perhaps  more  potent,  factors  are  the  outcome  of  motives  grouped  round  the  drive 
of  vanity,  the  desire  for  social  recognition,  and  the  fact  that  value  is  often  the 
outcome  of  what,  for  want  of  a  better  term,  I  may  call  'historic  sentimentalism.' 18 

Women,  as  well  as  men,  frequently  owned  movable  objects  in  primitive 
times.  This  was  especially  the  case  where,  as  among  the  Iroquois,  women 
occupied  a  position  of  unusual  prestige  and  power. 

An  especially  striking  refutation  of  the  idea  that  property  notions  and 
rights  are  only  slightly  developed  among  primitive  peoples  is  afforded  by 
the  extensive  evidence  of  incorporeal  property  and  intangible  rights.19 
Among  these  intangible  property  rights,  usually  the  possession  of  indi- 
viduals, are  such  things  as  songs,  magic  formulas  and  incantations,  local 
legends,  poems,  the  right  to  make  carvings  and  other  ornamental  works, 
religious  rites,  ceremonial  privileges,  the  cultivation  of  sacred  herbs,  and 
the  revelation  of  visions.  Among  some  primitive  peoples  we  find  notions 
and  usages  identical  with  our  concept  of  copyrights  and  patent  rights. 

Property  in  the  Ancient  Near  East.  With  the  so-called  dawn  of  history 
in  the  ancient  Near  East  property  usages  and  rights  were  embodied  in 
formal  legislation  and  enforced  by  the  absolutism  of  the  ancient  mon- 
archs.  These  early  historic  civilizations  of  the  Near  East  were  built  upon 
the  ruins  of  primitive  culture,  which  was  brought  to  an  end  by  many 
centuries  of  wars  of  conquest.  The  monarchs  who  ruled  over  the  new 
states  usually  claimed  the  formal  ownership  of  the  land  and  embodied 
their  claim  in  laws  and  proclamations.  But  they  gave  out  the  land  to 
their  followers  in  the  form  of  gifts  and  leases  which  conferred  most  of 
the  salient  points  of  ownership  of  private  property.  The  chief  limitation 
was  that  very  often  such  lands  could  not  be  disposed  of  with  the  same 
degree  of  freedom  that  prevails  under  a  system  of  complete  private 
ownership. 

There  were  many  changes  in  the  property  system  in  the  course  of  the 
history  of  ancient  Egypt.20  In  the  Old  Kingdom  we  find  a  hangover 
of  primitive  customs.  There  was  a  persistence  of  communal  ownership 
of  land  along  with  private  ownership  of  flocks  and  tools.  In  the  crafts, 
private  ownership  of  tools  was  the  normal  thing.  As  the  kings  grew 
stronger,  they  tended  to  assert  their  ownership  over  all  the  land  of  Egypt 
and  to  give  it  out  in  leaseholds.  But  the  nobles  were  able  to  dispose  of 
such  holdings  if  they  obtained  the  king's  consent. 

This  situation  of  formal  legal  ownership  of  all  lands  by  the  Pharaoh, 
its  subsequent  redistribution  to  nobles,  and  the  freedom  of  the  latter  to 
dispose  of  their  holdings  with  royal  permission  continued  with  no  im- 
portant changes  in  principle  throughout  the  Middle  Kingdom  and  the 
Empire.  The  Egyptian  priesthood  owned  vast  sections  of  the  best  land 


is  Beaglehole,  op.  cit.,  pp.  147,  183. 

19Lowie,  op.  cit.,  pp.  235  ff.,  and  Herskovits,  op.  cit.,  pp.  348  ff. 
20  See  Alexandra  Moret,  The  Nile  and  Egyptian  Civilization,  Knopf,  1927,  pp.  13&- 
140,  144,  265-267,  347-348. 


172  THE   INSTITUTION  OF  PROPERTY 

of  Egypt.  This  was  owned  under  a  communal  religious  set-up  and  was 
relatively  free  from  royal  interference,  except  in  the  case  of  the  strongest 
monarchs.  It  might  be  pointed  out,  in  passing,  that  the  priests  were 
the  largest  slave  owners  in  ancient  Egypt. 

In  the  earliest  days  of  ancient  Mesopotamia — the  Sumerian  era — we 
find  well-developed  property  rights,  both  communal  and  private: 

In  Sumer  and  Akkad,  from  the  earliest  times,  property  in  land  was  vested  in 
individuals,  or  in  social  groups;  pre-Sargonic  deeds  of  sale  afford  precious  evi- 
dence for  this.  The  temples  had  their  fields  and  their  orchards;  the  ishakku's 
wife  and  children  their  private  lands.  The  little  house  of  the  poor  man  was  not 
always  immune  from  the  greed  of  the  rich,  and  his  mother's  plot  was  too  often 
plundered  by  the  priest.  Already,  apparently,  the  prince  rewarded  his  faithful 
servants  by  grants  of  land,  either  in  perpetuity,  or  simply  in  usufruct.21 

In  Babylonia,  the  king  theoretically  owned  much  of  the  land  and  gave 
it  out,  as  had  the  Egyptian  Pharaoh,  to  his  loyal  followers.  Both  the 
city-states  and  individuals  owned  land.  Weapons,  tools,  and  implements 
were  usually  owned  privately  by  all  those  who  had  the  means  to  obtain 
them.  Only  those  too  poor  to  provide  their  own  movable  objects  pooled 
their  resources  and  owned  them  communally.  The  Code  of  Hammurabi 
distinguished  between  private  property  and  ilku  possessions.  The  latter 
were  granted  by  the  king  as  a  reward  for  public  services,  and  could  not 
be  seized,  mortgaged,  or  sold  except  after  the  fulfillment  of  required  duties 
and  with  royal  consent.  Even  the  disposition  of  private  property  was 
restricted  by  family  rights  and,  as  a  rule,  could  be  alienated  only  for 
debt.  The  high  value  put  upon  property  rights  in  the  Code  of  Ham- 
murabi is  demonstrated  by  the  severe  penalties  imposed  for  the  violation 
of  contract. 

In  Assyria,  there  was  both  communal  and  private  ownership  of  land. 
The  cities  often  owned  vast  rural  properties  and  leased  or  sold  them  to 
private  individuals.  Frequently,  large  farms  were  owned  by  several 
individuals  or  families.  Assyrian  legislation  was  particularly  strict  with 
respect  to  boundary  rights.  A  man  dishonestly  moving  his  boundary,  if 
discovered,  was  compelled  to  make  restitution  of  three  times  the  area 
taken,  to  be  whipped,  and  to  work  for  a  month  for  the  king  without  pay. 
He  might  also  be  mutilated. 

The  Hebrew  ideas  of  property  emphasized  the  principle  of  social  justice, 
stressed  the  fact  that  man  is  the  "steward  of  God"  in  all  that  he  holds, 
and  held  that  property  should  be  so  used  as  to  promote  the  good  both  of 
the  owner  and  his  group.22 

Property  in  Greece  and  Rome.  Homeric  society  in  ancient  Greece 
represented  a  transition  from  primitive  to  historic  culture,  and  there  was 
a  definite  tendency  towards  the  increase  of  private  ownership  of  land: 

We  are  in  a  time  when  groups  of  the  patriarchal  type,  smaller  families,  and 
isolated  individuals  all  exist  together,  when  collective  ownership  continues  to 

21 L.  Delaporte,  Mesopotamia,  Knopf,  1925,  p.  101. 
22  C/.  Gore,  op.  cit.,  Chap.  IV. 


THE   INSTITUTION   OF  PROPERTY  173 

exist  by  the  side  of  personal  ownership,  when  vast  estates  are  surrounded  by 
medium-sized  fields  and  small  plots,  and  when  movable  wealth  allows  industry 
to  put  in  a  timid  appearance.23 

In  early  Attica,  a  family  system  of  land  ownership  predominated  but 
individual  ownership  was  already  making  strong  headway.  In  the 
Periclean  period  in  Athens,  the  formal  system  which  prevailed  was  one 
of  private  property,  under  the  general  control  and  supervision  of  Athens: 

This,  at  bottom,  was  the  principle  which  governed  ownership.  Property 
belonged  to  the  individual,  under  the  control  of  the  city.  There  was  neither 
communism  nor  anarchy.  The  maintenance  of  each  in  what  belonged  to  him, 
under  conditions  determined  by  the  law — no  system  could  be  imagined  more 
favourable  to  society.  All  goods  were  at  the  disposal  of  the  State  without 
belonging  to  it  slavishly,  and  its  demands  detracted  nothing  from  the  pride  or 
activity  of  the  citizen.24 

The  state  owned  most  of  the  mines  and  quarries,  though  they  fre- 
quently leased  out  such  public  domains  to  private  concerns  in  the  form 
of  "concessions."  Private  property  in  both  lands  and  tools  predominated. 
The  laws  governing  the  transmission  of  estates  encouraged  the  division 
of  medium  and  small  estates,  until  farms  frequently  became  so  small  that 
they  could  not  support  the  owners.  Great  estates  were  built  up  on  the 
ruins  of  small  holdings  by  a  process  something  like  that  in  which  the 
Roman  latifundia  were  created  upon  the  ruins  of  the  old  Roman  free- 
holds. 

There  was  some  capitalism  in  Athens,  but  it  bore  little  resemblance 
to  that  of  modern  times.  Piracy  and  trade  were  put  upon  essentially 
the  same  ethical  plane.  The  slowness  with  which  money  was  able  to 
assert  itself  as  a  form  of  property  is  revealed  by  the  general  opposition 
to  the  taking  of  interest.  All  interest  was  branded  as  usury  whatever 
the  rate  charged. 

The  situation  presented  by  Sparta  was  an  unusual  one.25  Sparta  was 
one  of  the  first  totalitarian  states.  Its  social  system  was  essentially  one 
of  military  socialism.  The  highest  class  in  Sparta  were  the  so-called 
Spartiates.  They  were  strictly  organized  according  to  the  system  of 
military  socialism.  They  occupied  the  so-called  civic  lands  of  Sparta, 
which  were  divided  into  equal  entailed  and  inalienable  family  estates. 
There  was  equality  of  land  holding  and  taxes.  These  estates  were  trans- 
mitted through  the  system  of  primogeniture.  The  estates  were  cultivated 
by  helots,  who  were  legally  servile,  but  were  often  fairly  well  off  in  a 
material  sense.  They  bore  a  certain  resemblance  to  the  medieval  serf. 
The  other  free  class  in  Sparta  were  the  so-called  Perioeci.  They  were 
both  farmers  and  city  industrialists.  They  were  not  subjected  to  the 
regimentation  of  military  socialism,  though  they  might  often  be  called 
upon  for  military  service  in  time  of  emergency.  They  owned  their 


28  Gustave  Glotz,  Ancient  Greece  at  Work,  Knopf,  1926,  p.  11. 
™  Ibid.,  p.  151. 

.,  pp.  87  ff. 


174  THE   INSTITUTION  OF   PROPERTY 

own  shops,  tools,  lands,  and  herds.    Their  property  was  alienable  and 
could  be  disposed  of  with  relative  freedom. 

In  early  Rome,  agricultural  property  was  usually  regarded  as  sacred.28 
Agriculture  was  as  much  a  phase  of  religious  life  as  of  economic  activity. 
In  the  earliest  days  there  was  much  common  landowning  with  private 
property  in  herds  and  implements.  The  cities  owned  much  land  and  city 
ownership  died  slowly.  When  a  city  conquered  adjoining  lands  it  par- 
celed out  this  area  among  citizens. 

In  the  days  of  the  kings  and  the  early  Republic  we  find  a  form  of  patri- 
archal agrarian  life,  in  which  each  family  owned  a  little  plot  of  land 
called  an  hcredium,  containing  a  little  less  than  two  acres.  When  Rome 
conquered  the  Italian  peninsula  some  of  the  conquered  land  was  sold  out- 
right to  private  individuals.  The  rest  was  retained  as  public  land  which 
the  state  rented  out  to  private  cultivators,  either  Roman  citizens  or  con- 
quered peoples. 

This  conquest  of  Italy  and  the  subsequent  conquest  of  the  Mediter- 
ranean world  by  Rome  gradually  brought  to  an  end  the  era  of  small  land- 
holders. Many  Roman  farmers  were  killed  off  in  war  and  the  wealthy 
element  which  survived  and  had  profited  by  war  bought  up  the  land  and 
created  the  great  estates  or  latifundia.  This  disappearance  of  a  nation 
of  small  landowners  and  free  men  is  regarded  by  historians  as  the  lead- 
ing cause  of  the  decline  of  Roman  power. 

Capitalism  and  monetary  property  developed  much  further  in  Rome 
than  they  did  in  Greece.  There  were  two  main  types  of  capitalists: 
(1)  those  who  worked  for  the  government  as  tax-collectors  and  on  public 
works,  and  (2)  ordinary  businessmen.  Great  fortunes  grew  up,  some  of 
which  were  created  by  methods  exactly  paralleling  our  modern  rackets 
Crassus,  in  fact,  may  fairly  be  regarded  as  the  father  of  the  arson  racket. 

In  the  Roman  Empire  the  masses  were  generally  dispossessed,  whether 
in  city  or  country.  In  the  city,  they  usually  lived  on  public  largesse  in 
the  form  of  "bread-and-circuses."  In  the  country,  they  sank  to  the  level 
of  serfs  in  the  so-called  colonate.  In  neither  case  did  they  have  any 
private  possessions  worthy  of  the  name.  The  middle  class  was  gradually 
ruined  by  the  taxation  system.  Those  who  had  property  were  chiefly  a 
few  great  landholders,  who  defied  most  of  the  laws  and  dodged  their 
obligations  to  the  state.  The  army  was  owned  by  the  state  and  lived  in 
a  condition  which  may  be  regarded  as  military  socialism. 

Property  in  the  Middle  Ages.  It  was  long  popular  to  find  in  early 
German  society  a  system  of  complete  communism  in  landholding.  But 
today  most  up-to-date  historians  doubt  that  there  was  much  outright 
communal  ownership  of  arable  lands.  It  appears  that  the  pasture  and 
woodland  were  owned  by  the  community  at  large,  but  cultivated  land  was 
only  subject  to  communal  control  like  the  medieval  manor.  Each  free 
cultivator  had  a  right  to  the  land  he  worked  and  to  its  products,  though 


26  On  Roman  property,  see  Paul  Louis,  Ancient  Rome  at  Work,  Knopf,  1927, 
pp.  17-20,  30-36,  51-56,  106,  121. 


THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY  175 

he  did  not  own  it  nor  could  he  dispose  of  it.  Private  or  family  ownership 
of  weapons,  tools,  and  herds  seems  to  have  been  the  rule.27 

In  theory,  Christianity  favored  communal  property,  and  the  Apostolic 
Christians  set  up  a  sort  of  primitive  communism,  while  awaiting  the  ex- 
pected second  coming  of  Christ.  Monastic  communities  for  some  time 
supported  a  communal  system  of  landholding.  Stress  was  laid  on  the 
dangers  of  accumulating  too  much  private  property,  lest  one  become  ab- 
sorbed with  this  world's  goods  and  neglect  the  exercises  essential  to  insure 
salvation  in  the  world  to  come.  Jesus  had  warned  that,  where  a  man's 
treasure  is,  there  also  will  his  heart  be.  Wealth  and  property  were  to  be 
used  only  to  supply  elemental  human  needs,  to  glorify  God,  and  to  support 
the  Church.  But  this  noble  theory  soon  evaporated  under  the  stress  of 
practical  conditions  in  medieval  life. 

Land  was  far  and  away  the  most  important  type  of  property  since  the 
civilization  was  overwhelmingly  rural.  The  only  person  who  might  be 
regarded  as  an  outright  owner  of  land  was  the  king,  or  the  superior  feudal 
lord  who  was  not  obligated  to  any  overlord.  But  it  was  not  uncommon 
in  the  Middle  Ages  for  even  a  king  to  hold  land  under  obligations  to  some 
feudal  lord.  The  possession  of  land,  known  as  the  fief,  was  bestowed 
by  the  practice  of  investiture.  It  was  normally  passed  on  through  primo- 
geniture, in  order  to  keep  the  fief  intact.  But  each  fief  carried  respon- 
sibilities to  the  overlord,  such  as  military  service  or  money  payments. 
If  these  obligations  were  not  met,  the  overlord  could,  if  he  were  strong 
enough,  dispossess  the  holder  of  the  fief.  A  feudal  lord  was  normally 
invested  with  a  fief  as  reward  for  military  services  already  rendered. 

The  agricultural  system  of  the  Middle  Ages  revolved  about  the  manor, 
which  might  be  roughly  regarded  as  the  fief  viewed  in  its  economic 
aspects.28  A  part  of  the  manor — the  demesne — was  cultivated  for  the 
lord  by  his  serfs,  and  he  received  all  the  produce  thereof.  The  rest  of 
the  manor,  known  as  land  held  in  villeinage,  was  under  communal  con- 
trol, but  each  serf  had  the  right  to  cultivate  certain  sections  of  this  area 
and  get  the  produce  thereof.  The  serfs  usually  owned  their  own  animals 
and  tools,  but  they  generally  had  to  pool  these  and  use  them  in  a  cooper- 
ative manner  to  carry  on  farming  operations.  Even  their  labor  was  not 
their  own,  since  they  had  to  give  approximately  half  their  time  for  free 
work  on  the  lord's  demesne.  They  could  not  dispose  of  their  land,  but 
neither  could  they  be  thrown  off  the  land.  Flour  mills  and  other  needed 
institutions  were  supplied  by  the  lord,  and  the  serfs  paid  for  their  use. 

The  Church  entered  actively  into  the  feudal  landholding  system. 
Bishops  and  abbots  might  be  great  feudal  landlords.  The  vast  tracts 
of  land  owned  by  the  monasteries  were  usually  communally  owned. 
They  might  be  worked  by  the  monks,  but  monastic  lands  were  also 
frequently  cultivated  by  serfs  under  conditions  very  similar  to  those 
which  existed  on  secular  manors. 


27  See  J.  W.  Thompson,  Economic  and  Social  History  oj  the  Middle  Ages,  Apple- 
ton-Century,  1928,  pp.  87-92. 

28  Thompson,  op.  cit.f  Chap.  XXVI. 


176  THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY 

In  the  few  towns  the  property  was  held  chiefly  by  the  masters  of  the 
gilds.  In  the  craft  gilds,  the  shops  and  tools  were  usually  privately  owned 
by  individual  gild  masters,  though  journeymen  frequently  owned  their 
own  tools.  The  control  of  medieval  towns  over  town  buildings,  fortifica- 
tions, and  military  enterprise  resembled  urban  socialism.  The  most  ex- 
tensive control  of  property  by  medieval  towns  was  manifested  by  organ- 
izations of  merchants — particularly  the  Hanseatic  League,  which  included 
various  commercial  cities  in  Germany  and  northern  Europe  and  main- 
tained a  great  merchant  marine,  trading  stations,  a  navy,  and  an  army. 

As  in  ancient  Greece,  the  idea  of  monetary  property  and  property  rights 
made  progress  slowly.  There  was  sharp  limitation  on  all  forms  of  specu- 
lation. All  interest  was  regarded  as  usury  and  was  forbidden  except  in 
the  case  of  Jews,  who,  by  special  dispensation,  acted  as  bankers  and 
moneylenders. 

Though  the  Church  praised  poverty  as  a  leading  Christian  virtue  and 
warned  against  absorption  with  earthly  goods,  it  was  actually  the  largest 
single  property  holder  in  the  Middle  Ages.  While  it  held  its  lands  and 
other  property  as  "the  steward  of  Christ,"  it  maintained  its  property  with 
as  great  pride  and  tenacity  as  any  secular  owner.  However,  the  Church 
supported  the  policy,  in  theory  at  least,  of  using  property  for  the  public 
good,  and  condemned  as  sinful  most  of  the  policies  now  universally  fol- 
lowed under  capitalism  to  get  profits  and  accumulate  property.  More- 
over, the  rise  of  the  Franciscans  and  the  mendicant  friars  in  the  later 
Middle  Ages  revived  once  more  the  Christian  eulogy  of  poverty.29 

In  short,  the  Middle  Ages  represented  a  reversion  to  a  predominantly 
communal  economy  and  extensive  limitations  of  private  property.  It 
has  been  not  inaccurately  observed  that  in  the  Middle  Ages  the  property 
system  rested  more  upon  personal  and  legal  relationships  than  it  did  upon 
clear  title  to  ownership.  But,  as  medievalism  wore  on,  the  communal 
aspect  and  relationship  system  tended  to  give  way  slowly  before  the 
inroads  of  private  enterprise. 

Property  in  Early  Modern  Times  After  the  Commercial  Revolution. 
With  the  rise  of  modern  times  we  pass  from  the  medieval  system,  where 
property  rested  more  upon  personal  and  functional  relationships  than 
upon  absolute  ownership,  to  a  situation  in  which  complete  private  prop- 
erty in  land,  movables,  and  business  accessories  became  the  rule.  And 
the  political  and  legal  system  gave  nearly  complete  recognition  and  pro- 
tection to  these  remarkable  extensions  of  private  property  concepts  and 
practices,  making  it  what  some  economic  historians  call  the  "proprietary 
period"  in  the  evolution  of  property. 

It  must  be  remembered  that  modern  economic  institutions  did  not  come 
with  the  same  rapidity  to  all  the  countries  of  Europe.  They  appeared 
first  in  England  and  the  Low  Countries.  In  some  parts  of  Europe,  espe- 
cially eastern  and  central  Europe,  the  feudal  system,  the  manor,  and  the 
gilds  lingered,  in  differing  degrees  of  consistency,  for  generations  or  cen- 


.  Gore,  op.  cit.,  Chaps.  IV-V. 


THE   INSTITUTION  OF   PROPERTY  177 

turies.  There  the  property  relationships  of  the  Middle  Ages  hung  over 
with  slight  change.  Where  the  new  economic  setup  was  realized,  thor- 
oughgoing private  ownership  of  land  was  established,  whether  in  large 
estates  created  by  enclosing  the  scattered  strips  of  the  medieval  manor, 
or  in  the  lesser  holdings  of  the  squires  and  small  farmers.  The  com- 
munal system  of  the  medieval  manor  was  wiped  out  and  the  serfs  became 
either  peasant  workers  for  wages  or,  less  frequently,  small  proprietors. 
In  almost  every  case  those  who  owned  the  land  also  owned  the  imple- 
ments and  tools  necessary  to  cultivate  it. 

In  the  realm  of  industry,  private  ownership  became  nearly  universal 
in  western  Europe.  The  gild  system  was  replaced  by  the  putting-out 
system,  in  which  the  merchant  capitalist  owned  the  raw  materials  and 
the  workers  in  their  homes  normally  owned  their  tools.  In  commercial 
activity,  which  required  larger  investment,  joint-stock  companies  fre- 
quently arose,  and  ownership  was  divided  among  the  participants. 

One  of  the  most  revolutionary  changes  in  property  at  this  time  was 
the  rise  of  capitalism  and  a  money  economy,  the  final  triumph  of  the 
notion  of  property  in  money  and  the  freedom  to  use  it.  The  medieval 
identification  of  interest  with  usury  was  wiped  out.  The  use  of  money 
to  acquire  more  monetary  property  through  lending,  investment,  and 
speculation  became  generally  approved. 

These  innovations  constituted  the  essential  elements  of  the  new  capi- 
talism.80 Private  property  was  deemed  necessary,  and  it  was  thought 
to  be  essential  to  accumulate  it  for  further  investment.  Business  had  to 
produce  a  surplus  for  further  investment  and  expansion.  The  appear- 
ance at  this  time  of  double-entry  bookkeeping  concentrated  attention 
upon  private  profits  and  the  virtues  of  private  property: 

Ideas  of  profit-seeking  and  economic  rationalism  first  became  possible  with  the 
invention  of  double-entry  bookkeeping.  Through  this  system  can  be  grasped 
but  one  thing — the  increase  in  amount  of  values  considered  purely  quantitatively. 
Whoever  becomes  immersed  in  double-entry  bookkeeping  must  forget  all  qualities 
of  goods,  and  services,  abandon  the  limitations  of  the  need-covering  principle,  and 
be  filled  with  the  single  idea  of  profit;  he  may  not  think  of  books  and  cargoes, 
meal  and  cotton,  but  only  of  amounts  of  values,  increasing  or  diminishing.81 

Economic  philosophy  bestowed  its  blessings  upon  the  new  era  of  pri- 
vate property.  John  Locke,  David  Hume,  Adam  Smith,  and  others 
praised  property  as  a  supreme  virtue  and  the  chief  incentive  to  human 
effort.  Sir  William  Blackstone  observed  that  "nothing  so  generally 
strikes  the  imagination,  and  engages  the  affections  of  mankind,  as  the 
right  of  property."  Property  came  to  be  regarded  as  an  inherent  natural 
right  of  mankind  and  property  itself  was  regarded  as  "inalienable,  im- 
mutable, and  indefeasible."  Even  religion  gave  warm  approval  to  the 
new  era  of  private  property  rights.  As  Max  Weber,  Ernst  Troeltsoh, 


80  Cf.  Jerome  Davis,  Capitalism  and  Its  Culture,  Farrar  &  Rinehart,  1935. 

81  Werner  Sombart,  Der  Moderne  Kapitalismus,  Munich,  1921-27,  Vol.  II,  pp.  119- 
120. 


178  THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY 

R.  H.  Tawney,  and  others  have  pointed  out,  Protestant  ethics  thoroughly 
backed  up  the  concepts  and  practices  of  the  new  capitalistic  system.  But 
the  element  of  stewardship  was  not  ignored.32  John  Locke  contended 
that  the  chief  purpose  of  government  is  to  protect  property,  and  legisla- 
tors quickly  took  heed  and  made  this  abstract  theory  a  practical  reality. 

This  remarkable  development  and  extension  of  private  property  gave 
a  new  incentive  to  personal  effort  in  economic  life.  Personal  ownership 
produced  personal  opportunity  and  responsibility  for  acquiring  profits. 
Property  in  this  era  was  real,  active,  dynamic,  and  widely  distributed. 
In  the  twentieth  century,  property  owners  and  their  legal  defenders  ex- 
ploited these  facts  of  earlier  centuries  in  order  to  defend  quite  a  different 
economic  system,  in  which  property  and  property  rights  had  taken  on 
remarkably  altered  traits  and  attributes  had  become  passive  and  para- 
sitical. The  beginnings  of  the  change  were  to  be  found  even  in  the 
early  period  with  the  rise  of  joint-stock  companies  and  the  growth  of  stock 
exchanges.  Through  these  instruments,  a  new  form  of  property  arose. 
It  was  not  the  ownership  of  a  material  thing  but  of  a  piece  of  paper 
which  stood  for  the  thing,  and  constituted  a  claim  upon  the  profits  of 
enterprise  and  speculation. 

Property  after  the  Industrial  Revolution.  The  Industrial  Revolution 
stimulated  the  growth  of  capitalism  and  the  power  and  scope  of  private 
property.  In  England,  peasants  were  thrown  off  their  small  holdings, 
which  they  had  occupied  tenuously  through  customary  copyholds,  and 
the  land  was  concentrated  in  great  estates  through  the  enclosing  of  land 
between  1760  and  1830.  In  France,  the  French  Revolution  brought  about 
the  opposite  results  by  breaking  up  great  estates  and  increasing  the 
number  of  small  peasant  holdings.  In  English  colonies  in  America  much 
of  the  land  was  formally  owned  by  great  proprietors  who  held  by  royal 
grant,  or  by  the  Dutch  patroons  along  the  Hudson.  But  in  the  later 
Colonial  period,  private  ownership  became  more  usual  and  a  major  social 
result  of  the  American  Revolution  was  the  wiping  out  of  great  estates,  and 
of  entail  and  primogeniture.  The  private  ownership  of  relatively  small 
farms  became  the  rule.  This  process  was  encouraged  by  the  settlement 
of  the  West,  and  particularly  by  the  famous  Homestead  Act  of  1862. 
The  building  of  transcontinental  railroads  threw  much  land  into  the 
hands  of  the  railroad  companies,  but  even  most  of  this  was  later  sold 
off  to  homesteaders.  Timber  and  mineral  interests,  however,  acquired 
vast  tracts  of  the  public  domain,  to  the  detriment  of  the  country  which 
was  not  yet  alive  to  the  pressing  need  for  conservation  policies. 

This  trend,  however,  was  reversed  in  the  twentieth  century  and  there 
has  been  a  marked  decrease  in  outright  farm  ownership.  The  number 
of  mortgaged  farms  has  increased  notably.  In  1890,  the  tenants  made 
up  only  28  per  cent  of  all  farm  occupants,  while  in  1930  they  constituted 
42  per  cent.  Tenancy  is  still  on  the  gain  in  over  forty  states.  Some  of 
these  tenants,  such  as  the  southern  sharecroppers,  live  in  extremely  pre- 


C/.  Gore,  op.  cit.,  Chap.  VI. 


THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY  179 

carious  fashion.  Inadequate  conservation  methods  and  foolish  methods 
of  cultivation  have  led  to  the  exhaustion  of  the  land  and  forced  migra- 
tion of  the  owners,  particularly  in  the  western  dust  bowl  region. 

The  first  World  War  in  Europe  was  followed  by  much  agrarian  reform, 
particularly  in  Central  Europe  and  the  Balkans.  Large  estates  were 
broken  up  and  given  over  to  small  holders.  But  in  Russia,  private  own- 
ership of  land  was  either  extinguished  or  subjected  to  extreme  forms  of 
state  control.  The  rise  of  fascism  has  been  accompanied  by  a  large 
increase  of  state  control  over  private  property.  If  current  tendencies 
continue,  independent  private  ownership  of  land  in  Europe  seems  likely 
to  be  severely  controlled  or  entirely  obliterated. 

The  invention  of  machinery  for  production  created  the  factory  system. 
Many  of  these  factories  were,  at  first,  privately  owned.  Even  when  they 
came  to  be  owned  by  partnerships  and  joint-stock  companies  the  owner- 
ship of  the  factories  was  vested  in  those  who  operated  them  and  received 
the  profits.  Ownership  was  not  yet  separated  from  management  and 
control. 

While  property  holding  by  the  business  classes  became  more  impressive, 
the  Industrial  Revolution  and  the  factory  system  produced  opposite  re- 
sults for  the  laboring  masses.  They  no  longer  owned  their  own  tools  or 
shops.  They  became  what  has  been  called  "wage-slaves,"  rarely  owning 
even  their  own  homes  and  becoming  wholly  dependent  upon  those  who 
controlled  the  factories: 

First,  there  appears  the  important  fact  that  the  proletarian  is  a  typical 
representative  of  that  kind  of  man  who  no  longer  is  in  relation  (either  internal 
or  external)  to  Nature.  The  proletarian  does  not  realise  the  meaning  of  the 
movement  of  the  clouds  in  the  sky;  he  no  longer  understands  the  voice  of  the 
storm.  ...  He  has  no  fatherland,  rather  he  has  no  home  in  which  he  takes 
root.  Can  he  feel  at  home  in  the  dreary  main  streets,  four  stories  high?  He 
changes  his  dwelling  often  either  because  he  dislikes  his  landlord  or  because  he 
changes  his  place  of  work.  As  he  moves  from  room  to  room,  so  he  goes  from 
city  to  city,  from  land  to  land,  wherever  opportunity  (i.e.,  capitalism)  calls. 
Homeless,  restless,  he  moves  over  the  earth;  he  loses  the  sense  of  local  colour;  his 
home  is  the  world.  He  has  lost  the  call  of  Nature,  and  he  has  assimilated  mate- 
rialism. It  is  a  phenomenon  of  today  that  the  great  mass  of  the  population  has 
nothing  to  call  its  own.  In  earlier  times  the  poorest  had  a  piece  of  land,  a 
cottage,  a  few  animals  to  call  his  own;  a  trifle  on  which,  however,  he  could  set 
his  whole  heart.  Today  a  handcart  carries  all  his  possessions  when  a  proletarian 
moves.  A  few  old  scraps  are  all  by  which  his  individual  existence  is  to  be 
known.  ...  All  community  feeling  is  destroyed  by  the  iron  foot  of  capitalism. 
The  village  life  is  gone;  the  proletarian  has  no  social  home;  the  separate  family 
disappears.33 

The  need  for  greater  expenditures,  with  the  development  of  the  factory 
system,  increased  production  and  trade,  and  stimulated  the  growth  of 
capitalism.  Larger  fortunes  arose.  Banking  institutions  became  more 
extensive  and  powerful,  to  provide  credit  for  the  new  business.  Indus- 


33  Werner  Sombart,  Das  Proletariat,  cited  in   Milton  Briggs  and   Percy  Jordan, 
Economic  History  of  England,  4th  ed.,  University  Tutorial  Press,  Ltd.,  1914,  p.  182. 


180  THE   INSTITUTION  OF  PROPERTY 

trial  expansion  became  the  rule.  Property  was  accumulated,  in  part 
to  reinvest,  to  extend  productive  plants  and  to  increase  profits.  But 
throughout  this  era,  preeminently  the  nineteenth  century,  management 
and  control  remained  in  the  hands  of  owners.  A  considerable  group,  to 
be  sure,  derived  their  income  from  investment  in  securities  and  thus  be- 
came what  we  know  as  "absentee  owners/'  but  they  were  the  exceptions 
rather  than  the  rule  until  near  the  close  of  the  nineteenth  century. 
With  the  growth  of  larger  property  interests  there  was  ever  greater 
effort  upon  the  part  of  owners  to  secure  more  legal  protection  of  their 
right  of  ownership  and  their  freedom  of  enterprise.84 

Property  under  Finance  Capitalism.  Few  persons  other  than  tech- 
nical students  of  economic  history  and  corporation  finance  realize  that 
the  twentieth  century  has  produced  one  of  the  greatest  revolutions  in 
the  whole  history  of  property,  especially  in  the  United  States.  With  the 
concentration  of  industry  and  growth  in  the  size  of  plants,  legal  owner- 
ship in  large  corporations  has  been  vested  chiefly  in  a  large  number  of 
security  holders.  But  these  owners  do  not  control  the  policies  of  the 
corporations  or  actively  manage  the  operation  of  the  factories.  They 
are  what  we  call  absentee  owners,  meaning  by  this  that  they  have  no 
personal  contact  with  either  the  corporate  offices  or  the  plants  which  turn 
out  goods  and  services.  Their  ownership  is  both  passive  and  relatively 
impotent.  Only  a  few  very  rich  families,  like  the  Fords,  the  Mellons,  and 
the  DuPonts  have  enough  personal  wealth  to  own  and  operate  their  giant 
concerns. 

In  the  middle  of  the  nineteenth  century  the  industrialist  owned  and 
operated  his  factories  and  machines.  He  controlled  the  policies  of 
production  and  sales,  and  actively  managed  the  operation  of  his  plant. 
Ownership,  control,  and  management  were  unified.  Those  who  control 
business  enterprise  today  are  the  officers  and  directors  of  the  giant  cor- 
porations. But  they  own  relatively  few  of  the  securities  of  such  corpo- 
rations, rarely  as  much  as  10  per  cent  and  usually  less  than  5  per  cent. 
They  rarely  take  any  part  in  the  actual  management  of  factories  and 
business  enterprises,  but  hand  it  over  to  salaried  experts,  often  trained 
in  schools  of  business  administration.  These  experts  run  the  plant  in 
accordance  with  policies  laid  down  by  the  few  men — the  official  clique — 
who  have  gained  control  of  the  corporate  enterprise  through  juggling 
securities. 

All  this  constitutes  a  sweeping  revolution  in  the  former  system  of  uni- 
fied ownership,  control  and  management  of  business.  Owners  cannot 
control  the  use  of  their  property  and  have  only  a  precarious  legal  claim 
on  some  possible  return  from  the  use  of  their  property  by  others.35 
Those  who  control  the  use  of  property  do  not  own  what  they  use  and 
control  but  can  use  it  as  they  wish,  short  of  the  most  overt  and  palpable 
fraud.  They  are  frequently  able  to  escape  detection  even  when  guilty 


84  See  Gore,  op.  cit.,  Chap.  VIII. 

85  Cf.  Harry  Scherman,  The  Promises  Men  Live  By,  Random  House,  1938. 


THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY  181 

of  gigantic  swindles.  Property,  therefore,  is  no  longer  active  and 
dynamic,  as  it  was  in  early  modern  times.  It  is  now  mainly  passive  in 
great  business  enterprises: 

The  characteristic  fact,  which  differentiates  most  modern  property  from  that 
of  the  pre-industrial  age,  and  which  turns  against  it  the  very  reasoning  by  which 
formerly  it  was  supported,  is  that  in  modern  economic  conditions  ownership  is 
not  active,  but  passive,  that  to  most  of  those  who  own  property  today  it  is  not 
a  means  of  work  but  an  instrument  for  the  acquisition  of  gain  or  the  exercise  of 
power,  and  that  there  is  no  guarantee  that  gain  bears  any  relation  to  service,  or 
power  to  responsibility.  For  property  which  can  be  regarded  as  a  condition  of 
the  performance  of  function,  like  the  tools  of  the  craftsman,  or  the  holding  of  the 
peasant,  or  the  personal  possessions  which  contribute  to  a  life  of  health  and 
efficiency,  forms  an  insignificant  proportion,  as  far  as  its  value  is  concerned,  of 
the  property  rights  existing  at  present.  In  modern  industrial  societies  the  great 
mass  of  property  consists,  as  the  annual  review  of  wealth  passing  at  death  re- 
veals, neither  of  personal  acquisitions  such  as  household  furniture,  nor  of  the 
owner's  stock-in-trade,  but  of  rights  of  various  kinds,  such  as  royalties,  ground- 
rents,  and,  above  all,  of  course,  shares  in  industrial  undertakings  which  yield  an 
income  irrespective  of  any  personal  service  rendered  by  their  owners.  Owner- 
ship and  use  are  normally  divorced.  The  greater  part  of  modern  property  has 
been  attenuated  to  a  pecuniary  lien  or  bond  on  the  product  of  industry  which 
carries  with  it  a  right  to  payment,  but  which  is  normally  valued  precisely  be- 
cause it  relieves  the  owner  from  any  obligation  to  perform  a  positive  or  construcr 
tive  function.36 

Control  is  now  the  active  and  dynamic  development  in  business  enter- 
prise, not  ownership  or  property.  The  owners,  in  most  cases,  do  not 
even  know  how  their  property  is  being  used.  Though  the  great  corpora- 
tions give  out  annual  reports,  they  are  either  inadequate,  very  technical, 
or  both.  As  Alden  Winthrop  has  made  clear,  not  one  stockholder  out  of 
a  hundred  can  read  and  understand  a  corporation  report,  even  if  the 
report  happens  to  be  comprehensive  and  accurate.  Owners  can  only 
trust  to  their  luck  and  hope  to  escape  from  the  worst  forms  of  fraud  and 
mismanagement. 

Since  those  who  do  control  business  enterprise  own  only  a  negligible 
part  of  the  enterprise,  they  cannot  expect  any  large  income  from  the 
direct  and  legitimate  profits  paid  out  in  dividends.  They  must  seek 
their  reward  primarily  in  large  salaries  and  bonuses  at  the  expense  of  the 
owners,  or  in  speculative  profits  from  internal  manipulations,  which  are 
even  more  disastrous  to  the  owners  than  lavish  salaries  and  bonuses.  We 
have  described  in  Chapter  VI  how  such  speculative  frauds  and  misman- 
agement have  already  sent  more  than  half  of  the  great  business  enter- 
prises of  our  country  into  bankruptcy  and  reorganization.  When  this 
bankruptcy  takes  place,  those  in  control — officials  and  directors — usually 
take  over  the  reorganized  enterprise  and  the  original  owners  are  left  more 
or  less  propertyless,  so  far  as  the  enterprise  in  question  is  concerned.87 
This  tremendous  revolution  in  the  character  and  use  of  property,  as  a 


86  R.  H.  Tawney,  The  Acquisitive  Society,  Harcourt  Brace,  1920,  pp.  61-62. 
37  Cf.  Max  Lowenthal,  The  Investor  Pays,  Knopf,  1933. 


182  THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY 

phase  of  the  corporate  revolution  and  the  separation  of  ownership  from 
control,  has  been  competently  summarized  by  A.  A.  Berle  and  Gardiner 
Means: 

Corporations  have  ceased  to  be  merely  legal  devices  through  which  the  private 
business  transactions  of  individuals  may  be  carried  on.  Though  still  much  used 
for  this  purpose,  the  corporate  form  has  acquired  a  larger  significance.  The 
corporation  has,  in  fact,  become  both  a  method  of  property  tenure  and  a  means 
of  organizing  economic  life.  Grown  to  tremendous  proportions,  there  may  be 
said  to  have  evolved  a  "coq:>orate  system" — as  there  was  once  a  feudal  system — 
which  has  attracted  to  itself  a  combination  of  attributes  and  powers,  and  has 
attained  a  degree  of  prominence  entitling  it  to  be  dealt  with  as  a  major  social 
institution.  .  .  . 

In  its  new  aspect  the  corporation  is  a  means  whereby  the  wealth  of  innumer- 
able individuals  has  been  concentrated  into  huge  aggregates  and  whereby  control 
over  this  wealth  has  been  surrendered  to  a  unified  direction.  The  power  attend- 
ant upon  such  concentration  has  brought  forth  princes  of  industry,  whose 
position  in  the  community  is  yet  to  be  defined.  The  surrender  of  control  over 
their  wealth  by  investors  has  effectively  broken  the  old  property  relationships 
and  has  raised  the  problem  of  defining  these  relationships  anew.  The  direction 
of  industry  by  persons  other  than  those  who  have  ventured  their  wealth  has 
raised  the  question  of  the  motive  force  back  of  such  direction  and  the  effective 
distribution  of  the  returns  from  business  enterprise. 

Outwardly  the  change  is  simple  enough.  Men  are  less  likely  to  own  the 
physical  instruments  of  production.  They  are  more  likely  to  own  pieces  of 
paper,  loosely  known  as  stocks,  bonds,  and  other  securities,  which  have  become 
mobile  through  the  machinery  of  the  public  markets.  Beneath  this,  however, 
lies  a  more  fundamental  shift.  Physical  control  over  the  instruments  of  produc- 
tion has  been  surrendered  in  ever  growing  degree  to  centralized  groups  who 
manage  property  in  bulk,  supposedly,  but  by  no  means  necessarily,  for  the 
benefit  of  the  security  holders.  Power  over  industrial  property  has  been  cut  off 
from  the  beneficial  ownership  of  this  property — or,  in  less  technical  language, 
from  the  legal  right  to  enjoy  its  fruits.  Control  of  physical  assets  has  passed 
from  the  individual  owner  to  those  who  direct  the  quasi-public  institutions,  while 
the  owner  retains  an  interest  in  their  product  and  increase.  We  see,  in  fact,  the 
surrender  and  regrouping  of  the  incidence  of  ownership,  which  formerly  bracketed 
full  power  of  manual  disposition  with  complete  right  to  enjoy  the  use,  the  fruits, 
and  the  proceeds  of  physical  assets.  There  has  resulted  the  dissolution  of  the 
old  atom  of  ownership  into  its  component  parts,  control  and  beneficial  ownership. 

The  dissolution  of  the  atom  of  property  destroys  the  very  foundation  on 
which  the  economic  order  of  the  past  three  centuries  has  rested.  Private  enter- 
prise, which  has  molded  economic  life  since  the  close  of  the  middle  ages,  has  been 
rooted  in  the  institution  of  private  property.  .  .  . 

In  the  quasi-public  corporation,  such  an  assumption  no  longer  holds.  As  we 
have  seen,  it  is  no  longer  the  individual  himself  who  uses  his  wealth.  Those  in 
control  of  that  wealth,  and  therefore  in  a  position  to  secure  industrial  efficiency 
and  produce  profits,  are  no  longer,  as  owners,  entitled  to  the  bulk  of  such  profits. 
Those  who  control  the  destinies  of  the  typical  modern  corporation  own  so 
insignificant  a  fraction  of  the  company's  stock  that  the  returns  from  running 
the  corporation  profitably  accrue  to  them  in  only  a  very  minor  degree.  The 
stockholders,  on  the  other  hand,  to  whom  the  profits  of  the  corporation  go, 
cannot  be  motivated  by  those  profits  to  a  more  efficient  use  of  the  property,  since 
they  have  surrendered  all  disposition  of  it  to  those  in  control  of  the  enterprise. 
The  explosion  of  the  atom  of  property  destroys  the  basis  of  the  old  assumption 
that  the  quest  for  profits  will  spur  the  owner  of  industrial  property  to  its 
effective  use.  It  consequently  challenges  the  fundamental  economic  principle 
of  individual  initiative  in  industrial  enterprise.  It  raises  for  reexamination  the 


THE   INSTITUTION  OF  PROPERTY  183 

question  of  the  motive  force  back  of  industry,  and  the  ends  for  which  the  modern 
corporation  can  be  or  will  be  run.38 

The  sweeping  transformation  in  the  property  system  has  not  only 
separated  ownership  from  control  and  created  a  system  of  passive  and 
helpless  absentee  ownership,  but  it  has  also  made  property  holding  and 
claims  exceedingly  complex,  as  compared  with  the  days  when  property 
consisted  mainly  of  the  direct  ownership  and  use  of  lands,  weapons,  or 
tools.  Professor  Tawney  lists  some  of  the  outstanding  types  of  property 
today,  running  from  the  direct  and  personal  to  the  most  abstruse  legal 
claims: 

1.  Property  in  payments  made  for  personal  services. 

2.  Property  in  personal  possessions  necessary  to  health  and  comfort. 

3.  Property  in  land  and  tools  used  by  their  owners. 

4.  Property  in  copyright  and  patent  rights  owned  by  authors  and  inventors. 

5.  Property  in  pure  interest,  including  much  agricultural  rent. 

6.  Property  in  profits  of  luck  and  good  fortune:  "quasi-rents." 

7.  Property  in  monopoly  profits. 

8.  Property  in  urban  ground  rents. 

9.  Property  in  royalties.39 

Most  of  the  changes  in  property  concepts  and  usages  in  recent  years 
have  borne  some  definite  relationship  to  corporate  practices  and  inter- 
ests. Outstanding  among  such  changes  has  been  the  enormous,  even 
absurd,  extension  of  the  legal  concept  of  property  and  property  rights. 
At  the  very  time  when  actual  property  rights  are  being  blurred  almost  out 
of  existence  by  corporation  finance,  and  when  property  itself  is  becoming 
progressively  more  insecure,  a  vast  field  of  vested  interests,  claims,  and 
relationships,  which  cannot  in  any  literal  sense  be  regarded  as  property, 
have  been  brought  under  the  legal  cloak  of  property,  and  glorified  and 
protected.  Due  to  the  ingenuity  of  corporation  lawyers,  who  serve 
those  controlling  contemporary  business  enterprise,  the  concept  of  prop- 
erty has  been  extended  until  it  has  lost  all  realism. 

Any  vested  private  interest  which  was  threatened  by  progressive  legis- 
lation for  the  public  welfare  was  christened  "property"  by  the  legal  bat- 
talions of  corporation  finance  and  the  courts  have  usually  upheld  this 
legal  casuistry.40  As  Professor  Hamilton  has  sagely  observed,  the  courts 
did  not  so  much  literally  protect  property;  they  gave  the  name  "property" 
to  everything  they  protected.41  This  innovation  was  brought  about  in 
the  United  States  primarily  as  the  result  of  the  Fourteenth  Amendment 
to  the  Federal  Constitution,  originally  framed  and  adopted  to  protect  the 
civil  rights  of  the  Negroes  in  the  South.  It  stated,  among  other  things, 
that  no  state  shall  deprive  any  person  of  life,  liberty,  or  property  without 
due  process  of  law.  About  fifteen  years  later,  the  lawyers  induced  the 
courts  to  regard  a  corporation  as  a  person.  Then  they  used  the  vague 


38  The  Modern  Corporation  and  Private  Property,  Macmillan,  1932,  pp.  1,  2,  7-9. 
89  Tawney,  op.  cit..  pp.  63-64. 

40  Cf.  T.  W.  Arnold,  The  Folklore  of  Capitalism,  Yale  University  Press,  1937. 

41  Hamilton,  loc.  cit.,  p.  536. 


184  THE   INSTITUTION  OF  PROPERTY 

"due  process  of  law"  concept  as  the  means  of  declaring  unconstitutional 
almost  any  attack  upon  vested  economic  interests,  even  notorious  offenses 
against  the  public  weal.  Policies  and  acts  which  powerful  economic  inter- 
est opposed  were  declared  contrary  to  due  process  of  law  and  were  thus 
set  aside  by  the  courts  as  unconstitutional. 

The  Supreme  Court  of  the  United  States  admitted  to  legal  protection 
under  the  concept  of  property  and  property  rights  such  matters  as 
monopoly  and  the  restraint  of  trade,  the  ability  to  charge  such  railroad 
rates  as  the  railroads  saw  fit,  the  right  to  manufacture  shoddy  material 
and  to  use  short  weights  in  making  sales,  the  right  to  escape  the  taxation 
of  income,  inheritances,  and  stock  dividends,  the  right  to  maintain  any 
working  conditions  that  businessmen  saw  fit  to  impose  upon  their  em- 
ployees, the  right  to  outlaw  union  labor,  and  the  right  of  business  prac- 
tices to  evade  governmental  control.  The  fact  that  some  of  these  "rights" 
were  later  denied  does  not  affect  the  fact  that  they  were  defended  as  prop- 
erty rights  by  lawyers  and  were  so  sustained  for  many  years  by  the 
supreme  law  of  the  United  States.  Indeed,  most  of  these  stood  as  law 
until  President  Roosevelt's  attack  upon  the  Supreme  Court  in  1937.42 
The  relation  of  the  American  constitution  to  the  protection  of  property 
and  the  degree  to  which  the  sanctity  of  property  has  developed  under 
judicial  protection  is  described  by  Arthur  W.  Calhoun: 

The  United  States  Constitution  was  made  by  a  convention  of  property  interests 
for  the  express  purpose  of  preventing  democracy  and  with  the  positive  aim  of 
keeping  the  propertyless  masses  in  subjection.  The  Constitution  was  designed 
as  a  frame-work  of  government  to  operate  for  the  purpose  of  carrying  out  a 
supreme  principle  antecedent  to  the  Constitution  and  possessing  untouchable 
sanctity,  namely  the  sacredness  of  private  property,  which  no  government  was 
entitled  to  infringe. 

One  may  read  the  Constitution  with  considerable  care  and  not  detect  its 
capitalistic  nature  unless  he  is  primed  for  the  discovery.  Unless  one  knows  all 
about  the  making  of  the  document  and  the  "higher  law"  that  it  ordained  to 
carry  out,  he  may  still  cherish  fatal  illusions  about  "the  charter  of  our  liberties." 
The  best  corrective  of  such  fallacies  is  the  behavior  of  the  United  States  Supreme 
Court  specifically  in  its  refusal  to  take  jurisdiction  for  the  protection  of  life  and 
personal  property  of  an  ordinary  sort,  whereas  it  will  comb  to  the  limit  any  case 
in  which  a  state  is  charged  with  confiscation  of  capitalist  property. 

If  Sacco  and  Vanzetti  had  been  proprietors  of  a  little  electric  plant  in  a  small 
Massachusetts  town,  the  United  States  Supreme  Court  would  have  been  glad 
to  see  that  justice  was  done  them  in  a  rate  case  by  the  state  courts.  So  sacred 
is  capitalist  property.  But  no  federal  judge  could  be  found  to  guarantee  their 
rights  to  life  and  liberty  against  the  fatuous  and  bungling  travesty  on  justice 
perpetrated  by  the  Massachusetts  courts.  The  Constitution  professes  to  give 
the  same  protection  to  life  and  liberty  that  it  does  to  property,  but  the  profession 
amounts  to  virtually  nothing  in  any  crucial  case. 

All  this  is  entirely  natural  for  inevitably  the  central  purpose  of  government 
must  be  to  safeguard  the  economic  system  that  prevails  at  the  given  time.  Any 
other  procedure  would  be  suicidal.  Consequently  those  that  support  the  capi- 
talist system  have  no  ground  for  objecting  when  government  lends  itself  as  a 
tool  to  the  capitalist  interests.43 

42  C).  L.  B.  Boudin,  Government  by  Judiciary,  2  Vols.,  Godwin,  1932,  Vol.  II. 

43  A.  W.  Calhoun,  The  Social  Universe,  Vanguard,  1932,  pp.  45-47. 


THE   INSTITUTION  OF  PROPERTY  185 

During  the  early  New  Deal  days  the  Court  upheld,  as  property  rights, 
freedom  from  the  restrictions  of  the  National  Industry  Recovery  Act  and 
the  Agricultural  Adjustment  Act.  It  upheld  the  immunity  of  the  soft 
coal  industry  from  adequate  government  control  and  set  aside  the  New 
York  State  minimum  wage  act.  The  foregoing  are  only  some  of  the 
more  important  extensions  of  the  property  concept  sanctioned  by  the 
Supreme  Court.  They  are  only  a  fraction  of  the  interests  and  policies 
which  vested  interests  and  lawyers  maintained  to  be  legitimate  categories 
of  property.  The  excesses  and  abuses  contained  therein  were  largely 
responsible  for  the  revolt  against  the  Supreme  Court.  Its  reconstruction 
by  President  Roosevelt  seems  likely  to  bring  about  a  marked  restriction 
of  further  legalistic  adventures  in  this  field. 

We  now  seem  on  the  eve  of  a  new  era  in  economic  life  which  tnay  bring 
about  startling  changes  in  property  rights  and  usages.  In  Soviet  Russia, 
state  socialism  was  thoroughly  established  and  with  it  came  the  end  of 
the  private  ownership  of  the  means  of  production  and  distribution.  In 
so-called  "Middle-Way"  countries,  like  Sweden,  and  in  Fascist  states, 
differing  degrees  of  state  capitalism  were  instituted.  This  innovation 
imposed  serious  restrictions  upon  many  property  rights  and  substituted 
actual  government  ownership  of  such  things  as  public  utilities  and  natural 
resources.  Under  the  pressure  of  war,  the  movement  towards  government 
control  and  government  ownership  has  been  rapid  even  in  the  democracies. 
It  would  be  rash  to  make  precise  predictions  about  the  future  of  property, 
but  one  would  be  safe  in  suggesting  that  the  days  of  unrestricted  or  even 
predominant  private  property  are  numbered.  It  is  doubtful  if  they  will 
survive  the  present  generation. 

The  Inheritance  of  Property 

Since  we  have  relative  freedom  in  the  transmission  of  property  in  the 
United  States,  we  usually  assume  that  this  situation  prevails  everywhere 
among  civilized  peoples.  Such  is  not  the  case.  Only  in  England  and 
the  United  States  do  we  find  relatively  complete  freedom  in  the  disposi- 
tion of  property  through  inheritance.  Group  and  family  claims  on  the 
estate  are  widely  recognized  elsewhere  because  of  the  so-called  right  of 
legitim,  or  the  legally  enforceable  claim  of  widows  and  children  to  some 
part  of  the  estate  of  the  deceased. 

Another  consideration  is  that  today  the  right  of  inheritance  has  no 
great  personal  significance  to  the  mass  of  mankind,  whatever  its  signif- 
icance for  our  economic  system  as  a  whole.  Only  a  very  small  fraction 
of  the  populace  can  accumulate  enough  property  so  that  it  may  be 
transmitted  as  large  fortunes.  For  example,  in  England  and  Wales  just 
before  the  first  World  War  only  15  per  cent  of  all  persons  possessing  any 
personal  income  had  property  valued  at  more  than  $500  and  only  7 
per  cent  possessed  more  than  $2,500  in  property.  In  Prussia,  in  1908, 
only  about  14  per  cent  of  the  population  had  property  valued  at  more 
than  $1,200. 


186  THE  INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY 

In  primitive  society,  the  inheritance  of  private  property  was  relatively 
unimportant.  Most  of  the  land  was  owned  communally  or  by  family 
groups.  Therefore,  inheritance  was  mainly,  though  not  wholly,  limited 
to  the  transmission  of  movable  objects  and  chattels.  However,  primitive 
magic  and  religion  imposed  limitations  on  the  transmission  of  even  these 
privately  owned  objects.  Since  possession  and  use  were  believed  to 
confer  the  magic  potency — the  mana — of  the  possessor,  it  was  often 
deemed  dangerous  for  any  survivor  to  claim  and  use  the  personal  property 
of  a  deceased  person.  As  the  result  of  this  notion,  weapons,  tools,  and 
other  private  possessions  were  often  either  buried  with  the  deceased  or 
burned  at  his  death. 

Though  primitive  uses  in  respect  to  inheritance  may  have  been  rela- 
tively unimportant  in  an  economic  sense,  they  were  numerous  and  com- 
plicated.44 As  a  general  rule,  those  things  useful  to  men  were  transmitted 
to  male  relatives  and  those  things  most  serviceable  to  females  to  the 
female  survivors.  Anthropologists  believe  that  this  custom  was  one 
reason  why  women  were  so  frequently  excluded  from  inheriting  property 
belonging  to  their  husbands  or  fathers. 

The  relatives  favored  in  the  inheritance  of  property  were  decided  by 
the  particular  relationship  system  prevailing,  which  was  usually  com- 
plicated* Collateral  inheritance  was  common.  Under  this  system, 
property  went  to  the  surviving  brothers  of  the  deceased  before  it  could  be 
transmitted  to  his  sons.  Primogeniture,  or  inheritance  of  the  whole 
property  by  the  eldest  son,  sometimes  existed,  but  it  was  relatively  rare 
in  primitive  society.  Indeed,  the  opposite  system  at  times  prevailed. 
Then  the  older  sons  were  compelled  to  leave  the  family  home.  The 
youngest  son  stayed  at  home  and  inherited  the  property  of  his  father. 

In  ancient  Egypt,  it  was  the  usual  thing  to  permit  nobles  to  transmit 
their  lands  and  goods  with  the  consent  of  the  Pharaoh.  The  tools  and 
implements  used  in  the  crafts  and  trades  were  handed  on  from  father  to 
sons  within  the  family.  But  the  right  of  inheritance  was  always  strictly 
limited  by  the  power  of  the  monarch: 

,  It  was  in  families  that  peasants,  craftsmen,  and  officials  worked  for  the  King. 
Children  succeeded  their  fathers  in  fields,  workshops,  and  offices.  But  we  should 
note  that  this  heredity  was  always  uncertain,  not  giving  complete  ownership  and 
in  no  way  impairing  the  principle  of  the  King's  eminent  ownership  of  lands  and 
employments.  In  consequence,  there  were  no  social  castes  in  ancient  Egypt,  and 
a  man  could  always  change  his  calling,  at  his  wish  or  by  desire  of  the  King.45 

Much  the  same  situation  with  respect  to  inheritance  prevailed  in 
Mesopotamia.  The  right  of  inheritance  was  frequently  not  equal  among 
all  the  heirs.  For  example,  in  Assyria  the  eldest  son  was  often  allowed 
to  take  two  thirds  of  the  estate,  one  third  of  which  he  personally  selected, 
the  other  third  being  chosen  by  lot.46 


44Lowie,  op.  cit.,  pp.  243  ff. 
45  Moret,  op.  cit.,  p.  273. 
*6Delaporte,  op.  cit.,  p.  295. 


THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY  187 

In  Athenian  society  the  right  to  transmit  property  was  definitely  limited 
by  the  ties  and  claims  of  kindred.  No  bequests  could  be  made  outside  of 
the  clan  without  its  consent  and  a  special  dispensation.  The  property  of 
a  man  went  directly  to  his  sons.  No  legitimate  son  could  be  disinherited. 
If  a  dying  man  had  no  son  he  might  adopt  one,  and  he  usually  imposed 
the  condition  that  this  adopted  son  marry  one  of  his  daughters,  if  there 
were  any.  The  dying  man  could  then  will  his  property  to  this  adopted 
son. 

In  Sparta  the  civic  land  held  by  the  Spartans  was  equally  divided 
among  the  families  and  was  transmitted  undivided  to  the  children.  In- 
heritance was,  thus,  .closely  controlled  by  the  group.  The  property  of 
the  Perioeci  could  be  more  freely  transmitted  by  wills  and  bequests,  but 
even  here  there  were  restrictions. 

In  early  Rome,  the  inheritance  of  property  was  controlled  by  family 
relationships.  All  the  children,  both  male  and  female,  had  equal  rights, 
and  a  grandchild  had  the  rights  of  a  child  if  his  father  was  dead.  Since 
the  early  Roman  land  holdings  were  small,  they  were  rarely  divided  up 
among  the  heirs  but  all  continued  to  use  the  property  as  beneficiaries  in 
common.  Women  were  not  allowed  to  make  a  will  in  early  days  but 
were  later  freed  from  this  disability.  It  was  a  disgrace  to  leave  an 
insolvent  estate.  In  such  cases  the  testator  usually  willed  his  property 
to  a  slave,  on  whom  the  disgrace  might  fall.  The  claims  of  the  kin  were 
protected  even  in  later  Roman  law.  The  famous  law  Papia  Poppaea  of 
9  A.D.  prevented  distant  kinsmen  from  inheriting  the  complete  estate  of 
a  deceased  relative.  Further,  married  people  without  children  were 
restricted  in  the  amount  which  they  could  will  to  each  other.  There  were 
many  subtleties  and  technicalities  in  the  Roman  law  of  inheritance  into 
which  we  need  not  go  here.47  The  above-mentioned  concept  of  the 
legitim  was  basic  in  Roman  inheritance.  It  has  persisted  in  Romance 
countries,  where  the  legal  system  has  been  modeled  on  that  of  Rome,  thus 
limiting  the  freedom  of  inheritance  in  those  countries. 

In  early  German  law  a  father's  property  was  divided  equally  among 
his  sons.  This  practice  even  restricted  somewhat  the  practice  of  primo- 
geniture in  Germany  during  the  feudal  period,  though  primogeniture  was 
common  there.  In  most  of  western  Europe  inheritance  by  primogeniture 
prevailed  among  the  nobility  and  knights.  For  both  military  and  eco- 
nomic reasons  it  was  desirable  to  keep  estates  intact.  The  serfs  on  the 
manor  had  no  power  of  free  transmission  of  property.  They  did  not  own 
any  land,  and  their  tools  and  cattle  were  communally  controlled  and 
handed  on  through  the  family.  The  gildsmen  in  the  towns  could  transmit 
their  property  to  their  heirs,  but  gild  laws  and  usages  restricted  complete 
independence  in  testamentary  disposition  of  property. 

Even  in  Britain  and  the  United  States  there  are  restrictions  likely  to 
be  enforced  by  law.  Male  descendants  have  an  advantage  over  females 


47  See  a  brief  summary  in  J.  E.  Sandys,  A  Companion  to  Latin  Studies f  Cambridge 
University  Press,  1921,  pp.  311-316. 


188  THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY 

in  their  claims  and,  if  a  man  disinherits  any  or  all  of  his  legitimate  chil- 
dren, there  is  a  reasonable  prospect  that  legal  action  will  succeed  in 
destroying  or  modifying  the  will  of  the  deceased.  When  there  is  no 
legitimate  heir  the  general  rule  of  inheritance  is  that  the  closest  male 
relative  shall  receive  the  property. 

In  Soviet  Russia,  the  inheritance  of  property  was  at  first  wiped  out 
entirely.  Later  on,  relative  freedom  of  inheritance  was  restored.  But 
since  most  private  property  has  been  extinguished  in  Soviet  Russia,  about 
all  that  can  be  transmitted  are  personal  possessions.  In  Fascist  states, 
inheritance  has  not  only  been  curtailed  but  in  some  cases  nullified  through 
heavy  inheritance  taxes  and  confiscation.  Under  a  system  of  state  so- 
cialism or  state  capitalism  the  inheritance  of  property  is  therefore  rela- 
tively as  unimportant  as  it  was  in  primitive  society. 

Since  inheritance  today  is  a  major  cause  of  the  existence  and  perpetua- 
tion of  great  inequalities  of  wealth,  the  ethics  of  inheritance  have  been 
warmly  debated.  Those  who  support  freedom  of  inheritance  argue  that 
it  is  an  incentive  to  economic  effort,  that  it  alone  makes  possible  an 
adequate  accumulation  of  capital  for  re-investment,  and  that  it  promotes 
great  bequests  to  culture  and  charity. 

Against  this  is  the  argument  that  the  rich  seek  to  acquire  for  their  own 
sake  rather  than  for  their  children.  Many  hang  on  to  their  estates  until 
their  death  in  spite  of  the  penalty  of  high  inheritance  taxes.  It  is  stated 
that  too  much  capital  is  accumulated  and  invested.  The  unequal  dis- 
tribution of  wealth  makes  it  impossible  for  the  masses  to  buy  what  is  al- 
ready turned  out  by  the  existing  capital  plant.  Finally,  it  has  been  shown 
that  the  bequests  for  charity  and  cultural  purposes  by  the  wealthy  are 
relatively  insignificant.  In  France,  on  the  eve  of  the  first  World  War, 
only  one  per  cent  of  great  fortunes  went  for  such  purposes.  While  the 
percentage  is  a  little  higher  in  England  and  the  United  States,  it  is  rela- 
tively negligible,  as  Abraham  Epstein,  E.  C.  Lindeman,  and  Horace  Coon 
have  amply  shown. 

Professor  Lindeman's  book,  Wealth  and  Culture,  is  an  important  study 
of  the  social  significance  of  bequests  from  the  estates  of  the  wealthy.  It 
is  an  elaborate  survey  of  the  relation  between  great  fortunes  and  humani- 
tarian effort.  The  product  of  several  years  of  careful  study,  it  is  an 
impressive  statistical  analysis  of  the  problem.  Mr.  Lindeman  here  pre- 
sents evidence  as  to  the  enormous  concentration  of  property  and  income  in 
the  United  States,  such  as  the  fact  that  one  per  cent  of  the  people  own 
59  per  cent  of  the  total  wealth  of  the  country,  and  13  per  cent  own 
90  per  cent  of  the  total  wealth,  and  75  per  cent  own  practically  nothing. 
In  the  matter  of  income,  there  is  also  a  large  concentration  in  the  hands 
of  a  fortunate  few.  For  example,  the  1.7  per  cent  of  the  population 
having  incomes  of  over  $5,000  a  year  receive  14.8  per  cent  of  the  total 
money  income. 

Do  those  who  are  fortunate  with  respect  to  wealth  and  income  hand 
back  most  of  it  for  the  benefit  of  humanity?  Mr.  Lindeman  finds  that 
there  is  no  such  general  tendency,  as  is  usually  taken  for  granted,  for 


THE    INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY  189 

the  wealthy  to  return  any  considerable  part  of  their  income  to  be  put  at 
the  service  of  mankind: 

It  seems  entirely  clear  that  persons  who  possess  large  estates  do  not,  at  death, 
redistribute  any  sizeable  portion  of  their  wealth  to  society.  They  pass  their 
wealth  on,  so  far  as  is  possible,  to  a  small  circle  of  relatives  and  friends.  Only 
six  per  cent  of  the  wealthy  distribute  their  estates  among  agencies  and  institutions. 
Moreover,  the  sum  which  they  thus  distribute  amounts  to  only  six  per  cent  of 
the  total  wealth  bequeathed. 

And,  what  is  even  of  greater  significance,  perhaps,  is  the  fact  that  the  bulk  of 
wealth  thus  distributed  flows  into  the  treasuries  of  churches,  hospitals,  and  con- 
ventional charities.  In  short,  the  cultural  importance  of  redistributed  personal 
wealth  is  slight.  This  analysis  of  probated  wills  and  appraised  estates  reveals 
that  Americans  on  the  whole  regard  their  wealth  as  personal  possessions  to  be 
disposed  of  according  to  individual  interest  or  fancy.48 

From  the  funds  at  the  disposal  of  the  foundations  and  community 
trusts  in  the  United  States  there  is  contributed  only  some  five  to  ten 
per  cent  of  the  total  of  our  philanthropic  budget.  Most  of  their  appro- 
priations here  have  gone  for  the  furtherance  of  projects  devoted  to 
education,  health,  and  social  welfare.  Ninety  per  cent  of  all  their  ex- 
penditures from  1920  to  1930  went  for  such  purposes. 

Coon  has  gone  even  further  and  shown  that  many  gifts  for  charitable 
and  cultural  purposes,  especially  in  the  form  of  great  endowments,  have 
been  consciously  bestowed  mainly  to  protect  property  from  state  inter- 
ference. By  linking  up  these  endowments  with  science,  medicine,  engi- 
neering, and  art,  it  is  possible  for  those  who  defend  vested  wealth  to 
allege  that  any  attack  upon  property  and  profits  means  a  blow  at  all 
human  culture.  Social  reforms  can  thus  be  blocked  or  discredited  by 
propaganda.  In  other  words,  many,  if  not  most,  bequests  are  consciously 
given  as  a  mode  of  insurance  against  a  greater  degree  of  state  restriction 
of  economic  freedom  and  property  rights.49 

Another  point  to  be  emphasized  is  that  the  higher  the  taxes  that  are 
imposed  upon  great  fortunes,  especially  upon  their  transmission,  the 
greater  the  probability  that  gifts  will  be  made  for  charitable  and  cultural 
purposes  before  decease. 

The  Social  Justification  of  Property  and 
Property  Rights 

In  considering  the  arguments  in  support  of  the  institution  of  private 
property  it  should  be  kept  clearly  in  mind  that  there  is  no  such  thing  as 
a  natural  or  inherent  right  of  property  which,  like  the  law  of  gravitation, 
antedates  the  appearance  of  man  on  the  planet.  Property,  especially 
private  property,  is  purely  a  social  institution,  which  made  its  appearance 
relatively  late  in  the  experience  of  mankind.  If  property  is  to  be  justified 
and  vindicated,  this  can  only  be  done  by  showing  that  the  contributions 

48  Lindeman,  op.  cit.,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1935,  p.  50. 

49  Horace  Coon.  Money  to  Burn,  Longmans,  Green,  1939. 


190  THE  INSTITUTION  OF  PROPERTY 

of  private  property  to  human  well-being  and  social  progress  outweigh 
the  evil  effects  of  private  property.  This  institution  must  stand  on  its 
own  merits.  Like  all  other  social  institutions,  it  must  be  judged  by  its 
social  contributions  and  liabilities.50 

The  most  elementary  argument  for  private  property  is  that  it  is  neces- 
sary to  provide  for  the  bare  needs  of  human  subsistence.  But,  to  assure 
mere  subsistence,  private  property  has  not  been  required.  Communally 
held  property  has  assured  both  subsistence  and  a  considerable  surplus  over 
the  bare  needs  of  living.  Certain  schools  of  radical  thought  even  contend 
that  state  ownership  would  bring  about  a  far  higher  standard  of  living 
than  private  property  has  ever  produced.  We  do  not  assume  here  to  con- 
firm or  refute  any  such  assertion.  All  we  need  do  is  to  make  it  clear  that 
private  property  is  not  essential  to  life,  even  in  well  developed  societies. 
The  vital  necessity  is  to  have  the  materials  essential  to  life  available  for 
use  by  groups  and  individuals.  Private  property  has  often  performed  this 
function,  but  it  is  by  no  means  indispensable  in  this  service.  Whatever 
can  assure  effective  use  of  lands,  tools,  and  goods  will  suffice. 

Though  private  property  may  not  be  necessary  to  assure  mere  liveli- 
hood it  may  supply  the  most  dynamic  human  initiative  and  stimulate 
the  highest  degree  of  human  efficiency.  This,  indeed,  is  the  most  usual 
argument  in  behalf  of  private  property.  Volumes  have  been  spoken  and 
written  on  "the  magic  touch  of  private  property"  in  awakening  human 
effort.  One  of  the  most  impressive,  Carl  Snyder's  Capitalism  the  Creator, 
appeared  in  1940.  There  is  considerable  validity  to  this  argument  under 
conditions  in  which  the  mode  of  holding  and  using  property  bears  a  direct 
relationship  to  private  gain.  It  should  be  made  clear,  however,  that 
human  effort  can  be  stimulated  by  other  motives  than  pecuniary  greed. 
The  normal  man  wishes  to  rate  well  according  to  the  standards  and 
judgments  which  prevail  in  his  society.  When  these  standards  and  judg- 
ments are  primarily  related  to  property  and  money,  then  private  property 
may,  indeed,  constitute  a  great  impulse  to  effort.  But,  with  a  shift  of 
such  standards  in  society,  monetary  gain  and  status  would  have  less 
potency.  History  supports  this  contention  through  such  examples  as 
medieval  monasticism,  in  which  the  ideal  of  poverty  and  the  repudiation 
of  private  property  was  a  major  social  value  and  stimulus  to  conduct. 
Social  pressures  may  do  quite  as  much  as  private  property  in  stimulating 
effort  and  initiative.  This  is  proved  by  the  effect  of  state  supervision  of 
work  in  Periclcan  Athens,  and  the  power  of  gild  ideals  in  stimulating 
pride  in  workmanship  during  the  Middle  Ages.  In  other  words,  indus- 
trial initiative  can  be  of  a  social  as  well  as  a  personal  origin. 

The  best  illustration  of  the  impulse  afforded  to  personal  efficiency  and 
industrial  effort  by  private  property  is  drawn  from  conditions  in  early 
modern  times,  say  from  1650  to  1800.  Then,  both  land  and  tools  were 
owned  by  private  individuals,  upon  whose  efforts  depended  the  possi- 


o  Cj.  Gore,  op.  tit.,  Chaps.  II-III,  VII. 


THE   INSTITUTION  OF   PROPERTY  191 

bility  not  only  of  making  additional  profits  and  extending  property 
holdings  but  even  of  retaining  the  property  in  hand: 

When  property  in  land  and  what  simple  capital  existed  were  generally  diffused 
among  all  classes  of  society,  when,  in  most  parts  of  England,  the  typical  workman 
was  not  a  laborer  but  a  peasant  or  small  master,  who  could  point  to  the  strips 
which  he  had  plowed  or  the  cloth  he  had  woven,  when  the  greater  part  of  the 
wealth  passing  at  death  consisted  of  land,  household  furniture  and  a  stock  in 
trade  which  was  hardly  distinguishable  from  it,  the  moral  justification  of  the  title 
to  property  was  self-evident.  It  was  obviously,  what  theorists  said,  that  it  was, 
and  plain  men  knew  it  to  be,  the  labor  spent  in  producing,  acquiring  and 
administering  it. 

Such  property  was  not  a  burden  upon  society,  but  a  condition  of  its  health 
and  efficiency,  and  indeed,  of  its  continued  existence.  To  protect  it  was  to  main- 
tain the  organization  through  which  public  necessities  were  supplied.  If,  as  in 
Tudor  England,  the  peasant  was  evicted  from  his  holding  to  make  room  for 
sheep,  or  crushed,  as  in  eighteenth  century  France,  by  arbitrary  taxation  and 
seignurial  dues,  land  went  out  of  cultivation  and  the  whole  community  was  short 
of  food.  If  the  tools  of  the  carpenter  or  smith  were  seized,  plows  were  not  re- 
paired or  horses  shod.  Hence,  before  the  rise  of  a  commercial  civilization,  it 
was  the  mark  of  statesmanship,  alike  in  the  England  of  the  Tudors  and  in  the 
France  of  Henry  IV,  to  cherish  the  small  property-owner  even  to  the  point  of 
offending  the  great.  ... 

They  found  the  meaning  of  property  in  the  public  purposes  to  which  it  con- 
tributed, whether  they  were  the  production  of  food,  as  among  the  peasantry,  or 
the  management  of  public  affairs,  as  among  the  gentry,  and  hesitated  neither  to 
maintain  those  kinds  of  property  which  met  these  obligations  nor  to  repress 
those  uses  of  it  which  appeared  likely  to  conflict  with  them.  Property  was  to  be 
an  aid  to  creative  work,  not  an  alternative  to  it.  The  patentee  was  secured 
protection  for  his  own  brain,  but  the  monopolist  who  grew  fat  on  the  industry  of 
others  was  to  be  put  down.  The  law  of  the  village  bound  the  peasant  to  use  his 
land,  not  as  he  himself  might  find  most  profitable,  but  to  grow  the  corn  the 
village  needed.51 

However,  these  conditions  no  longer  prevail  in  most  civilized  states. 
Hence  arguments  in  behalf  of  property  drawn  from  conditions  of  the 
seventeenth  and  eighteenth  centuries  possess  little  or  no  validity  in  the 
second  third  of  the  twentieth  century. 

In  the  earlier  days  of  the  Industrial  Revolution,  productive  effort  and 
industrial  expansion  were  stimulated  by  private  property.  When  a  man 
owned  and  operated  his  own  factory  he  had  an  immediate  incentive  to 
industrial  activity.  The  property  motive  also  encouraged  saving  and 
further  investment  in  plant  expansion  because,  with  an  extension  of  the 
factory  facilities,  there  was  every  reason  to  expect  greater  production 
and  profits.  Nevertheless,  we  cannot  attribute  the  great  industrial  de- 
velopment of  Europe  and  the  United  States  between  1750  and  1900  solely 
to  the  energy  and  efforts  of  businessmen,  impelled  by  the  profit  and 
property  motives.  As  Professor  F.  W.  Taussig  pointed  out  in  his  im- 
portant book  on  Investors  and  Moneymakers,  we  owe  this  remarkable 
industrial  expansion  quite  as  much  to  scientists,  engineers,  and  other 
inventors.  And  these  scientists  and  technicians  were  not  dominated 


51  Tawney,  op.  dt.t  pp.  57,  59-60. 


192  THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY 

primarily  by  pecuniary  impulses  and  the  desire  to  accumulate  property. 
Many  of  them  died  penniless. 

There  is  little  doubt,  then,  that  the  acquisition  and  holding  of  property 
were  once  of  great  aid  in  accumulating  capital  to  promote  industrial  ex- 
pansion. Until  recent  times,  property  may  be  regarded  as  having  served 
a  useful  service  in  this  regard.  But  in  late  years  the  results  of  property 
accumulation  have  been  mainly  anti-social  and  disastrous.  There  has 
been  a  tendency  to  concentrate  wealth  and  to  overinvest  in  plant  expan- 
sion at  the  expense  of  wages  and  salaries.  As  a  result,  businessmen  have 
been  able  to  sell  only  a  fraction  of  what  they  can  produce.  This  under- 
consumption, growing  out  of  inadequate  purchasing  power,  is  an  out- 
standing reason  for  the  decline  of  the  capitalistic  system.  In  other 
words,  excessive  savings,  overinvestment  in  plant  expansion,  and  notori- 
ous concentration  of  wealth  are  paralyzing  rather  than  stimulating  capi- 
talistic industry  and  business. 

Under  the  system  of  absentee  ownership,  the  possession  of  private 
property  docs  not  stimulate  productive  effort  but,  rather,  indolence  and 
passivity.  Property,  in  any  large  amount,  is  valuable  today  primarily 
for  the  social  prestige  and  display  which  it  affords.  And  one  of  the  major 
ways  in  which  this  prestige  and  display  may  be  manifested  is  through 
unusual  and  conspicuous  waste.  It  is  not  unfair,  then,  to  maintain  that 
a  great  deal  of  property  today  promotes  idleness  and  waste  rather  than 
any  effort  whatever  at  productive  efficiency.  This  important  considera- 
tion has  been  summarized  with  incomparable  force  and  irony  by  Thorstein 
Veblen  in  his  famous  book  of  The  Theory  of  the  Leisure  Class: 

So  soon  as  the  possession  of  property  becomes  the  basis  of  popular  esteem, 
therefore,  it  becomes  also  a  requisite  to  that  complacency  which  we  call  self- 
respect.  In  any  community  where  goods  are  held  in  scveralty  it  is  necessary,  in 
order  to  insure  his  own  peace  of  mind,  that  an  individual  possess  as  large  a 
portion  of  goods  as  others  with  whom  he  is  accustomed  to  class  himself;  and  it 
is  extremely  gratifying  to  possess  something  more  than  others.  But  as  fast  as  a 
person  makes  new  acquisitions,  and  becomes  accustomed  to  the  resulting  new 
standard  of  wealth,  the  new  standard  forthwith  ceases  to  afford  appreciably 
greater  satisfaction  than  the  earlier  standard  did.  The  tendency  in  any  case  is 
constantly  to  make  the  present  pecuniary  standard  the  point  of  departure  for  a 
fresh  increase  of  wealth;  and  this  in  turn  gives  rise  to  a  new  standard  of  suffi- 
ciency and  a  new  pecuniary  classification  of  one's  self  as  compared  with  one's 
neighbours.  .  .  . 

In  order  to  gain  and  hold  the  esteem  of  men  it  is  not  sufficient  merely  to  possess 
wealth  or  power.  The  wealth  or  power  must  be  put  in  evidence,  for  esteem  is 
awarded  only  on  evidence.  And  not  only  does  the  evidence  of  wealth  serve  to 
impress  one's  importance  on  others  and  to  keep  their  sense  of  his  importance 
alive  and  alert,  but  it  is  of  scarcely  less  use  in  building  up  and  preserving  one's 
self-complacency.  ... 

Abstention  from  labour  is  not  only  a  honorific  or  meritorious  act,  but  it 
presently  comes  to  be  a  requisite  of  decency.  The  insistence  on  property  as 
the  basis  of  reputability  is  very  naive  and  very  imperious  during  the  early  stages 
of  the  accumulation  of  wealth.  Abstention  from  labour  is  the  conventional  evi- 
dence of  wealth  and  is  therefore  the  conventional  mark  of  social  standing;  and 
this  insistence  on  the  merit oriousness  of  wealth  leads  to  a  more  strenuous  in- 
sistence on  leisure.  .  .  . 


THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY  193 

The  quasi-peaceable  gentleman  of  leisure  .  .  .  not  only  consumes  of  the  staff 
of  life  beyond  the  minimum  required  for  subsistence  and  physical  efficiency,  but 
his  consumption  also  undergoes  a  specialization  as  regards  the  quality  of  the 
goods  consumed.  He  consumes  freely  and  of  the  best,  in  food,  drink,  narcotics, 
shelter,  services,  ornaments  .  .  .  amulets,  and  idols  or  divinities.  .  .  . 

Conspicuous  consumption  of  valuable  goods  is  a  means  of  reputability  to  the 
gentleman  of  leisure.  As  wealth  accumulates  on  his  hands,  his  own  unaided 
effort  will  not  avail  to  sufficiently  put  his  opulence  in  evidence  by  this  method. 
The  aid  of  friends  and  competitors  is  therefore  brought  in  by  resorting  to  the 
giving  of  valuable  presents  and  expensive  feasts  and  entertainments.  .  .  . 

From  the  foregoing  survey  of  the  growth  of  conspicuous  leisure  and  consump- 
tion, it  appears  that  the  utility  of  both  alike  for  the  purposes  of  reputability  lies 
in  the  element  of  waste  that  is  common  to  both.  In  the  one  case  it  is  a  waste 
of  time  and  effort;  in  the  other  it  is  a  waste  of  goods.  Both  are  methods  of 
demonstrating  the  possession  of  wealth,  and  the  two  are  conventionally  accepted 
as  equivalents.52 

Property  holding  and  property  motives  in  our  day  are,  thus,  likely  to 
lead  to  the  exploitation  of  society  and  indifference  to  public  interest: 

If,  therefore,  under  the  modern  conditions  which  have  concentrated  any  substan- 
tial share  of  property  in  the  hands  of  a  small  minority  of  the  population,  the  world 
is  to  be  governed  for  the  advantages  of  those  who  own,  it  is  only  incidentally  and 
by  accident  that  the  results  will  be  agreeable  to  those  who  work.  In  practice 
there  is  a  constant  collision  between  them.  Turned  into  another  channel,  half  the 
wealth  distributed  in  dividends  to  functionless  shareholders,  could  secure  every 
child  a  good  education  up  to  18,  could  re-endow  English  Universities,  and  (since 
more  efficient  production  is  important)  could  equip  English  industries  for  more 
efficient  production.  Half  the  ingenuity  now  applied  to  the  protection  of  property 
could  have  made  most  industrial  diseases  as  rare  as  smallpox,  and  most  English 
Cities  into  places  of  health  and  beauty.  What  stands  in  the  way  is  the  doctrine 
that  the  rights  of  property  are  absolute,  irrespective  of  any  social  function  which 
its  owners  may  perform.  So  the  laws  which  are  most  stringently  enforced  are  still 
the  laws  which  protect  property,  though  the  protection  of  property  is  no  longer 
likely  to  be  equivalent  to  the  protection  of  work,  and  the  interests  which  govern 
industry  and  predominate  in  public  affairs  are  proprietary  interests.  A  mill-owner 
may  poison  or  mangle  a  generation  of  operatives ;  but  his  brother  magistrates  will 
let  him  off  with  a  caution  or  a  nominal  fine  to  poison  and  mangle  the  next.  For  he 
is  an  owner  of  property.  A  landowner  may  draw  rents  from  slums  in  which 
young  children  die  at  the  rate  of  200  per  1000;  but  he  will  be  none  the  less 
welcome  in  polite  society.  For  property  has  no  obligation  and  therefore  can  do 
no  wrong.  Urban  land  may  be  held  from  the  market  on  the  outskirts  of  cities 
in  which  human  beings  are  living  three  to  a  room,  and  rural  land  may  be  used 
for  sport  when  villagers  are  leaving  it  to  overcrowd  them  still  more.  No  public 
authority  intervenes,  for  both  are  property.  To  those  who  believe  that  institu- 
tions which  repudiate  all  moral  significance  must  sooner  or  later  collapse,  a 
society  which  confuses  the  protection  of  property  with  the  preservation  of  its 
functionless  perversions  will  appear  as  precarious  as  that  which  has  left  the 
memorials  of  its  tasteless  frivolity  and  more  tasteless  ostentation  in  the  gardens 
of  Versailles.53 

It  is,  thus,  very  evident  that  there  is  no  important  incentive  to  effort  in 
passive  or  functionless  property,  as  it  now  exists  under  a  system  of 


52  From  The  Theory  of  the  Leisure  Class,  by  Thorstein  Veblen.    Copyright  1899, 
1912.    By  permission  of  The  Viking  Press,  Inc.,  New  York.    Pp.  31,  36-37,  41,  73,  75,  85. 
fi8  Tawney,  op.  cit.,  pp.  79-81. 


194  THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY 

absentee  ownership.  Indeed,  the  situation  today  is  one  in  which  the 
dominion  of  functionless  property  threatens  the  existence  of  the  whole 
property  system  and,  with  it,  capitalistic  society: 

Indeed,  functionless  property  is  the  greatest  enemy  of  legitimate  property  it- 
self. It  is  the  parasite  which  kills  the  organism  that  produced  it.  Bad  money 
drives  out  good,  and,  as  the  history  of  the  last  two  hundred  years  shows,  when 
property  for  acquisition  or  power  and  property  for  service  or  for  use  jostle  each 
other  freely  in  the  market,  without  restrictions  such  as  some  legal  systems  have 
imposed  on  alienation  and  inheritance,  the  latter  tends  normally  to  be  absorbed 
by  the  former,  because  it  has  less  resisting  power.  Thus  functionless  property 
grows,  and  as  it  grows  it  undermines  the  creative  energy  which  produced  property 
and  which  in  earlier  ages  it  protected.  It  cannot  unite  men,  for  what  united 
them  is  the  bond  of  service  to  a  common  purpose,  and  that  bond  it  repudiates, 
whence  its  very  essence  is  the  maintenance  of  rights  irrespective  of  service.  It 
cannot  create;  it  can  only  spend,  so  that  the  number  of  scientists,  inventors, 
artists,  or  men  of  letters  who  have  sprung  in  the  course  of  the  last  century  from 
hereditary  riches  can  be  numbered  on  one  hand.  It  values  neither  culture  nor 
beauty,  but  only  the  power  which  belongs  to  wealth  and  the  ostentation  which  is 
the  symbol  of  it.54 

As  J.  A.  Hobson  and  others  have  suggested,  there  are  many  incentives 
other  than  property  which  may  impel  man  to  efficient  and  productive 
effort.  Such  are  the  pride  of  workmanship,  community  spirit,  interest 
in  the  public  weal,  and  striving  for  cultural  and  professional  superiority. 
The  competitive  spirit  can  be  stimulated  even  in  economic  production  by 
other  than  profit  and  property  motives.  This  has  been  demonstrated  by 
the  Stakhanov  system  in  Soviet  Russia,  where  prizes  and  prestige  have 
been  bestowed  upon  those  who  create  outstanding  records  for  productive 
efficiency.  Self-expression,  prestige,  and  superiority  are  powerful  mo- 
tives among  mankind.  Property  is  a  strong  stimulus  only  when  social 
prestige  and  superiority  rests  primarily  upon  wealth.  When  other  types 
of  achievement  confer  comparable  or  greater  prestige,  they  immediately 
become  more  powerful  than  property  in  stimulating  human  effort. 

In  conclusion,  while  private  property  has  constituted  a  powerful  im- 
pulse to  initiative  and  efficiency  in  the  past,  and  especially  in  early 
modern  times,  much  of  present-day  property  encourages  industrial 
'passivity  and  personal  sloth,  rather  than  efficient  productive  effort.  As 
L.  T.  Hobhouse  puts  it,  modern  economic  conditions  have  all  but  abolished 
property  for  use  and  have  substituted  property  for  power.55  And  a 
great  deal  of  property  is  accumulated,  held,  and  utilized  by  methods 
which  hamper  production  and  undermine  the  health  of  the  capitalistic 
system. 

In  any  event,  it  is  high  time  to  seek  new  incentives  for  mankind. 
Rightly  or  wrongly,  whether  we  approve  or  regret  the  change,  it  seems 
that  we  are  headed  towards  an  era  in  which  private  property  will  be 
greatly  reduced,  if  not  entirely  obliterated,  except  for  purely  personal 
possessions.  If  we  pass  into  an  age  in  which  there  is  little  private 


c*  Ibid.,  pp.  81-82. 

05  Gore,  op.  cit.,  p.  23. 


THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY  195 

property  and  we  have  no  other  incentives  for  human  effort,  the  state  of 
mankind  will  be  unfortunate  indeed. 

From  the  ethical  and  psychological  point  of  view,  it  has  been  argued 
that  private  property  is  desirable  for  its  influence  upon  the  human  per- 
sonality— that  property  rounds  out  the  personality,  gives  a  sense  of 
responsibility,  and  helps  to  provide  a  salutary  discipline  over  ideas  and 
conduct.  There  is  some  element  of  truth  in  this  contention.56  But  it  is 
also  true,  as  others,  especially  reformers  and  Christian  socialists,  have 
maintained,  that  the  excesses  and  abuses  of  property  have  done  more 
than  anything  else  to  stimulate  human  brutality,  selfishness,  exploitation, 
and  misery.  Even  Jesus  remarked  on  the  ethical  handicaps  of  the  rich 
man. 

Some  Outstanding  Abuses  of  Property 

While  conceding  the  stimulus  which  property  has  offered  to  human 
effort  in  the  past,  we  must  also  recognize  the  evils  which  have  followed 
in  the  train  of  property.  In  ancient  days,  perhaps  the  greatest  evil  of 
private  property  was  human  slavery  and  the  exploitation  of  the  masses. 
The  sad  story  has  been  told  in  the  monumental  work  of  C.  Osborne  Ward, 
The  Ancient  Lowly,  a  book  which  has  been  unfortunately  neglected  by 
students  of  social  history.57  The  slave  system  was  probably  most  ex- 
tensive and  brutal  in  the  later  Roman  Republic  and  the  early  days  of 
the  Empire.  Not  only  were  great  numbers  enslaved  under  conditions  of 
gross  brutality  and  oppression,  but  the  masses  were  demoralized  and  im- 
poverished. Even  when  sustained  by  the  state,  as  in  the  instance  of  the 
Roman  system  of  bread-and-circuses,  the  masses  lost  their  morale,  initia- 
tive, and  self-respect. 

In  the  Middle  Ages,  the  property  system  not  only  encouraged  the 
exploitation  of  serfs,  but  also  the  unabashed  robbery  and  pillage  carried 
on  by  the  medieval  nobles  and  knights.  The  church  itself  became 
enormously  rich  at  the  price  of  impoverishing  many  of  its  loyal  followers. 
Its  avarice  was  a  major  cause  of  the  Protestant  Revolt.  The  kings  and 
princes  resented  the  crushing  church  taxation,  and  the  religious  reformers 
were  shocked  at  the  degradation  of  religion  by  ecclesiastical  materialism. 

When,  at  the  end  of  the  Middle  Ages,  absolute  monarchs  arose,  they 
created  their  brilliant,  corrupt,  and  expensive  court  life  on  the  basis  of 
crushing  exploitation  of  the  majority  of  the  citizens.  The  nobility 
wasted  lavishly  while  the  bulk  of  the  nation  suffered  in  want  and  poverty. 
Not  infrequently  did  the  court  live  riotously  while  famines  swept  away 
thousands  of  loyal  subjects. 

More  horrible  in  many  ways  was  the  exploitation  of  the  working  classes 
in  the  new  factories  which  sprang  up  as  a  phase  of  the  Industrial  Revolu- 
tion. The  working  conditions  in  the  factories  themselves  were  shocking, 
and  the  hours  of  labor  long.  Wages  were  low,  and  the  apologetic  econo- 

™  C/.  Gore,  op.  cit.,  Chap.  VII. 
"  2  Vols.,  Kerr,  1907. 


196  THE  INSTITUTION  OF   PROPERTY 

mists  contended  that  they  must  remain  low  because  only  a  limited  sum — 
given  the  mystic  title  of  "the  wages-fund" — could  be  paid  without  wreck- 
ing industry.  An  economist  of  great  prestige  at  the  time,  Nassau  Senior, 
maintained  that  the  working  day  could  not  be  shortened  because  the 
employer  had  to  make  all  his  profits  during  the  last  hour.  Senior  was, 
accordingly,  dubbed  "Last  Hour"  Senior.  The  eulogy  of  property  as  a 
natural  right  of  man  and  the  idea  that  the  chief  obligation  of  government 
is  to  protect  property  united  with  the  dogmas  of  the  economists  to  create 
stubborn  obstacles  to  factory  reform  and  the  promotion  of  social  justice. 

We  have  already  discussed  certain  of  the  evils  which  have  arisen  as  a 
result  of  the  corporate  revolution  and  the  rise  of  finance  capitalism.  To 
list  some  of  the  major  evils:  It  has  transformed  property  owners  from 
workers  and  producers  into  absentee  drones.  It  has  enormously  increased 
the  expenses  of  living.  For  every  dollar  which  we  pay  to  the  pro- 
ducer of  goods,  we  pay  around  $2.30  for  overhead,  much  of  which  goes  to 
those  who  take  no  active  part  in  economic  life.  Finance  capitalism  has 
restricted  and  curtailed  productive  output  to  an  unbelievable  degree. 
Even  capitalistic  experts  contend  that  we  could  produce  approximately 
100  per  cent  more  with  our  present  capital  plant,  were  it  not  for  handicaps 
imposed  mainly  by  finance  capitalism.  Radical  technicians  estimate  that 
we  might  produce  more  than  three  times  as  much,  if  our  productive  plant 
were  operated  by  engineers.  Through  the  maldistribution  of  income 
under  finance  capitalism,  the  masses  have  never  been  able  to  buy  enough 
of  any  vital  necessity.  We  hear  much  talk  about  the  surplus  of  farm 
products  in  this  country,  but  even  in  1928  and  1929  only  10  per  cent  of  our 
American  families  were  able  to  buy  enough  to  eat,  if  they  lived  according 
to  the  standards  advocated  by  the  government  of  the  United  States. 

Among  the  evils  of  property  is  its  opposition  to  desirable  social  change 
and  economic  reform.  As  we  have  already  pointed  out,  no  other  influence 
has  been  so  powerful  as  the  legal  claims  of  property  in  suppressing  and 
thwarting  social  legislation,  and  thereby  encouraging  economic  stagna- 
tion, inefficiency,  depression,  and  impoverishment.  Most  important  of 
all — by  making  adequate  reforms  through  gradual  and  democratic 
methods  all  but  impossible,  it  has  already  brought  violent  revolutions  to 
a  number  of  countries,  and  is  inviting  revolution  in  the  majority  of 
civilized  states.  In  this  way,  property  is  committing  suicide  by  provok- 
ing the  establishment  of  a  type  of  society  in  which  property  interests  and 
holdings  will  be  severely  curtailed,  if  not  wholly  eliminated. 

Finally,  the  desire  to  protect  and  augment  private  property  is  an 
important  cause  of  war.  Indeed,  H.  N.  Brailsford  contends  that  we 
cannot  logically  expect  world  peace  until  we  abolish  private  property: 
"Our  goal  of  order  and  peace  can  be  reached  only  by  a  relentless  concen- 
tration on  the  single  purpose  of  abolishing  private  property  in  the  means 
of  life."58  Moreover,  as  H.  D.  Lasswell  has  pointed  out,  the  personal 
insecurity  produced  by  the  inequalities  of  property  is  a  strong  stimulant 


8  Property  or  Peace,  Covici-Friede,  1934,  p.  253. 


THE   INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY  197 

to  war  in  that  it  generates  sentiments  of  indignation,  frustration,  reck- 
lessness, and  rebellion,  with  the  result  that  rulers  attempt  to  distract 
attention  by  inviting  or  provoking  a  war.59 

Some  Major   Inroads  on   Private  Property  Today 

A  direct  threat  to  property  comes  from  crime.  We  ordinarily  think  of 
crime  as  taking  property  through  various  types  of  thefts  and  burglaries. 
However,  the  total  loss  from  all  forms  of  burglary,  robbery  and  thievery 
does  not  amount  to  more  than  half  a  billion  dollars  annually  in  the  United 
States.  But  the  cost  of  organized  crime  and  racketeering  annually 
amounts  to  at  least  5  billion  dollars.  To  this  we  must  add  another  5 
billions  for  the  cost  of  law-enforcing  agencies  and  the  support  of  appre- 
hended criminals.  The  losses  due  to  gambling  each  year  rim  to  5  or  6 
billion  dollars. 

Another  serious  inroad  upon  private  property,  however  legitimate  an 
inroad  it  may  be,  is  public  taxation.  And  these  tax  burdens  are  growing 
heavier  each  year.  In  1938,  before  our  armament  program  began,  it  is 
estimated  that  the  total  federal,  state,  and  local  expenditures  were  in 
excess  of  18  billion  dollars.  These  enormous  sums  must  be  raised  directly 
by  taxes  or  through  government  borrowing,  paid  off  ultimately  by  those 
possessing  taxable  property,  unless  the  public  debt  is  repudiated  and  those 
who  hold  government  bonds  lose  all  their  investment.  The  burden  of 
taxation,  even  on  small  incomes,  today  can  be  illustrated  by  the  income 
tax  in  England  in  1940:  60 

Income :  Tax 

$2,000  $171.25 

$4,000  796.25 

$6,000  1,421.25 

$8,000  2,171.25 

With  large  incomes  the  rate  of  taxation  is  higher,  until  it  becomes  con- 
fiscatory  (100  per  cent)  in  the  higher  brackets.  And  income  taxes  are 
but  a  part  of  the  total  tax  burden.  Since  the  second  World  War  started, 
the  income  tax  rates  have  been  raised,  and  the  government  has  the  legal 
power  to  take  a  man's  complete  income  and  confiscate  his  property 
through  a  capital  levy  if  the  crisis  becomes  sufficiently  acute.  Now  that 
the  United  States  is  in  the  war,  our  income  taxes  are  likely  to  rise  to  the 
English  level,  and  a  great  variety  of  other  taxes  are  being  levied  on  the 
populace. 

When  taxation  becomes  unbearable,  the  next  resort  is  inflation,  which, 
if  carried  far  enough,  wipes  out  all  property  values  in  fixed  investments. 
Germany  got  rid  of  her  World  War  debt  in  this  way  in  1923-24.  A 
friend  of  the  author  had  at  this  time  an  insurance  annuity  amounting 
to  450  thousand  dollars.  In  1924,  it  entirely  disappeared — not  being 


89  World  Politics  and  Personal  Insecurity,  McGraw-Hill,  1935. 
6°  This  is  the  tax  paid  by  a  married  man  with  one  child. 


198  THE   INSTITUTION  OF   PROPERTY 

sufficient  to  pay  the  postage  on  a  postcard  to  the  United  States.  This  is 
only  a  representative  example  of  what  inflation  does  to  most  property 
values. 

Perhaps  the  greatest  losses  of  property  have  come  about  through  specu- 
lation under  finance  capitalism.  The  losses  in  bank  failures  between 
the  end  of  the  first  World  War  and  the  beginning  of  the  New  Deal 
amounted  to  at  least  5  billion  dollars.  The  paper  losses  in  securities 
between  1929  and  1933  were  in  excess  of  100  billion  dollars,  and  the  actual 
losses  were  probably  a  quarter  of  this  sum,  perhaps  more.61  The  case 
of  Samuel  Insull  and  the  Insull  utilities,  and  of  the  Associated  Gas  and 
Electric  Company  under  Howard  Hopson,  are  only  dramatic  examples 
of  the  mulcting  of  investors  in  holding  companies.  The  depression  after 
1929,  for  which  finance  capitalism  has  been  primarily  blamed,  has  cost 
our  country  over  100  billion  dollars  in  the  resulting  curtailment  of  in- 
dustrial activity.02 

It  is  generally  believed  that  trust  funds,  administered  by  banks  and 
trust  companies,  represent  the  safest  possible  custody  of  property.  But, 
as  Fred  C.  Kelly  has  pointed  out  in  his  book,  How  To  Lose  Your  Money 
Prudently,™  billions  of  dollars  have  been  lost  in  trust  funds  through 
unwise  investment,  lethargy  in  executing  sensible  sales  and  reinvestments, 
overt  graft  between  various  banks  and  trust  companies,  and  excessive 
commissions  and  charges.  Indeed,  it  may,  perhaps,  be  said  that  prop- 
erty is  safer  in  the  hands  of  an  alert  and  responsible  broker  than  it  is  in 
a  trust  fund  handled  by  a  bank  or  trust  company.64 

The   Future  of  Private   Property 

Less  than  a  decade  ago,  Berle  and  Means  predicted  that  the  corporate 
revolution  was  building  a  new  property  system  which  might  dominate 
the  economic  future  for  many  years  to  come.  But  the  economic  and 
political  trends  indicate  that  the  world  is  headed  towards  momentous 
social  and  economic  changes  which  will  sweep  away  the  corporate  system 
as  thoroughly  as  nationalism  and  capitalism  wiped  out  the  feudal  system 
o.f  the  Middle  Ages.  Even  in  democratic  and  capitalistic  countries,  the 
expense  of  social  reform  programs  and  the  relief  of  the  poor  is  bringing 
about  taxation  and  increases  in  the  public  debt  that  seriously  menace 
the  existence  of  the  whole  property  system.  Relief  cost  the  United  States 
13  billion  dollars  between  1933  and  1939.  But,  the  cost  of  war  is  far  more 
expensive  than  any  past  or  projected  outlay  for  social  reform  and  relief. 
Armament  appropriations  in  the  United  States  in  1941-42  were  ten  times 
as  great  as  the  relief  expenditures  from  1933  to  1940.  It  is  difficult  to 
see  how  the  system  of  private  property  can  endure  in  the  face  of  the 
expenditures  involved  in  total  war. 


61  (?/.  J.  T.  Flynn,  Security  Speculation,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1934. 
02  Some  economists  put  the  loss  at  twice  this  figure. 

63  Swain,  1933. 

64  C/.  J.  T.  Flynn,  Investment  Trusts  Gone  Wrong,  New  Republic  Press,  1930. 


THE    INSTITUTION   OF   PROPERTY  199 

In  Europe,  even  before  the  war,  the  growth  of  totalitarianism,  in  the 
form  of  state  capitalism  and  state  socialism,  had  already  sounded  the 
death  knell  of  the  system  of  private  property  in  several  important  coun- 
tries. The  virtual  obituary  of  private  property  came  in  those  countries 
when  they  entered  the  second  World  War.  Even  in  Great  Britain,  which 
entered  the  second  World  War  as  an  ostensible  democracy,  there  is  no 
prospect  that  the  system  of  private  property  can  weather  a  war  of  long 
duration.  Already,  all  property  in  Britain  has  been  placed  at  the  dis- 
posal of  the  state,  and  is  being  rapidly  used  up  in  war — at  the  rate  of 
over  50  million  dollars  a  day  or  20  billions  a  year. 

Even  if  the  war  comes  to  a  speedy  end,  the  outlook  for  the  system  of 
private  property  is  dark  indeed.  The  burdens  of  the  war  are  likely  to 
give  a  fatal  shock  to  the  property  system  in  democratic  and  capitalistic 
states.  And  there  is  not  the  slightest  probability  that  the  totalitarian 
states  will  reverse  their  steps  and  revive  the  system  of  unrestricted 
private  property. 

Even  leaving  aside  entirely  the  insuperable  burdens  placed  upon  prop- 
erty by  war,  it  is  doubtful  if  our  present  empire  of  machines  can  be 
efficiently  controlled  under  a  system  of  private  property  and  a  capitalistic 
economy.  The  economic  ideals  of  Wendell  Willkie,  however  sincerely 
held,  may  fairly  be  likened  to  the  astro-physical  doctrines  of  Ptolemy. 
Some  form  of  collectivistic  economy,  directed  by  industrial  engineers, 
appears  to  many  to  be  the  only  system  compatible  with  the  technology 
of  the  twentieth  century. 


PART  III 
Political  and  Legal  Institutions  in  Transition 


CHAPTER  VII 

The  Framework  of  Democracy:  The  National  State 
and  Constitutional  Government 

An  Outline  of  the  History  of  Nationalism 

WE  HAVE  now  come  to  the  point  in  this  volume  where  we  consider 
the  more  important  political  problems  of  the  contemporary  era.  These 
are  closely  related  to  the  economic  trends  analyzed  in  earlier  chapters. 
The  central  problem  of  contemporary  political  life,  particularly  in  the 
United  States,  is  the  fate  of  democracy.  But  the  problems  of  democracy 
cannot  be  understood  unless  we  first  treat  of  those  political  institutions 
and  practices  which  are  mainly  responsible  for  the  problems  democracy 
faces  and  which  have  provided  the  technique  democracy  employs  in  its 
operations. 

This  makes  it  desirable  to  preface  our  treatment  of  democracy  by  an 
account  of  the  rise  and  influence  of  nationalism  and  party  government. 
The  national  state  has  brought  to  democracy  the  major  problems  with 
which  it  has  to  cope — the  highly  complex  life  of  great  territorial  states, 
and  the  bellicose  psychology  which  creates  the  threat  of  war.  Party 
government  has  been  the  only  technique  democracy  has  thus  devised  for 
the  operation  of  representative  government.  In  short,  nationalism  hands 
over  to  democracy  the  main  problems  with  which  it  has  to  deal,  while 
party  government  provides  the  current  mode  of  solving  such  problems. 

The  course  of  the  development  of  nations  and  national  states  has  been 
*a  complicated  process.  So  many  and  deep-seated  are  the  psychic  ele- 
ments and  the  cultural  characteristics  which  are  carried  over  from  the 
tribal  period  into  the  political,  that  it  is  nearly  impossible  to  fix  any  defi- 
nite period  as  marking  the  origin  of  nations.  One  can  scarcely  agree  with 
Israel  Zangwill  that  the  tribally  organized  Jews  of  ancient  Palestine 
constituted  a  national  state,  in  the  sense  used  to  describe  the  Germany  of 
Bismarck,  Treitschke,  and  Reventlow,  or  the  Italy  of  Crispi,  Carducci, 
and  Sonnino.  Yet  it  is  not  easy  to  deny  his  criticism  of  those  writers  who 
find  nations  a  phenomenon  of  very  recent  origin.  Rather,  it  is  best  to 
agree  that  modern  nations  have  their  psychic  traits  deeply  rooted  in  the 
tribal  past.  The  history  of  nationalism  and  of  nation-building  involves 
tracing  the  expansion  of  cultural  entities  and  the  centers  of  emotional 
fixation ;  in  other  words,  the  record  of  the  expansion  and  rationalization  of 
"herd-instinct." 

200 


NATIONS,  CONSTITUTIONS  AND  REPUBLICS    201 

As  human  society  has  undergone  tremendous  transformations  in  the 
period  between  the  gradual  breakdown  of  tribal  society  and  the  twentieth 
century,  differences  of  corresponding  scope  have  developed  between  the 
expression  of  group  psychology  in  tribal  society  and  in  the  national  states. 
The  most  profound  and  far-reaching  of  these  contrasts  is  the  conversion 
of  group  solidarity  from  blood-kinship,  real  or  assumed,  to  a  definite 
territorial  habitat,  along  with  the  development  of  what  is  conventionally 
known  as  "political  society."  The  distinctions  will  appear  clearly  only 
after  a  careful  historical  analysis  of  the  development  of  the  constituent 
principles  of  the  nations  of  today.  It  is  this  fact  that  renders  such  a 
survey  of  vital  importance,  entirely  aside  from  the  specific  content  of  the 
historical  facts  enumerated. 

Tribal  Society.  Students  of  cultural  anthropology  generally  agree  that 
the  earliest  well-defined  units  of  social  organization  were  either  the  village 
or  the  clan,  both  of  which  were  normally  linked  with  others  of  the  same 
type  in  a  larger  and  looser  entity — the  tribe. 

It  is  difficult  to  describe  tribal  government  briefly,  for  there  were  many 
kinds  of  government  in  primitive  society,  from  the  crudest  of  social  con- 
trol in  small  local  groups  and  villages  to  fairly  well-developed  tribal 
monarchies.1  As  a  general  rule,  however,  government  in  primitive  society 
was  an  elementary  type  of  representative  government  with  marked  demo- 
cratic tendencies.  The  council  of  chiefs  was  at  times  chosen  by  undemo- 
cratic methods  and  was  rather  tyrannical  in  its  government.  Usually, 
however,  it  was  elected  by  the  tribesmen  and  ruled  with  due  consideration 
for  group  traditions.  There  is  little  evidence  that  women  ruled  under 
what  has  been  called  a  matriarchal  system.  Women  sometimes  had 
unusual  political  power,  as  in  the  case  of  the  Iroquois,  but  men  always 
held  the  dominant  political  posts.  Modern  research  has  upset  the  old 
idea  that  democracy  had  its  birth  in  the  tribal  assemblies  of  the  Germans 
and  was  passed  on  directly  by  them  to  the  Anglo-Saxon  peoples  and 
Americans.  Democracy  is  a  product  of  modern  conditions  and  not  a 
heritage  from  the  primitive  past. 

While  much  of  the  psychology  of  tribal  relationships  has  been  carried 
over  into  modern  society,  the  contrasts  between  tribal  society  and  the 
modern  national  state  are  many.  Tribal  society  was  primarily  based 
upon  blood-kinship,  either  real  or  assumed,  and  tribal  relations  were 
personal  rather  than  political.  Force,  custom,  and  blood-feud  were  the 
foundation  of  tribal  juristic  concepts  and  methods.  The  "instinct  of  the 
herd"  had  a  much  fuller  sway  over  the  group  than  it  has  at  the  present 
day.  Cultural  solidarity  was  more  intense  and  there  was  little  personal 
individuation,  except  that  which  set  off  a  few  leaders.  An  intense  reli- 
gious loyalty  and  deep  attachment  to  all  the  symbols  of  group  unity  were 
ever  present.  So  powerful  was  the  domination  of  the  group  over  the 
individual  that  some  eminent  students,  such  as  Emile  Durkheim  and  his 
school,  have  claimed  that  all  categories  of  religion  and  thought  were 


1  Lowie,  Primitive  Society,  Liveright  Publishing  Corporation,  Chap.  XIII. 


202     NATIONS,  CONSTITUTIONS  AND   REPUBLICS 

derived  from  expressions  of;  and  reactions  to,  group  life.  Indeed,  Emile 
Durkheim  held  that  the  essence  of  religion  is  only  the  psychic  exuberance 
or  stimulation  arising  from  group  life  and  activities,  and  Wilfred  Trotter 
holds  the  "instinct  of  the  herd"  to  be  the  primordial  and  all-pervading 
psychic  force  which  has  controlled  man  from  the  origin  of  the  race  to  the 
present  day. 

Whatever  may  be  the  exaggerations  of  these  writers  in  matters  of  detail, 
it  is  generally  agreed  that  the  struggle  for  the  preservation  and  extension 
of  group  solidarity  has  been  the  basic  factor  in  the  evolution  of  mankind, 
and  it  was  inevitable  that  the  psychic  traits  developed  in  this  process 
would  become  deeply  grounded  in  the  mental  life  of  humanity: 

Man  is  in  fact  fundamentally  social  by  nature.  He  has  never  lived  in  isolation 
but  always  in  groups.  Lacking  special  organs  of  defense  he  found  strength,  as  did 
the  ants  and  the  bees,  in  group  solidarity.  Consequently,  the  struggle  for  exist- 
ence on  the  human  plane  has  been  fundamentally  a  struggle  of  group  with  group. 
Since  his  survival  turned  largely  on  the  perfection  of  his  gregarious  instinct,  there 
has  been  achieved  in  man  a  keen  sensitiveness  to  the  call  of  the  group.  This  herd 
instinct,  as  Trotter  calls  it,  is,  therefore,  the  very  basis  of  human  society  and  the 
most  profound  aspect  of  man's  social  nature.  It  is  for  the  group  what  the  instinct 
of  self-preservation  is  for  the  individual.  It  is  aroused  only  in  times  of  stress  and 
danger;  group  fear  in  some  form  is  essential  to  its  development;  when  awakened 
it  not  only  grips  every  tribesman  in  an  atmosphere  of  electrified  suggestibility,  but 
stirs  within  his  bodily  mechanism  the  internal  secretory  apparatus  whose  proclucts 
are  essential  to  deeds  of  valor.  It  is  in  its  strength  and  vigor  an  assertion  of  the 
group  will  to  live,  and  is  therefore  as  deep  and  mysterious  and  indeed  as  perma- 
nent as  the  eternal  nisus  of  nature,  the  insistent  push  of  everything  that  throbs 
with  life  and  energy.2 

Tribal  groups  were  relatively  small.  While  such  groups  often  held  with 
great  tenacity  to  particular  areas,  it  was  because  of  the  economic  advan- 
tages, such  as  better  fishing  or  hunting  grounds,  rather  than  a  purely 
territorial  attachment.  There  was  little  hesitancy  in  leaving  a  particular 
locality  to  follow  migrations  of  game  or  fish: 

Patriotism,  the  love  of  one's  terra  patria,  or  natal  land,  is  a  recent  thing.  Dur- 
ing far  the  greater  part  of  his  existence  man  has  wandered  over  the  earth's  face 
'as  a  hunter  and  can  hardly  have  had  any  sweet  and  permanent  associations  with 
the  tree  or  rock  under  which  he  was  born.  But  the  fore-runners  of  territorial 
emotion  were  the  group  loyalties  of  the  tribe,  clan,  family  and  totemistic  group, 
in  whatever  order  and  with  whatever  peculiarities  these  may  have  originated  and 
come  to  exist  side  by  side.3 

Early  City-States.  The  transition  from  tribal  groupings  and  modes  of 
life  to  the  city-state,  the  earliest  type  of  true  political  organization,  was 
gradual  and  slow.  The  chief  contrast  between  tribal  society  and  that  of 
the  proto-historic  city-states  was  that,  in  the  latter,  the  basis  of  group 
relations  gradually  came  to  be  political  and  territorial,  rather  than  purely 


2F.  H.  Hankins,  Patriotism  and  Peace,  Clark  University  Press,  1919. 
3J.  H.  Robinson,  The  Human  Comedy,  Harper,  1936,  p.  269. 


NATIONS,   CONSTITUTIONS  AND   REPUBLICS     203 

personal  and  consanguineous.  Very  often  there  was  an  intermediate 
political  stage  between  tribal  society  and  the  city-state,  which  we  call 
feudalism.  Here  the  relations  were  partly  personal,  those  of  patron  and 
client,  and  partly  territorial,  based  on  the  possession  of  lands  by  the 
feudal  lords. 

Groups  tended  to  consolidate  about  certain  vantage  points,  determined 
by  considerations  of  fortification  and  protection,  religious  sentiment, 
economic  superiority,  or  better  potentialities  for  brigandage.  Stability 
replaced  the  earlier  nomadic  life,  and  the  habitat  became  more  or  less 
permanent.  The  early  city-states  did  not,  however,  resemble  the  modern 
urban  centers  of  life  and  industry.  Life  was  still  primarily  agricultural, 
and  the  "city"  was  little  more  than  a  citadel  surrounded  by  the  homes  of 
the  peasants  who  retired  within  the  walls  in  time  of  danger. 

As  trade  developed  and  the  division  of  labor  between  city  and  country 
was  established,  the  early  city-states  assumed  more  of  an  industrial  and 
commercial  character.  The  coming  of  foreign  merchants  created  those 
problems  of  assimilation  and  the  extension  of  citizenship  which  were  a 
chief  force  in  breaking  down  the  remaining  vestiges  of  tribal  society  and 
in  creating  the  origins  of  the  modern  political  order.  A  few  historical  or 
semi-historical  instances  of  this  all-important  change  from  tribal  to  civil 
society  have  been  preserved  in  historical  records.  Such  were  the  occupa- 
tion of  ancient  Palestine  by  the  Jews  and  their  subsequent  choice  of  a 
king;  the  constitutional  reforms  of  Cleisthenes  in  Attica  at  the  close  of  the 
sixth  century  B.C.;  the  alleged  reforms  of  Scrvius  Tullius  in  early  Rome 
and  the  subsequent  constitutional  struggle  between  the  patricians  and 
plebians;  and  the  breakdown  of  Teutonic  tribal  society  and  the  establish- 
ment of  political  relations  in  the  interval  between  Arminius  and  Alaric — 
the  transition  which  Paul  Vinogradoff  called  "one  of  the  most  momentous 
turning-points  in  the  history  of  the  race." 

The  city-states  of  antiquity  were  soon  submerged  in  the  patriarchal 
empires  which  arose  in  the  "state-making  age"  through  the  superior  force 
and  aggressiveness  of  one  of  these  cities.  The  ancient  Egyptian  Empire 
was  a  product  of  the  forcible  subjugation  of  the  city-states  of  the  Nile 
Valley;  the  Babylonian,  Assyrian,  and  Persian  empires  were  built  up  out 
of  the  progressive  amalgamation  of  the  city-states  of  the  valleys  of  the 
Tigris  and  Euphrates,  and  the  coast  of  Asia  Minor. 

Only  the  cities  of  ancient  Hellas  retained  their  independence  long 
enough  during  the  historical  period  to  give  us  any  adequate  conception  of 
the  type  of  cultural  solidarity  and  political  reactions  which  characterized 
the  antique  city-state.  Here  personal  and  kinship  relations  were  replaced 
by  the  institution  of  citizenship,  based  upon  residence  and  naturalization, 
instead  of  blood-relationship  or  elaborate  initiation  ceremonies.  Groups 
were  generally  more  populous,  and  civilization  more  advanced  than  in 
tribal  society. 

Most  of  the  psychic  characteristics  of  tribal  life,  however,  were  present 
in  a  modified  degree  in  the  civilization  of  Athens,  which  may  be  taken  as 
the  most  advanced  product  of  the  ancient  city-state  civilization.  Group 


204     NATIONS,   CONSTITUTIONS  AND   REPUBLICS 

solidarity  was  still  intense.  The  elements  of  common  culture  were  prized, 
even  to  the  extent  of  being  vested  with  a  sacred  significance.  Ceremonies, 
costumes,  legal  forms  and  political  practices,  moral  codes,  religious  fes- 
tivities, and  even  amusements  were  tinged  with  the  divinity  of  their 
alleged  origin.  The  gods  were  limited  to  a  particular  political  group  and 
were  regarded  as  solicitous  for  its  welfare.  The  attitude  toward  for- 
eigners was  well  exemplified  by  the  well-known  contrast  between  "Greek 
and  Barbarian,"  in  which  Aristotle  was  able  to  find  a  justification  for  the 
subjection  of  inferior  peoples  to  the  Greek  "genius"  for  governing.  The 
group  leaders  passed,  after  their  death,  into  the  realm  of  the  gods  or 
supermen,  and  their  magnified  prowess  became  a  highly  prized  group 
possession. 

When  fixity  of  habitat  had  become  the  rule,  a  new  attachment  to  terri- 
torial possessions  arose.  Not  only  were  specially  sacred  places,  such  as 
Olympus  and  Delphi,  prized  and  venerated,  but  the  whole  habitat  of  the 
group  was  valued  as  a  special  gift  from  the  gods.  Aristotle  found  that 
the  fortunate  situation  of  the  Greeks  in  their  geographical  habitat  served 
sufficiently  to  explain  the  "superiority"  of  Greek  genius. 

The  ancient  city-state  was  so'  important  a  stage  in  political  and  cultural 
evolution  that  we  may  well  include  Hutton  Webster's  colorful  summary 
of  its  characteristics: 

A  Greek  or  Roman  city  usually  grew  up  about  a  hill  or  refuge  (acropolis, 
capitolium),  to  which  the  people  of  the  surrounding  district  could  flee  in  time  of 
danger.  This  mount  would  be  crowned  with  a  fortress  and  the  temples  of  the 
gods.  Not  far  away  was  the  market  place  (agora,  forum),  where  the  people 
gathered  to  conduct  their  business  and  enjoy  social  intercourse.  About  the  citadel 
and  market  place  were  grouped  the  narrow  streets  and  low  houses  of  the  town. 
Thus  an  ancient  city  was  closely  built  up  and  lacked  the  miles  of  suburbs  that 
belong  to  a  modern  metropolis.  .  .  . 

Each  of  these  numerous  cities  was  an  independent  self-governing  community. 
It  formed  a  city-state.  Just  as  a  modern  nation,  it  could  declare  war,  arrange 
treaties,  and  make  alliances  with  its  neighbors.  Such  a  city-state  included  not 
only  the  territory  within  its  walls,  but  also  the  surrounding  district  where  many 
of  the  citizens  lived.  It  was  usually  of  small  size.  Aristotle  once  said  that  "a 
city  could  not  consist  of  ten  men,  nor  again  of  one  hundred  thousand."  By  this 
he  meant  that  a  city  ought  not  to  be  so  small  that  no  community  life  was  possible 
in  it,  yet  not  so  large  that  a  man  could  not  know  many  of  his  fellow-citizens.  .  .  . 

The  members  of  an  ancient  city-state  were  very  closely  associated.  The 
citizens  believed  themselves  to  be  descended  from  a  common  ancestor  and  so  to 
be  all  related.  They  were  united  also,  in  the  worship  of  the  patron  god  or  hero 
who  had  them  under  his  protection.  These  two  ties,  the  tie  of  supposed  kinship 
and  the  tie  of  a  common  religion,  made  citizenship  a  great  privilege  which  came 
to  an  individual  only  by  birth.  Elsewhere  he  was  only  a  foreigner  without  legal 
rights — a  man  without  a  country.  .  .  . 

To  the  free-born  inhabitant  of  Athens  or  of  Rome  his  city  was  at  once  his 
country  and  his  church,  his  club  and  his  home.  He  shared  in  its  government;  he 
took  part  in  the  stately  ceremonies  that  honored  its  patron  god;  in  the  city  he 
could  indulge  his  taste  for  talking  and  for  politics;  here  he  found  both  safety  and 
society.4 


*  Ancient  History,  Heath,  1913,  pp.  165-166,  562-563. 


NATIONS,  CONSTITUTIONS  AND  REPUBLICS     205 

The  government  of  city-states  was  usually  an  aristocratic  type  of  repre- 
sentative government.  The  majority  of  the  inhabitants  were  often  ex- 
cluded from  citizenship  and  were  not  allowed  to  take  part  in  government. 
This  was  the  case  even  in  Athens.  Some  city-states  were  kingdoms  and 
others  were  called  democracies.  In  both  cases,  however,  the  council  was 
the  most  important  element  in  the  government.  In  kingdoms,  the  council 
might  be  aristocratic  and  hereditary  or  it  might  be  chosen  by  the  members 
of  the  city  aristocracy.  In  democratic  city-states,  the  council  was  elected 
by  the  citizens,  and  the  latter  frequently  met  as  a  body  to  discuss  public 
problems  and  pass  fundamental  laws.  Representative  government  began 
in  primitive  society,  but  it  rested  on  a  kinship  rather  than  a  political  and 
territorial  basis.  The  city-state  created  a  representative  system  based  on 
territorial  residence  and  a  truly  civic  life.  The  democratic  city-states 
were  such  in  name  only.  All  the  citizens  might  participate  in  government 
but  the  citizens  were  always  a  minority  of  the  whole  population.  In  some 
city-states,  like  Sparta,  we  find  a  system  of  military  socialism  which  was 
a  forerunner,  on  a  small  scale,  of  contemporary  totalitarianism. 

The  ancient  city-states  made  notable  advances  toward  transforming 
group  life  from  the  tribal  to  the  modern  national  basis.  Had  their 
progress  not  been  arrested  by  the  development  of  the  great  patriarchal 
empires,  the  national  state  in  its  fullness  might  have  been  a  product  of 
antiquity.  For  better  or  worse,  this  was  not  to  be,  and  even  Athens  was 
swallowed  up  in  the  imperial  domains  of  the  Macedonian  conqueror  after 
its  African  and  Asiatic  prototypes  had  long  before  bowed  to  the  might 
of  Thebes,  Memphis,  Babylon,  Nineveh,  Ecbatana,  Sardis,  and  Susa. 
James  Bryce  has  admirably  described  the  general  absence  of  anything 
approaching  a  national  cultural  or  political  unity  before  the  conquests  of 
Rome: 

Men  with  little  knowledge  of  each  other,  with  no  experience  of  wide  political 
union,  held  differences  of  race  to  be  natural  and  irremovable  barriers.  Similarly, 
religion  appeared  to  them  a  purely  local  matter;  and  as  there  were  gods  of  the 
hills  and  gods  of  the  valleys,  of  the  land  and  of  the  sea,  so  each  tribe  rejoiced  in 
its  peculiar  deities,  looking  on  the  natives  of  other  countries  who  worshipped  other 
gods  as  Gentiles,  natural  foes,  unclean  beings.  Such  feelings,  if  keenest  in  the 
East,  frequently  show  themselves  in  the  early  records  of  Greece  and  Italyj  in 
Homer  the  hero,  who  wanders  over  the  unfruitful  sea,  glories  in  sacking  the  cities 
of  the  stranger;  the  primitive  Latins  have  the  same  word  for  a  foreigner  or  ati 
enemy;  the  exclusive  systems  of  Egypt,  Hindostan,  China  are  only  the  more 
vehement  expressions  of  the  belief  which  made  Athenian  philosophers  look  upon 
a  state  of  war  between  Greeks  and  barbarians  as  natural,  and  defend  slavery  on 
the  same  ground  of  the  original  diversity  of  the  races  that  rule  and  the  races 
that  serve.5 

The  Patriarchal  Empires  of  Antiquity.  The  formation  of  the  far-flung 
autocratic  patriarchal  empires,  in  what  Walter  Bagehot  has  somewhat 
loosely  called  "the  nation-making  age"  was  one  of  the  sweeping  trans- 
formations in  the  political  evolution  of  humanity.  Paradoxical  as  it 


5  Bryce,  The  Holy  Roman  Empire,  Macmillan,  1900,  pp.  80-90. 


206     NATIONS,  CONSTITUTIONS  AND   REPUBLICS 

may  seem,  the  empires  both  stifled  and  promoted  the  growth  of  nations 
and  national  unity.  Their  development  was  invariably  brought  about  by 
the  cumulative  extension  of  the  power  and  prestige  of  some  powerful  and 
aggressive  city-state  at  the  expense  of  its  neighbors.  This  very  process 
naturally  produced  an  enormous  inflation  of  group  pride  and  egotism  on 
the  part  of  the  conquering  city.  On  the  other  hand,  while  subject  cities 
were  severely  treated  and  their  national  culture  sternly  repressed,  nothing 
makes  a  group  so  proud  and  tenacious  of  its  cultural  possessions  as 
persecution,  and  the  conquerors  unwittingly  only  intensified  the  partic- 
ularism and  local  pride  of  such  subject  communities.  Prior  to  the  rise  of 
Persia,  the  history  of  the  ancient  empires  is,  in  part,  a  record  of  constant 
warfare  produced  by  the  attempts  of  the  ruling  city  and  dynasty  to 
suppress  the  revolts  of  subject  cultural  groups. 

We  can  illustrate  the  character  of  the  more  highly  developed  ancient 
empires  by  briefly  describing  the  remarkable  Persian  Empire  of  the  fifth 
and  sixth  centuries  B.C.  Never  before  had  so  extensive  an  empire  existed. 
The  victory  over  Egypt  in  525  B.C.  meant  that  the  Persian  Empire 
stretched  from  the  Nile  in  the  west  to  the  mountain  frontiers  of  India  in 
the  east.  In  extent  and  in  excellence  of  administration  and  organization, 
only  the  Roman  Empire  of  later  centuries  can  be  compared  to  it  among 
the  political  achievements  of  antiquity. 

The  organization  of  so  vast  an  empire  was  a  problem  of  the  first  magni- 
tude. The  task,  begun  by  Cyrus,  was  completed  by  Darius  the  Great  in 
the  sixth  and  fifth  centuries  B.C.  Following  an  older  Sumerian  tradition, 
Darius  was  called  the  Ruler  of  the  Four  Quarters  of  the  Globe,  and  the 
government  centered  in  his  hands.  In  attempting  to  create  unity  out  of 
the  heterogeneous  elements  which  composed  this  vast  empire,  the  Persian 
rulers  made  a  radical  departure  from  the  traditional  practice  of  the 
Near  East.  They  permitted  the  distinction  between  conqueror  and  con- 
quered— between  the  rulers  and  the  subject  peoples — slowly  to  disappear. 
The  conquered  regions,  or  satrapies,  which  under  the  older  system  were 
distinguished  by  the  payment  of  tribute,  gradually  acquired  the  status 
of  provinces.  Later  on,  the  word  "satrapy"  simply  implied  an  adminis- 
trative unit  of  the  empire,  and  even  Persia  itself  became  a  satrapy,  though 
it  enjoyed  certain  special  privileges. 

What  was  here  attempted,  though  never  completely  realized,  was  the 
establishment  of  a  heterogeneous  empire  bound  together,  in  fact  united, 
through  the  ties  created  by  an  administrative  system.  Each  administra- 
tive division,  each  satrapy,  was  ruled  by  a  governor  (a  "satrap")  and 
other  officials  appointed  by  the  king.  This,  too,  was  an  innovation,  for 
the  subjects  of  the  older  empires  had  usually  been  ruled  by  natives.  In 
addition  to  the  satrap,  who  was  essentially  a  civil  officer,  a  general  and  a 
secretary  were  stationed  in  each  province.  Royal  commissioners,  called 
the  "Eyes  of  the  King"  and  resembling  the  later  missi  dominici  of  Charle- 
magne, traveled  through  the  empire  inspecting  the  satrapies  and  reporting 
to  the  ruler.  In  the  time  of  Darius  there  were  twenty  administrative 
divisions  in  the  empire. 


NATIONS,  CONSTITUTIONS  AND  REPUBLICS    207 

Much  of  the  harshness,  cruelty,  and  terrorism  of  Assyrian  rule  were 
absent  from  the  Persian  system.  Persian  rule  was  not  only  milder,  but 
it  was  clearly  one  of  tolerance.  The  attempt  to  establish  unity  did  not 
progress  far  beyond  the  political  sphere.  Little  effort  was  made  to  en- 
force the  use  of  the  Persian  tongue  and  cuneiform  script,  or  the  Persian 
religion,  Zoroastrianism.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  Aramaic  became  the  com- 
mon language  of  imperial  business,  and  the  local  languages  remained  in 
use.  The  same  is  true  of  social  customs  and  economic  conditions.  In 
these  matters  the  localities  were  unmolested  and  continued  to  practice 
their  old  habits.  The  imperial  structure  was  simply  superimposed  upon 
the  life  of  the  subject  peoples,  which  continued  with  little  modification. 
Even  in  local  government,  many  sections  of  the  Persian  Empire  continued 
under  the  same  forms  of  rule  they  had  possessed  before  their  conquest, 
especially  the  Phoenician  and  Greek  cities  in  Asia  Minor. 

This  process  of  ancient  empire-building  culminated  in  the  expansion 
of  imperial  Rome,  in  its  task  of  absorbing  most  of  the  then-known  world 
and  of  bringing  into  existence  the  ideal  "reign  of  universal  peace"  and 
uniform  law.  The  process  of  Roman  expansion  marked  the  nearest 
approximation  to  the  spirit  and  methods  of  aggressive  nationalism.  The 
crude  and  almost  tribal  expression  of  collective  egotism  in  "international" 
policy;  the  public  theory  that  all  her  wars  were  "defensive"  and  that 
Rome  was  always  threatened  by  aggressive  states ;  the  alleged  conviction 
that  the  gods  were  always  favorable  to  these  defensive  wars;  the  control 
of  diplomatic  and  military  policy  by  the  landed  "Junker"  aristocracy — 
the  Senate;  the  ambition  for  private  or  family  glory  in  war,  as  manifested 
by  Claudius  in  the  first  Punic  War  and  by  Flaminius  in  the  second  Mace- 
donian War;  the  "surplus  population"  argument  for  expansion;  the 
"scrap  of  paper"  attitude  toward  treaties  as  evidenced  in  the  second 
Samnite  War;  the  harsh  and  brutal  treatment  of  conquered  populations, 
extending  to  the  devastation  of  fields,  the  burning  of  cities,  and  the  en- 
slaving of  populations;  the  insatiable  greed  for  further  expansion;  the 
disregard  of  the  "rights  of  small  nationalities" — all  of  these  aspects  of 
Roman  expansion  sound  exceedingly  modern. 

The  formation  of  empires  was  influential  in  creating  that  tradition  of 
the  glory  of  territorial  expansion  which  serves  as  an  important  impulse  to 
the  aggressiveness  of  the  modern  national  and  territorial  state.  However, 
it  should  not  be  forgotten  that  there  was  a  most  radical  difference  between 
the  political  and  cultural  basis  of  such  a  far-flung  political  entity  as  the 
Roman  Empire  and  the  compact  German  Empire  of  a  few  decades  ago. 
Though  there  was  a  universal  political  system,  there  was  little  cultural 
homogeneity  or  common  sentiment  of  loyalty,  which  are  the  indispensable 
foundations  of  the  national  state.  Only  the  citizens  of  Italian  Rome  felt 
any  emotional  thrills  or  shared  patriotic  reactions  at  the  triumphal  pro- 
cessions of  conquering  emperors  or  generals  and  at  the  recitation  of  the 
Virgilian  epic  of  the  growth  of  the  Pax  Romana.  Though  the  subject 
peoples  might  acquiesce  in  the  apotheosis  of  the  Roman  emperor  and 
render  formal  allegiance,  they  retained  their  deeper  loyalty  and  allegiance 


208     NATIONS,  CONSTITUTIONS  AND  REPUBLICS 

to  their  own  pantheon.  A  common  spontaneous  patriotism  and  a  uni- 
versal loyalty  to  the  sovereign  imperial  state  were  quite  unknown  in  the 
ancient  empires,  and  the  cultural  homogeneity  which  must  precede  the 
political  expression  of  national  life  was  as  remote  from  realization.  Even 
the  prevailing  political  philosophy — Stoicism — decried  the  sentiments  of 
nationalism  and  patriotism,  and  lauded  the  notion  of  the  brotherhood  of 
man  and  the  cosmopolitanism  of  world-citizenship: 

No  quarrels  of  race  or  religion  disturbed  that  calm,  for  all  national  distinctions 
were  becoming  merged  in  the  idea  of  a  common  Empire.  The  gradual  extension 
of  Roman  citizenship  through  the  coloniae,  the  working  of  the  equalized  and 
equalizing  Roman  law,  the  even  pressure  of  the  government  on  all  subjects,  the 
movement  of  population  caused  by  commerce  and  the  slave  traffic,  were  steadily 
assimilating  the  various  peoples.  .  .  .  From  Rome  came  the  laws  and  language 
that  had  overspread  the  world;  at  her  feet  the  nations  laid  the  offerings  of  their 
labor;  she  was  the  head  of  the  Empire  and  of  civilization,  and  in  riches,  fame  and 
splendor  far  outshone,  as  well  the  cities  of  the  time  as  the  fabled  glories  of 
Bablyon  or  Persepolis/1 

Had  Rome  continued  to  exist  with  an  efficient  method  of  imperial  ad- 
ministration and  communication  for  some  centuries  after  Diocletian,  it 
might  have  been  possible  for  her  to  have  welded  her  diverse  subject  popu- 
lations into  a  single  loyal  and  unified  national  unit,  but  the  experiment  was 
not  permitted  to  continue.  In  378  A.D.,  the  Teutonic  barbarians  from  the 
North,  who  had  been  gradually  filtering  into  the  empire  for  three  cen- 
turies, broke  their  leash  and  started  on  their  migrations,  which  submerged 
the  ancient  world  in  a  return  of  preclassical  barbarism,  and  produced  a 
Clovis,  a  Charlemagne,  and  an  Otto  the  Great  to  repeat  the  tasks  of  an 
Agamemnon,  an  Alexander,  and  an  Augustus.  The  ancient  world,  then, 
passed  away,  without  producing  the  prototype  of  the  modern  national 
state,  but  it  laid  the  psychological  and  political  basis  upon  which  the  latter 
could  develop.  Nevertheless,  growth  of  the  modern  national  state  has 
been,  to  a  large  degree,  a  process  sui  generis,  primarily  independent  of 
ancient  impulses,  even  if  influenced  by  ancient  models. 

The  Middle  Ages:  Feudal  Politics  and  Universal  Culture.  The  politi- 
cal, social,  economic  and  cultural  conditions  of  the  "Middle  Ages"  were  no 
better  adapted  to  the  production  of  the  national  state  than  imperial 
antiquity.  The  unit  of  political  organization  and  administration  was  the 
domain  of  the  feudal  lord,  which  varied  greatly  in  extent.  Usually  the 
domain  was  but  a  small  isolated  element  in  the  feudal  hierarchy,  and  it 
made  for  political  decentralization.  The  center  of  social  life  was  the 
infinite  number  of  isolated  and  minute  medieval  manors — village  commu- 
nities— and  the  few  small  and  scattered  medieval  towns.  These  were 
isolated,  self-sufficient,  and  narrowly  selfish  and  provincial,  and  were  not 
well  adapted  to  providing  any  firm  economic  foundations  for  national 
unity. 

Feudalism  dominated  the  political  scene  during  the  Middle  Ages,  so  we 


6Bryce,  op.  cit.,  pp.  26-27. 


NATIONS,  CONSTITUTIONS  AND  REPUBLICS     209 

may  pause  for  a  brief  description  of  this  important  stage  of  political  evo- 
lution. Feudalism  has  been  a  general,  if  not  quite  universal,  stage  in  the 
evolution  of  society  and  political  control.  Its  two  fundamental  charac- 
teristics are:  (1)  partial  protection  of  the  helpless  members  of  society,  and 
(2)  their  exploitation  by  the  noble  classes  for  economic  and  military 
purposes.  In  return  for  the  protection  of  his  clients  against  robbery  and 
invasion,  the  lord  demanded  that  the  clients  work  for  him,  help  him  in  his 
own  raids  and  brigandage,  and  follow  him  into  war.  The  relationship 
binding  the  overlord  and  his  clients  together  was  primarily  a  personal  one, 
as  distinguished  from  the  real  or  fictitious  blood  relationship  of  primitive 
society,  and  the  territorial  and  political  foundations  of  later  civil  society. 
Feudalism  is  always  encouraged  by  a  breakdown  of  social  systems  and 
by  the  resulting  necessity  of  turning  to  powerful  personages  for  protection 
and  security. 

From  the  period  of  the  later  Roman  Empire  until  the  twelfth  century 
more  or  less  intermittent  anarchy  existed  in  western  Europe.  The  admin- 
istrative power  and  authority  of  the  Roman  Empire  disintegrated.  The 
middle  class  was  crushed  as  a  result  of  bearing  most  of  the  financial 
burdens  of  taxation  because  of  the  defiant  default  of  the  landed  aristoc- 
racy. This  left  in  Roman  society  an  arrogant  and  anarchic  agrarian 
aristocracy  at  the  top,  and  at  the  bottom  a  vast  mass  of  free  and  semi- 
servile  men,  who  lacked  protection  and  economic  security.  Therefore,  the 
poor  free  men  tended  to  give  up  their  freedom  in  return  for  protection. 

From  the  German  side  an  evolutionary  process  was  contributing  to 
feudal  developments.  Between  the  time  of  Tacitus  and  Clovis  kinship 
society  broke  down  among  the  Germanic  peoples.  Feudalism  followed  in 
natural  sequence.  Free  men  banded  together  in  the  comitatus  under  the 
leadership  of  powerful  individuals  in  order  to  assist  in  raids  and  secure 
a  part  of  the  booty,  and  to  attain  protection.  To  these  domestic  condi- 
tions were  added  foreign  intrusions  that  also  encouraged  feudal  develop- 
ments. First  came  the  invasions  of  the  Huns,  which  strengthened  the 
power  of  the  warrior  class  among  the  Germans  and  intensified  the  con- 
fusion in  the  later  Roman  Empire.  Next  came  the  alarming  incursions  of 
the  Muslims.  Finally,  there  were  the  Viking  raids,  which  carried  death 
and  destruction  throughout  northwestern  Europe  and  threw  the  common 
people  and  their  lords  together  for  the  purpose  of  mutual  salvation.  For 
centuries  everything  seemingly  worked  toward  localism  and  personal 
relations  in  society,  and  against  strong  and  centralized  political  dominion. 
Medieval  feudalism  was  the  outcome. 

In  earlier  periods  feudalism  had  represented  an  institutional  step  in 
advance — progress  from  kinship  society  toward  civil  society.  This  was 
true  of  medieval  feudalism,  as  well,  insofar  as  it  applied  to  barbarian 
peoples  emerging  from  kinship  society.  But  in  the  case  of  regions  and 
populations  that  had  once  been  a  part  of  the  Roman  Empire  it  was  a 
retrogression  from  more  highly  developed  civil  society. 

Medieval  feudalism  was  a  merging  of  personal,  economic,  and  political 
elements,  From  the  personal  side  Rome  contributed  the  patrocinium,  or 


210     NATIONS,  CONSTITUTIONS  AND   REPUBLICS 

the  practice  of  an  unprotected  man's  joining  himself  to  a  powerful  patron 
for  protection.  Germany  added  the  comitatus,  whereby  the  underlings 
not  only  received  protection  but  also  willingly  took  part  in  the  raids  and 
wars  of  the  leaders,  and  received  their  share  of  the  booty.  The  Muslim 
invasion  transformed  this  relationship  devoted  primarily  to  brigand- 
age into  a  firmer  system  involving  organized  military  service.  The 
patrocinium  and  the  comitatus  were  merged  through  the  institution  of 
commendation  (commendatio) ,  to  constitute  the  vassalage  of  medieval 
feudalism,  which  involved  not  only  protection  but  military  obligations. 

On  the  economic  side  we  start  with  the  Roman  prccarium.  This  was 
the  land  or  other  property  handed  over  by  the  helpless  free  men  to  fur- 
nish the  local  lord  with  some  material  incentive  to  guarantee  his  protec- 
tion. The  Germans  added  nothing  comparable  in  this  economic  phase 
of  feudalism.  But  the  necessity  of  raising  soldiers  to  repel  the  Muslims 
led  the  Prankish  kings  to  seize  church  lands  and  to  confer  them  upon 
their  followers  to  obtain  the  soldiers,  horses,  and  other  items  necessary 
for  warfare.  In  short,  dependents  of  lords  were  given  what  was  called 
the  beneficium  in  return  for  reciprocal  military  obligations.  In  due  time, 
it  became  usual  for  the  vassal  to  hand  down  to  his  descendants  the  bene- 
ficium conferred  upon  him  by  his  lord.  When  the  beneficium  became 
definitely  hereditary  and  carried  with  it  the  obligation  to  furnish  military 
equipment  and  other  feudal  aids,  it  became  the  fi,cj,  the  material  core 
of  the  feudal  system. 

Had  the  king  been  powerful  enough  to  assert  his  authority  over  the 
local  communities  of  his  realms,  there  would  have  been  no  particular 
need  for  feudal  institutions.  As  soon  as  kings  became  sufficiently  strong 
to  govern  their  realms  and  to  protect  their  subjects,  the  feudal  system 
disintegrated.  In  the  meantime,  politics  and  law  rested  upon  the  insti- 
tution of  immunity.  That  is,  the  feudal  lords  owed  specific  feudal  obliga- 
tions to  the  kings.  Once  these  were  met,  the  lords  enjoyed  essential 
sovereignty  on  their  own  domains.  They  were  legally,  as  well  as  prac- 
tically, immune  to  royal  interference,  and  were  empowered  to  govern 
and  control  their  own  realms  in  harmony  with  the  prevailing  practices  of 
'feudal  law  and  administration.  Decentralization  was  supreme,  and  so 
remained  until  the  feudal  system  gave  way  in  the  face  of  the  rising  tide 
of  nationalism  and  royal  strength. 

Set  off  against  the  actual  political  diversity  and  localism  of  the  feudal 
system  was  the  political  symbol  of  unity  and  cosmopolitanism — the  Holy 
Roman  Empire.  Whatever  its  actual  weaknesses,  its  symbolic  power 
over  the  mind  of  Europeans  was  sufficient  to  cause  so  ardent  a  nationalist 
and  so  blase  an  advocate  of  Realpolitik  as  Frederick  the  Great  to  bow 
before  it,  even  in  the  days  of  its  declining  strength.  A  universal  moral 
and  religious  control  over  medieval  life  was  provided  by  the  Roman 
Catholic  Church,  whose  growth  has  been  described  as  "the  rise  of  the  new 
Rome."  The  medieval  church  exerted  control  over  the  religious,  and  to 
a  large  extent  the  mental,  life  of  the  medieval  period.  With  the  aid  of 
the  inquisition  against  heresy,  it  brought  about  a  degree  of  psychic  unity 


NATIONS,  CONSTITUTIONS  AND  REPUBLICS     211 

throughout  Europe  never  before  equaled.  Under  its  greatest  popes,  such 
as  Innocent  III,  the  Church  also  exercised  a  degree  of  control  over  Euro- 
pean politics  never  matched  by  any  emperor  of  the  period.  The  three 
leading  crowned  heads  of  Europe  were  in  turn  disciplined  by  Innocent. 
The  Church  prescribed  a  single  theology  for  all  western  Europe,  which 
was  embodied  in  the  Book  of  Sentences  of  Peter  Lombard  and  the  Summa 
Theologica  of  St.  Thomas  Aquinas.  Since  theology  was  regarded, 
throughout  the  medieval  period,  as  the  "queen  of  the  sciences,"  and  since 
education  was  chiefly  in  the  hands  of  the  churchmen,  the  realm  of  learn- 
ing was  no  less  unified  than  was  the  spiritual  world. 

There  was  a  striking  unity  of  language  and  literature  during  the  me- 
dieval period.  The  vernacular  languages  and  literatures  began  to  appear 
in  the  eleventh  and  twelfth  centuries,  but  Latin  was  the  language  of 
politics,  business,  and  learning  throughout  western  Europe  during  the 
greater  part  of  the  medieval  period.  The  literature  read  by  those  who 
were  able  to  read  was  not  less  uniform  than  the  language.  The  Bible, 
the  works  of  the  leading  "Fathers,"  the  crude  Latin  encyclopedic  compila- 
tions by  Isidore,  Rhabanus  Maurus,  and  Vincent  of  Beauvais,  the  theo- 
logical and  pedagogical  manuals,  and  the  few  classical  texts  on  logic,  law, 
and  medicine  were  almost  the  only  books  read  until  the  prose  and  verse  of 
the  vernacular  languages  began  to  appear  at  the  height  of  the  medieval 
period.  Even  Aristotle  was  read  in  Latin  translations.  Lord  Bryce  has 
characterized  the  remarkable  unity  which  was,  at  least  Symbolically, 
brought  to  the  medieval  period  by  the  Church  and  Empire: 

It  is  on  the  religious  life  that  nations  repose.  Because  divinity  was  divided, 
humanity  had  been  divided  likewise;  the  doctrine  of  the  unity  of  God  now 
enforced  the  unity  of  man,  who  had  been  created  in  his  image.  The  first  lesson 
of  Christianity  was  love,  a  love  that  was  to  join  in  one  body  those  whom  sus- 
picion and  prejudice  and  pride  of  race  had  hitherto  kept  apart.  There  was  thus 
formed  by  the  new  religion  a  community  of  the  faithful,  a  Holy  Empire,  de- 
signed to  gather  all  men  into  its  bosom,  and  standing  opposed  to  the  manifold 
polytheisms  of  the  older  world,  exactly  as  the  universal  sway  of  the  Caesars 
was  contrasted  with  the  innumerable  kingdoms  and  republics  that  had  gone 
before  it.  The  analogy  of  the  two  made  them  appear  parts  of  one  great  world- 
movement  toward  unity;  the  coincidence  of  their  boundaries,  which  had  begun 
before  Constantine,  lasted  long  enough  for  him  to  associate  them  indissolubly 
together,  and  make  the  names  of  Roman  and  Christian  convertible.  Ecumen- 
ical councils,  where  the  whole  spiritual  body  gathered  itself  from  every  part  of 
the  temporal  realm  under  the  presidency  of  the  temporal  head,  presented  the 
most  visible  and  impressive  examples  of  their  connection.  The  language  of  civil 
government  was,  throughout  the  West,  that  of  the  sacred  writings  and  of  wor- 
ship; the  greatest  mind  of  his  generation  consoled  the  faithful  for  the  fall  of 
their  earthly  commonwealth,  Rome,  by  describing  to  them  its  successor  and 
representative,  the  "City  which  hath  foundations,  whose  builder  and  maker  is 
God." 7 

Despite  this  unique  prevalence  of  the  universal  and  the  uniform  in 
fact  and  symbol  during  the  medieval  period,  forces  were  working  be- 


7  Bryce,  op.  dt.,  pp.  90-91. 


NATIONS,   CONSTITUTIONS  AND   REPUBLICS 

neath  the  surface  that  were  to  rend  asunder  this  century-old  artificial 
unity.  As  early  as  the  Strassburg  Oaths  of  842,  there  could  be  detected 
the  first  beginnings  in  the  differentiations  of  language  which  were  t<* 
lay  the  literary  basis  for  national  diversity  and  rivalry.  The  revival 
Of  Roman  law  in  western  Europe  in  the  twelfth  century  became  a 
powerful  instrument  for  royal  supremacy  and  the  rise  of  the  dynastic 
state.  The  new  commerce  with  the  east,  which  had  been  built  up  by  the 
Italian  cities  in  the  period  of  the  Crusades  enriched  the  Italian  city- 
states,  which  first  successfully  defied  the  principle  of  imperial  unity. 
The  breakdown  of  the  principle  took  place  in  northern  Europe,  when  the 
opening  of  the  new  trade  routes  to  the  east  and  west  ushered  in  the 
"Commercial  Revolution"  and  with  it  the  dawn  of  the  Modern  Age. 

The  Rise  of  the  National  State.  At  the  opening  of  the  sixteenth  cen- 
tury a  number  of  new  forces  and  influences  made  for  the  creation  of 
national  spirit  and  a  national  state.  Perhaps  the  economic  factors  were 
the  most  potent.  The  Roman  Catholic  Church  imposed  heavy  taxes 
Upon  the  various  nations  of  Europe.  For  example,  at  some  periods  in 
medieval  Europe  the  amount  of  money  which  went  to  the  church  far 
exceeded  that  which  went  to  the  king.  Around  the  opening  of  the  six- 
teenth century  there  was  a  trend  toward  heavier  taxation,  in  order  to 
raise  money  for  a  new  building  campaign  carried  on  by  the  Church, 
which,  at  this  period  was  particularly  wasteful  and  extravagant.  The 
various  princes  and  kings  were  naturally  eager  to  escape,  so  far  as  pos- 
sible, from  these  heavy  financial  demands  made  by  the  Church  on  their 
realms.  Hence  they  welcomed  the  movement  led  by  Luther  and  other 
Protestant  reformers,  especially  since  this  movement  provided  a  con- 
venient religious  and  moral  cloak  for  their  motives. 

Other  and  major  economic  influences  making  for  nationalism  in  early 
modern  times  grew  later  out  of  exploration,  colonization,  and  the  ensu- 
ing Commercial  Revolution.  It  was  believed  that  each  state  should 
closely  control  its  own  and  its  colonies'  economic  and  commercial  life,  in 
order  to  increase  national  prosperity  and  the  income  of  the  national 
treasury.  This  belief  made  the  nation  that  industrial  and  commercial 
unit  we  know  as  a  Mercantile  state.  Mercantilism  dominated  European 
economic  policy  generally  in  the  seventeenth  and  eighteenth  centuries. 
The  American  Revolution  was  an  effort  to  combat  the  enforcement  of 
mercantilist^  regulations. 

Religious  factors  also  made  for  nationalism.  The  politic.al  rulers  not 
only  wished  freedom  from  taxation  by  Rome  but  they  also  desired  to 
control  the  religious  life  of  their  kingdoms.  The  Catholic  challenge  to 
the  political  absolutism  of  the  king  during  the  Middle  Ages  had  been 
regarded  as  an  annoying  nuisance  and  a  menace  by  the  political  poten- 
tates. Religious  reformers,  like  Luther,  despairing  of  bringing  about 
adequate  religious  reforms  within  Catholicism,  advocated  overt  secession 
from  Rome.  Th6y  were  rendered  indispensable  assistance  by  the  political 
rulers,  who  had  good  financial  and  religious  reasons  for  favoring -the 
Protestant  revolt.  In  the  case  of  England,  Henry  VIII  added  a -highly 


NATIONS,  CONSTITUTIONS  AND   REPUBLICS     213 

personal  element  to  the  general  picture,  namely  his  desire  to  divorce 
Catherine  and  marry  Anne  Boleyn.  In  return  for  the  aid  rendered  by 
princes  and  kings,  the  Protestant  leaders  tended  to  give  their  blessing  to 
the  monarchs  and  to  the  spirit  of  nationalism. 

Dynastic  ambitions  of  European  rulers — Ferdinand  and  Isabella  and 
Philip  II  in  Spain,  the  Tudors  in  England,  the  Bourbons  in  France,  the 
Hohenzollerns  in  Prussia,  the  Hapsburgs  in  Austria,  and  the  Romanovs 
in  Russia — promoted  nationalistic  expansion  and  unification  until  the 
days  of  Bismarck.  They  desired  to  enhance  their  personal  prestige  and 
the  strength  and  extent  of  their  realms  through  war  and  conquest.  This 
was  the  main  factor  which  led  to  the  creation  of  relatively  large  and 
well  integrated  national  states  in  modern  Europe  and  throughout  the 
western  world. 

By  the  time  of  the  famous  Treaty  of  Westphalia,  in  1648,  the  national 
state  had  become  a  recognized  institution  in  the  public  law  of  Europe. 
Yet  there  was  little  popular  enthusiasm  for  nationalism — little  which 
could  properly  be  called  national  spirit.  Nationalism  was  still  primarily 
a  matter  of  dynasties,  religious  dogmas,  and  economic  interests,  which 
did  not  inflame  the  masses.  Popular  enthusiasm  was  first  brought  to 
nationalism  by  the  French  Revolution  and  the  Napoleonic  wars.  The 
French  masses  were  deeply  stirred  by  the  successful  wars  which  the 
revolutionary  leaders  waged  against  the  European  reactionaries.  The 
slogan  of  Fraternity  galvanized  the  French  nation.  Frenchmen  were 
even  more  thrilled  by  the  dramatic  successes  of  Napoleon.  Among  the 
enemies  of  Napoleon,  nationalism  and  patriotism  were  given  a  popular 
basis  through  the  necessity  of  waging  war  against  conquest  and  absorp- 
tion. English,  Prussian,  Spanish,  and  Austrian  nationalism  were  par- 
ticularly stimulated  as  a  defense  reaction  against  Napoleonic  aggression. 

The  popularization  of  national  sentiment  carried  over  from  the  Napo- 
leonic period  into  the  nineteenth  century  and  provided  psychological 
support  for  the  unification  of  Germany  and  Italy  in  1870,  and  for  the 
later  rise  of  nationality  in  the  Balkan  states,  which,  incidentally,  served 
to  set  off  the  first  World  War. 

If  nationalism  was  to  be  both  popularized  and  rendered  permanent, 
it  needed  a  real  nervous  system  for  the  communication  of  emotions  and 
ideas.  This  was  provided  by  the  Industrial  Revolution  and  the  rise  of 
modern  science,  which  brought  into  being  the  telegraph,  telephone,  radio, 
cheap  daily  newspapers,  and  moving  pictures.  This  made  it  feasible  to 
keep  alive  a  vivid  national  sentiment,  even  when  there  were  no  wars 
to  stimulate  and  heighten  national  excitement.8  The  Industrial  Revo- 
lution also  contributed  powerfully  to  the  system  of  nationalism  by  pro- 
ducing an  ever  greater  body  of  goods  to  be  sold,  thus  encouraging  legis- 
lation for  the  protection  of  the  home  market,  such  as  tariff  laws,  which 
emphasized  the  economic  unity  of  industrial  states. 

The  national  state  has  passed  through  many  stages  of  governmental 


s  See  below,  pp.  219-221. 


214     NATIONS,  CONSTITUTIONS  AND  REPUBLICS 

practice.  It  first  produced  the  absolute  monarchies  of  early  modern 
times  under  Philip  II  of  Spain,  Henry  VIII  of  England  and  Louis  XIV 
of  France.  The  reign  of  the  latter  is  usually  regarded  as  the  culmina- 
tion of  both  the  glories  and  miseries  of  absolute  monarchy. 

Next  came  what  is  often  called  Enlightened  Despotism.  Representa- 
tive of  such  rulers  were  Elizabeth  of  England,  Frederick  the  Great  of 
Prussia,  Catherine  the  Great  of  Russia,  Joseph  II  of  Austria,  and  Charles 
III  of  Spain.  While  the  people  had  little  to  say  about  government  under 
the  enlightened  despots,  the  latter  did  try  to  rule  according  to  what  they 
believed  was  the  best  interests  of  their  subjects. 

Representative  government,  in  which  elected  legislatures  became  su- 
preme in  government,  first  appeared,  in  any  important  state,  in  England 
after  the  Revolution  of  1688.  It  grew  up  in  America  in  the  English 
colonies  and  took  on  a  national  expression  in  the  new  federal  government 
of  1789.  Then  it  came  to  France  after  the  French  Revolution.  In  the 
nineteenth  century,  it  gradually  made  headway  in  the  other  major 
states  of  Europe,  with  the  exception  of  Russia,  which  maintained  its 
absolutistic  system  until  the  first  World  War. 

Representative  government  was  undemocratic  at  first.  Only  a  mi- 
nority elected  the  members  of  legislatures.  The  earliest  example  of 
democratic  government  in  a  large  state  was  that  of  the  United  States 
after  Andrew  Jackson  democratized  our  federal  government  following 
1829. 

Nationalism  in  the  United  States.  The  rise  of  nationalism  in  the 
United  States  is  the  most  impressive  achievement  of  its  kind  in  the  New 
World.  As  E.  P.  Cheyney  so  convincingly  indicated,  the  settlement 
of  America  was  more  closely  connected  with  the  economic  impulses 
arising  from  the  Commercial  Revolution  in  Europe  than  it  was  with 
the  religious  revolts  from  Catholicism  on  the  Continent  and  the  Estab- 
lished Church  in  England.  These  new  commercial  forces  were  most  in- 
fluential in  promoting  unity  among  the  colonists.  A  century  of  virtual 
ignoring  of  British  commercial  restrictions,  making  smuggling  a  powerful 
vested  interest,  gave  the  thirteen  colonies  a  strong  common  motive  for 
Vinified  action  in  opposing  the  proposed  enforcement  of  the  long-dormant 
mercantilist^  restrictions  after  1763 — a  motive  that  A.  M.  Schlesinger 
has  fully  proved  to  have  been  far  more  powerful  than  any  theoretical  or 
legal  abstractions  involved  in  colonial  resistance  to  British  imperial 
power. 

In  addition  to  these  economic  origins  of  American  national  senti- 
ment, there  was  also  at  work  a  fundamental  sociological  process,  which 
has  been  aptly  termed  by  Carl  Lotus  Becker  "the  beginnings  of  the 
American  people."  A  geographical,  social,  political,  and  economic  en- 
vironment, much  different  from  that  of  Europe,  had  long  been  operating 
upon  a  population  psychologically  more  daring  than  the  great  mass  of 
Englishmen  who  remained  at  home.  This  tended  inevitably  to  create  in 
the  colonies  a  people  who  became,  generation  after  generation,  more 
and  more  divergent  in  mentality  and  institutions  from  their  kinsmen  in 


NATIONS,   CONSTITUTIONS   AND   REPUBLICS     215 

the  mother  country  across  the  Atlantic.  A  fairly  homogeneous  and 
united  American  people  was  being  created,  and  the  beginnings  of  a  na- 
tional self-consciousness  were  coming  into  being. 

Initiated  (in  part  unintentionally)  by  the  enterprising  and  recalcitrant 
merchants,  the  American  Revolution  was  favored  by  the  debtor  landlords 
and  disgruntled  frontiersmen  and  carried  to  success  by  courage  and 
audacity,  by  the  not  disinterested  aid  of  the  French,  and  by  the  aid  of 
the  British  Whigs.  The  revolt  furnished  a  unifying  force  of  great 
potency  for  a  time,  but  the  reaction  in  the  days  of  the  Confederation 
threatened  a  lapse  into  anarchy  and  dismemberment.  Thanks,  however, 
to  their  desire  for  financial  stability  and  commercial  prosperity,  the 
vigorous  capitalistic  class,  led  by  the  great  constructive  statesman  of 
early  nationalism,  Alexander  Hamilton,  turned  the  tide  of  political  opin- 
ion from  separatism  and  provincialism  to  nationalism  and  unity.  The 
work  was  carried  on  by  the  strongly  nationalistic  court  decisions  of  John 
Marshall,  whom  not  even  Jefferson's  emnity  could  remove  from  the 
Supreme  Court.  Indeed,  the  Jeffersonian  Republicans,  when  they  came 
into  power  in  1801,  abandoned  their  localism  and  accepted  most  of  the 
nationalistic  program  that  they  had  criticized  with  such  vigor  and 
acrimony.  Jefferson  could  purchase  Louisiana;  Madison  could  be  won 
for  war  with  Great  Britain;  and  Monroe  could  formulate  a  strongly 
nationalistic  foreign  policy. 

Nationalism  in  America,  as  in  Europe,  was  completed  by  the  Indus- 
trial Revolution.  The  new  factories  in  the  North  created  an  industrial 
interdependence  among  various  sections  of  the  country  and  attracted 
an  immigrant  population  with  no  sectional  sentiments.  The  new  canals 
and  railroads  helped  on  that  great  nationalistic  enterprise  of  the  nine- 
teenth century  in  America — the  conquest  of  the  west,  studied  with  such 
fruitfulness  by  Frederick  Jackson  Turner  and  his  disciples.  While  the 
territorial  additions  were  temporarily  a  cause  of  sectional  dispute  and 
friction,  they  ultimately  became  a  matter  of  national  pride  and  common 
interest.  Though  Negro  slavery,  and  the  accompanying  states-rights 
movement,  threatened  to  disrupt  the  embryonic  nation,  the  success  of 
the  North  in  the  Civil  AVar  demonstrated  by  the  verdict  of  physical  force 
that  Webster,  rather  than  Calhoun  or  Hayne,  was  right  in  his  interpre- 
tation of  the  nature  of  the  federal  union. 

Events  and  tendencies  since  the  Civil  War  have  been  even  more  con- 
ducive to  the  development  of  national  unity.  An  industrial  revolution, 
like  that  which  affected  New  England  in  the  first  half  of  the  nineteenth 
century,  has  come  to  the  South,  and  the  sharp  sectional  divisions  of 
economic  interests  have  now  been  greatly  lessened.  The  further  de- 
velopment of  the  means  of  rapid  transportation  and  almost  instantaneous 
communication  of  information  have  made  our  extensive  country  an 
economic  and  psychological  unit  to  a  degree  unknown  in  a  much 
smaller  area  in  1789.  The  intersectional  investment  of  capital  has  also 
encouraged  financial  unity. 

A  national  literature  has  been  provided  by  such  writers  as  Irving, 


216     NATIONS,  CONSTITUTIONS  AND   REPUBLICS 

Bryant,  Cooper,  Longfellow,  Lowell,  Whitman,  Thoreau,  Emerson,  Haw- 
thorne, Poe,  Clemens,  Howells,  Riley,  and  Garland.  A  collection  of 
the  sources  of  national  history  was  planned  and  partly  executed  by 
Peter  Force,  and  a  national  historical  epic,  eulogizing  the  American  past, 
was  created  in  the  writings  of  Bancroft,  Palfrey,  Fiske,  Hoist,  and  Bur- 
gess. Elaborate  national  expositions  and  public  projects,  such  as  the 
Chicago  World's  Fair  (1893),  the  St.  Louis  Exposition  (1904),  the  Cen- 
tury of  Progress  Exposition  at  Chicago  (1933-34)  and  the  World's  Fair 
in  New  York  (1939-40),  have  furnished  a  series  of  impulses  to  unity. 

Many  pessimists  believed  that  the  great  influx  of  foreigners  into  the 
United  States  in  the  last  fifty  years  threatened  national  disruption.  But 
the  experience  of  the  United  States  in  the  first  World  War  definitely  dis- 
proved their  forebodings  and  demonstrated  that,  whatever  the  other 
results  of  immigration,  it  has  not  brought  national  disintegration. 

A  "glorious"  foreign  war  at  the  close  of  the  century  gave  a  great 
stimulus  to  the  completion  of  national  development.  The  participation 
of  the  United  States  in  the  first  World  War  produced  a  welling-up  of 
exuberant  national  sentiment  and  an  intolerant  patriotism  that  caused 
both  the  Entente  and  the  Central  Powers  to  gasp  with  astonishment  and 
incredulity.  Organizations  of  ex-soldiers  devote  themselves  to  perpetuat- 
ing this  state  of  mind. 

Nationalism  in  the  Western  Hemisphere  has  not  been  limited  to  the 
United  States.  The  Dominion  of  Canada,  despite  a  formal  connection 
with  Great  Britain,  has  developed  a  marked  spirit  of  national  self-con- 
sciousness. A  century  or  more  of  independent  political  existence  has 
created  a  strong  spirit  of  national  unity  and  pride  in  the  Latin  American 
countries.  Nationalism  seems  as  well  established  in  the  Americas  as  in 
Europe. 

While  nationalism  was  a  main  cause  of  the  first  and  second  World 
Wars,  it  seems  likely  that  the  second  World  War  will  gravely  modify, 
if  it  does  not  suppress  entirely,  the  national-state  system.  As  H.  N. 
Brailsford,  W.  H.  Chamberlin,  and  others  have  suggested,  there  is  not 
much  likelihood  that  small  national  states  will  survive  the  present  world- 
conflict.  A  few  great  states,  far  exceeding  nationalistic  boundaries,  with 
lesser  states  within  their  spheres  of  interest,  are  likely  to  emerge  when  the 
war  is  over.  Regional  federations  will  probably  supplant  national  states. 

The  national  state  has  been  based  on  a  territorial  and  property  founda- 
tion, and  representative  government  has  been  operated  by  means  of  terri- 
torial, or  district,  representation.  But  the  more  alert  and  progressive 
political  theorists  are  inclined  to  believe  that  the  territorial  state  is  now 
giving  way  to  the  functional  state.  Though  the  external  boundaries  of 
a  country  may  remain  as  before,  the  political  organization  and  operations 
within  the  country  will  be  markedly  transformed.  Instead  of  voting 
through  territorial  districts,  voters  will  choose  their  representatives  as 
members  of  vocations  or  functional  groups.  In  other  words,  bankers, 
industrialists,  lawyers,  teachers,  farmers,  mechanics,  and  the  like,  will 
elect  representatives  to  the  various  state  and  national  legislatures.  It  is 


NATIONS,   CONSTITUTIONS  AND   REPUBLICS     217 

held  that  this  system  will  give  greater  logic  and  honesty  to  representative 
government.9 

Whether  or  not  this  is  a  sound  theory,  there  are  many  signs  that  this 
transformation  is  under  way.  This  system  has  been  adopted,  in  differing 
degrees  of  thoroughness,  in  some  European  countries.  In  this  country, 
the  lobby,  which  is  really  a  vocational  representative  body,  is  frequently 
more  powerful  than  the  legislatures  themselves.  If  territorial  representa- 
tion is  supplanted  by  functional  or  vocational  representation,  it  will  con- 
stitute as  sweeping  a  political  revolution  as  the  transition  from  tribal  to 
civil  society  at  the  dawn  of  history. 

We  may  conclude  this  historical  survey  with  a  brief  summary  or  outline 
of  the  outstanding  stages,  periods,  or  types  of  political  evolution: 

I.  Tribal  Society: 

Kinship  basis. 

Personal  relations. 
II.  The  Transitional  Period  of  Feudalism: 

Personal  relationships. 

Quasi-territorial  basis  of  politics. 

III.  The  Territorial  State  and  Civil  Society: 

City-states. 
Patriarchal  empires. 
The  national  state: 

Absolut  istic. 

Representative. 

Democratic  (usually  republican). 

IV.  The  Functional  Society  of  the  Future: 

Political  federations  and  spheres  of  interest. 
Functional  or  vocational  representation. 

Nationalism,  State  Activity,  and  the  Growing 
Complexity  of  Political   Problems 

To  national  spirit  and  dynastic  aggression  we  owe,  primarily,  the 
origin  of  the  large  political  states  of  our  day.  It  was  a  matter  of  pride 
and  satisfaction  to  carve  out  these  great  territories  and  bring  them  under 
the  wing  of  a  particular  dynasty  or  political  authority.  No  tremendous 
new  political  responsibilities  were  imposed,  because  the  economy  was  then 
still  a  simple  and  rudimentary  one.  Most  of  the  great  national  states 
were  built  up  either  in  a  pastoral  or  agricultural  era,  or  on  the  eve  of  the 
new  industrialism.  While  it  was  natural  that  the  problems  of  admin- 
istration would  be  somewhat  extended  and  complicated  with  the  addition 
of  new  territory  and  populations,  political  problems  still  remained  essen- 
tially simple  and  rudimentary.  They  did  not  threaten  to  swamp  the 
political  intelligence  or  administrative  methods  of  earlier  eras. 

But  this  simplicity  of  life  and  of  political  problems  soon  passed  away. 
The  empire  of  machines  arose.  Cities  came  into  being  in  ever  greater 


See  below,  pp.  263-266. 


218     NATIONS,  CONSTITUTIONS  AND   REPUBLICS 

numbers  and  on  an  ever  larger  scale.  New  problems  of  industry  and 
transportation  appeared  which  required  public  regulation.  The  fiscal  and 
commercial  policies  of  states  became  ever  more  extensive  and  complicated. 
New  forms  of  poverty,  dependency,  and  social  pathology  came  into  being 
and  demanded  the  attention  of  political  authorities.  Mass  movements 
of  population  and  international  migrations  demanded  a  definite  political 
policy.  New  questions  of  public  health  arose.  Crime  became  more  com- 
plicated and  menacing.  Even  agriculture  lost  its  earlier  directness  and 
simplicity,  became  mechanized,  and  required  extensive  public  attention. 
The  ravages  of  industrialism  made  it  essential  to  turn  to  problems  of 
conservation. 

At  the  same  time,  a  change  came  about  in  political  philosophy.  The 
old  notion  that  the  state  should  act  chiefly  as  a  policeman,  simply  protect- 
ing life  and  property,  gave  way  before  the  notion  that  the  state  must 
assume  responsibility  for  social  welfare  and  must  regulate  an  ever  in- 
creasing number  of  social  and  economic  processes.  The  philosophy  of 
laissez-faire  was  supplanted  by  that  of  state-activity.  Even  those  par- 
ties and  groups  which  emphasized  the  fact  that  there  should  be  as  little 
government  as  possible  in  business  inevitably  had  to  accept  a  degree  of 
state  intervention  in  economic  life  which  would  have  amazed,  and  per- 
haps appalled,  Alexander  Hamilton  and  other  earlier  apostles  of  state 
intervention.  The  administration  of  Herbert  Hoover,  for  example,  made 
that  of  George  Washington  appear  almost  a  condition  of  political  anarchy 
by  comparison. 

Nationalism  thus  handed  down  into  our  complicated  urban,  industrial 
world  civilization  large  political  units,  the  so-called  national  states.  As 
the  problems  which  must  be  dealt  with  by  political  agencies  became  more 
numerous  and  complex,  the  national  state  system  began  to  add  markedly 
to  the  difficulties  of  political  control  over  human  life  and  social  institu- 
tions. Political  problems  were  difficult  enough  in  small  states  with  few 
inhabitants.  The  more  extensive  the  territory  and  the  larger  the  popu- 
lation of  a  state,  the  more  numerous  and  complicated  were  the  problems 
of  politics.  The  great  political  units  of  our  day,  which  brought  so  much 
pride  to  their  original  creators,  now  became  in  many  ways  a  political 
liability. 

The  major  public  problems  of  our  era  baffle  experts,  to  say  nothing  of 
the  rank  and  file  of  political  legislators  and  administrators.  The  populace 
at  large  is  usually  woefully  ignorant  of  the  facts  concerning  any  major 
public  issue.  To  submit  such  issues  to  a  popular  referendum  is  becom- 
ing ever  more  ludicrous,  but  such  is  the  necessity  in  democratic  procedure. 
It  would  be  regarded  as  ridiculous  to  propose  a  plebiscite  on  some  com- 
plicated problem  of  astronomy  or  physics  today.  But  the  more  im- 
portant economic  problems,  which  must  be  dealt  with  through  politics, 
such  as  the  farm  problem,  the  utility  problem,  the  transportation  prob- 
lem, or  the  money  problem,  are  far  more  complicated  than  any  single 
issue  of  astronomy  or  physics. 

Some  few  years  ago  Irving  Fisher  suggested  that  only  about  a  dozen 


NATIONS,  CONSTITUTIONS  AND  REPUBLICS     219 

men  in  the  world  were  really  fitted  to  discuss  the  problem  of  money  with 
competence.  An  enterprising  organization  took  him  at  his  word  and 
sent  out  a  questionnaire  to  the  experts  he  named,  asking  for  their 
opinions  on  certain  major  monetary  facts  and  principles.  The  results  of 
this  questionnaire  revealed  clearly  that  even  the  leading  experts  could 
not  agree  upon  the  most  essential  phases  of  monetary  theory.  And  the 
money  problem  is  one  of  the  clearest  and  simplest  of  the  economic 
problems  of  our  age. 

Democracy  is  frequently  attacked  because  it  is  said  that  it  cannot 
muster  the  intelligence  to  deal  with  the  difficulties  of  our  era  of  civiliza- 
tion. There  may  be  a  great  deal  of  truth  in  this  indictment.  But  we 
must  remember  that  it  has  been  the  national  state,  projected  into  an 
era  of  industrialism  and  urbanism,  which  has  been  responsible  for  many 
of  the  current  perplexities  of  democratic  government.  Had  democracy 
been  able  to  operate  in  the  small  political  units,  for  which  it  was  recom- 
mended by  its  original  sponsors,  it  might  have  continued  to  work  with 
eminent  success.  Indeed,  it  has  been  eminently  successful  in  a  number 
of  the  smaller  states  of  the  western  world — such  as  Sweden,  Finland,  and 
Switzerland. 

Nationalism,   Patriotism,  and  War  Psychology 

A  century  or  so  ago  the  prevailing  and  most  common  psychological 
unit  in  human  society  was  the  neighborhood.  It  had  been  such  for 
countless  centuries.  Along  with  many  good  qualities,  the  neighborhood 
produced  several  less  lovely  psychological  traits,  such  as  smugness,  pro- 
vincialism, and  hostility  and  suspicion  toward  outsiders. 

So  backward  was  the  general  level  of  thought  and  social  interests  on 
the  eve  of  the  Industrial  Revolution  that  the  sudden  development  of 
means  for  quickly  communicating  the  prevalent  attitudes  throughout  the 
modern  national  state  tended  to  give  to  national  thought  and  emotion 
the  same  self-satisfied  provincialism  sand  smug  arrogance  that  had  earlier 
prevailed  on  a  local  scale.  The  inhabitants  of  whole  national  states 
came  to  entertain  towards  their  neighbors  much  the  same  sentiments  of 
suspicion  and  hostility  that  dwellers  in  neighborhoods  and  local  com- 
munities had  once  possessed  towards  strangers  from  outside.  Therefore 
it  is  not  surprising  when  James  Harvey  Robinson  finds  that:  "Our  an- 
cient tribal  instinct  evidently  retains  its  blind  and  unreasoning  character- 
istics despite  the  fact  that  we  are  able  nowadays,  by  means  of  newspapers, 
periodicals,  railroads,  and  telegraphs,  to  spread  it  over  vast  areas,  such  as 
are  comprised  in  modern  states  like  Germany,  France,  Russia,  and  the 
United  States."  Carlton  J.  H.  Hayes  has  very  effectively  stated  the 
relation  of  the  Industrial  Revolution  to  this  spread  of  national  sentiment 
and  of  nationalistic  propaganda: 

Without  the  Industrial  Revolution,  it  would  be  impossible  to  raise  funds,  to 
supply  textbooks  and  material  equipment,  or  to  exercise  centralized  supervision 
and  control  requisite  to  the  establishment  and  maintenance  of  great  systems  of 


220     NATIONS,  CONSTITUTIONS  AND  REPUBLICS 

free  universal  schooling.  Without  the  Industrial  Revolution,  it  would  be  im- 
possible to  take  all  able  bodied  young  men  away  from  productive  employment 
and  put  them  in  an  army  for  two  or  three  years,  feeding  and  clothing  and  hous- 
ing them  and  providing  them  with  transport,  arms  and  hospitals.  Without  the 
Industrial  Revolution,  it  would  be  impossible  to  produce  huge  quantities  of 
journals,  to  collect  news  for  them  quickly,  to  print  them  in  bulk,  to  distribute 
them  widely,  to  have  a  numerous  public  to  read  them  and  much  advertising 
to  pay  for  them.  Without  the  Industrial  Revolution,  it  would  be  impossible  for 
a  propagandist  society  to  flood  a  large  country  with  written  and  oral  appeals.  .  .  . 
The  technological  advance  itself  is  not  more  favorable  to  one  purpose  (na- 
tionalism) than  to  the  other  (internationalism).  It  can  be  used  for  either  or 
for  both.  In  fact,  it  has  been  used  for  a  century,  and  is  still  used,  preeminently 
for  nationalist  ends.  Societies,  journals,  and  schools,  as  well  as  armies,  are 
today  predominantly  nationalist,  and  the  nationalism  which  they  inculcate  tends 
to  bo  more  exclusive  and  more  vigorous.  Indeed,  economic  development  seems 
to  be  a  handmaid  to  nationalist  development,  rather  than  the  reverse.10 

The  development  of  new  means  for  the  communication  of  information, 
as  a  result  of  the  Industrial  Revolution,  made  possible  a  true  psychic 
unity  within  each  nation,  broke  up  local  isolation,  and  completed  the 
process  of  popularizing  national  sentiment  and  perfecting  national  self- 
consciousness.  It  made  the  various  national  manifestations  of  the  "herd 
instinct"  more  communicable,  more  responsive,  and  more  liable  to  sudden 
and  hysterical  explosions.  It  also  has  rendered  "jingoistic"  expressions 
in  other  countries  better  known  and  more  likely  to  arouse  antagonisms. 
Great  national  states  have  thus  been  rendered  as  cohesive  and  inflam- 
mable as  local  neighborhods  were  some  generations  back: 

In  our  modern  life  there  is  more  of  instantancousness  than  there  has  ever  been 
in  the  world  before.  Never  since  the  world  began  was  it  possible  to  conceive  such 
a  situation  as  this:  that  one  hundred  and  twenty  million  people  stretching  over 
a  continent,  an  imperial  expanse,  should  think  and  feel  simultaneously.  By 
radio  we  all  hear  the  same  fact  at  the  same  time.  It  may  happen  to  be  six 
o'clock  in  New  York  when  I  hear  it,  and  two  o'clock  in  California  when  some- 
body else  hears  it;  but  however  the  clocks  may  vary,  the  instant  in  time  is 
identical.  The  isolation  that  once  existed  when  news  traveled  slowly,  advancing 
in  waves,  reaching  first  one  area,  then  another,  then  a  third,  with  the  first  having 
time  to  meditate  about  it  before  it  became  a  universal  idea — all  this  is  a  thing 
of  the  past.  Now  we  not  only  get  the  same  idea  at  the  same  moment,  but  we 
all  react  to  it  at  the  same  time.  Therefore,  what  was  once  an  inescapable 
moment  of  meditation  vouchsafed  to  most  of  us  before  the  universality  of  an 
idea  was  accomplished,  is  now  abolished.11 

Neighborhoods,  however  smug,  suspicious,  and  arrogant,  could  not, 
however,  go  on  a  rampage  and  wreck  civilization.  An  entire  rural  com- 
munity, armed  with  all  the  available  muskets,  pitchforks,  scythes,  and 
rolling-pins,  could  not  do  a  vast  amount  of  damage  to  society  as  a  whole. 
But  great  national  states,  equipped  with  the  formidable  armaments  of  our 


10  C.  J.  H.  Hayes,  Historical  Evolution  of  Modern  Nationalism,  Farrar  &  Rinehart, 
1931,  pp.  23&-241. 

11  Newton  D.  Baker,  "The  Answer  is  Education,"  Journal  of  Adult  Education, 
June,   1931,  p.  265.    See  also   O.  W.  Riegel,  "Nationalism   in   Press,   Radio,  and 
Cinema,"  American  Sociological  Review,  August,  1938,  pp.  510-515. 


NATIONS,   CONSTITUTIONS  AND   REPUBLICS     221 

day,  can  wreck  civilization.  Indeed,  they  are  making  good  headway  at 
it  right  now. 

The  first  World  War  was,  in  part,  brought  about  by  nationalistic  psy- 
chology and  it  dealt  a  severe  blow  to  democratic  institutions.  Though  it 
was  fought  to  make  the  world  safe  for  democracy,  the  greater  part  of 
Europe  today,  from  the  standpoint  of  both  territory  and  population,  has 
gone  over  to  dictatorship.  It  was  an  even  more  ruthless  and  intense 
nationalism  that  fanned  the  flames  of  arrogance  and  hatred  into  a  new 
fever  heat  and  brought  about  the  second  World  War  in  September,  1939. 

It  is  to  nationalism,  then,  that  we  owe  two  of  the  major  problems  which 
confront  contemporary  democracy,  namely:  (1)  the  enormous  increase 
of  political  complexities  and  difficulties,  as  a  result  of  large  territorial 
states  in  an  industrial  era;  and  (2)  the  intensification  of  national  senti- 
ment on  a  large  scale,  which  threatens  and  produces  destructive  war 
and  imposes  greatly  increased  financial  and  diplomatic  responsibilities 
upon  modern  states. 

The  Rise  of  Constitutional   Government  and  the 
Ascendancy  of  Republics 

The  ideals  of  the  middle  class  from  the  seventeenth  century  to  the 
twentieth  are  clear  enough — nationalism,  freedom  for  business  enterprise, 
the  protection  of  property,  and  the  guarantee  of  civil  liberties.  But  it 
was  necessary  to  do  something  more  than  to  enunciate  and  eulogize  these 
ideals.  They  had  to  be  applied,  made  permanent,  and  be  protected.  In 
short,  it  was  necessary  to  create  constitutions,  which  would  embody 
these  ideals  and  make  them  the  basis  of  the  law  and  politics  of  the  state. 
Hence  the  growing  power  of  the  middle  class  and  the  success  of  revolutions 
were  everywhere  accompanied  by  the  rise  of  constitutional  government. 

Back  of  the  rise  of  all  constitutions  lie  basic  aspirations  and  principles. 
First,  there  is  the  conception  of  a  higher  or  absolute  law,  to  which  any  and 
all  secular  rulers  are  subordinate.  Second,  there  is  the  doctrine  of  pri- 
mordial and  inalienable  individual  rights — such  as  life,  liberty,  and 
property.  Finally,  there  is  the  notion  of  a  sacred  written  charter,  em- 
bodying the  higher  law  and  personal  rights,  and  immune  to  change  except 
through  a  formal  and  indubitable  expression  of  the  public  will.  Con- 
stitutional government  states  the  supreme  law,  enumerates  individual 
rights,  and  places  all  on  semi-sacred  parchment. 

A  constitution  may  be  defined  in  general  terms  as  the  organic  instru- 
ment of  government.  It  creates  the  form  of  political  institutions,  enu- 
merates the  functions  of  political  machinery,  and  also  prescribes  the 
rights  and  immunities  of  the  individual  citizen.  For  example,  a  con- 
stitution determines  whether  or  not  a  state  will  be  a  monarchy  or  a 
republic;  it  may  prescribe  either  executive  or  parliamentary  ascendancy 
in  the  government,  or  it  may  distribute  the  powers  of  government  equally 
among  the  executive,  legislative,  and  judicial  branches,  as  is  theoretically 
done  in  the  United  States;  it  may  describe  in  detail  the  nature,  terms, 


222     NATIONS,  CONSTITUTIONS  AND  REPUBLICS 

and  mode  of  election  of  the  various  members  of  each  department  of  the 
government;  and  it  may  specifically  enumerate  the  liberties  and  im- 
munities of  the  individual  citizen  under  the  particular  form  of  govern- 
ment created.  In  short,  the  constitution  defines  and  describes  the  legal 
rights  of  the  citizen  and  the  structure  and  operation  of  the  government 
that  is  to  make  him  secure  in  the  enjoyment  of  these  rights.  As  Walton 
H.  Hamilton  puts  it:  "A  law  for  the  government,  safeguarding  individual 
rights,  set  down  in  writing — that  is  the  constitution." 

A  constitution  may  be  a  very  precise  written  document,  worked  out  all 
at  one  time  by  a  specific  constitutional  convention.  Or,  it  may  be  a  col- 
lection of  documents  and  precedents  running  over  many  centuries.  Our 
Federal  Constitution  is  a  good  example  of  the  first,  and  the  English  con- 
stitution of  the  second. 

Since  the  middle  of  the  seventeenth  century,  constitutions  have  been 
mainly  the  creation  of  the  middle  classes.  But  any  dominant  class  can 
make  and  operate  a  constitution.  Constitutional  government  may  well 
support  a  landed  aristocracy,  as  does  that  of  Hungary  today.  It  may 
just  as  well  bring  into  being  a  proletarian  regime  that  virtually  outlaws 
both  the  landed  nobility  and  the  middle-class  capitalists.  Such  has  been 
the  result  of  the  constitution  of  Soviet  Russia  in  our  day.  But  thus  far 
in  modern  history  the  movement  for  constitutions  has  been  so  closely 
linked  with  the  program  and  activities  of  the  middle  class  that  we  may 
almost  identify  the  desire  for,  and  the  creation  of,  constitutions  with  the 
interests  and  strategy  of  that  class.  Down  to  1789,  the  middle-class  con- 
stitutions were  designed  to  protect  property  from  assault  by  royalty  and 
nobility — those  socially  above  the  middle  class.  The  United  States  set 
the  precedent  in  creating  a  constitution  to  protect  property  against  in- 
dustrial workers  and  peasants — that  is,  to  protect  the  middle  class  from 
those  below  it.  The  violence  in  Shay's  Rebellion  and  other  uprisings 
of  the  desperate  and  embattled  farmers  and  the  first  rumbles  of  labor 
organization  frightened  the  property  owners.  Therefore,  they  drew  up 
a  constitution  which  rendered  property  relatively  immune  from  any 
radical  legislation  and  made  the  amendment  of  the  constitution  very 
difficult,  so  that  the  property  class  was  not  likely  to  lose  control  of  the 
government.  This  protection  of  property  from  the  depredations  of  the 
lower  classes  was  made  still  more  impregnable  after  the  Civil  War  by 
the  "due  process"  clause  of  the  Fourteenth  Amendment. 

The  political  institutions  and  policies  of  the  Western  world  since  the 
seventeenth  century  have  reflected  the  economic,  social,  and  political 
ideals  of  the  capitalistic  middle  class.  These  were  chiefly  legal  protec- 
tion of  property,  enforcement  of  contract,  and  a  large  degree  of  freedom 
in  personal  and  business  initiative.  Everywhere  the  bourgoisie  have 
opposed  state  interference  with  economic  activities,  except  where  this 
interference  has  been  believed  to  foster  their  interests.  They  have  been 
opposed  to  social  legislation  designed  to  protect  the  working  classes  and 
hence  likely  to  hamper  the  freedom  of  the  employer  to  deal  with  his 
employees  as  he  sees  fit. 


NATIONS,   CONSTITUTIONS  AND   REPUBLICS     223 

Most  modern  constitutions  have  embodied  these  fundamental  bour- 
geois ideals  of  freedom  from  arbitrary  governmental  interference  and 
have  assured  the  protection  of  personal  rights  and  property  interests. 
The  fundamental  rights  and  immunities  for  all  men  and  the  appropriate 
guarantees  of  economic  liberty  were  embodied  in  the  first  ten  Amend- 
ments to  the  American  Constitution — really  an  integral  part  of  the 
document,  since  they  were  all  added  immediately.  The  French  Declara- 
tion of  the  Rights  of  Man,  drawn  up  in  1789,  mentions  property  among 
the  "natural  and  imprescriptible  rights  of  man"  in  Article  2,  and  in 
Article  17  also  describes  it  as  "an  inviolable  and  sacred  right." 

The  relative  stability  of  constitutional  governments  and  their  specific 
guarantees  of  political  and  economic  rights  to  the  propertied  classes  have 
been  the  chief  reasons  why  the  triumph  of  the  bourgeoisie  in  politics 
throughout  the  Western  world  has  been  followed  by  the  immediate 
adoption  of  written  constitutions.  The  degree  of  fixity  and  rigidity  in 
constitutional  government  varies  greatly.  In  Great  Britain,  Parliament 
can  theoretically  amend  the  constitution  with  as  little  formal  difficulty 
as  it  meets  in  passing  a  bill  appropriating  a  petty  sum  for  repairing  a 
local  bridge.  In  the  United  States  the  process  of  amendment  is  so  diffi- 
cult that  only  twelve  Amendments  have  been  added  to  the  original  ten 
adopted  a  hundred  and  fifty  years  ago.  But  even  in  England  constitu- 
tional changes  are  infrequent  and  never  undertaken  in  a  lighthearted 
manner,  chiefly  because  of  the  British  reverence  for  precedent  and  their 
reluctance  to  experiment.  In  practice,  then  the  English  constitution  is 
not  so  easy  to  alter  in  any  fundamental  sense.  Almost  without  exception, 
constitutions  have  been  changed  slowly  and  infrequently,  and  constitu- 
tional government  has  been  characterized  by  relative  rigidity  and  per- 
manence. The  middle  class  have  thus  far  been  vindicated  in  their  re- 
liance upon  constitutional  government  as  a  safeguard  against  either  royal 
arbitrariness  or  proletarian  radicalism.  It  is  easy  to  understand  the 
devotion  of  contemporary  American  businessmen  to  the  Constitution. 

While  the  first  important  written  constitution  of  modern  times  was  the 
so-called  Instrument  of  Government,  drawn  up  by  Cromwell  for  his 
Commonwealth  government,  constitutions^  are  by  no  means  a  product 
of  modern  history.  Aristotle  is  said  to  have  studied  the  text  of  some  158 
constitutions,  to  serve  as  the  basis  of  his  book  on  the  Athenian  Constitu- 
tion. The  forerunners  of  modern  written  constitutions  were  the  charters 
granted  to  the  medieval  towns,  to  the  English  colonies  in  America,  and 
to  chartered  trading  companies.  The  English  constitution  is  a  curious 
combination  of  various  documents.  Among  the  most  important  of  these 
documents  are  the  Magna  Charta  (1215),  the  Petition  of  Right  (1628), 
the  Bill  of  Rights  (1688-1689)  and  the  legislation  immediately  following 
it,  the  Reform  Bill  of  1832,  the  Suffrage  Acts  of  1867,  1884,  and  1918, 
the  Parliament  Bill  of  1911,  and  the  Suffrage  Acts  of  1918  and  1928. 
Among  the  other  things  that  go  to  make  up  the  English  Constitution,  are 
"the  privileges  of  Parliament,"  the  Conventions  of  the  Constitution,  the 
Common  Law,  and  the  like. 


224     NATIONS,   CONSTITUTIONS  AND   REPUBLICS 

The  first  great  crop  of  written  constitutions  in  modern  society  were 
those  adopted  by  the  American  states  after  the  Declaration  of  Inde- 
pendence. They  were  founded  on  the  precedents  of  the  colonial  charters, 
the  revolutionary  doctrines  of  the  British  Whigs,  and  the  Bill  of  Rights 
of  1689.  These  early  state  constitutions  in  America  almost  perfectly 
exemplified  the  political  ideals  of  the  middle-class  liberals.  The  aris- 
tocratic and  monarchical  elements  in  government  were  eliminated,  espe- 
cially the  hereditary  executive.  Special  privilege  and  hereditary  rights 
were  denounced.  The  doctrine  of  popular  sovereignty  and  the  assertion 
that  all  powers  were  originally  given  to  the  government  by  the  people 
were  boldly  and  universally  proclaimed. 

The  French  philosopher  Montesquieu  maintained,  about  the  middle  of 
the  eighteenth  century,  that  the  chief  guarantee  of  liberty  lies  in  a  proper 
separation  of  governmental  powers  into  executive,  legislative,  and 
judicial  branches,  and  in  an  elaborate  system  of  checks  and  balances. 
This  doctrine  was  embodied  very  generally  in  these  American  state  con- 
stitutions. The  lingering  fear  of  the  king  was  reflected,  nevertheless,  in 
a  general  tendency  to  exalt  the  legislature  at  the  expense  of  the  execu- 
tive department.  Short  terms  for  governors  were  the  rule.  John  Adams 
said  that  annual  elections  were  the  only  safeguard  against  tyranny. 

The  laissez-faire  tendencies  of  the  economic  liberalism  of  that  time 
were  accepted,  and  the  functions  of  government  were  limited  to  the  pro- 
tection of  life,  liberty,  and  property.  Any  extensive  development  beyond 
this  was  frowned  upon.  Yet  there  were  some  vestiges  of  aristocracy  and 
privilege.  Property  qualifications  for  voting  and  office-holding  were 
common,  and  even  religious  qualifications  for  office  and  the  ballot  were 
frequent. 

Constitution-making  was  carried  to  a  national  scope  in  the  Articles  of 
Confederation  of  March,  1781.  But  these  were  weak  and  inadequate. 
A  Constitution  embodying  strong  federal  principles  was  framed  in  1787 
and  adopted  by  1789. 

The  French  Revolution  produced  a  number  of  constitutions,  all  pro- 
foundly influenced  by  British  and  American  precedents.  The  one  of 
1791,  which  provided  for  the  creation  of  a  limited  monarchy  under  the 
Legislative  Assembly,  was  more  widely  followed  as  a  model  than  the 
later  and  more  radical  constitutions,  because  at  this  time  limited 
monarchy  aroused  fewer  objections  from  conservative  minds  than  did 
republican  government.  Napoleon  popularized  constitutional  govern- 
ment. Even  though  he  ruled  with  an  iron  hand,  he  governed  under  con- 
stitutional forms  in  France  and  handed  out  charters  and  constitutions 
to  his  subject  territories.  A  famous  and  influential  constitution  of  the 
Napoleonic  period  was  that  adopted  in  Spain  in  1812,  based  on  the 
French  constitution  of  1891.  This  constitution,  proclaiming  popular 
sovereignty  and  parliamentary  government,  was  widely  studied  by  the 
European  liberals  in  their  struggle  for  constitutions  between  the  Congress 
of  Vienna  (1815)  and  the  Revolutions  of  1848.  It  was  also  widely 
imitated  by  the  Latin-American  peoples.  The  constitution  of  industrial 


NATIONS,   CONSTITUTIONS   AND   REPUBLICS     225 

Belgium,  influenced  by  the  British  constitution,  and  adopted  and  approved 
in  1830-1831,  was  especially  admired  by  middle-class  liberals  and'widely 
copied. 

From  1815  to  1848  the  battle  for  constitutions  met  many  and  serious 
rebuffs  at  the  hands  of  Prince  Metternich.  He  knew  that  constitutions 
almost  always  involve  representative  institutions,  and,  hence  he  recog- 
nized their  threat  to  the  system  of  autocracy  that  maintained  him  in 
power.  But  after  1848  his  influence  waned.  The  Kingdom  of  Piedmont 
and  Sardinia  obtained  a  constitution  in  1848,  which  developed  into  the 
constitution  of  United  Italy.  The  King  of  Prussia  granted  a  constitu- 
tion in  1850,  which  lasted  with  few  changes  until  the  close  of  the  first 
World  War.  The  Emperor  of  Austria  was  compelled  to  establish  con- 
stitutional government  in  1861.  The  minor  European  countries  adopted 
constitutions  at  various  times  during  the  nineteenth  century,  particularly 
after  1850.  The  Latin-American  states  entered  the  constitution-making 
age  in  the  first  quarter  of  the  nineteenth  century. 

Those  states  which  adopted  constitutions  relatively  late  had  a  decided 
advantage  in  studying  the  experience  of  earlier  constitutional  systems. 
Most  of  the  constitutions  of  Australasia  embody,  for  example,  the  best 
features  of  the  English  and  American  constitutions.  The  dozen  or  so 
states  that  came  into  existence  in  Europe  after  the  first  World  War 
adopted  constitutions  which,  in  many  cases,  embodied  not  only  previous 
political  experience  but  also  novel  principles  of  political  science,  such  as 
proportional  and  vocational  representation.  The  Turkish  constitution 
conferred  remarkable  powers  upon  the  executive.  In  Russia,  and  in 
Spain  for  a  time,  constitutional  government  was  turned  against  wealth 
and  privilege  and  made  a  bulwark  of  proletarian  radicalism.  A.  C.  Flick 
summarizes  the  extent  and  significance  of  this  era  of  constitution -making: 

Between  1776  and  1850  well  on  towards  a  hundred  written  constitutions  were 
created  throughout  the  world.  For  the  most  part  they  represented  political 
victories  won  by  the  people  for  democracy  and  nationality.  Many  of  them 
stood  as  protests  against  the  oppression  of  a  motherland,  such  as  the  new 
American  states  against  Great  Britain,  Spain,  and  Portugal.  Others  embodied 
hostility  to  control  by  other  lands,  as  Belgium  against  Holland,  Greece  against 
Turkey,  and  Italy  and  Hungary  against  Austria.  Some  stood  as  revolts  against 
tyrannical  rulers  as  in  France,  Spain,  Getmany,  and  Austria.  Others  incorpo- 
rated internal  demands  for  reform,  as  in  Switzerland  and  Holland.  Taking 
these  documents  as  a  whole,  they  measure  the  decline  of  absolutism  and  mark 
the  progress  of  the  world  in  liberty  and  equality.12 

In  the  rise  of  Fascism  and  dictatorship  after  the  first  World  War  there 
was  a  strong  tendency  to  abandon  representative  government,  though 
there  is  no  reason  why  a  constitution  may  not  readily  be  founded  upon 
the  most  extreme  Fascist  principles.  But  the  most  striking  aspect  of  the 
rise  of  Fascism  is  the  implication  that  the  middle  class  have  lost  con- 


12  A.  C.  Flick,  Modern   World  History,  Knopf,   1928,   p.  215. 


226     NATIONS,   CONSTITUTIONS  AND  REPUBLICS 

fidence  in  representative  government  as  a  means  of  protecting  the  vested 
interests  of  property.  A  main  reason  for  this  lies  in  the  increasing 
strength  of  the  working  class  in  contemporary  society,  and  the  consequent 
demand  of  this  class  that  constitutions  shall  express  their  interests  as  well 
as  those  of  the  middle  class. 

In  Russia  the  working  class  seized  power  and,  for  the  first  time  in 
human  history,  drew  up  a  working  constitution  which  represented  prole- 
tarian interests.  In  the  same  way  that  many  bourgeois  constitutions 
outlawed  revolution  and  made  property  secure  from  working-class  at- 
tacks, in  Russia  private  property  in  the  instruments  of  production  was 
outlawed,  and  only  members  of  the  working-class  were  allowed  to  par- 
ticipate in  government.  The  Russian  Soviet  constitution  represents  the 
very  opposite  extreme  in  class  interests  and  control  from  the  constitution 
of  the  United  States. 

The  conception  of  the  divine  right  of  kings  has  come  down  to  us  some- 
what modified  in  the  theory  of  the  divine  status  and  sanctity  of  constitu- 
tions. The  existence  of  constitutions  has,  indeed,  begotten  a  perverted 
mental  attitude  towards  them  known  as  "constitutionalism."  This  has 
been  defined  by  Professor  Hamilton  as  follows: 

Constitutionalism  is  the  name  given  to  the  trust  which  men  repose  in  the 
power  of  words  engrossed  on  parchment  to  keep  a  government  in  order.  The 
writing  down  of  the  fundamental  law,  beyond  peradventure  and  against  mis- 
understanding, is  an  important  political  invention.  It  offers  exact  and  endur- 
ing language  as  a  test  for  official  conduct  at  the  risk  of  imposing  outworn  stand- 
ards upon  current  activities.13 

The  vested  interests  frequently  ignore  the  fact  that  our  constitution  was  a 
result  of  many  compromises,  and  looked  upon  by  its  framers  as  a  very 
imperfect  experiment. 

The  theory  of  the  divine  right  of  kings  became  archaic  and  out  of 
adjustment  with  the  social  and  economic  interests  of  the  seventeenth  and 
eighteenth  centuries.  Constitutions  that  were  drawn  up  a  century  or 
a  half-century  ago  have  likewise  been  found  poorly  adapted  to  the  needs 
of  a  far  different  civilization  from  that  which  presided  over  their  drafting. 
This  defect  is  likely  to  become  even  more  serious  in  the  face  of  future 
cultural  alterations,  which  take  pl£ce  with  far  greater  rapidity  today  than 
ever  before.  Further,  constitutions,  which  are  but  a  means  to  the  end 
of  orderly  and  free  government,  have  come  to  be  regarded  as  an  end  in 
themselves.  It  is  doubtful  if  the  excesses  of  divine-right  panegyric  under 
Louis  XIV  were  greater  than  the  absurdities  of  constitution  eulogy  in 
our  own  age.  It  is  difficult  to  keep  in  mind  or  practice  the  basic  truth, 
so  well  phrased  by  Thomas  Jefferson,  that  constitutions  are  made  to 
serve  society  and  that  society  does  not  exist  to  serve  constitutions.  A 
characteristic  product  of  the  constitution  cult  is  the  following  excerpt  from 
an  address  by  an  eminent  corporation  lawyer,  Henry  D.  Estabrook,  cited 


ia  "Constitutionalism,"  Encyclopedia  oj  the  Social  Sciences,  Macmillan,  Vol.  4, 
p.  255. 


NATIONS,   CONSTITUTIONS  AND   REPUBLICS     227 

in  Harry  F.  AtwoocTs  Back  to  the  Republic,  a  book  that  has  enjoyed  an 
amazing  popularity  with  the  American  plutocracy: 

And  so,  on  this  great  continent,  which  God  had  kept  hidden  in  a  little  world 
— here,  with  a  new  heaven  and  a  new  earth,  where  former  things  had  passed 
away,  the  people  of  many  nations,  of  various  needs  and  creeds,  but  united  in 
heart  and  soul  and  mind  for  the  single  purpose,  builded  an  altar  to  Liberty, 
the  first  ever  built,  or  that  ever  could  be  built,  and  called  it  the  Constitution 
of  the  United  States.  .  .  . 

O  marvelous  Consitution!  Magic  parchment,  transforming  word,  maker, 
monitor,  guardian  of  mankind!  Thou  hast  gathered  to  thy  impartial  bosom 
the  peoples  of  the  earth,  Columbia,  and  called  them  equal.  Thou  hast  conferred 
upon  them  imperial  sovereignty,  revoking  all  titles  but  that  of  man.  Native 
and  exotic,  rich  and  poor,  good  and  bad,  old  and  young,  lazy  and  the  industrious, 
those  who  love  and  those  who  hate,  the  mean  and  lowly,  the  high  and  mighty, 
the  wise  and  the  foolish,  the  prudent  and  the  imprudent,  the  cautious  and  the 
hasty,  the  honest  and  the  dishonest,  those  who  pray  and  those  who  curse — these 
are  "We,  the  people  of  the  United  States" — these  are  God's  children — these  are 
thy  rulers,  O  Columbia.  Into  our  hands  thou  hast  committed  the  destinies  of 
the  human  race,  even  to  the  omega  of  thine  own  destruction.  And  all  thou 
rcquirest  of  us  before  we  o'erstep  boundaries  blazed  for  guidance  is  what  is 
required  of  us  at  every  railroad  crossing  in  the  country:  "Stop.  Look.  Listen." 
Stop  and  think.  Look  before  and  after  and  to  the  right  and  left.  Listen  to 
the  voice  of  reason  and  to  the  small  still  voice  of  conscience.14 

These  abuses  in  the  form  of  constitution  worship  have  been  most 
evident  in  the  United  States,  in  part  because  of  the  antiquity  of  the 
American  Constitution  and  in  part  because  of  the  degree  to  which  this 
document  is  a  bulwark  of  the  vested  propertied  interests.  This  attitude 
appears  not  only  in  such  silly  brochures  as  the  one  just  quoted,  but  also 
in  such  $  pretension  to  sober  scholarship  as  James  M.  Beck's  The  Con- 
stitution of  the  United  States.15  That  a  recognition  of  this  state  of 
affairs  does  not  necessarily  imply  any  subversive  attitude  may  be  seen 
from  the  judicious  criticism  of  the  American  constitutional  system  in 
William  MacDonald's  A  New  Constitution  for  a  New  America,  the  work 
of  an  eminently  conservative,  respectable,  and  balanced  writer,  wholly 
devoid  of  any  violently  revolutionary  motives,  and  in  W.  Y.  Elliott's 
The  Need  for  Constitutional  Reform. 

But  it  should  be  remembered  that  constitution  worship,  intellectually 
indefensible  as  it  may  be  when  used  as  a  mask  for  the  advantage  that  it 
lends  the  vested  propertied  class,  ought  not  so  to  antagonize  its  opponents 
that  they  forget  that  any  constitution,  along  with  its  archaic  and  in- 
equitable sections,  usually  embodies  many  guarantees  and  safeguards 
of  personal  liberty  that  have  been  won  during  the  age-long  growth  of 
social  conscience. 

While  constitutions  may  be  provided  for  monarchical,  aristocratic, 
democratic,  and  totalitarian  forms  of  government,  the  middle  class  have 
been  very  generally  favorable  to  the  republican  form  of  government. 


14  H.  F.  Atwood,  Back  to  the  Republic,  Whitman,  1926,  pp.  66-67. 

15  Cf.  T.  R.  Powell,  "Constitutional  Metaphors,"  in  the  New  RepMic,  February 
11,  1925,  pp.  314-315. 


228     NATIONS,   CONSTITUTIONS   AND   REPUBLICS 

Monarchy  has  symbolized  to  them,  on  the  basis  of  the  historical  expe- 
riences of  previous  centuries,  arbitrary  royal  rule  and  interference  with 
their  business  and  prosperity.  Bourgeois  political  supremacy  has,  there- 
fore, generally  been  followed  by  the  establishment  of  the  republican 
form  of  government  and  the  adoption  of  written  constitutions.  This  has 
not  been  invariably  true,  because,  in  certain  instances,  the  monarchical 
tradition  has  been  too  strong  for  the  middle  class  to  uproot  at  once. 
One  must,  of  course,  be  on  his  guard  lest  he  take  it  for  granted  that  a 
republic  necessarily  means  a  more  liberal  form  of  government  than  can 
exist  under  a  constitutional  monarchy.  The  formal  monarchy  of  Eng- 
land, before  1939,  provided  a  government  more  democratic  and  more 
responsive  to  popular  will  than  does  the  republic  of  the  United  States. 
Even  Nazi  Germany  saw  fit  for  a  time  to  retain  the  fiction  of  a  republic. 

Though  the  republican  form  of  government  has  been  the  usual  ex- 
pression of  middle-class  political  liberalism  in  modern  times,  it  is  well 
known  that  republics  are  in  no  sense  an  exclusively  modern  institution. 
Republican  government  was  fairly  common  among  the  Greeks.  Rome 
remained  a  republic  for  hundreds  of  years.  In  the  Middle  Ages  there 
were  city-state  republics,  such  as  Genoa.  Switzerland  became  a  republic 
in  1291. 

The  first  important  republic  of  modern  times  was  the  Dutch  Republic, 
which  was  formed  in  1579  and  lasted  for  two  centuries.  A  far  more  ex- 
tensive republic  appeared  on  this  side  of  the  Atlantic  when  the  United 
States  of  America  was  given  permanence  by  the  Federal  Constitution, 
framed  1787.  The  First  French  Republic  came  into  being  in  1792.  The 
Second  French  Republic  lasted  from  1848  to  1852.  The  Third  French 
Republic  was  declared  in  1870  and  assured  in  1879.  The  revolutions 
in  Latin  America  after  1810  usually  brought  into  existence  what  were 
at  least  formally  called  republics,  however  dictatorial  the  rule  of  the 
leader.  In  South  Africa  the  Boers  established  two  republics:  the  Orange 
Free  State  in  1836  and  the  Transvaal  in  1852. 

After  the  first  World  War  a  considerable  crop  of  new  republics  sprung 
up  in  Europe.  Among  them  were  Czechoslovakia,  Austria,  Poland,  the 
Baltic  Republics — Lithuania,  Latvia,  Estonia,  and  Finland — The  Union 
of  Socialist  Soviet  Republics,  Portugal,  and  Spain.  The  Soviet  Republics 
and  the  Spanish  Republic  of  1933-1938  have  well  illustrated  the  fact 
that  republican  government  need  not  be  inseparably  connected  with  the 
dominion  and  aspirations  of  the  middle  class.  In  both  of  these  countries 
republican  forms  of  government  have  been  used  to  advance  the  interests 
of  the  radical  proletariat  and  the  peasantry. 


CHAPTER  VIII 

The  Technique  of  Democracy:  Political  Parties 
and  Party  Government 

The  Role  of  Political   Parties  in  Modern  Government 

IN  THE  preceding  chapter  we  traced  the  rise  of  the  national  state  and 
the  growth  of  constitutional  government.  Within  this  framework  repre- 
sentative government  and  democracy  have  developed  in  modern  times 
and  have  given  us  the  characteristic  political  system  of  our  day.  In 
this  chapter  we  shall  consider  the  technique  whereby  representative  gov- 
ernment and  democracy  have  been  able  to  operate.  So  that  represent- 
ative government  and  democracy  may  work,  some  method  must  be  found 
for  assuring  majority  rule  and  placing  the  representatives  of  the  people 
in  a  position  of  political  power.  Thus  far  in  human  experience  the  only 
practicable  method  of  so  doing  that  has  been  discovered  is  party  govern- 
ment. Representative  government  and  the  development  of  antagonistic 
social  and  economic  interests  in  contemporary  society — industrial,  finan- 
cial, commercial,  agricultural,  and  proletarian — have  begotten  party  poli- 
tics as  a  natural  mode  of  procedure. 

In  contemporary  western  society,  outside  of  totalitarian  states,  the 
average  citizen  participates  in  political  life  chiefly  as  a  member  of  a 
party.  His  interest  in  politics  centers  mainly  in  the  victory  of  a  given 
list  of  party  candidates.  The  average  voter  has  little  conception  of  the 
general  nature  or  purpose  of  government.  He  grasps  feebly,  or  not  at  all, 
the  fundamental  issues  that  are  involved.  His  whole  political  outlook 
is  concentrated  upon  the  entity  or  organization  known  as  the  political 
party,  and  upon  the  candidates  and  symbols  that  give  to  the  party 
vitality  and  personal  interest. 

Realistic  students,  however,  look  upon  the  political  party  not  as  a 
spontaneous  benevolent  association  but  as  the  public  organization  through 
which  the  various  interest-groups  in  modern  society  seek  to  promote  their 
specific  objects  and  ambitions.  These  interest-groups  must  compromise 
with  each  other  in  organizing  a  great  party.  For  this  reason,  considerable 
latitude  exists  in  party  platforms  or  whatever  serves  as  the  basis  of  party 
unity.  The  strongest  parties  are  those  which  can  unite  the  largest 
assemblage  of  persons  in  a  single  interest-group  or  can  combine  in  a 
harmonious  manner,  without  sacrificing  aggressiveness,  the  largest  num- 

229 


230  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

ber  of  interest-groups.    This  conception  of  the  political  party  has  been 
concisely  summarized  by  Bentley: 

The  party  gets  its  strength  from  the  interests  it  represents,  the  convention 
and  executive  committee  from  the  party,  arid  the  chairman  from  the  conven- 
tion and  committee.  In  each  grade  of  this  series  the  social  fact  actually  before 
us  is  leadership  of  some  underlying  interest  or  set  of  interests.1 

Charles  A.  Beard  has  also  expressed  the  fundamentally  economic  basis 
of  party  activity  and  organization  as  an  outgrowth  of  interest  pressures: 

The  grand  conclusion,  therefore,  seems  to  be  exactly  that  advanced  by  our 
own  James  Madison  in  the  Tenth  Number  of  the  Federalist.  To  express  his 
thought  in  modern  terms:  a  landed  interest,  a  transport  interest,  a  railway 
interest,  a  shipping  interest,  an  engineering  interest,  a  manufacturing  interest,  a 
public-official  interest,  with  many  lesser  interests,  grow  up  of  necessity  in  all 
great  societies  and  divide  themselves  into  different  classes  actuated  by  different 
sentiments  and  views.  The  regulation  of  these  various  and  interfering  interests, 
whatever  may  be  the  formula  for  the  ownership  of  property,  constitutes  the 
principal  task  of  modern  statesmen  and  involves  the  spirit  of  party  in  the 
necessary  and  ordinary  operations  of  government.  In  other  words,  there  is  no 
rest  for  mankind,  no  final  solution  of  eternal  contradictions.  Such  is  the  de- 
sign of  the  universe.  The  recognition  of  this  fact  is  the  beginning  of  wisdom — 
and  of  statesmanship.2 

Sociologists  are  inclined  to  hold  that,  in  spite  of  all  obvious  selfishness 
and  corruption,  party  strife  is  the  chief  dynamic  agency  in  promoting 
political  progress  and  stimulating  healthy  political  activity.  In  the  same 
way  that  the  physical  conflict  of  social  groups  created  the  state  and 
modern  political  institutions,  so  the  more  peaceful  struggle  of  parties 
within  the  state  secures  the  continuance  of  political  evolution. 

The  psychological  technique  through  which  party  leaders  dominate 
the  party  and  manipulate  public  opinion  has  been  incisively  analyzed  by 
Graham  Wallas  and  others.3  The  political  issues  that  concern  mankind 
are  not  approached  by  the  majority  of  citizens  as  a  complex  of  ideas  and 
desires.  They  are  recognized  through  the  association  of  a  political  prob- 
lem with  some  symbol.  Therefore,  while  a  party  may  have  a  conscious 
intellectual  origin  and  be  designed  to  achieve  a  definite  social  end,  it  has 
little  strength  or  duration  unless  it  secures  symbols  with  sufficiently  high 
emotional  values,  such  as  party  animals,  colors,  tunes,  names,  rhetoric, 
catchwords,  and  the  like.  A  skillful  party  makes  use  of  its  symbols  in 
the  same  way  that  a  commercial  concern  employs  its  trademarks  and 
advertisements.  If  a  candidate  is  not  properly  vested  with  symbols  he 
has  no  chance  of  success.  The  most  insignificant  nonentity,  properly  and 
fully  identified  with  the  party  symbols,  is  much  more  likely  to  be  suc- 
cessful in  an  election  than  the  strongest  personality  in  the  country,  if  the 


1  A.  F.  Bentley,  The  Process  of  Government,  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1908, 
p.  225. 

2C.  A.  Beard,  The  Economic  Basis  of  Politics,  Knopf,  1922,  p.  99. 
8  See  Graham  Wallas,  Human  Nature  in  Politics,  Houghton,  Mifflin,  1909. 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  231 

latter  has  cut  himself  off  from  party  connections  and  makes  an  appeal 
solely  to  the  intelligence  and  good  judgment  of  the  citizens. 

The  two-party  system,  the  exception  rather  than  the  rule  in  democracies, 
has  been  perpetuated  in  our  country  for  a  number  of  reasons.  Down  to 
1861  there  were  numerous  and  frequent  shifts  in  the  major  parties,  mak- 
ing it  possible  for  minor  parties  to  participate  in  the  formation  of  new 
major  parties.  There  has  been  little  real  radicalism  in  the  country  since 
the  Revolutionary  War.  Hence  radical  parties  have  not  appeared  with 
frequency  and  popular  psychology  has  been  hostile  towards  those  which 
have  arisen.  When  liberal  third  parties  have  developed,  it  has  been 
usual  for  one  or  both  of  the  major  parties  to  appropriate  the  more 
attractive  and  popular  portions  of  their  platforms,  thus  speedily  break- 
ing up  the  third  parties. 

Further,  the  two  major  parties  have  long  had  a  special  psychological 
hold  on  the  masses.  The  Democrats  appeal  to  tradition  and  proudly 
point  to  the  fact  that  their  party  has  endured  for  over  a  century,  un- 
changed even  in  name.  The  Republicans  call  attention  to  the  fact  that 
they  saved  the -Union  and  allege  with  a  straight  face  that  they  have  been 
responsible  for  our  remarkable  economic  expansion  and  material  pros- 
perity since  1861. 

Moreover,  labor  and  agriculture,  nominally  the  source  of  distinct  in- 
terests and  special  party  movements,  have  been  unable  to  form  united 
and  permanent  political  parties.  Labor  did  not  become  well  integrated 
until  after  the  Civil  War.  The  Knights  of  Labor  might  have  formed 
a  labor  party,  but  their  career  was  cut  short  too  quickly.  The  policy  of 
the  American  Federation  of  Labor  under  Samuel  Gompers  was  to  keep 
labor  out  of  politics  as  a  distinct  party  and  to  seek  favors  from  one  or 
another  of  the  major  parties.  Moreover,  there  can  be  no  real  labor  party 
until  the  American  proletariat  accepts  the  permanence  of  its  status.  This 
the  American  laborers  have  thus  far  refused  to  do.  They  have  regarded 
themselves  as  potential  capitalists  and  have  been  more  interested  in 
rising  above  the  laboring  groups  than  in  improving  themselves  within 
their  proletarian  status.  The  frontier  optimism  and  individualism  of 
"the  American  dream"  have  persisted  in  them  long  after  the  frontier  has 
ceased  to  exist.  Radical  labor  in  the  United  States  has  been  too  much 
divided  into  bitter  cliques  to  form  powerful  and  permanent  party  or- 
ganizations. The  Congress  of  Industrial  Organizations  (CIO)  may  pro- 
vide the  basis  for  a  Labor  party  in  the  United  States.  However,  in 
1936  Mr.  Lewis  threw  his  cohorts  to  Mr.  Roosevelt  and  in  1940  he  at- 
tempted to  line  them  up  for  Mr.  Willkie  and  the  Republicans. 

With  the  exception  of  sporadic  developments,  such  as  the  Greenback, 
Granger,  Populist,  Progressive,  and  Non-Partisan  League  movements, 
the  farmers  have  been  loyal  to  the  old  parties,  rebelling  only  briefly  in 
moments  of  near-starvation  and  losing  their  rebellious  secession  spirit 
with  a  rise  in  the  price  of  agricultural  products. 

In  Europe,  before  totalitarianism  set  in,  there  were  in  most  countries 
a  multiplicity  of  parties,  a  number  of  which  were  frequently  united  into 


232  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

blocs  or  groups.  This  has  been  true  because,  in  Europe,  party  organiza- 
tion has  been  more  normally  and  naturally  associated  with  the  underly- 
ing interests  of  the  various  groups  and  classes.  Moreover,  there  have 
been  more  classes  and  interests  in  Europe  than  in  the  United  States — 
everything  from  monarchists  to  communists  and  anarchists.  And  within 
each  major  group  there  has  been  an  inclination  to  split  over  minor  inter- 
pretations of  social,  economic,  or  political  dogmas.  Further,  party  ma- 
chinery is  less  powerful  and  cohesive  in  Europe  than  in  the  United 
States. 

The  bloc  system  naturally  invites  disorganization  and  chaos,  as  com- 
pared to  the  two-party  system,  but  at  least  the  parties  do  stand  for 
something  definite.  The  choice  is,  essentially,  between  the  unreality  of 
the  two-party  system  of  the  United  States  and  the  chaotic  character  of 
the  bloc  system  of  Europe.  The  latter  seemed  to  be  winning  out  before 
1939.  Even  England,  long  the  home  of  the  two-party  system,  had  in 
1939  a  half-dozen  definite  parties  represented  in  the  House  of  Commons. 
Even  the  old  parties,  such  as  the  Liberal,  were  beginning  to  split  up. 
The  futility  of  the  two-party  system  in  the  United  States  is  becoming 
increasingly  apparent.  Whatever  one's  preferences  in  the  matter,  it 
certainly  seems  that  the  interests  in  modern  society  are  too  diversified 
and  numerous  to  allow  adequate  expression  through  the  medium  of  two 
political  parties.  There  would  need  to  be  at  least  three  parties — a  con- 
servative, a  liberal,  and  a  radical  party. 

While  there  is  a  trend  towards  multiple  parties  in  democracies,  the 
new  totalitarian  states  have  installed  one-party  systems.  But  there  the 
party  does  not  function  as  a  phase  of  representative  government.  It  is 
chiefly  a  propaganda  agency  and  an  administrative  errand  boy  for  the 
dictatorship  and  bureaucracy  which  run  all  totalitarian  states. 

The  Rise  of  Party  Government 

Factions  representing  distinct  interest  groups  have  existed  from  a  very 
early  day,  though  party  government,  as  a  publicly  recognized  agency, 
could  scarcely  appear  until  after  the  rise  of  representative  government. 
In  the  Greek  city-states,  especially  in  Athens,  there  were  political  parties 
or  factions.  Aristotle,  in  fact,  made  an  analysis  of  the  genesis  and  nature 
of  factional,  party,  and  class  activity,  though  he  himself  clearly  disap- 
proved of  these  divisions.  But  there  was  no  permanent  party  organiza- 
tion in  Athenian  democracy,  much  less  any  recognition  of  the  party  as 
a  factor  in  political  society.  The  Romans  produced  vigorous  political 
factions,  but  here  again  political  factions  and  interests  shifted  rapidly. 

After  the  collapse  of  Rome,  the  western  world  broke  up  into  the  feudal 
system.  With  such  world-order  as  existed  being  furnished  by  the  church 
and  the  unifying  tradition  of  Rome,  there  was  still  no  place  for  party 
government.  The  feudal  political  relations  of  the  Middle  Ages  were 
based  chiefly  upon  personal  allegiance,  a  condition  somewhat  interme- 
diate between  the  bond  of  blood  relationship  (real  or  fictitious) ,  in  primi- 
tive society,  and  the  political  status  of  developed  civil  society.  The 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  233 

chief  struggle  during  the  Middle  Ages  was  that  between  the  church  and 
the  state,  but  such  conflicts  were  partly  international  in  their  scope,  and 
they  rarely  produced  any  permanent  party  alignment  upon  the  questions 
at  issue.  The  struggles  within  the  church,  which  culminated  in  the 
Conciliar  Movement  of  the  fifteenth  century,  were  also  international  in 
scope  and  more  directly  productive  of  representative  government  than 
of  the  party  system. 

The  factions  or  parties  that,  at  times,  existed  in  the  medieval  period 
are  well  exemplified  by  the  historic  conflict  between  the  Guelphs  and 
the  Ghibellines.  These  parties  were  produced  by  the  struggle  between 
the  Holy  Roman  Emperor  and  the  Italian  city-states,  but  their  conflicts 
were,  in  part,  personal,  family,  or  municipal  feuds,  carried  on  with  great 
bitterness.  The  other  form  of  political  conflict  that  prevailed  in  the 
Middle  Ages,  especially  in  the  latter  part  of  the  period,  namely,  that 
between  the  newly  developing  cities  and  the  feudal  lords  or  the  king, 
was  a  conflict  of  different  types  of  society  rather  than  party  strife. 

The  origins  of  modern  political  parties  are  tied  up  with  the  Commer- 
cial Revolution  and  the  rise  of  capitalism,  which  created  a  middle  class 
powerful  enough  to  challenge  the  landed  aristocracy.  The  first  parties 
were  thus  representatives  of  the  aristocratic  landed  interests  and  of  the 
growing  urban  middle  class,  respectively.  This  party  development  and 
struggle  could,  however,  find  significant  expression  only  where  the  middle 
class  had  become  strong  enough  to  institute  representative  government. 
England  was  the  only  important  European  state  where  this  was  achieved 
before  the  middle  of  the  eighteenth  century.  Here  the  kings  drew  their 
support  chiefly  from  the  artistocratic  landed  groups,  and  revolution  was 
promoted  mainly  by  the  urban  middle  class.  The  former  grew  into  the 
Tories  and  the  latter  into  the  Whigs,  this  development  taking  place  slowly 
between  1640  and  1700. 

When  William  III  came  to  the  throne  of  England  after  the  Revolution 
of  1688,  English  political  parties  were  already  a  recognized  element  in 
Parliamentary  life.  Something  like  strict  partisanship  in  the  consti- 
tution of  ministries  came  about  with  the  rise  of  the  cabinet  system  during 
the  reigns  of  George  I  and  George  II.  George  I,  the  founder  of  the 
Hanoverian  dynasty,  was  a  German  by  birth  and  culture,  and  never 
mastered  either  the  English  language  or  the  English  political  system.  He 
was  content  to  rule  through  ministers  who  assumed  actual  charge  of  the 
political  situation.  He  was  fortunate  in  securing  for  his  prime  minister 
the  leading  representative  of  the  middle-class  Whigs,  Robert  Walpole. 
Walpole  took  all  his  ministers  from  the  party  that  commanded  the  con- 
fidence of  Parliament.  In  this  way,  he  built  up  the  idea  of  the  responsible 
partisan  ministry.  Walpole  ruled  with  wisdom  and  discretion,  avoid- 
ing foreign  wars  and  entangling  international  relations.  Under  his  long 
leadership,  England  became  gradually  accustomed  to  the  party  system. 

The  next  important  stage  in  the  development  of  the  English  party  and 
representative  system  came  after  the  Reform  Bill  of  1832,  which  did  away 
with  the  rotten  boroughs  and  widened  the  suffrage  to  some  degree.  After 


234  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

that  time,  when  there  was  a  clash  between  ministry  and  Parliament  and 
an  appeal  was  taken  to  the  constituencies,  the  ministry  resigned  if  the 
election  went  against  it.  In  1835,  we  have  the  first  instance  of  a  ministry 
resigning  because  of  a  defeat  in  the  general  Parliamentary  elections — the 
Peel  ministry.  In  this  way,  both  the  ministry  and  the  House  of  Com- 
mons were  rendered  responsible  to  the  electorate. 

The  old  division  of  Whigs  and  Tories  began  to  break  down  after  the 
Reform  Bill  of  1832,  and  the  Liberals  and  Conservatives  took  their  place 
before  1850.  Their  early  battles  turned  about  factory  reform  and  free 
trade.  The  Conservatives  at  first  championed  labor  legislation,  and 
the  Liberals  the  abolition  of  the  Corn  Laws  (tariff  on  wheat)  and  other 
such  protective  measures.  During  the  last  half  of  the  century,  the 
Liberals  became  less  rigidly  laissez-faire  and  favored  social  legislation, 
especially  after  1905.  The  Conservatives  were  urged  to  do  the  same  by 
Joseph  Chamberlain,  but  he  met  with  indifferent  success.  Irish  Home 
Rule  became  a  burning  issue  between  the  parties  from  1884  to  the  first 
World  War.  The  Liberals  favored  it.  During  the  last  decade  of  the 
nineteenth  century  the  Labor  party  came  into  existence,  and  it  assumed 
an  important  role  in  English  political  life  after  1906.  It  threw  in  its 
weight  with  the  Liberal  party  from  1905  to  1914  to  forward  social 
legislation.  Growing  in  strength,  it  has  been  in  office  twice  since  the 
World  War  and  recently  seems  to  be  regaining  popularity.  The  first 
World  War  hopelessly  split  the  Liberal  party,  and  British  politics, 
divided  between  various  groups  of  Conservatives  and  Laborites,  took 
the  trend  towards  the  group  party  system  that  prevailed  on  the  con- 
tinent of  Europe. 

Party  government  on  the  continent  of  Europe  passed  through  the  same 
general  stages  as  did  party  government  in  England.  The  most  notable 
difference  we  have  already  touched  upon,  namely,  the  tendency  of  the 
party  system  in  continental  Europe  to  develop  on  the  lines  of  the  group  or 
bloc  system  rather  than  the  two-party  type. 

Before  the  adoption  of  our  Constitution  in  1789,  the  people  of  the 
United  States  had  enjoyed  more  than  one  hundred  and  fifty  years  of 
practice  in  the  organization  of  political  institutions.  Although  there 
was  no  widespread  organization  of  parties  until  after  the  adoption  of  the 
Constitution,  political  parties  had  existed  from  the  beginning  of  settle- 
ment in  America.  As  John  Adams  said  in  1812:  "You  say  our  divisions 
began  with  Federalism  and  anti-Federalism?  Alas!  they  began  with 
human  nature;  they  have  existed  in  America  from  its  first  plantation. 
In  every  colony,  divisions  always  prevailed.  In  New  York,  Pennsyl- 
vania, Virginia,  Massachusetts,  and  all  the  rest,  a  court  and  country 
party  has  always  contended." 

The  "Fathers"  were  familiar  with  the  effects  of  parties,  or  better,  "fac- 
tions." They  regarded  party  government  as  detrimental  to  public  life, 
and  tried  to  guard  against  it  in  the  new  national  government  created  by 
the  Constitution  of  1787.  They  provided  for  an  Electoral  College  to 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  235 

select  the  President,  and  apparently  expected  that  this  would  operate 
in  a  nonpartisan  manner. 

Yet  the  very  system  of  government  created  by  the  Constitution  was 
one  that  strongly  encouraged  the  origin  and  development  of  a  party 
system.  There  was  a  division  of  political  authority  and  responsibility 
between  the  federal  and  state  governments.  Moreover,  following  the 
dictum  of  Montesquieu,  there  was  a  strict  separation  of  the  three  phases 
of  governmental  power  in  the  federal  government.  The  executive,  legis- 
lative, and  judicial  departments  were,  in  formal  theory  at  least,  sharply 
separated  and  balanced  against  each  other.  It  was  necessary  to  have 
some  organization  that  would  produce  unity  of  policy  and  action  in  state 
and  federal  governments,  and  also  unify  the  three  formally  separated 
departments  in  the  federal  government,  especially  the  executive  and  the 
legislative.  The  political  party  was  the  agency  that  achieved  this  needed 
unification.  Finally,  the  new  American  government  was  one  which  in- 
cluded a  large  number  of  important  elective  offices.  Organization  was 
essential  to  provide  candidates  for  these  offices  and  to  secure  their  elec- 
tion. The  party  fulfilled  this  function  as  well. 

Therefore,  the  party  system  arose  not  long  after  the  establishment  of 
what  the  Fathers  thought  was  a  nonpartisan  government.  The  Electoral 
College  virtually  ceased  to  operate  as  an  independent  body  by  1796, 
and  by  1800  it  had  already  become  a  meaningless  relic.  Party  develop- 
ment thus  took  place  speedily,  in  spite  of  President  Washington's  earnest 
efforts  to  preserve  the  nonpartisan  system  contemplated  by  the  framers 
of  the  Constitution.  Washington  chose  the  members  of  his  cabinet  from 
both  parties,  as  English  monarchs  had  done  a  hundred  years  before.  The 
legitimate  function  of  an  opposition  party  was  not  comprehended  by 
him.  The  party  spirit  of  his  administration  and  the  bitterness  of  the 
party  recriminations,  with  those  in  his  own  official  family  employing 
pamphleteers  to  attack  political  opponents,  remind  one  of  the  party 
strife  during  the  reigns  of  William  and  Anne. 

County  and  town  nominating  conventions  had  developed  in  the  latter 
part  of  the  eighteenth  century.  When  it  became  necessary  to  organize 
state  and  national  governments,  some  form  of  party  organization  of  com- 
parable scope  was  rendered  essential.  The  legislative  caucus,  that  is, 
the  nomination  of  party  candidates  by  members  of  the  legislatures,  at 
first  supplied  the  need.  The  legislators  were  relatively  prominent  men 
from  all  sections  of  the  political  community  and  fairly  represented  the 
parties  in  the  legislature.  ,  Owing  to  the  difficulty  of  travel  in  those  days, 
it  was  a  great  convenience  to  have  a  group  of  party  men  from  all  parta 
of  the  state  or  country  already  assembled  in  some  central  place — the 
capital  city.  The  legislative  caucus  became,  for  a  time,  the  natural 
nominating  convention  and  the  one  fairly  permanent  bit  of  party  ma- 
chinery. In  its  federal  form  this  was  known  as  the  Congressional  Caucus, 
and  it  controlled  the  party  nominations  for  the  Presidency  from  1804 
to  1824,  Because  parties  were  at  this  time  looked  upon  as  extra-legal, 


236  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

with  sinister  potency — being  in  fact  literally  without  standing  in  public 
law — the  central  organization  of  the  parties,  the  caucus,  was  naturally 
severely  criticized.  It  was  hailed  as  "King  Caucus,"  and  the  deposition 
of  this  monarch  was  eagerly  sought. 

The  destruction  of  the  caucus  system  as  a  factor  in  national  politics 
was  accomplished  as  a  part  of  the  democratic-frontier  wave  which  brought 
Andrew  Jackson  to  the  Presidency.  Jackson  believed  himself  at  a  dis- 
advantage with  the  smooth  and  devious  politicians  who  controlled  the 
caucus.  Further,  he  and  his  followers  were  still  enraged  by  the  con- 
tested election  for  the  Presidency  in  1824,  for  Jackson  believed  that  he 
had  been  cheated  out  of  the  election.  He  and  his  supporters  began  a 
thoroughgoing  attack  upon  the  congressional  control  of  the  party  nom- 
inating system.  By  the  time  of  the  campaign  of  1828  the  congressional 
Caucus  had  been  undermined,  and  in  1832  the  national  nominating  con- 
vention had  taken  its  place. 

The  first  national  nominating  convention  was  held  by  the  Anti- 
Masonic  party,  which  met  in  Baltimore  in  1831  and  nominated  William 
Wirt  as  its  candidate  for  the  Presidency.  The  Whigs  met  there  later  in 
the  year  and  nominated  Clay,  and  the  next  year  the  Democrats  followed 
and  nominated  Jackson.  An  important  revolution  had  been  achieved, 
and  the  party  had  grown,  to  some  degree,  beyond  the  outlaw  stage.  The 
nominating  convention  soon  supplanted  the  caucus  in  the  local  subdi- 
visions of  the  country.  Along  with  it  came  the  development  of  per- 
manent national,  state,  and  county  committees — political  machines — to 
look  after  party  interests  in  the  interval  between  the  periodic  nominating 
conventions. 

The  political,  or  party,  machine  first  developed  on  a  large-scale  in 
American  cities,  especially  those  cities  which  had  a  large  foreign-born 
population,  which  could  be  easily  manipulated.  These  machines  not 
only  dominated  city  but  state  politics  as  well,  and  often  exerted  a  large 
influence  on  national  party  organization.  Examples  of  such  city  ma- 
chines have  been  Tammany  Hall  in  New  York,  the  Catholic-Democratic 
machine  in  Boston,  the  Republican  machine  in  Philadelphia,  the  Thomp- 
soh  and  Kelly-Nash  machines  in  Chicago,  the  Pendergast  machine  in 
Kansas  City  and  the  Hague  machine  in  Jersey  City.  Urban  party 
machines  often  promote  graft  and  corruption.  The  large  and  unwieldy 
city  populations  have  made  it  difficult  to  get  a  united  front  for  reform 
and  thus  facilitated  and  perpetuated  the  corrupt  party  machines.  The 
machine  continues  to  exist,  even  with  a  shift  of  party  control. 

The  history  of  parties,  as  conventionally  taught  in  the  schools,  is  often 
little  more  than  a  meaningless  chronicling  of  the  results  of  the  quadrennial 
presidential  campaigns.  Yet  the  history  of  parties  in  America,  if  properly 
presented,  furnishes  an  admirable  reflection  of  the  various  phases  of  the 
progress  of  American  society.  It  is  the  basic  purpose  of  government  to 
mediate  between  the  various  conflicting  ideals  and  interests  in  society  and 
to  adjust  these  conflicts,  as  well  as  possible,  in  the  interest  of  public  order 
and  progress,  Parties  have  been  the  organization  through  which  our 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  237 

major  social  interests  have  attempted  to  advance  their  causes.  A  study 
of  parties  and  their  activity  reveals  the  more  important  public  issues 
that  have  faced  the  country  since  the  establishment  of  our  national 
government. 

At  the  outset,  the  Federalists,  under  the  leadership  of  Hamilton, 
planned  to  reorganize  the  government  after  the  chaos  of  the  Confeder- 
ation, restore  order,  establish  a  sound  system  of  public  and  private 
finance,  assume  the  state  debts,  fund  the  national  debt,  and  make  it 
possible  for  business  to  resume  with  confidence. 

The  program  had  the  backing  of  the  moneyed  groups  in  the  East,  but 
it  aroused  the  opposition  of  the  agrarian  interests  in  the  South  and  West, 
which  had  little  to  gain  from  a  revival  of  business  and  sound  finances. 
These  did  not  feel  that  any  important  benefit  would  come  from  a  redemp- 
tion of  the  public  securities  and  a  funding  of  the  public  debt.  In  fact, 
they  would  be  the  losers,  for  many  of  the  farmers  were  debtors  and  most 
of  the  certificates  of  indebtedness  were  held  by  the  business  clashes. 
Further,  they  resented  the  greater  burden  of  taxation  put  upon  them  by 
Hamilton's  constructive  program.  Especially  was  this  true  of  states,  like 
Virginia,  which  had  already  paid  off  their  state  indebtedness.  They  found 
their  slogan  in  a  strict  construction  of  the  Constitution,  denying  the 
validity  of  Hamilton's  contention  for  "implied  powers/'  They  discovered 
an  astute  leader  in  Thomas  Jefferson. 

As  a  result  of  fatal  divisions  within  their  ranks,  and  legislative  indiscre- 
tions— as  in  the  case  of  the  Alien  and  Sedition  Laws — the  Federalists  were 
weakened.  In  the  party  revolution  of  1800,  they  were  displaced  by  the 
Democratic-Republicans.  This  Jeffersonian  party  soon  accepted  the  con- 
structive national  policy  of  Hamilton,  but  put  it  on  a  more  popular  and 
democratic  foundation. 

With  the  development  of  new  problems  in  our  national  evolution, 
appropriate  parties  arose  to  defend  their  diversified  interests.  The  rem- 
nants of  the  old  Federalists  and  the  more  conservative  Democratic- 
Republicans  developed  into  the  National  Republican  or  Whig  party,  of 
which  Clay  and  Webster  were  the  spokesmen.  They  represented  the 
business  and  financial  interests  of  the  East  and  the  more  Rationalistic 
element  among  the  Middle-Westerners.  They  adopted  for  their  program 
national  improvements  in  the  way  of  building  roads,  canals,  and  railroads, 
the  fostering  of  manufactures,  an  increase  of  the  tariff,  according  to  the 
so-called  "American  system,"  the  maintenance  of  a  United  States  Bank, 
and  the  granting  of  loans  to  the  West  for  sectional  development. 

The  opposition  party  was  called  the  Democratic  party,  and  it  chose  for 
its  leader  Andrew  Jackson.  The  party  members  were,  in  part,  a  debtor 
group,  came  to  a  large  extent  from  the  frontier,  where  sentiments  and 
practices  of  equality  were  the  rule,  and  resented  the  power  and  arrogance 
of  the  business  and  financial  element  of  the  East.  They  desired  state 
banks,  so  that  they  might  supply  their  own  credit  and  be  free  from  the 
economic  control  of  the  Easterners.  The  demand  for  the  democratization 
of  the  suffrage  and  the  abolition  of  imprisonment  for  debt  appeal&f 


238  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

especially  to  the  lower  classes,  and  led  the  eastern  working-classes  to  join 
hands  with  the  frontiersmen  in  bearing  Jackson  to  triumph  in  1828. 

Soon  after  Jackson 's  period  the  issues  that  had  confronted  the  parties  in 
the  thirties  were  superseded  by  the  struggle  over  slavery.  The  Whig 
party  became  divided  on  the  slavery  issue  and  gradually  disintegrated. 
The  Democratic  party  came  more  completely  under  the  domination  of  the 
slavery  group,  for  which  Calhoun  was  the  spokesman,  and  the  Jacksonian 
philosophy  lost  its  hold.  The  Democratic  party  became  the  party  of  the 
"Slavocracy"  of  the  South.  It  was  joined  by  the  pro-slavery  Whigs. 

Out  of  the  disintegrating  Whig  party  and  the  minor  radical  and  anti- 
slavery  parties,  the  new  Republican  party  was  formed  in  1856.  It  was  at 
first  mainly  a  radical  party,  with  its  chief  support,  as  in  the  case  of  the 
early  Democrats,  in  the  laborers  of  the  East  and  the  frontiersmen  of  the 
West.  Coming  into  power  in  1860,  as  the  result  of  a  fatal  division  of  the 
Democratic  party,  it  was  the  party  that  won  the  Civil  War  and  thus 
gained  the  support  of  the  banking  and  business  classes,  which  had  profited 
by  the  war.  It  soon  lost  its  radical  traits  and  became  the  party  of  the 
capitalistic  conservatives.  It  supported  the  new  banking  plans,  railroad 
expansion  and  the  land  grants,  retention  of  the  high  war  tariff,  the  growth 
of  corporations,  and  the  elimination  of  political  interference  with  the 
freedom  of  business  enterprise.  The  Democratic  party,  freed  from  the 
slavery  octopus,  became,  for  the  time  being,  the  minority  party,  support- 
ing political  reform  and  a  more  liberal  policy  in  Southern  reconstruction. 

Neither  major  party  has  been  consistently  either  progressive  or  reac- 
tionary since  1865.  While  the  Republicans  have  been  more  uniformly 
conservative  and  the  more  dependable  exponents  of  big  business  and  the 
protective  tariff,  they  have  at  times  shown  signs  of  liberalism,  as  under 
Theodore  Roosevelt  from  1901  to  1909.  There  has  always  been  a 
powerful  liberal  wing  in  the  Republican  party,  which  has  been  known 
successively  as  Liberal  Republican,  Mugwump,  and  Progressive.  The 
Democratic  party  has  wabbled  from  marked  liberalism,  as  under  Bryan 
in  1896,  Wilson  in  1913,  and  Roosevelt  in  1933,  to  extreme  conservatism, 
as  under  Parker  in  1904,  but  it  has  inclined  towards  the  moderate  con- 
servatism of  the  Cleveland  type  during  most  of  the  period  since  1877. 
Under  Wilson,  it  ran  the  whole  course  from  the  liberalism  of  the  "New 
Freedom"  to  the  ultra-reactionary  orgy  after  1918,  during  which  the 
country  was  all  but  ruled  by  Attorney-General  Palmer  and  the  Depart- 
ment of  Justice. 

There  is  no  longer  any  fundamental  division  between  the  two  old  parties 
over  the  basic  institutions  of  society.  In  1800,  the  parties  represented 
mercantile  versus  agricultural  interests.  In  1850,  the  southern  Slavoc- 
racy was  lined  up  against  northern  manufacturing  and  commercial  groups 
and  frontier  agricultural  interests.  In  1896,  it  was  a  division  between  the 
plutocracy  and  the  progressive  agrarian  and  labor  interests.  But,  since 
1900,  both  great  parties  have  wholeheartedly  supported  the  capital- 
istic system.  Even  Mr.  Roosevelt,  in  1933,  deliberately  and  exclusively 
sought  to  patch  up  the  capitalistic  system.  The  campaign  of  1940  was 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  239 

probably  the  greatest  sham  in  American  party  history.  There  was  no 
opportunity  for  the  voters  to  decide  upon  the  most  burning  issue  of  the 
day — that  of  American  attitude  towards  the  second  World  War.  It  was 
observed  that  Mr.  Willkie  seemed  to  be  "campaigning  for  a  seat  in  the 
Roosevelt  cabinet "  rather  than  for  the  Presidency.  Our  entry  into  the 
second  World  War  makes  it  possible  that  we  may  adopt  the  one-party 
system  of  totalitarian  states. 

The  more  extreme  liberals  and  some  radicals  have  tended  to  be  skeptical 
of  gaining  their  ends  in  either  great  party  and  have  persistently  organized 
radical  minor  parties,  such  as  the  Granger  movement,  the  Greenback 
party,  the  Populist  party,  the  Non-Partisan  League  (really  a  party) ,  the 
Socialist  and  Socialist-Labor  parties,  and,  most  recently  the  Farmer- 
Labor  party  and  the  Communist  party.  In  one  way  these  parties  have 
been  successful.  They  have  forced  the  major  parties  to  embody  many  of 
the  progressive  proposals  in  their  platforms. 

Any  logical  party  alignment  in  this  country,  at  present,  would  probably 
call  for  a  clean  sweep  of  the  two  old  parties  and  for  the  amalgamation 
of  the  conservative  and  liberal  elements  respectively  into  two  new  parties. 
This  would  probably  have  happened  long  before  this,  had  party  organi- 
zation been  as  fluid  and  undeveloped  as  in  1830.  But  so  powerful  has 
the  party  machinery  become  that  the  party  issues  are  now  subordinated 
to  party  machinery.  The  means — party  machinery — have  been  con- 
verted into  the  end.  The  two  major  parties  today  have  so  much  un- 
reality and  so  few  real  differences  because  they  exist  chiefly  to  obtain  the 
elective  offices  and  the  economic  power  that  comes  from  being  in  control. 
The  revolt  of  reactionary  Democrats  against  the  New  Deal,  particularly 
against  Mr.  Roosevelt's  plan  for  reorganizing  the  Supreme  Court  in  1937, 
has  suggested  to  some  that  we  may  be  on  the  eve  of  a  rational  reorganiza- 
tion of  the  American  party  system.  In  his  Jackson  Day  Speech,  on 
January  8th,  1938,  President  Roosevelt  threw  down  the  gauntlet  to  reac- 
tionary renegades  in  his  own  party,  and  made  an  appeal  to  all  types  of 
liberals  to  rally  about  him.  At  the  same  time,  reactionary  Republican 
leaders  have  beckoned  the  conservative  Democrats  into  their  ranks.  It 
is  too  early  as  yet  to  say  what  may  be  accomplished,  but  these  rumblings 
may  be  symptomatic  of  more  far-reaching  changes  just  over  the  horizon. 
The  second  World  War  may,  of  course,  bring  to  an  end  representative 
government  and  the  party  system,  in  the  United  States  as  well  as  the  Old 
World. 

Outstanding   Problems  of  Party  Government 

In  spite  of  the  indispensable  nature  of  the  political  party  in  representa- 
tive government  and  democracy,  it  inevitably  developed  by-products 
which  created  serious  abuses.  Many  of  these  abuses  are  inherent  in  party 
government.  Others  are  the  blunders  inevitable  in  the  first  stages  of 
experimentation  with  any  procedure. 

Among  the  difficulties  and  abuses  which  seem  to  be  inseparably  asso- 


240  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

ciated  with  political  parties  is  their  tendency  to  become  oligarchical  in 
organization  and  to  oppose  the  popular  will  in  the  democracies  they  are 
supposed  to  serve.  Franklin  H.  Giddings  suggested  that  this  is  the  result 
of  the  inevitable  proclivity  of  the  few  to  dominate  in  all  social  organiza- 
tion and  activity.  He  finds  that  some  react  to  new  issues  and  oppor- 
tunities much  more  readily  than  others  and,  by  their  alertness  and 
resourcefulness,  dominate  social  situations  and  activities: 

Not  all  individuals  react  to  a  given  stimulation  with  equal  promptness,  or 
completeness,  or  persistence.  Therefore,  in  every  situation  there  are  individuals 
that  react  more  effectively  than  others  do.  They  reinforce  the  original  stimula- 
tion and  play  a  major  part  in  interstimulation.  They  initiate  and  take  respon- 
sibility. They  lead:  they  conduct  experiments  in  a  more  or  less  systematic 
fashion. 

Those  individuals  that  react  most  effectively  command  the  situation  and  create 
new  situations  to  which  other  individuals  must  adjust  themselves.  Few  or  many, 
the  alert  and  effective  are  a  protocracy :  a  dominating  plurum  from  which  ruling 
classes  are  derived.  Protocracy  is  always  with  us.  We  let  George  do  it,  and 
George  to  a  greater  or  less  extent  "does"  us.4 

Every  kleptocracy  of  brigands  and  conquerors,  every  plutocracy,  every  aristoc- 
racy, and  every  democracy  begins  as  a  protocracy.  It  comes  into  existence  and 
begins  its  career  as  a  little  band  of  alert  and  capable  persons  who  see  the  situation, 
grasp  the  opportunity,  and  in  the  expressive  slang  of  our  modern  competitive  life, 
"go  to  it"  with  no  unnecessary  delay. 

We  have  now  arrived  at  the  first  induction,  the  fundamental  principle  of  politi- 
cal Science,  which  is,  namely:  The  few  always  dominate. 

Invariably,  the  few  rule,  more  or  less  arbitrarily,  more  or  less  drastically,  more 
or  less  extensively.  Democracy,  even  the  most  radical  democracy,  is  only  that 
state  of  politically  organized  mankind  in  which  the  rule  of  the  few  is  least  arbi- 
trary and  most  responsible,  least  drastic  and  most  considerate.5 

A  number  of  social  psychologists  have  suggested  explanations  for  the 
oligarchical  tendency  in  parties.  Sighele,  LeBon,  Tarde,  Durkheim,  and 
Ross  have  held  that  it  is  due  to  the  prevalence  of  crowd  psychology  in 
modern  political  assemblies  and  even  in  states  as  a  whole.  Psychic  con- 
tagion is  promoted  by  the  press  and  other  modern  agencies  for  expediting 
the  communication  of  information  and  the  creation  of  uniform  emotional 
states.  Under  these  circumstances,  the  leaders  can  usually  manipulate 
the  masses  at  will.  Contemporary  propaganda  has  facilitated  this  de- 
moralizing trend.6 

Robert  Michels,  in  his  book,  Political  Parties  7  finds  that  oligarchical 
tendencies  are  inevitable  in  any  form  of  political  organization,  even 
though  it  be  that  extreme  form  of  revolutionary  decentralization  known 
as  Syndicalism.  He  finds  the  average  individual  stupid,  and  lacking  in 
initiative  and  resourcefulness.  The  more  alert  and  intelligent  persons 
naturally  come  to  the  top  as  leaders.  But  the  psychological  consequences 


4  Giddings,  "Pluralistic  Behavior,"  American  Journal  of  Sociology,  March,  1920, 
p.  539. 

5  Giddings,  The  Responsible  State,  Houghton,  Mifflin,  1918,  pp.  19-20. 

6  See  below,  pp.  545  ff. 

7  Hearst's  International  Library,  1915. 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  241 

for  the  leaders  are  all  too  often  vanity,  arrogance,  and  a  tendency  to  forget 
that  they  owe  their  position  to  popular  consent. 

Under  modern  conditions,  democracy,  in  a  broad  sense,  is  mass  rule. 
But  masses  are  incoherent  and  inarticulate;  they  must  have  leaders. 
Further,  the  masses  cannot  participate  directly  in  government;  they  must 
choose  representatives,  and  representative  government  requires  party 
organization.  Since  the  masses  are  subject  to  mob  psychology,  they  are 
easily  manipulated  in  elections.  Modern  parliaments,  made  up  of  chosen 
representatives,  operate  under  psychological  conditions  very  similar  to 
those  of  the  crowd.  They  are  so  large  and  unwieldy  that  they  inevitably 
come  under  the  domination  of  the  able  minority. 

The  main  cause  of  oligarchy  in  political  parties  comes,  therefore,  from 
the  necessity  of  organization.  The  inevitable  organization  which  a  politi- 
cal party  must  create  to  function  effectively  produces  the  necessity  of 
leadership.  The  consequent  oligarchy  then  defeats  the  democracy  that 
originally  called  forth  party  organization.8 

First  among  the  abuses  of  the  modern  party  is  the  tyrannical  dominion 
of  the  boss  and  the  machine.  A  general  and  popular  superstition  in  re- 
gard to  the  American  government  is  that  the  individual  citizen  is  able  to 
advance  his  interests  and  make  his  opinion  felt  in  governmental  matters. 
In  other  words,  the  government  is  supposed  to  be  directly  representative 
of  the  mass  of  citizens. 

Those  who  have  made  even  an  elementary  study  of  the  processes  of 
American  government  in  the  last  fifty  years  know  that  this  conception  is 
only  a  pious  aspiration.  It  has  been  very  difficult  for  any  citizen  or  any 
small  group  of  public-spirited  citizens  directly  to  exert  effective  pressure 
upon  any  governmental  organization.  Legislation  can  usually  be  secured 
only  through  advance  negotiations  with,  and  approval  by,  the  boss  and 
the  machine.  Instead  of  direct  government,  we  have  built  what  has  been 
frequently  called  the  "invisible  'government/'  which  controls  most  phases 
of  American  political  life.  Elihu  Root  once  said  that,  for  nearly  a  gener- 
ation, the  government  of  the  Empire  State  was  not  located  at  Albany  but 
in  the  private  offices  of  Boss  Thomas  C.  Platt,  of  the  United  States  Express 
Company,  in  New  York  City.9 

Down  to  a  couple  of  generations  ago,  voting  was  not  secret.  It  was 
possible  for  a  boss  or  his  representative  to  know  how  every  citizen  voted. 
This  made  it  easy  for  the  employer  of  a  voter  or  for  representatives  of  the 
political  machine  to  intimidate  the  citizen  and  thus  control  his  vote. 

Again,  the  party  machine  has  controlled  the  selection  of  delegates  to  the 
nominating  conventions.  There  the  delegates  themselves  have  had  rela- 
tively little  part  in  the  choice  of  candidates,  who  are  normally  selected 
beforehand  by  a  narrow  clique  of  the  more  powerful  members  of  the 
machine.  The  people  are  then  given  the  opportunity  to  reject  or  ratify 


s  Mickels,  op.  cit.,  pp.  21-22,  26-27,  31-35,  130,  135,  230,  401,  405. 
9  Platt  was  the  Republican  boss  of  New  York  State. 


242  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

these  candidates.  Thus,  political  officers,  who  theoretically  owe  their 
position  to  popular  election,  are  actually  chosen  by  the  machine. 

The  nomination  of  Warren  G.  Harding  in  1920  was  one  of  the  most 
flagrant  examples  of  the  undemocratic  nature  of  convention  nominations. 
At  the  time,  Mr.  Harding  was  known  only  as  a  strictly  regular  Republican 
Senator,  above  the  average  in  appearance  and  bearing.  He  made  a 
miserable  showing  in  the  preconvention  primaries,  and  even  his  own  cam- 
paign manager  was  not  elected  to  the  Chicago  convention.  The  weather 
was  unbearably  hot  in  Chicago  at  the  time,  the  beer  supply  was  low,  and 
there  was  a  long  deadlock  between  Johnson,  Lowden,  and  Wood.  The 
delegates  were  disconsolate  at  the  thought  of  another  week-end  in  the  city. 
The  leaders  of  the  plutocrats  at  the  convention  saw  their  chance  to  exploit 
the  desire  of  the  delegates  to  get  away  from  Chicago,  and  to  slip  in  a 
candidate  who  would  be  most  plastic  in  their  hands,  if  elected  to  the 
Presidency.  Harding  seemed  to  be  their  man,  as  he  was  known  to  be 
wholly  safe  and  complaisant,  and  his  physiognomy  seemed  a  most  promis- 
ing decoration  for  the  campaign  posters.  Hence  Myron  T.  Herrick, 
George  Harvey,  and  a  half-dozen  others  railroaded  him  through  the  con- 
vention. He  was  in  no  sense  whatever  the  choice  of  the  people.  Had 
there  been  a  popular  plebiscite  throughout  the  United  States  on  the  eve  of 
that  Chicago  convention,  it  is  doubtful  if  Harding  would  have  'received 
100,000  votes.  He  was  nominated,  and  over  15,500,000  surged  forward 
in  November  to  place  their  stamp  of  approval  upon  him.  The  man 
whom  the  great  majority  of  the  people  desired  to  see  nominated  for  the 
Presidency,  Mr.  Herbert  Hoover,  was  not  seriously  considered  by  the 
convention. 

Not  only  do  the  boss  and  the  machine  control  voting  and  nominations ; 
they  also  control  much  of  the  legislation.  Even  if  the  machine  graciously 
allows  a  citizen  or  a  group  of  citizens  to  introduce  a  bill  it  stands  no 
chance  of  being  favorably  reported  out  of  committee  and  passed  unless 
the  party  leaders  approve.  In  many  cases,  bills  not  approved  by  the 
party  machine  are  not  even  introduced.  Legislation  is  mainly  a  matter 
secretly  and  effectively  arranged  between  the  favored  groups  and  classes 
on  the  one  hand,  and  the  party  machine  on  the  other. 

We  are  not  charging  any  special  diabolism  to  American  capitalism  in 
relation  to  politics.  Jefferson  and  the  agrarians  were  politically  as  un- 
scrupulous in  their  day,  and  if  a  society  were  dominated  by  the  proletariat 
we  would  certainly  witness  a  most  faithful  continuance  of  much  the  same 
political  methods  that  they  now  so  warmly  criticize.  It  merely  happens 
that  since  1865  we  have  been  controlled  mainly  by  the  business  and 
financial  classes.  In  some  instances,  where  the  labor  groups  possessed  an 
unusual  degree  of  power,  they  also  exerted  the  same  pressures  upon  legis- 
lation that  had  been  used  by  the  representatives  of  capitalistic  interests. 

What  we  are  concerned  with  is  the  fact  that,  during  the  last  fifty  years, 
popular  wishes  have  had  little  to  do  with  the  major  part  of  the  important 
legislation  passed  in  our  federal  and  state  governments.  The  plutocracy 
have  blandly  used  their  power  to  embody  their  wishes  and  objectives  in 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  243 

legislation.10  They  have  then  utilized  a  generally  willing  press  to  con- 
vince the  populace  that  such  laws  and  policies  were  not  only  what  the 
people  really  needed,  but  were  also  exactly  what  the  mass  of  people 
actually  desired.  In  most  cases,  the  press  was  very  successful  in  execut- 
ing this  deception  down  to  1936. 

The  only  important  limitation  upon  unlimited  government  by  the  vested 
interests  and  the  machine,  at  least  down  to  1920,  was  that  this  collusion 
could  not  be  carried  too  far  without  leading  to  popular  indignation  and 
the  development  of  a  revolt  against  it.  Such  rebellion  has  appeared  in 
the  Liberal  Republican  movement,  the  Mugwump  secession,  Bryan 
Democracy,  the  Roosevelt  Progressivism  of  1912,  the  repudiation  of 
Wilsonism  and  Palmerism  in  1920,  and  the  Farmer-Labor  revolt  of  1924. 
For  the  most  part,  however,  the  "interests"  and  the  politicians  have  been 
able  to  deceive  and  reassure  the  public,  and  the  revolts  against  plutocratic 
control  have  not  been  frequent  or  successful.  The  failure  to  repudiate 
Coolidge  and  the  Republican  party,  in  1924,  after  the  oil  and  Veterans* 
Bureau  scandals  illustrates  the  docility  or  cynicism  of  the  public  in  the 
face  of  the  gravest  political  abuses. 

As  their  reward  for  keeping  the  government  in  line  with  the  interests 
of  the  dominant  economic  groups,  the  boss  and  the  machine  have  been 
granted  all  sorts  of  gross  and  petty  graft.  The  "spoils  system"  has 
become  something  far  more  diversified,  ingenious,  and  remunerative  than 
it  was  in  its  primitive  days  under  Andrew  Jackson.  Favorable  contracts 
on  government  works,  the  spoils  of  appointive  offices,  "pork-barrel"  legis- 
lation, and  other  types  of  rewards  have  been  handed  over  to  the  boss  for 
his  efficient  services  in  keeping  the  populace  and  the  party  subservient. 

With  the  growth  of  the  population  and  the  increased  necessity  for 
partisan  alertness,  the  expenses  that  have  been  connected  with  successful 
party  organization  and  political  campaigns  have  endrmously  increased.11 
Vast  sums  of  money  have  been  spent  to  secure  the  nomination  of  favored 
candidates,  and  political  leaders  have  demanded  large  contributions  from 
the  powerful  economic  interests  which  expect  to  profit  by  the  election  of 
their  candidates. 

This  practice  first  became  notorious  in  the  Republican  campaign  of 
1896,  when  Mark  Hanna  raised  vast  sums  from  Wall  Street  in  order  to 
secure  the  election  of  Major  McKinley  and  defeat  what  was  believed  to 
be  the  revolutionary  program  of  William  Jennings  Bryan.  It  had  cost 
only  $250,000  to  elect  Abraham  Lincoln,  but  Hanna  is  said  to  have  col- 
lected in  all  some  $3,350,000.  This  was  far  the  largest  sum  ever  expended 
in  behalf  of  a  single  candidate  down  to  that  time.  It  was  probably  a 
good  bargain  for  the  economic  interests  that  were  faithfully  shielded  by 
McKinley's  administration,  though  the  advantages  were  in  part  lost 
by  the  succession  of  the  more  liberal  Theodore  Roosevelt  after  McKinley's 


10  Cf.  Matthew  Josephson,  The  Robber  Barons,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1935;  The 
President-Makers,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1940;  and  Ferdinand  Lundberg,  America's  Sixty 
Families,  Vanguard,  1937. 

"  See  E.  B.  Logan,  Ed.,  The  American  Political  Scene,  Harper,  1938,  Chap.  V. 


244  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

assassination  in  1901.  The  Democrats  spent  only  $700,000  on  Bryan. 
The  amount  of  money  spent  for  the  election  of  McKinley  was  extraor- 
dinary at  the  time  and  was  not  exceeded  until  1920.  Campaign  ex- 
penses in  the  last  thirty  years  have  increased  enormously  in  comparison 
with  those  before  1896.  In  1916,  the  Republican  party  spent  $3,500,000, 
altogether,  in  trying  to  elect  Hughes,  and  has  not  spent  less  on  its  presi- 
dential candidate  since  that  time.  It  spent  $7,265,000  on  Harding  in 
1920.  The  Democrats  spent  $2,300,000  for  Cox.  In  the  campaign  of 
1928,  about  $16,600,000  was  expended  by  national  and  state  committees — 
some  $9,433,600  for  Hoover  and  $7,152,500  for  Smith.  The  following 
table  gives  the  expenditures  of  the  national  committees  of  the  Republican 
and  Democratic  parties,  alone,  since  1896  in  the  presidential  campaigns: 

Year  Republican  Democratic 

1896 $3,350,000  $  675,000 

1900 3,000,000  425,000 

1904 1,900,000                     •  700,000 

1908 1,655,000  619,000 

1912 1,076,000  1,134,000 

1916 2,441,000  2,284,000 

1920 5,417,000  1,470,000 

1924 4,020,000  1,108,000 

1928 6,256,000  5,342,000 

1932 2,900,000  2,245,000 

1936 8,892,000  5,194,000 

1940 2,242,000  2,438,000 

These  sums  are  only  a  part  of  the  total  campaign  expenditures.  The 
total  Republican  expenditures  in  the  campaign  of  1920  were  $7,265,000, 
as  compared  with  the  $5,417,000  spent  by  the  national  committee.  The 
Republicans  and  Democrats,  together,  spent  between  18  and  20  million 
dollars  in  the  campaign  of  1940.  Most  of  this  money  is  contributed  by 
individuals  and  interests  that  expect  favors  or  protection.  Five  powerful 
interests — Standard  Oil,  Guggenheim,  steel,  automobiles,  and  public 
utilities — contributed  approximately  $1,000,000  to  the  Hoover  chest  in 
1928.  Some  239  individuals  gave  over  $2,500,000  to  the  Hoover  cause; 
<5ne  Republican  contributed  $175,000.  Three  Democrats  each  gave  more 
than  $100,000  to  the  Smith  fund.  In  1928,  a  new  method  of  campaigning 
— radio  addresses — was  developed.  The  Republicans  spent  $600,000  in 
this  way,  and  the  Democrats  $500,000. 

Congressional  elections  also  often  involve  colossal  campaign  expendi- 
tures. One  senatorial  candidate  spent  over  2  million  dollars  for  his 
nomination  and  election.  Since  the  first  World  War,  3  would-be  Senators 
have  been  challenged  by  the  Senate  and  refused  seats  because  of  excessive 
expenditures  for  nomination  and  election.12 

Recently  there  has  been  a  deplorable  development  of  excessive  expendi- 
tures in  the  effort  to  secure  nominations  for  office,  particularly  the 


12  Truman  H.  Newberry  of  Michigan  in  1918;  Frank  L.  Smith  of  Illinois  in  1926; 
and  William  S.  Vare  of  Pennsylvania  in  1926. 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  245 

•nomination  for  the  Presidency.  Theodore  Roosevelt's  campaign  for 
nomination  in  1912  cost  $750,000,  and  in  the  period  preceding  the 
Republican  convention  of  1920  so  much  money  was  expended  by  candi- 
dates in  the  struggle  for  delegates  that  two  of  the  most  prominent 
candidates  were  practically  disqualified  by  the  revelation  of  their  expendi- 
tures. The  unsuccessful  campaign  of  Leonard  Wood  for  nomination  at 
this  time  cost  $1,775,000.  Frank  0.  Lowden's  expenses  at  the  same 
time  were  $415,000.  The  Newberry,  Smith,  and  Vare  cases  involved 
heavy  nomination,  as  well  as  election,  expenses.  The  direct  primary  has 
been,  in  part,  responsible  for  this  large  increase.  It  costs  more  to  secure 
the  support  of  the  many  who  vote  in  primaries  than  it  did  to  control  the 
few  in  caucuses  and  conventions.  In  states  like  Pennsylvania,  that  have 
been  preponderantly  one-party  states,  the  nomination  has  been  tanta- 
mount to  election.  Hence  it  is  logical  that  more  money  be  spent  in  the 
primaries  than  in  the  formal  election  campaign.  About  $1,500,000  was 
spent  in  the  Republican  senatorial  primary  in  Pennsylvania  in  1938. 

Not  only  has  there  been  a  scandalous  use  of  money  in  campaigns  for 
nomination  and  election  to  public  office.  There  has  been  much  overt 
fraud  and  intimidation.  Voters  of  minority  parties  are  often  kept  away 
from  the  polls  by  violence.  Repeaters  cast  many  ballots  each  for  the 
candidates  favored  by  the  dominant  machine.  Ballots  are  fraudulently 
counted.  It  has  been  a  persistent  belief  that  Mr.  Bryan  was  cheated  out 
of  hundreds  of  thousands,  if  not  millions,  of  votes  in  the  campaign  of 
1896  through  fraudulent  counts  in  centers  controlled  by  the  desperate 
big-business  forces.  Intimidation  and  fraud  at  the  polls  have  become 
especially  prevalent  in  the  last  fifteen  years  with  the  rise  of  racketeering 
and  gangdom  and  their  affiliations  with  dominant  political  machines. 
Our  election  laws  are  archaic  and  provide  inadequate  protection  to  insure 
fair  elections,  even  when  enforced: 

Every  investigation  or  election  contest  brings  to  light  glaring  irregularities, 
errors,  misconduct  on  the  part  of  precinct  officers,  disregard  of  election  laws  and 
instuctions,  slipshod  practices,  and  downright  frauds.  The  entire  country  has 
been  shocked  from  time  to  time  by  the  revelation  of  wholesale  election  frauds 
in  some  of  our  large  cities.  Competent  political  observers  report  that  election 
frauds  are  by  no  means  confined  to  these  few  cities,  but  are  widely  prevalent  in 
less  populous  communities.  Even  these  election  scandals  and  the  slipshod  ad- 
ministration revealed  by  election  recounts  do  not  indicate  the  real  state  of  affairs 
which  prevails  generally  in  election  administration.  The  truth  of  the  matter 
is  that  the  whole  administration — organizations,  laws,  methods  and  procedures, 
and  records — are,  for  most  states,  quite  obsolete.  The  whole  system,  including 
the  election  laws,  requires  a  thorough  revision  and  improvement.13 

The  machine  and  party  organization,  which  are  supposed  to  be  a  means 
for  advancing  the  party  program,  have  become  ends  in  themselves.  From 
the  campaign  of  1904  to  the  New  Deal  the  Republican  and  Democratic 
parties  rarely  took  a  fundamentally  divergent  stand  upon  the  more 


13  J.  P.  Harris,  Election  Administration  in  the  United  States,  Brookings  Institu- 
tion, 1934,  p.  1. 


246  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

significant  public  issues.  The  main  goal  of  both  parties  has  been  the 
protection  of  vested  economic  interests  and  the  spoils  of  office.  An  effort 
has  been  made  to  keep  the  party  machinery  intact,  and  to  discourage  any 
insurgent  movement  that  might  wreck  one  of  the  grand  old  parties  and 
substitute  a  new  party  with  an  independent  party  program. 

For  over  twenty-five  years  the  citizen  could  decide  only  between  party 
machines.  He  was  not  permitted  to  choose  between  two  fundamentally 
different  programs  of  public  policy.  The  election  of  1912  offered  some 
exception,  but  even  this  demonstrated  the  power  of  the  machine.  The 
most  popular  figure  in  American  political  life  at  the  time  with  the  most 
attractive  party  program  since  the  original  platform  of  the  Republican 
party  of  1856,  was  unable  to  carry  through  a  revolt  against  the  reac- 
tionary machine.  The  power  of  the  machine  was  demonstrated  by  its 
ability  to  exclude  from  the  Republican  nomination  the  man  who  was 
certainly  the  choice  of  the  great  majority  of  the  Republican  voters. 

Since  the  majority  react  to  propositions  in  a  fundamentally  emotional 
manner,  party  symbols,  party  shibboleths,  and  campaign  catchwords — 
such  as  "the  bloody  shirt,"  "the  full  dinner  pail,"  "the  new  freedom," 
"the  abundant  life,"  references  to  "the  grand  old  party"  and  to  distin- 
guished men  who  have  led  the  party  in  the  past — are  relied  upon  to  hold 
the  voters  in  line  and  secure  their  allegiance,  even  though  they  know 
nothing  of  the  platform  of  the  party,  and  would  be  likely  to  disapprove 
if  it  were  made  clear. 

Those  who  fight  against  the  corruption  and  inefficiency  in  our  political 
life  find  the  strength  of  the  party  symbolism  and  phraseology  an  almost 
insuperable  obstacle.  To  the  average  American  audience,  the  flashing 
upon  the  screen  of  the  elephant,  the  donkey,  the  pictures  of  Jefferson, 
Lincoln,  the  Roosevelts,  arouses  more  instant  response  and  approval  than 
the  most  carefully  prepared  and  informing  political  speech  imaginable. 
Particularly  significant  is  the  fact  that  during  the  political  campaign, 
the  period  in  which  the  voter  should  employ  the  greatest  rationality,  he 
is  most  at  the  mercy  of  the  emotions  provoked  by  party  strife.  The 
partisanship  that  is  a  mild  aberration  between  campaigns  becomes  in- 
flated during  the  campaign  periods  into  what  is  often  downright  hysteria 
and  a  paralysis  of  rational  judgment — a  campaign  psychosis. 

A  fundamental  problem  in  party  government  goes  to  the  very  heart 
of  representative  institutions.  The  old  territorial  units  of  representation 
are  proving  ever  more  inadequate  to  meet  the  problems  of  our  com- 
plicated industrial  civilization.  Outside  of  purely  rural  districts,  a  con- 
stituency is  made  up  of  a  great  diversity  of  social  and  economic  classes 
and  group  interests.  No  man  can  truly  "represent"  them  all,  or  any 
considerable  proportion.  If,  as  is  usually  the  case,  he  represents  a  few 
of  the  stronger  interests  in  his  constituency,  he  dare  not  do  so  too  openly, 
lest  he  incur  the  displeasure  of  the  others  and  risk  defeat  at  the  next 
election.  As  a  result  of  this  situation,  an  extra-legal  type  of  representa- 
tion has  arisen  in  the  powerful  and  complicated  lobby  that  has  grown 
up  in  the  national  capital  and  in  most  state  capitals.  Here  the  repre- 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  247 

sentatives  of  the  dominant  interests — bankers,  industrialists,  exporters, 
farmers,  war  veterans,  labor  leaders,  and  racketeers — assemble  and  deal 
directly  with  legislators.  They  try  to  secure  the  passage  of  favorable 
laws  and  kill  restrictive  legislation.  So  powerful  has  this  national  lobby 
become  that  E.  P.  Herring  has  described  it  as  a  "third  house  of  Con- 
gress." 14  It  is  more  important  than  the  House  or  the  Senate.  This 
development  may  be  inevitable*,  but  it  is  a  challenge  to  the  existing  type 
of  representative  government  and  to  our  party  system: 

In  place  of  nations  of  individuals,  all  more  or  less  alike  in  respect  to  conditions 
and  ideas,  the  Industrial  Revolution  has  given  us  nations  differentiated  into 
classes  and  corporate  and  occupational  groups,  more  or  less  different  and  often 
sharply  antagonistic,  in  which  lines  of  division  have  little  or  nothing  to  do  with 
the  territorial  areas  on  which  political  representation  is  based.  The  government, 
nominally  composed  of  persons  chosen  to  represent  the  will  of  the  people  in 
certain  territorial  areas,  finds  that  the  crucial  problems  of  the  time,  which  are 
essentially  economic,  cannot  be  solved  without  taking  into  account  the  will  of 
the  people  grouped  in  certain  economic  categories.  Such  is  doubtless  the  real 
source  of  the  diminished  state  of  Deputies  and  Congressmen.  What  they  too 
often  legally  represent  is  a  group  of  people  without  any  definite  common  will 
to  be  expressed;  what  they  have  to  deal  with  are  groups  of  people  (and  not  labor 
groups  only)  who  can  get  their  will  expressed  only,  or  much  better,  by  using 
their  extra-legal  power  as  a  means  of  dictation.15 

In  a  stimulating  book  A.  N.  Holcombe  predicts  the  end  of  the  old  rustic 
American  party  system  based  upon  sections,  and  the  rise  of  a  new  party 
alignment  founded  directly  and  openly  upon  class  interests.  The  grow- 
ing importance  of  the  city  in  American  life  will,  he  believes,  render  such 
a  transformation  necessary: 

The  passing  of  the  frontier  and  the  growth  of  urban  industry  have  shaken  the 
foundations  of  the  old  party  system  in  national  politics.  The  old  sectional  in- 
terests are  changing  and  the  old  sectional  alliances  are  breaking  down.  The  old 
party  politics  is  visibly  passing  away.  The  character  of  the  new  party  politics 
will  be  determined  cjiiefly  by  the  interests  and  attitudes  of  the  urban  population. 
It  will  be  less  rustic  than  the  old  and  more  urbane.  There  will  be  less  sectional 
politics  and  more  class  politics.  That  the  old  rustic  sectional  politics  is  passing 
is  easy  to  demonstrate.  What  the  new  urbane  class  politics  will  be  like  and  how 
it  may  be  made  most  serviceable  to  the  people  of  the  United  States  are  more 
difficult  questions.18 

Another  important  issue  in  representative  government  is  raised  by  the 
exponents  of  proportional  representation.  They  point  out  the  injustice 
of  leaving  the  defeated  party  with  no  representation  whatever.  They 
contend  that  sound  and  equitable  representative  government  must  give 
the  parties  representation  in  proportion  to  their  strength.  They  hold  that 
it  is  unfair  to  give  one  party  or  group  100  per  cent  of  the  representation 


14  E.  P.  Herring,  Group  Representation  before  Congress,  Johns  Hopkins  Press, 
1929. 

15  C.  L.  Becker,  "Lord  Brycc  on  Modern  Democracies/'  Political  Science  Quarterly, 
Academy  of  Political  Science,  December,  1921,  pp.  674-675. 

10  Holcombe,  The  New  Party  Politics,  Norton,  1933,  pp.  1-2,  and  Chap.  I,  passim. 


248  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

when  it  may  have  won  the  election  in  a  given  district  by  a  majority  of 
only  one  per  cent  of  the  votes.  Yet  it  must  be  remembered  that  pro- 
portional representation  would  probably  increase  the  number  of  parties 
in  legislatures,  thus  encouraging  the  bloc  system  with  its  complexities. 

Corruption   and   Extravagance   Under   Party  Government 

The  irritation  associated  with  the  annual  task  of  making  our  federal 
and  state  income-tax  returns  and  submitting  to  the  even  more  distressing 
indignities  of  local  assessors  and  tax-collectors  has  led  many  thrifty 
citizens  to  consider  more  seriously  the  reasons  for  the  ever  greater 
expenditures  involved  in  the  maintenance  of  public  agencies. 

For  the  decade  from  1791  to  1800,  the  total  federal  expenditures  of  our 
government  were  $68,256,000,  which  constituted  an  expenditure  per  indi- 
vidual, on  the  basis  of  the  census  of  1800,  of  approximately  $13.  In 
the  decade  from  1911  to  1920  the  federal  expenditures  for  the  ten-year 
period  had  increased  to  $425  per  head.  For  the  year  1934  alone  the 
federal  expenditures  were  over  $56  per  individual,  or  more  than  four 
times  the  expenditures  per  individual  during  the  whole  first  decade  of 
our  national  history.  In  1937  the  annual  per  capita  expenditures  of  the 
federal  government  stood  at  $62.69,  and  in  1940  they  were  $73.16. 

In  this  discussion  we  do  not  assume  that  democracy  is  necessarily 
accompanied  by  more  graft  and  corruption  than  all  other  forms  of  govern- 
ment. The  most  relevant  fact  in  the  contrast  between  democracy  and 
autocracy  is  that  as  one  contemporary  writer  has  expressed  it,  democracy 
inevitably  brings  more  "snouts  to  the  trough"  than  any  other  leading 
form  of  government. 

The  ever-increasing  costs  of  government  are,  however,  to  no  small 
degree  produced  by  the  enormous  complexity  of  the  social  problems  that 
have  arisen  in  the  last  hundred  and  fifty  years.  The  growing  number 
of  practical  problems  that  must  be  handled  by  governmental  agencies 
has  resulted  in  an  ever  greater  state  intervention  in  social,  economic,  and 
cultural  activities.  Many  writers  have  attributed  this  extension  of  gov- 
ernmental activity  primarily  to  the  growing  popularity  of  bureaucracy 
and  state-socialistic  doctrines.  To  a  very  large  degree,  however,  such 
"state  socialism"  has  only  been  the  practical  acceptance  of  the  actual 
responsibilities  forced  upon  society  by  scientific,  technological,  and  eco- 
nomic revolutions.  Wars,  also,  have  become  much  more  expensive,  and 
so  have  the  armaments  preparatory  to  wars.  There  is  much  sumptuary 
legislation,  like  our  late  Prohibition  laws,  that  is  either  useless  or  harmful 
and  calls  for  needless  expenditures  to  maintain  the  officials  who  execute  it. 
But,  after  making  due  allowance  for  such  excesses,  the  fact  remains  that 
the  social  changes  of  the  last  century  have  inevitably  made  necessary  a 
remarkable  increase  in  the  scope  and  expense  of  government  activities. 

During  the  first  ten  years  of  our  national  history  we  spent  through  the 
federal  government  only  $68,256,000.  The  appropriations  for  the  fiscal 
year  of  1932  ran  to  the  staggering  sum  of  $4,674,073,917.  "The  New 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  249 

Deal"  more  than  doubled  these  expenditures  before  the  defense  and  war 
periods.  The  total  expenditures  for  the  fiscal  year  1933-34  included 
ordinary  expenditures  of  $3,100,914,000;  extraordinary  expenditures  of 
$4,004,135,000,  and  a  budget  deficit  of  $3,989,496,000.  In  1937,  federal 
expenditures  totalled  $8,105,158,547.  In  1940,  they  were  $9,666,085,000, 
with  total  appropriations  of  $13,351,786,000.  Even  the  recently  founded 
Department  of  Commerce  uses  up  about  as  much  in  one  year  as  was 
required  to  run  our  whole  federal  government  for  a  decade  in  the  days 
of  Washington.  The  annual  appropriation  for  the  District  of  Columbia 
alone  is  over  seven  times  the  annual  budget  for  the  federal  government 
in  Washington's  administration. 

The  percentage  of  the  total  income  of  the  population  of  the  United 
States  which  goes  into  governmental  expenditures — federal,  state,  and 
local — has  increased  amazingly  since  1913.  In  that  year  governmental 
expenditures,  some  3  billion  dollars,  amounted  to  8  per  cent  of  our  total 
national  (not  governmental)  income.  By  1932  they  had  mounted  to  31 
per  cent,  when  they  stood  at  $13,470,000,000.  Governmental  costs  have 
increased  markedly  since  1932,  owing  in  part  to  the  increasing  expendi- 
tures for  the  relief  of  the  unemployed.  They  were  $15,500,000,000  in 
1934.  By  1938,  total  government  costs  were  estimated  to  be  $18,000,- 
000,000.  The  second  World  War  greatly  raised  government  expenditures. 
The  appropriations  for  1942  exceeded  seventy  billion  dollars  for  the 
federal  government  alone.  The  graph  on  page  250  is  a  composite  picture 
of  the  increases  in  federal  expenditures,  the  types  of  expenditures  in- 
volved, and  the  sources  of  government  revenue. 

An  important  source  of  mounting  expenditures  in  the  federal  govern- 
ment is  the  increase  in  federal  job-holders.  This  is  usually  associated, 
in  particular,  with  democratic  institutions  and  practices,  though  in  all 
probability  the  increase  of  federal  employees  has  been  brought  about  to 
no  small  degree  by  the  inevitable  growth  of  state  intervention  in  various 
aspects  of  social  problems.  In  1816,  there  were  about  6,000  in  the 
classified  and  unclassified  federal  positions.  By  1861,  they  had  increased 
to  about  50,000.  By  1890,  the  number  had  more  than  trebled,  reaching 
166,000.  By  1916,  the  year  before  we  entered  the  first  World  War,  the 
federal  civilian  positions  numbered  438,000.  In  1918,  the  war  increased 
these  to  some  917,760.  By  1922,  there  was  a  shrinkage  that  brought  the 
number  down  to  560,863;  but,  in  1932,  the  number  had  risen  to  732,460. 
The  salaries  amounted  to  $1,055,970,000.  The  total  number  of  persons 
on  the  federal  payroll  in  1932,  both  civil  and  military,  amounted  to 
1,032,688.  Their  salaries  ran  up  to  $1,341,670,431.  In  October,  1934, 
the  federal  civilian  employees  in  the  executive  branches  alone  totaled 
680,181  and  their  salaries  in  this  month  amounted  to  $101,888,573.  In 
June,  1937,  the  number  stood  at  841,664.  In  July,  1940,  they  had  passed 
the  million  mark — or  1,011,666.  The  second  World  War  greatly  in- 
creased this  figure.  In  April,  1941,  there  were  some  1,264,000  non- 
military  federal  employees.  The  graph  on  page  251  indicates  the  vast 
expansion  of  the  federal  bureaucracy  since  1910. 


WHERE    THE    MONEY   COMES   FROM 


3 


All  Other  Taxes 

Payroll  Taxes 

Agricultural  Adjustment  Taxes 

Foreign   Obligations 

Customs 

Misc.  fnternal  Revenue 

Income  Taxes 


4« 


I'M  II  !>>>  ill 


1929  1930  1931  1932  1933  1934  1935  1936  1937  1936  1939  1940 


'5 


WHERE    THE    MONEY     GOES    TO 


D*bt   Retirement 


loans-  and  Subscriptions 
to  Stock*,  etc. 


Unemptoymcnt  Relief 
Public  Works 
Bonus  Prepayment 
Ordinary    Expenditures 


19291930  J93I  1932  J933  1934  1935  »936  »937  1938  IP39  »S>40 


Courtesy  of  The  New  York  Times. 


250 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT 


251 


[A  THIRTY-YEAR  RECORD  OP  FEDERAL  CIViLIAN 


1000 


A  BREAKDOWN  OF  FEDERAL  CIVILIAN  EMPLOYE/  IN  1940 

TOTAL-   I,OII,O66 

44%  I  23%          |        16%       |   10%   1 7% 


CLERICAL 
Each  symbol  representr  57,  oP  total 


1 

[TRADE  AN&  MANUAL  |PROF_E//J: 


AND 

AbMINIXTRATIVE 


Courtesy  of  The  New  York  Times. 

When  these  figures  are  extended  to  include  those  holding  state,  munic- 
ipal, and  local  positions,  they  become  even  more  impressive.  Between 
1870  and  1932  the  number  of  persons  in  public  service  in  the  United  States 
increased  by  1,000  per  cent.  Even  before  the  New  Deal  went  into 
operation  and  produced  an  unprecedented  number  of  people  getting  pay 
from  the  federal,  state,  and  local  governments,  there  were  over  2% 
millions  on  all  public  payrolls.  They  received  4  billion  dollars  in  salaries 
and  wages — some  63  per  cent  of  all  tax  money  collected.  In  April,  1941, 
there  were  6,100,000  in  the  employ  of  the  federal,  state,  and  local  govern- 
ments. This  was  a  little  less  than  one  out  of  every  eight  of  the  total  num- 
ber of  workers  employed  in  the  country.  Their  total  remuneration  in  this 
month  was  667  million  dollars,  or  about  8  billion  dollars  for  the  year  at 


252  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

this  rate.  Of  the  federal  workers,  1,532,000  were  in  the  military  service 
and  1,264,000  in  nonmilitary  branches.  Some  3,300,000  were  in  the  em- 
ploy of  the  state  and  local  governments.  The  great  cost  of  this  govern- 
mental service  makes  it  desirable  that  competent  and  honest  persons  be 
employed,  so  that  the  public  can  get  its  money's  worth. 

The  slowly  established  federal  civil-service  system,  which  was  intro- 
duced in  a  feeble  fashion  in  1883  and  has  been  gradually  extended  and 
strengthened  since  that  time,  docs  not  notably  reduce  the  graft  and 
expense  connected  with  federal  offices.  It  is  designed  to  secure  greater 
efficiency  among  those  who  are  actually  chosen  for  federal  jobs.  In  one 
sense,  the  civil-service  system  doubtless  helps  to  increase  the  actual 
number  of  federal  employees,  in  that  it  makes  it  more  difficult  to  dis- 
continue an  obsolete  or  unnecessary  branch  of  the  service  and  to  discharge 
supposedly  faithful  employees. 

Most  criticisms  of  9  our  increasing  federal  expenditures  attribute  the 
increase  primarily  to  the  extravagance  of  Congressmen,  petty  waste,  and 
the  growth  of  state-socialistic  enterprises.  This  attitude  dominates  the 
late  James  M.  Beck's  Our  Wonderland  of  Bureaucracy.  But  such  critics 
overlook  what  is  far  and  away  the  chief  source  of  public  waste  and 
mounting  expenditures,  namely,  wars  and  vast  armaments — expenditures 
which  men  like  Mr.  Beck  have  been  the  first  to  support  with  great  enthu- 
siasm. We  may  have  an  expensive  civil-service  bureaucracy  and  may 
waste  large  sums  in  petty  graft  and  extravagance,  but  all  this  is  "pin- 
money,"  compared  to  the  large  and  often  unnecessary  expenditures  for 
war  purposes.  Moreover,  it  is  well  established  that  our  civil  servants  are, 
for  the  most  part,  underpaid. 

From  a  tabular  exhibit  of  our  federal  expenditures  in  1930,  it  may  be 
seen  that  in  a  normal  peace  year  war  accounted  for  nearly  70  per  cent  of 
our  federal  outlay.  Military  and  naval  expenditures  ran  to  38.5  per  cent; 
and  interest  and  retirement  on  the  national  debt,  due  chiefly  to  the  cost 
of  past  wars,  to  30.4  per  cent.  This  brings  the  total  up  to  68.8  per  cent. 
Payments  to  veterans  are  mounting  each  year.  It  is  inevitable  that  the 
vast  expenditures  for  the  second  World  War  will  greatly  increase  the 
proportion  of  the  budget  going  into  military  expenses,  even  in  the  years 
after  the  war  is  over.  Since  July,  1940,  Congress  has  voted  for  defense 
and  war  some  160  billion  dollars,  a  sum  equal  to  twelve  times  the  total 
expenditures  for  relief  and  social  aid  by  the  federal,  state,  and  local  gov- 
ernments from  1933  to  1940. 

The  governmental  expenditures  have  also  increased  in  state  and  local 
units  in  the  last  generation,  though  not  in  such  dramatic  fashion  as  in 
the  federal  government.  In  1913  the  total  expenditures  of  the  state 
governments  amounted  to  $388,000,000.  In  1932,  they  equaled  $2,322,- 
000,000.  In  1939,  they  stood  at  $3,464,000,000.  In  1913,  the  expendi- 
tures of  local  government  units  totaled  $1,844,000,000.  By  1932,  they  had 
increased  to  $6,906,000,000.19  However,  much  of  the  increase  in  1932  was 


10  Another  estimate  puts  this  as  high  as  $8,292,000,000. 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  253 

due  to  the  heavy  relief  expenditures  of  the  years  after  the  depression  of 
1929. 

In  England,  the  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer  is  compelled  to  determine 
the  expenditures  for  the  coming  year  and  the  various  sources  of  revenue 
that  will  cover  the  proposed  expenditures.  If  the  revenues  greatly  exceed 
or  fall  conspicuously  beneath  the  expenditures,  the  Chancellor  is  regarded 
as  manifestly  unfit  for  his  post.  In  the  United  States,  however,  there  has 
been  less  scientific  coordination  of  effort  in  determining  federal  expen- 
ditures and  providing  for  the  appropriations  to  meet  them  than  we  find 
in  England. 

Down  to  the  time  of  the  passage  of  the  Budget  and  Accounting  Act  of 
1921,  the  procedure  in  determining  federal  revenues  and  expenditures  was 
essentially  the  following:  In  October,  the  heads  of  the  cabinet  depart- 
ments sent  to  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury  their  estimate  for  the  expen- 
ditures for  the  ensuing  year.  These  departments  invariably  asked  for 
more  than  they  needed,  because  they  naturally  feared  that  their  requests 
would  be  pruned  by  congressional  committees.  The  Secretary  of  the 
Treasury  had,  however,  no  real  power  to  reduce  these  estimates.  While 
the  executive  department  heads  were,  in  this  way,  submitting  their  esti- 
mates to  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury,  the  committees  in  the  House  of 
Representatives  in  control  of  the  various  types  of  appropriations  prepared 
their  estimates,  largely  based  on  the  expenditures  of  the  previous  year. 
Often  there  was  no  cooperation  between  the  cabinet  heads  and  the  Secre- 
tary of  the  Treasury,  on  the  one  hand,  and  the  House  committees  on 
expenditure,  on  the  other. 

Even  more  striking  is  the  fact  that  neither  of  these  groups  was  very 
effectively  coordinated  with  the  House  committee  on  revenue  (the  Com- 
mittee on  Ways  and  Means).  There  was  opportunity  for  informal 
collaboration,  but  the  Committee  on  Ways  and  Means  could  work 
independently  of  the  Committees  on  appropriations  and  the  executive 
departments,  with  the  result  that  far  too  much  or  too  little  revenue  might 
be  raised  in  any  particular  year.  If  the  revenues  contemplated  by  the 
Committee  on  Ways  and  Means  were  not  adequate  to  meet  the  federal 
expenditures,  the  President,  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury,  and  the 
Comptroller  had  the  authority  to  decide  what  should  be  allotted  to  each 
department.  This  had  to  be  done  within  the  limitations  imposed  by  the 
existence  of  specific  departments.  The  unscientific  and  incoherent  nature 
of  such  a  financial  system  is  obvious. 

Much  enthusiasm  was  generated  by  the  passage,  in  1921,  of  the  Budget 
and  Accounting  Act.  Many  were  led  to  suppose  that  it  provided  fox; 
something  resembling  the  highly  scientific  English  budget  system.  Noth- 
ing could  be  further  from  the  truth.  About  all  that  the  bill  actually 
achieved  was  officially  to  invite  and  stimulate  what  had  been  possible 
before,  namely,  direct  presidential  scrutiny  and  leadership  in  the  prepa- 
ration of  the  estimated  executive  expenditures  for  the  fiscal  year. 

The  President  is  required  to  lay  before  Congress  at  the  opening  of 
each  regular  session  a  composite  budget,  setting  forth  the  revenues  and 


254  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

expenditures  of  the  previous  year  and  those  suggested  for  the  coming 
fiscal  year.  The  specific  information  required  is  furnished  to  the  Presi- 
dent by  the  Director  of  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  who  is  supposed  to 
gather  his  information  from  the  various  executive  departments  and  other 
disbursing  agencies.  In  no  way  does  the  President  or  any  cabinet  official, 
such  as  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury,  have  the  authority  to  introduce 
bills  to  authorize  these  expenditures  or  to  indicate  the  specific  basis  for 
raising  the  revenue  required.  The  committees  on  appropriations  can 
ignore  the  President's  recommendations,  and  the  Committee  on  Ways  and 
Means  is  not  in  any  way  legally  required  to  respect  the  proposals  of 
either  the  President,  the  Treasury,  or  the  committees  on  appropriations. 

Therefore,  our  present  budget  system,  as  compared  with  the  English 
plan  and  procedure,  is  no  budget  system  at  all.  The  direct  and  com- 
pulsory coordination  of  executive  and  legislative  activity,  which  charac- 
terizes the  English  system,  is  almost  entirely  absent.  Such  a  confused 
and  uncoordinated  system  of  controlling  receipts  and  expenditures  is  al- 
most perfectly  adapted  to  fostering  every  sort  of  partisan,  sectional,  and 
class  graft.  While  various  phases  of  New  Deal  legislation,  such  as  the 
Administrative  Reorganization  Act,  have  added  improvements,  we  are 
still  far  from  a  scientific  budget  system  like  that  of  Britain.  Our  budget 
scheme  does  not,  in  any  sense,  provide  for  effective  control  or  reduction 
of  the  pork  barrel  and  the  omnibus  bill,  the  two  conspicuous  and  ingenious 
techniques  for  raiding  the  federal  treasury.  Charles  Austin  Beard  con- 
cludes that  "in  actual  practice,  the  first  test  of  the  new  budget  system  .  .  . 
worked  a  number  of  economies,  but  it  did  not  materially  reduce  the 
amount  of  logrolling  or  the  size  of  the  'pork-barrel.' "  As  A.  E.  Buck 
summarizes  the  matter:  "While  the  development  of  the  budget  in  the 
United  States  has  made  considerable  progress  in  the  last  two  or  three 
decades,  it  has  as  yet  scarcely  passed  beyond  the  initial  stages." 

The  term  "pork  barrel"  orginated  from  a  usage  on  the  Southern  slave 
plantations.  Salt  pork  was  given  out  to  the  slaves  at  intervals  and  the 
usual  method  of  distribution  was  to  smash  a  large  barrel  that  contained 
pork  and  allow  the  slaves  to  crowd  up  and  seize  as  much  as  they  could 
for  themselves.  The  haste  of  the  Congressmen  to  include  appropriations 
for  their  own  localities  in  the  general  appropriation  bill  led  cynical 
observers  to  designate  the  practice  as  "the  pork  barrel,"  and  the  name 
has  clung  persistently. 

The  omnibus  bill  simply  means  the  abandonment  of  the  practice  of 
passing  specific  appropriations  for  particular  purposes  and  definite 
localities,  and  the  substitution  of  the  practice  of  lumping  together,  in  a 
single  bill,  the  appropriations  of  a  roughly  similar  type  for  the  country 
at  large. 

In  the  old  days,  when  appropriation  bills  were  introduced  for  specific 
purposes  in  a  particular  area  by  individual  Congressmen,  any  abuses  or 
excesses  in  the  proposal  were  zealously  criticized  by  fellow  Congressmen, 
who  feared  lest  inordinate  appropriations  might  cause  the  reduction  of 
the  revenue  available  for  the  needs  of  their  own  districts.  Hence  it  was 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  255 

relatively  difficult  to  get  by  with  any  notorious  example  of  graft  or 
wasteful  expenditure. 

In  due  time,  however,  the  typical  legislative  device  of  "log-rolling" 
suggested  a  way  out.  If  special  appropriations  were  provided  for,  not 
in  bills  introduced  by  individual  Congressmen  for  local  needs  but  in  the 
general  or  omnibus  bill,  then  the  majority  of  the  Congressmen  would  all 
have  fingers  in  the  pie  and  hence  a  very  definite  reason  for  supporting 
the  general  appropriation  bill.  From  this  time  on,  it  became  easy  to 
embody  proposals  for  extravagant  expenditures. 

The  pork-barrel  system  was  well  installed  in  the  appropriations  for 
rivers  and  harbors  from  the  close  of  the  American  Civil  War,  and  but 
two  Presidents,  namely,  Arthur  and  Cleveland,  have  ever  dared  to  try  to 
curtail  the  omnibus  appropriation  in  river-and-harbor  bills.  The  average 
annual  river-and-harbor  bills  have  provided  for  an  expenditure  of  around 
50  million  dollars,  and  the  best  authorities  estimate  that  probably  50 
per  cent  of  these  expenditures  were  for  useless  projects. 

The  pork-barrel  system  spread  into  the  methods  of  appropriation  for 
federal  buildings,  such  as  post  offices  and  custom  houses  in  1901.  Be- 
tween 1902  and  1919  the  appropriations  for  federal  buildings  were  four 
times  as  great  as  all  those  in  the  hundred  and  thirteen  years  preceding 
the  advent  of  the  pork-barrel  method.  Towns  whose  post-office  needs 
would  be  amply  provided  for  in  the  corner  of  a  drug  store  were  graced  by 
elaborate  granite  or  brick  structures  adequate  for  the  needs  of  a  sizable 
city.  C.  C.  Maxey  cites  the  following  interesting  figures  on  the  cost  of 
some  post  offices: 

Aledo,  III,  population  2,144,  cost  $65,000;  Bad  Axe,  Mich.,  population  1,559, 
cost  $55,000;  Bardstown,  Ky.,  population  2,136,  cost  $70,000;  Basin,  Wyo.,  popu- 
lation 763,  cost  $56,000;  Big  Stone  Gap,  Va.,  population  2,590,  cost  $100,000; 
Buffalo,  Wyo.,  population  1,368,  cost  $69,000;  Fallen,  Nev.,  population  741, 
cost  $55,000;  Gilmore,  Texas,  population  1,484,  cost  $55,000;  Jellico,  Tenn., 
population  1,862,  cost  $80,000;  Vernal,  Utah,  population  836,  cost  $50,000.17 

In  1909,  the  Postmaster-General  complained  that  Congress  had  appro- 
priated no  less  than  $20,000,000  for  the  construction  of  post  offices  in 
petty  towns  where  his  department  believed  that  no  changes  at  all  were 
required. 

Even  more  notorious  has  been  the  conquest  of  veterans'  pension  legis- 
lation by  the  omnibus  bill.  Down  to  1908  it  had  been  necessary  to  con- 
sider pension  bills  independently  and  on  their  individual  merit.  There 
had  been  abuses  in  pension  legislation  before  this  time,  particularly  under 
President  Harrison,  when  the  effort  was  made  to  conceal  the  income  from 
the  protective  tariff  by  reducing  the  treasury  reserve  through  lavish 
expenditures  for  pensions.  But  earlier  abuses  were  insignificant  com- 
pared to  those  which  have  sprung  up  in  the  last  three  decades,  and  partic- 

17  On  the  pork-barrel  system,  see  C.  C.  Maxey,  "A  Little  History  of  Pork," 
National  Municipal  Review,  December,  1919,  pp.  696-697.  For  a  more  comprehen- 
sive survey  of  graft  under  the  party  system,  see  C.  H.  Garrigues,  You're  Paying  for 
It:  A  Guide  to  Graft,  Funk  and  Wagnalls,  1936. 


256  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

ularly  since  1908.  Between  1908  and  1916,  50  per  cent  more  special 
pensions  were  granted  than  in  the  forty-seven  years  preceding.  Soon 
the  special  pension  grants  each  year  exceeded  the  number  allowed  in  the 
entire  thirty  years  following  1865.  The  graft  and  injustice  connected 
with  the  system  also  notoriously  increased: 

To  say  that  the  majority  of  them  have  provided  gratuities  for  persons  who 
have  absolutely  no  claim  upon  the  benevolence  of  the  country  is  to  speak  with 
great  moderation.  When  we  read  of  the  deserters,  the  bounty  jumpers,  the  un- 
pcnsionable  widows,  the  remote  relatives,  the  post-bellum  recruits,  and  the  vari- 
ous other  species  of  undeserving  scoundrels  who  have  had  their  names  inscribed 
on  the  pension  rolls  by  means  of  the  special  act,  we  wonder  whether  every 
omnibus  bill  is  not  a  tissue  of  venality  and  corruption.18 

» 

The  expenditures  for  pensions  in  1922  amounted  to  $252,576,000,  as 
compared  with  16  million  dollars  in  1865.  In  1937  the  annual  disburse- 
ments for  pensions  had  jumped  to  $396,030,000,  and  in  1940  to  $429,- 
138,000.  The  total  expenditures  for  pensions  in  all  our  national  history, 
exclusive  of  payments  to  World  War  veterans,  had  been  $8,300,000,000, 
to  1935.  By  1936,  we  had  already  paid  to  World  War  veterans  alone 
in  pensions  and  other  aids  over  6%  billions.  By  1941,  the  total  disburse- 
ments of  the  Veterans  Administration  had  mounted  to  $24,000,000,000. 
Our  pension  allotment  is  far  more  generous  than  the  European  practice. 
For  example,  in  the  budget  for  1933,  the  allotment  for  various  payments 
to  World  War  veterans  was  $1,020,000,000.  This  was  some  forty-seven 
times  the  payment  made  by  European  combatants  for  veterans'  relief, 
when  computed  on  the  per  capita  basis  of  the  men  under  arms  in  the 
great  conflict. 

The  river-and-harbor  bills,  the  appropriations  for  federal  buildings, 
and  the  exploitation  of  the  omnibus  bill  for  private  pension  grants  con- 
stitute the  outstanding  extravagances  in  federal  financial  legislation,  aside 
from  the  expenditures  for  armament  and  war. 

Among  the  other  aspects  of  the  pork-barrel  system  are  the  now  aban- 
doned provisions  for  the  distribution  of  tons  of  seed  to  the  constituents 
of  Congressmen,  the  abuses  in  the  congressional  franking  of  mail,  the 
waste  in  public  printing,  the  maintenance  of  assay  offices,  the  establish- 
ment and  financing  of  unnecessary  army  posts  and  obsolete  forts,  and 
the  support  of  Indian  schools  in  districts  remote  from  the  Indian  reserva- 
tions. These  forms  of  waste  and  graft,  however,  when  considered  in  their 
gross  volume,  are  perhaps  more  amusing  than  important,  even  though 
they  embody  expenditures  far  in  excess  of  the  usual  congressional  appro- 
priations for  educational,  scientific,  and  cultural  purposes. 

The  foregoing  represents  only  a  part  of  the  graft  and  corruption  in  fed- 
eral government  under  the  party  system.  Contracts  on  public  works  are 
let,  to  the  public  disadvantage,  to  friends  of  politicians  and  bosses. 
Money  or  special  favors  are  given  to  legislators  by  lobbyists  and  other 


18  Maxey,  loc.  cit. 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  257 

pressure  groups.  Appointments  are  handed  out  to  friends  and  relatives 
of  politicians,  especially  posts  outside  the  classified  civil  service.  Serv- 
ices, usually  in  the  form  of  large  donations  to  national  campaign  funds 
and  the  party  chests,  are  rendered  by  criminals  and  racketeers,  who  are 
given  protection  by  the  political  machine. 

Bribery  and  venality  in  party  government  and  legislation  are  more  fre- 
quent and  bald  in  state  government  than  in  federal  government.  There 
has  been  much  graft  in  the  construction  of  state  buildings.  Over  twenty 
million  dollars  was  spent  for  the  state  capitol  at  Albany,  whereas  even 
a  generous  estimate  would  put  the  actual  cost  at  a  quarter  of  this  sum. 
Even  more  notorious  was  the  graft  in  the  construction  of  the  state  capitol 
at  Harrisburg.  The  construction  of  state  highways  opened  up  a  new  and 
extensive  field  for  political  graft.  Inferior  construction  is  frequently 
approved  by  state  officials  in  return  for  a  kick-back  from  the  contractors. 

There  is  plenty  of  opportunity  for  graft  in  county  government,  in  con- 
nection with  county  buildings,  highways,  and  contracts.  But  the  most 
notorious  is  the  fee  system  which  prevails  in  the  administration  of 
county  jails.  It  has  been  estimated  that  this  at  least  doubles  the  expense 
of  running  our  jail  system. 

Since  most  of  our  great  party  machines  originate  in  cities,  it  is  not 
surprising  that  the  worst  political  graft  has  centered  in  city  governments. 
This  fact  has  been  notorious  since  Lincoln  Steffcns  published  his  The 
Shame  of  the  Cities  in  1904.  In  spite  of  sporadic  reform  since  then,  it  is 
doubtful  if  there  is  any  less  graft. 

The  city  of  Chicago  has,  perhaps,  been  most  notable  for  the  perpetu- 
ation of  graft,  corruption,  and  the  spoils  system.  Both  parties  have 
shared  in  this  plunder.  As  a  professor  at  the  University  of  Chicago 
once  put  it,  "The  Republican  and  Democratic  parties  are  but  the  two 
wings  of  the  same  bird  of  prey."  The  Chicago  political  machine  has 
acted  as  intermediary  between  the  great  banking,  real  estate,  traction,  and 
public  utility  interests  above,  and  the  gangster  elements  below.  The  big 
financial  and  business  interests  want  freedom  from  public  regulation  and 
a  reduction  of  taxation.  They  contribute  heavily  to  the  campaign  funds 
of  friendly  machines  and  candidates  and  offer  other  rewards  to  com- 
plaisant politicians.  At  the  other  end  of  the  scale,  the  gangsters  and 
racketeers  wish  to  be  let  alone  in  their  remunerative  activities  in  organized 
crime.  They  pay  protection  money,  stuff  ballot  boxes,  intimidate  inde- 
pendent voters,  discourage  political  reformers  by  threats  and  bombings, 
and  otherwise  aid  the  political  machine  in  emergencies. 

It  has  been  estimated  that,  in  the  days  of  the  Thompson  rule  in  Chicago, 
the  plain  and  outright  graft  ran  to  somewhere  between  75  and  125  million 
dollars  annually.  This  was  made  possible  in  a  number  of  ways.  Inflated 
contracts  were  awarded.  In  one  2V&  million  dollar  paving  job  there  was 
one  million  dollars  of  sheer  graft.  A  political  printer  was  paid  $120,000 
to  print  the  annual  message  of  the  president  of  the  board  of  trusteees  of 
the  Sanitary  District.  Payrolls  were  padded.  On  the  average,  16  out  of 
every  100  names  on  the  public  payrolls  in  Cook  County  were  bogus  and 


258  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

fraudulent.  In  campaign  years,  around  2  million  dollars  was  paid  out  in 
bogus  salaries. 

Tax  rebating  was  used  as  a  form  of  political  blackmail.  Coal  com- 
panies were  organized  by  friends  of  assessors  and  the  Board  of  Tax 
Review.  Following  protests  about  assessments  and  taxation,  agents  of 
these  coal  companies  would  call  and  promise  relief  if  orders  for  coal 
were  placed  with  them.  One  coal  company  openly  printed  cards  with 
the  encouraging  slogan,  "Buy  your  coal  of  us  and  cut  your  taxes." 
Ninety  per  cent  of  the  coal  in  the  Loop  District  was  bought  from  such 
companies,  and  in  one  year  alone  there  was  an  assessment  reduction  of 
500  million  dollars. 

High  prices  were  paid  for  real  estate  bought  by  the  city.  City  property 
was  often  sold  or  leased  to  favored  individuals  at  scandalously  low  rates. 
Public  funds  were  placed  with  favored  bankers.  Offices  and  promotions 
were  sold  to  the  highest  bidders.  Large  sums  of  money  poured  in  from 
the  racketeers,  bootleggers,  and  operators  of  organized  vice. 

In  one  case  $2,250,000  was  supposedly  paid  to  experts  for  their  opinions 
on  a  city  bond  issue.  But  the  experts  received  only  a  nominal  salary  and 
the  bulk  of  this  sum  went  into  the  Thompson  campaign  fund.  The  diffi- 
culty of  organizing  intelligent  public  opinion  behind  muncipal  reform  is 
revealed  by  the  fact  that  Mayor  Thompson  was  able  successfully  to  dis- 
tract public  indignation  from  municipal  scandals  by  waging  a  colorful 
rhetorical  campaign  against  King  George  V  of  England.  The  regime  of 
A.  J.  Cermak,  which  succeeded  that  of  Thompson,  was  held  to  be  more 
corrupt  than  its  predecessor,  and  the  articles  by  John  T.  Flynn  in  Collier's 
in  June,  1940,  indicated  that  the  graft  and  corruption  in  Chicago  under 
the  Kelly-Nash  machine  matched  that  under  the  Thompson  machine, 
while  the  public  was  soothed  into  general  acquiescence.  The  present 
machine  seems  to  be  a  more  smoothly  running  affair  than  the  old  Thomp- 
son organization. 

New  York  City  could  not  match  the  achievements  of  Chicago  in  munici- 
pal graft,  but  it  made  an  excellent  showing,  nevertheless.  During  the 
terms  of  Mayor  "Jimmy"  Walker,  who  "reigned"  contemporaneously  with 
"Big  Bill"  Thompson  in  Chicago,  the  Tammany  Tiger  enjoyed  an  unusu- 
ally rich  diet.  Judge  Seabury  and  his  associates  revealed  many  juicy 
scandals  in  the  Tammany  government,  but  even  before  the  investigation 
such  notorious  scandals  as  those  in  the  sewer  contracts  in  Queens  County 
had  been  exposed.  There  was  much  graft  in  connection  with  city  docks 
and  piers.  Fee-splitting  was  common.  One  employee  of  the  Bureau  of 
Standards  made  $25,000  monthly  out  of  this  form  of  graft.  The  firm  of 
a  fee-splitting  lawyer  in  the  zoning  department  deposited  $5,283,000  be- 
tween 1925  and  1931.  The  sheriff  of  New  York  County  banked  $360,000 
in  seven  years,  though  his  salary  and  other  official  income  were  not  more 
than  $90,000.  The  sheriff  of  Kings  County  banked  some  $520,000  in  six 
years,  although  his  salary  ran  to  less  than  $50,000  for  the  period.  A 
deputy  city  clerk,  whose  chief  official  duty  was  to  marry  couples,  deposited 
$384,000  in  six  years.  There  was  much  graft  in  the  city  bus  system. 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  259 

Organized  vice  and  gambling  flourished  under  police  protection.  In  the 
spring  of  1932,  Mayor  Walker  resigned  under  pressure  and  fear  of  re- 
moval. These  conditions  in  Chicago  and  New  York  were  unique  only  in 
the  size  of  the  totals  derived  from  graft  and  spoils.  In  Jersey  City  a 
machine  far  more  "reform  proof"  than  those  of  Chicago  and  New  York 
was  built  up.  The  powerful  Pendergast  machine  in  Kansas  City  was  at 
least  temporarily  broken  up  by  the  Federal  Department  of  Justice, 
allegedly  to  rival  Thomas  E.  Dewey's  record  as  a  Republican  racket- 
buster,  but  there  is  little  doubt  that  this  machine  or  another  one  equally 
venal  and  powerful  will  reassert  its  authority  in  the  not  distant  future. 

Reform  Measures  and  Their  Fate 

The  more  enlightened  citizens,  from  the  days  of  George  William 
Curtis  and  Carl  Schurz  in  the  'eighties,  have  been  aware  of  the  political 
degradation  associated  with  the  rise  and  domination  of  the  party  machine. 
There  have  been  various  attempts  to  reduce  the  autocracy,  corruption, 
and  inefficiency  in  party  government. 

Of  all  the  attempts  to  limit  the  complete  domination  of  the  "boss,"  the 
civil-service  movement  has  probably  been  the  most  effective  in  practice. 
This  movement  began  to  get  under  way  after  1872,  as  a  result  of  the 
Liberal  Republican  revolt.  It  has  gained  momentum  until  today  most 
federal  offices  are,  at  least  in  legal  theory,  filled  upon  the  basis  of  merit 
as  demonstrated  by  competitive  examinations.  But  the  federal  civil 
service  is  by  no  means  perfect  at  the  present  time,  and  the  state  and 
municipal  civil-service  systems  are  far  inferior.  Still,  the  situation  has 
been  greatly  improved,  in  comparison  to  that  which  existed  in  the  time 
of  President  Grant.  However,  the  selection  and  appointment  of  eligibles 
under  the  civil-service  system  is  still  determined  by  partisan  influence. 
Appointments  are  usually  made  from  the  three  highest  on  the  list  of  avail- 
able persons.  This  allows  considerable  leeway  for  partisan  influence. 
Elective  offices  are  still  completely  in  the  control  of  the  party  system. 

The  intimidation  of  the  voter  through  a  knowledge  of  how  he  is  voting 
was,  in  part,  eliminated  by  the  introduction  of  the  Australian  ballot  in 
the  decade  following  1885.  At  present  the  secret  ballot  is  used  in  every 
state  except  South  Carolina.  Yet  the  secret  ballot  does  not  fully  prevent 
the  boss  from  learning  how  a  man  votes.  Various  special  directions  as 
to  names  to  be  written  in  the  blank  column  of  the  ballot  can  serve  to 
reveal  the  vote  of  an  individual  to  the  boss  or  his  representatives  about 
as  adequately  as  in  the  earlier  days  when  the  method  of  voting  was  by 
show  of  hand  or  word  of  mouth.  Voting  machines  make  the  control  of 
voters  more  difficult,  and  the  political  machine  has  tended,  though  not 
always  successfully,  to  resist  their  introduction.  Boss  Frank  Hague  of 
Jersey  City  has  been  notable  for  his  opposition  to  voting  machines. 

Attempts  have  been  made  by  groups  of  citizens  to  organize  for  the 
purpose  of  promoting  certain  types  of  reform  legislation.  By  large-scale 
persistent  efforts  it  has  occasionally  become  possible  for  a  sufficiently 


260.  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

powerful  group  of  citizens  to  secure  the  introduction,  if  not  the  passage, 
of  bills  looking  towards  political  improvement  and  a  better  public  policy. 

A  notable  effort  to  break  down  the  control  of  the  boss  and  the  machine 
over  legislation  has  been  made  through  the  initiative  and  referendum. 
They  were  first  widely  used  in  Switzerland  and  were  introduced  into  the 
United  States  in  1899  by  South  Dakota.  Twenty  states  have  adopted 
them  in  one  form  or  another.  When  using  the  initiative,  a  stipulated 
number  of  citizens  affix  their  names  to  a  petition  and  force  the  submission 
of  the  proposed  legislation  to  the  people  of  the  state.  The  subsequent 
submission  of  the  measure  to  the  people  is  called  a  referendum.  If  a 
majority  of  the  people  approves,  the  measure  becomes  law.  In  this  way, 
the  law-making  process  can  be  taken  out  of  the  hands  of  the  boss- 
controlled  legislature.  The  initiative  and  referendum  may  be  worked 
together  or  separately.  When  they  are  applied  together  the  law  is  initi- 
ated by  the  people  and  then  approved  or  rejected  by  them.  When  they 
are  employed  separately,  a  bill  may  be  initiated  by  petition  and  its  fate 
decided  by  the  legislature,  with  no  popular  referendum.  Or,  a  propo- 
sition may  first  be  approved  by  the  legislature  and  then  submitted  to  a 
referendum  before  it  can  become  law. 

These  devices  are  intended  to  give  the  people  a  larger  share  in  the 
direct  proposal  and  initiation  of  legislation  and  in  the  rejection  of  legis- 
lation passed  by  the  machine-ridden  legislatures.  But,  excellent  as  these 
have  been  in  theory,  their  practical  operation  has  not  been  conspicuously 
successful.  The  people  have  shown  a  general  apathy,  the  education  of 
the  populace  has  been  difficult,  and  the  general  body  of  citizens  have  found 
it  hard  to  vote  intelligently  on  the  technical  problems  involved  in  many 
measures.  If  they  vote  at  all  on  such  matters,  they  often  prefer  to  accept 
the  suggestions  of  the  party  leaders.  It  is  still  true,  therefore,  that  most 
legislation  is  introduced  and  passed  at  the  behest,  and  under  the  control, 
of  the  machine  leaders. 

Attempts  have  been  made  to  reduce  the  volume  of  corruption  in  politics 

(1)  by  publicizing  and  curtailing  primary  and  campaign  expenditures; 

(2)  by  impeachment  or  dismissal  of  legislators  and  public  officials  found 
guilty  of  receiving  bribes;  (3)  by  investigations  of  building  scandals  in 
connection  with  state  structures  and  public  works;  and  (4)  by  the  intro- 
duction of  a  budget  system,  thus  reducing  the  possibility  of  the  wholesale 
graft  and  wild  expenditures  involved  in  the  "pork-barrel"  and  "rider" 
devices. 

The  large  expenditures  for  nomination  and  election  to  public  offices 
have  encouraged  efforts  to  curb  these  abuses.  Laws — especially  the 
Federal  Corrupt  Practices  acts  from  1911  to  1925 — designed  to  prevent 
elections  from  being  a  walkaway  for  the  wealthy,  have  outlawed  con- 
tributions from  employees  of  the  federal  government;  forbidden  con- 
tributions from  national  banks  and  public  corporations;  limited  the 
amount  that  may  be  spent  in  campaigns  for  federal  offices ;  made  it  illegal 
to  promise  a  job  as  a  reward  for  political  support;  tabooed  bribery  in 
voting;  and  ordered  campaign  expenses  to  be  listed. 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  261 

But  even  these  commendable  measures  have  failed  adequately  to 
remedy  the  situation.  The  poor  man  is  still  handicapped.  The  laws 
exempt  from  inclusion  under  election  expenses  everything  spent  for  per- 
sonal expenses — stationery,  postage,  printing,  telephone  and  telegraph 
charges — in  short,  most  legitimate  electioneering  expenses.  Friends  or 
friendly  interests  may  still  spend,  directly  or  indirectly,  almost  unlimited 
funds  for  the  candidate.  Expenditures  may  be  made  at  other  times  than 
during  the  campaign  without  any  severe  restrictions.  Great  deficits  may 
be  piled  up  and  paid  off  after  the  expense  report  has  been  filed.  The 
much-heralded  reporting  of  expenditures  is  often  perfunctory  and  gets 
little  publicity  unless  there  are  alert  newspapers  that  scent  a  scandal. 
There  is  little  machinery  for  enforcing  existing  legislation.  Finally, 
primaries  are  often  exempted  from  these  restrictive  laws,  and  in  many 
cases,  as  noted  before,  it  is  the  primaries  and  not  the  elections  that  count. 

Rejection  by  legislative  bodies  of  successful  candidates  who  have 
spent  too  much  in  primaries  or  elections  is  no  adequate  solution,  for  it 
cannot  be  relied  upon  to  operate  in  every  case.  Also,  this  device  affects 
only  the  successful  contestant.  His  opponent  may  have  spent  more. 
For  example,  in  Pennsylvania,  Mr.  Vare's  opponent  for  the  senatorial 
nomination  in  1926,  George  Wharton  Pepper,  is  said  to  have  spent  even 
more  in  the  primaries  than  Mr.  Vare  did. 

The  most  drastic  efforts  to  curtail  intimidation  and  corruption  in  polit- 
ical campaigns  and  to  limit  expenditures  in  national  elections  were  em- 
bodied in  the  Hatch  Acts  of  August  2,  1939,  and  July  20,  1940.  They 
were  brought  about  by  the  scandalous  use  of  WPA  money  and  jobs  to 
influence  primaries  and  campaigns,  especially  the  senatorial  primary  and 
campaign  in  Kentucky.  They  were  designed  to  prevent  federal  em- 
ployees from  taking  any  active  part  in  political  campaigns  beyond  their 
personal  exercise  of  the  right  of  suffrage.  These  laws  make  it  illegal 
for  government  employees  even  to  use  their  personal  influence  to  affect 
the  voting  of  a  single  individual.  The  1940  Act  extended  this  prohibition 
to  state  employees  receiving  any  payment  from  the  federal  government. 
It  also  limited  the  annual  expenditures  of  any  national  committee  to 
3  million  dollars  and  personal  campaign  contributions  to  a  national  com- 
mittee to  $5,000.  Except  where  limited  by  a  state  law,  contributions  to 
state  and  local  committees  may  be  of  any  amount. 

These  laws  have  had  some  effect,  but  there  is  plenty  of  subterfuge  and 
it  is  difficult  to  enforce  such  legislation.  As  we  have  pointed  out  above, 
there  are  many  ways  in  which  one  may  evade  legal  limitations  on  cam- 
paign expenditures.  That  even  such  drastic  legislation  cannot  curb  exces- 
sive expenditures  may  be  seen  from  the  fact  that  more  money  was  spent 
in  the  campaign  of  1940  than  in  any  other  in  American  history — about 
14  millions  by  the  Republicans  and  6  millions  by  the  Democrats.  The 
Democrats  also  made  good  use  of  the  bait  of  the  large  armament  expendi- 
tures they  controlled.  On  account  of  the  limitations  imposed  by  the 
Hatch  Acts,  most  of  the  money  had  to  be  dispensed  by  other  agents  than 
the  national  committees. 


262  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

The  complete  tyranny  of  the  party  machine  in  the  selection  of  candi- 
dates has  been  lessened  by  the  direct-primary  system.  Certain  early 
anticipations  of  the  principle  came  in  the  California  law  of  1866  and  the 
Ohio  law  of  1871,  but  most  of  the  progress  has  been  made  since  the  open- 
ing of  the  twentieth  century.  In  large  part,  the  contemporary  movements 
towards  direct  primaries  were  the  result  of  the  agitation  of  the  elder 
Robert  M.  LaFollette  of  Wisconsin,  in  his  struggle  against  the  boss- 
dominated  conventions  in  his  state.  The  direct-primary  system  was 
thoroughly  introduced  in  Minnesota  in  1901,  and  has  been  utilized  in 
widely  varying  degrees  in  all  but  three  of  the  states  of  the  Union — 
Connecticut,  Rhode  Island,  and  New  Mexico. 

The  most  extended  use  of  the  direct  primary  in  the  United  States 
has  been  in  nominations  for  the  presidency.  The  presidential  preference 
primary  was  first  established  in  Oregon  in  1910.  In  1912  some  ten  states 
used  it.  By  1916,  twenty-two  states  had  mandatory  presidential  primary 
laws  and  three  others  permitted  a  preferential  vote  on  presidential  candi- 
dates. It  was  believed  at  this  time  that  all  states  would  soon  have 
presidential  primary  laws,  but  the  movement  fell  off  sharply  after  1916. 
No  states  have  adopted  it  since  then  and  several  that  once  used  it  have 
abandoned  it. 

While,  in  theory,  the  direct  primary  provides  admirable  machinery  to 
break  down  the  control  of  the  bosses  over  the  nomination  of  party  candi- 
dates, it  has  in  practice  proved  unsatisfactory.  This  has  been  due  to 
the  lack  of  public  interest  and  intelligence  in  its  operation.  The  majority 
of  the  voters  usually  remain  away  from  the  polls  on  primary  day  and 
allow  a  few  faithful  members  of  the  old  guard,  who  vote  under  the 
direction  of  the  machine,  to  cast  most  of  the  votes  for  the  candidates.  In 
this  way,  the  machine  actually  controls  nominations,  as  it  did  under  the 
old  caucus  and  convention  systems.  The  main  difference  is  that  it  costs 
the  state  a  great  deal  more  to  select  candidates  under  the  primary  system. 
In  fact,  so  indifferent  have  the  people  shown  themselves  to  the  direct 
primary  in  some  states  that  they  have  allowed  the  bosses  to  reintroduce 
the  convention  system. 

For  the  emotional  power  of  party  symbols  and  catchwords,  the  effective 
antidote  is  knowledge  of  the  real  meaning  of  political  parties,  their  true 
function  in  political  life,  and  the  ways  in  which  politicians  deceive  the 
citizens  by  party  propaganda  and  symbolism.  As  Graham  Wallas 
pointed  out  in  the  first  part  of  his  Human  Nature  in  Politics,  party 
symbols  lose  their  power  once  the  people  are  shown  how  they  have  been 
duped  by  them  in  the  past.  Political  education  can  thus  furnish  a  real 
campaign  psychotherapy. 

Still  most  of  the  voters,  even  college  graduates,  are  likely  to  react 
to  political  appeals  on  an  emotional  plane.  Education  is  most  effective 
with  those  who  already  consider  public  and  other  problems  in  a  rational 
light.  In  many  ways  the  situation  is  more  depressing  than  it  was  forty 
years  ago,  when  Graham  Wallas  wrote  his  book.  Propaganda  technique 
has  been  improved  during  this  period.  The  radio  and  the  movies  have 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  263 

provided  new  mechanisms  for  propaganda.  The  poor  average  voter  is 
even  more  at  sea  and  less  capable  of  getting  at  the  real  truth  than  he  was 
four  decades  ago.  At  the  very  moment  when  problems  are  most  com- 
plicated and  when  clarity  of  thought  and  adequacy  of  information  are 
most  essential,  propaganda  is  most  effective  in  blinding  and  misleading 
the  average  citizen.20 

Broadly,  one  may  say  that  the  reform  of  contemporary  party  govern- 
ment is  but  a  phase  of  the  necessary  reorganization  of  modern  political 
life  as  a  whole.  It  is  doubtful  whether  complete  direct  majority  rule 
would  be  desirable  even  if  we  could  obtain  it.  In  all  probability,  society 
will  always  be  dominated  by  the  superior  intellects,  unless  certain  un- 
fair institutions  and  obstructive  practices  prevent  real  leadership  from 
asserting  itself.  Hence,  the  somewhat  autocratic  aspect  of  political 
parties  is  not,  in  itself,  to  be  deplored.  It  is  probably  both  inevitable 
and  desirable. 

Most  disastrous  in  modern  party  autocracy  is  the  type  of  leader  who 
has  dominated  contemporary  political  parties.  We  must  supplant  the 
corrupt  boss  by  educated  leaders,  who  will  assume  responsibility  in  public 
service.  No  doubt  this  is  only  a  pious  aspiration,  but  the  only  solution 
of  the  problems  of  democracy  lies  in  concentrated  efforts  to  realize  this 
worthy  goal. 

Intelligent  political  leadership  is  not  likely  to  operate  effectively  unless 
linked  with  an  active  popular  interest  in  political  life,  and  the  latter  is 
nearly  impossible  under  the  political  conditions  that  exist  in  the  modern 
state.  The  great  territorial  states  of  the  present  time,  with  their  com- 
plexity of  social  and  economic  problems,  have  so  far  removed  govern- 
ment from  the  interest  and  scrutiny  of  the  average  citizen  that  he  is 
unable  to  grasp  its  nature  and  problems.  The  citizen  has  thus  lost  most 
of  his  interest  in,  and  practical  knowledge  of,  general  political  issues. 
His  sole  participation  in  politics  usually  lies  in  an  unreasoning  allegiance 
to  some  emotion-provoking  party  or  personality. 

The  active  interest  in  government  which  characterized  citizens  in  earlier 
periods,  when  small  political  units  were  the  rule,  can  be  revived,  in  part, 
by  increasing  the  importance  of  local  government,  thus  bringing  many 
important  governmental  problems  closer  to  the  people.  Community  in- 
terests and  community  organization,  as  R.  M.  Maclver  and  Miss  M.  P. 
Follett  have  'pointed  out,  might  be  greatly  strengthened.  The  powers 
of  the  central  government  could  be  restricted  to  certain  large  general 
interests  that  concern  all  the  citizens  of  the  entire  country.  By  thus 
emphasizing  the  local  political  community,  it  is  likely  that  the  citizens 
would  begin  to  take  a  greater  interest  in  problems  of  government  and  be 
able  to  jexert  a  more  intelligent  control  over  public  affairs.  But  it  must 
be  conceded  that  the  main  trend  is  now  towards  greater  centralization  in 
government.  Another  promising  proposal  of  political  reform  lies  in 
wiping  out  the  irrational  practice  of  basing  representative  government  on 


20  See  below,  pp.  554  ff .,  572-573. 


264  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

territory  and  population,  and  the  substitution  of  representation  by  pro- 
fessions and  vocations.  Under  such  a  system,  every  citizen  would  have 
his  own  occupation  or  profession  directly  and  immediately  represented 
in  the  government.  This  would  give  a  real  logic  and  vitality  to  political 
affairs.  The  voter  might  then  take  an  active  interest  in  the  nomination 
and  election  of  representatives.  He  would  be  likely  to  insist  that  the 
representatives  of  his  profession  or  vocation  be  competent  and  worthy 
members  of  that  particular  calling.  He  would  no  longer  be  willing  to 
be  represented  in  a  law-making  body  by  a  person  whom  he  would  be 
embarrassed  to  entertain  in  his  home  or  recognize  upon  the  street.  Per- 
haps the  best  brief  statement  of  this  extremely  important  reform  pro- 
posal is  contained  in  an  article  by  Harry  B.  Overstreet,  in  The  Forum: 

One  of  the  most  serious  defects  of  our  political  machinery  is  found  in  the 
prevalent  theory  of  representation.  It  is  curious  how  contentedly  we  accept  that 
theory  as  if  it  had  been  handed  to  us  from  Sinai's  top,  noting  that  the  times 
have  so  changed  as  to  make  the  theory  no  longer  truly  applicable.  We  view 
it  as  a  matter  of  course  that  a  political  state  should  be  divided  into  its  smaller 
units,  and  these  into  still  smaller  units,  and  these  into  still  smaller;  and  that  in 
each  unit  citizens  should  vote  as  members  of  the  unit.  Thus  the  group  of  people 
who  constitute  precinct  eleven  of  district  four  of  the  borough  of  Manhattan 
recognize,  as  a  matter  of  course,  that  their  political  identity  lies  in  their  member- 
ship within  those  territorial  boundaries.  The  person  who  "represents"  these 
citizens  represents  them  as  inhabitants  of  that  particular  territory. 

Amid  all  the  serious  questioning  of  our  political  procedures,  it  is  curious  that 
this  system  of  territorial  division  and  territorial  representation  is  accepted  prac- 
tically without  question.  And  yet  it  is  not  an  exaggeration  to  say  that  of  all 
features  of  our  political  life,  it  is  the  one  that  is  most  distinctly  out  of  date  and 
the  source  of  the  most  serious  political  inefficiency.  It  is  not  difficult  to  see  that 
at  one  time  in  the  history  of  society  such  a  system  was  the  only  one  that  could 
work  with  secure  and  comprehensive  success.  In  a  community  thoroughly  agri- 
cultural, for  example,  similarity  of  interest  was  in  the  main  identical  with  spatial 
propinquity.  If,  in  such  a  community,  one  were  to  district  off  a  square  mile  of 
inhabitants,  one  would  find  that  within  that  square  mile  the  interests  were 
fundamentally  alike.  If  one  were  to  take  another  square  mile  a  hundred  or  a 
thousand  miles  away,  one  would  find,  indeed,  that  the  interests  differed  some- 
what from  those  within  the  first  square  mile — the  difference  between  wheat  land 
interests,  for  example,  and  grazing  land  interests, — but  within  the  second  square 
mile  one  would  again  find  the  interests  fundamentally  alike. 

It  was  this  fact  that  gave  the  territorial  plan  of  political  districting  its  erstwhile 
excuse  for  being.  But  suppose  one  advances  to  a  manufacturing  and  commercial 
community  of  today  and  districts  off  a  square  mile  of  inhabitants  in  any  large 
city.  Within  the  boundaries  of  that  small  domain  one  finds  a  barber  living  next 
to  a  grocer,  a  grocer  next  to  a  real-estate  broker,  a  real-estate  broker  next  to  a 
school  teacher,  a  school  teacher  next  to  a  saloon  keeper,  a  saloon  keeper  next  to 
a  mason,  a  mason  next  to  an  actor,  etc.  Within  the  square  mile,  in  brief,  are 
interests  as  worlds  apart  as  they  possibly  can  be;  and  yet  our  political  system 
operates  upon  the  supposition  that  all  this  heterogeneous  mass  of  beings  can  be 
swept  into  one  unity  by  the  mere  fiction  of  political  demarcation.  ...  * 

Social  enthusiasm  can  be  evoked  only  where  there  is  a  spirit  of  the  group. 
But  a,  spirit  of  the  group  lives  only  where  men  feel  that  they  belong  to  each  other. 
Men  thrown  accidentally  together  by  the  chance  renting  of  this  apartment  or 
that  house  cannot  be  made  to  feel  that  they  deeply  belong  together.  Herein  lies 
the  profoundest  defect  of  our  modern  political  system.  We  are  attempting,  in 
short,  to  bring  into  expression  group  loyalties  and  group  enthusiasms  when  the 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  265 

groups  through  which  we  operate  are  largely  and  inevitably  artificial.  There  is 
no  cure  for  this,  save  as  we  face  frankly  the  issue  of  organizing  political  life  into 
its  truly  natural  groups.  .  .  . 

Is  the  evolution  of  political  society  complete,  or  may  we  look  to  a  further 
development  of  social  and  political  grouping?  The  answer,  I  think,  lies  in  the 
recognition  that  the  groupings  of  the  past  were  determined  by  the  nature  of 
men's  occupations.  For  the  huntsman  life  was  a  roving  existence  and  the  only 
possible  bond  of  union  was  the  impalpable  bond  of  descent.  For  the  agriculturist, 
life  was  a  settled  occupancy  in  which  the  bond  of  union  was  the  perfectly  palpable 
one  of  land.  Are  men  in  large  measure  changing  the  nature  of  their  occupations? 
The  answer  is  clear.  Agriculture,  while  still  fundamental,  is  increasingly  com- 
panioned by  occupations  that  make  profound  alterations  in  our  life.  Indeed,  the 
present  age  may  properly  be  characterized  not  as  an  agricultural  but  as  a  manu- 
facturing and  commercial  economy.  If  now  the  change  from  hunting  to  agri- 
culture brought  to  pass  an  essential  transformation  of  the  principle  of  social  and 
political  grouping,  may  we  not  rightly  expect  that  the  change  from  the  agricul- 
tural to  the  manufacturing  and  commercial  economy  will  effect  a  transformation 
of  equal  moment  ? 

The  significant  change  that  has  occurred  is  that  territorial  propinquity  is  no 
longer  coincident  with  community  of  interest.  ...  if  one  were  to  trace  the  lines 
of  interest  demarcation  in  a  great  city,  one  would  find  them  here,  there,  and 
everywhere,  crossing  and  recrossing  all  the  conventional  political  boundaries.  If 
one  seeks,  in  short,  the  natural  groupings  in  our  modern  world,  one  finds  them 
in  the  associations  of  teachers,  of  merchants,  of  manufacturers,  of  physicians,  of 
artisans.  The  trade  union,  the  chamber  of  commerce^  the  medical  association, 
the  bar  association,  the  housewives'  league — these  even  m  their  half  formed  state 
are  the  fore-runners  of  the  true  political  units  of  the  modern  state.  .  .  . 

That  this  change,  from  the  territorial  to  the  vocational  basis  of  political  group- 
ing, perplexing  as  will  be  the  problems  which  it  will  generate,  will  mean  much 
for  our  political  life  cannot,  I  think,  be  doubted.  Of  primary  importance  will 
be  the  fact  that  the  basis  of  selection  of  candidates  will  be  both  logically  and 
psychologically  superior  to  that  of  the  present  system.  A  group  of  a  hundred 
physicians  or  of  a  hundred  teachers  or  of  a  hundred  artisans  would  be  far  more 
capable  of  making  secure  judgment  upon  one  of  its  number  than  a  helter-skelter 
group  of  citizens  selected  according  to  locality.  Again,  for  a  man  desirous  of 
serving  the  public  welfare,  there  would  be  a  peculiar  joy  in  standing  for  the 
fellows  of  his  craft.  His  appeal  to  them  for  support  would  be  an  appeal  to  their 
understanding  and  their  intelligent  interests.  There  would  be  no  need  for  him 
to  lower  himself  to  that  type  of  campaign  cajolery  which  is  necessary,  apparently, 
when  the  appeal  must  be  made  to  all  sorts  and  conditions  of  men.  It  is  precisely 
the  undignified  character  of  the  prevalent  politiccal  methods  of  campaigning  that 
deters  many  a  sensitive  mind  from  offering  service  to  the  public — the  printing 
of  one's  photograph  on  cards,  the  widespread  distribution  of  self-laudatory  hand- 
bills, the  posting  of  conspicuous  placards,  the  ringing  of  innumerable  doorbells, 
the  whole  sorry  business,  in  short,  of  making  one's  self  a  general  public  nuisance, 
of  doing  what  any  decently  self-respecting  man  would  in  ordinary  circumstances 
utterly  shrink  from  doing.  But  to  offer  one's  self  to  the  fellows  of  one's  craft — 
that  is  a  far  different  matter.  One  comes  then  not  as  a  stranger.  One  comes 
as  a  worker,  known  among  fellow  workers.  One  has  not  to  force  one's  self,  as 
it  were,  down  the  throats  of  the  indifferent  and  the  unknowing.  One  stands 
on  one's  honorable  reputation,  and  one  is  accepted  or  rejected  as  that  reputa- 
tion is  taken  to  be  adequate  or  not.  The  whole  spirit  of  elections,  in  short, 
would  change  from  an  undignified  attempt  to  wheedle  and  cajole  and  hypnotize 
men  into  a  transient  support,  into  a  self-respecting  expression  of  willingness  to 
serve  one's  fellow  men.  ... 

The  objection  is  often  raised  that  occupational  grouping  would  simply  mean  a 
battle  of  interests,  each  group  fighting  for  itself,  In  the  first  place;  matters, 


266  PARTY  GOVERNMENT 

in  this  respect,  could  scarcely  be  worse  than  they  now  are.  In  the  second  place, 
groups  such  as  we  have  indicated  are  not,  in  their  interests,  antagonistic.  House- 
wives are  not  antagonistic  to  physicians;  nor  carpenters  to  teachers'  nor  ministers 
of  religion  to  outdoor  unskilled  workers.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  trie  interests  of 
many  of  these  groups  coalesce,  as  in  the  case  of  housewives,  teachers,  physicians, 
etc.  But  what  is  significant  is  that,  with  as  many  occupational  groups  as  we  have 
indicated,  no  constant  balancing  of  interest  one  over  against  the  other  would  be 
possible — as  would  be  the  case,  for  example,  if  the  occupational  groups  were,  as 
has  elsewhere  been  suggested,  farmers,  merchants,  clerics.  .  .  . 

It  would  be  folly,  of  course,  to  pretend  that  a  high  grade  of  political  efficiency 
will  be  attained  at  once  when  men  change  from  the  anorganic  system  of  terri- 
torial to  the  organic  system  of  vocational  grouping.  But  it  may  at  least  be 
maintained,  with  some  show  of  reason,  that  with  that  change,  one  of  the  most 
insidiously  persistent  obstacles  to  political  efficiency  will  have  been  removed.21 

A  general  adoption  of  proportional  representation  would  be  likely  to 
stimulate  political  interest  and  activity,  especially  in  areas  where  one 
party  has  been  overwhelmingly  powerful  and  the  minority  has  little  or 
no  actual  representation  in  government.  But  proportional  representation 
requires  a  high  degree  of  political  intelligence  and  public  interest. 

Finally,  a  great  extension  of  realistic  education  upon  public  problems 
and  political  machinery  must  be  provided.  At  the  present  time,  there  is 
little  realistic  political  education  in  the  public  schools  and  surprisingly 
little  even  in  the  universities.  Greater  attention  must  be  given  to  the 
study  of  government,  and  the  instruction  in  such  courses  must  be  some- 
thing more  than  a  superficial  description  of  the  external  forms  of  political 
institutions  and  pious  generalizations  as  to  the  theoretical  operation  of 
political  machinery.  The  real  nature  and  purposes  of  existing  party 
government  must  be  candidly  taught,  and  the  defects  of  our  present 
experiments  very  clearly  brought  out.  Above  all,  our  teachers  must  cease 
inculcating  in  the  minds  of  students,  of  whatever  age,  the  fictitious  dogma 
that  our  form  of  government  is  not  only  better  than  any  other  in  existence, 
but  is  perfect  and  not  open  to  extensive  improvement.  Humility  is  the 
beginning  of  wisdom,  no  less  in  political  affairs  than  in  any  other  field 
of  human  activity. 

The  outlook  for  successful  party  government  was,  until  the  second 
World  War,  brighter  in  some  parts  of  Europe  than  in  the  United  States. 
Vocational  and  proportional  representation  had  made  headway  in  the 
governments  set  up  since  1918.  Where  these  did  not  exist  something 
which  achieved  roughly  similar  results,  the  group  or  bloc  party  system, 
prevailed.  There  tended  to  be  more  realistic  political  interest  there  than 
in  our  own  country.  If  dictatorship  gains,  it  will  triumph  at  the  expense 
of  the  representative  system  and  party  government.  Fascism  and  dicta- 
torship present  the  same  deadly  challenge  to  party  government  that  they 
do  to  democracy.  Where  there  is  no  democracy  there  can  be  no  real 
party  government. 

In  the  United  States,  E.  M.  Sait,  A.  N.  Holcombe,  and  P.  H.  Douglas, 
among  others,  have  argued  for  the  desirability  of  breaking  up  the  old  and 


21L0c.  cit.,  July,  1915. 


PARTY  GOVERNMENT  267 

irrational  Republican-Democrat  dualism  and  creating  a  real  conservative 
and  liberal  alignment.  In  fact,  Professors  Douglas,  John  Dewey  and 
others  believe  that  we  should  have  a  definitely  radical  party  to  represent 
workers  and  farmers,  even  though  this  might  produce  a  tripartite  set-up 
of  conservatives,  liberals,  and  radicals.  Some  rumblings  a  few  years  ago 
indicated  that  such  a  movement  might  be  getting  under  way,  but  as  yet 
the  visible  evidence  of  a  new  party  alignment  is  less  impressive  than  the 
logic  of  those  who  advocate  such  a  development.  The  defense  move- 
ment and  the  second  World  War  have  at  least  temporarily  suppressed  it. 
What  the  party  line-up,  if  any,  will  be  at  the  close  of  the  war  cannot  be 
foretold  at  present. 

If  it  is  a  rational  party  alignment,  suitable  for  the  stimulation  and 
successful  operation  of  democracy,  it  should  provide  for  three  strong 
major  parties — a  conservative  party,  a  liberal  party,  and  a  radical  party. 
A  one-party  system  is  a  vehicle  of  totalitarianism ;  our  two-party  system 
utterly  lacks  logic  and  realism,  never  more  so  than  today;  and  a  bloc 
system  makes  for  confusion  and  chaos. 


CHAPTER    IX 

The  Crisis  in  American  Democracy  and 
the  Challense  to  Liberty 

A  Brief   History  of  Democracy 

DEMOCRACY  has  been  viewed  mainly  as  a  political  concept,  meaning 
government  by  the  majority,  or  the  rule  of  the  people.  This  majority 
rule  has  been  achieved  by  means  of  universal  suffrage,  and,  usually, 
through  representative  government.  Only  rarely,  as  in  the  colonial  town 
meeting  or  the  forest  cantons  of  Switzerland,  has  the  population  been 
small  enough  so  that  all  the  people  can  govern  directly  without  choosing 
representatives.  Representation  has  been  the  rule. 

Party  government  has  provided  the  main  machinery  whereby  repre- 
sentative government  is  realized  and  practiced.  For  the  most  part,  repre- 
sentative government  has  been  carried  on  in  conjunction  with  republican 
forms  of  political  institutions;  but  formal  monarchy  can  be  made  com- 
patible with  democracy,  as  in  Great  Britain,  which  has  carried  on  a 
rather  advanced  form  of  political  democracy  in  association  with  tradi- 
tional monarchy. 

Especially  interesting  has  been  the  "democratizing"  of  the  very  concep- 
tion of  democracy  in  the  last  century.  The  old  Aristotelian  notion  of  the 
"people"  as  the  upper-class  and  middle-class  members  of  society,  which 
persisted  down  to  the  close  of  the  eighteenth  century,  has  been  supplanted 
by  the  contemporary  view,  which  regards  the  people  as  embracing  all 
members  of  society,  with  no  important  exceptions.  Consequently,  the 
conception  of  "government  by  the  people"  meant  quite  a  different  thing 
when  used  by  Lincoln  from  what  it  did  in  the  days  of  Aristotle,  of  the 
Magna  Carta,  of  Locke,  or  of  the  Fathers  of  our  Constitution. 

More  recent  scholars  have  begun  to  see  that  democracy  is  more  than 
merely  a  form  of  government  based  on  majority  rule.  F.  H.  Giddings, 
for  example,  finds  that  democracy  is  a  particular  kind  of  government,  a 
specific  form  of  the  state,  a  special  type  of  social  organization,  and  a 
definite  mode  of  social  control.  As  a  method  of  government,  a  "pure 
democracy"  implies  the  enfranchisement  of  the  majority  of  the  popula- 
tion and  direct  participation  of  all  the  citizens  in  public  affairs.  The 
much  more  common  "representative  democracy"  is  defined  as  one  in  which 
the  citizens  govern  indirectly,  through  periodically  selected  deputies  or 

268 


DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY  269 

representatives.  As  a  type  of  state,  democracy  implies  the  existence 
of  popular  sovereignty — the  ultimate  power  of  the  people.  As  a  type  of 
social  organization  and  control,  democracy  means  both  a  popular  organ- 
ization of  the  community  and  the  free  control  of  nonpolitical  activities 
through  the  force  of  public  opinion. 

A  number  of  students  of  democracy  are  dissatisfied  with  a  formalistic 
and  static  analysis  of  democracy.  They  have  given  it  a  pragmatic  defi- 
nition and  have  endowed  it  with  a  dynamic  perspective.  John  Dewey 
and  James  Harvey  Robinson,  for  example,  hold  that  democracy  not  only 
requires  the  popular  control  of  public  policy  but  also  implies  a  type  of 
social  organization  that  will  develop  to  the  fullest  extent  the  latent  poten- 
tialities of  every  member  of  the  society.  It  imposes  upon  society  the 
moral  obligation  to  do  everything  in  its  power  to  hasten  the  realization 
of  such  a  state  of  affairs. 

A  couple  of  generations  back,  it  was  assumed  that  democracy  originated 
in  primitive  political  assemblies,  especially  the  folkmoot  of  the  primitive 
Germans.  Anthropological  research  has  upset  this  notion.  There  was 
a  certain  amount  of  vsocial  and  political  democracy  among  early  peoples, 
particularly  in  the  pre-tribal  periods.  Representative  government  made 
its  first  appearance  in  tribal  assemblies.  But,  by  and  large,  well- 
developed  primitive  society  showed  marked  aristocratic  traits,  and 
monarchy  of  a  somewhat  crude  type  appeared  among  some  primitive 
peoples.  But  millenniums  of  monarchy,  aristocracy,  and  imperialism 
intervened  between  primitive  times  and  the  origins  of  modern  democracy. 

In  the  ancient  near  Orient,  democracy  had  little  opportunity  to  assert 
itself.  Kings  ruled  with  absolutism  and  divine  right,  often  being  them- 
selves regarded  as  partly  divine.  Among  the  Greeks,  a  limited  type  of 
representative  government  and  democracy  attained  a  high  degree  of 
development,  especially  among  the  Attic  Greeks.  But  Athenian  democ- 
racy was  exclusive — a  closed-shop — being  limited  to  the  citizen  class. 
The  slaves  and  the  Metics,  the  latter  a  non-citizen  foreign-born  class, 
outnumbered  the  citizens  at  all  times.  In  Rome,  democracy  was  even 
more  restricted  than  at  Athens.  The  plebeians  temporarily  won  the  right 
of  self-government;  but  the  trend  was  towards  dictatorship  in  the  last 
century  of  the  Republic,  and  imperialism  and  aristocracy  became  defi- 
nitely established.  For  a  time  in  the  Empire  the  emperors  became  abso- 
lute and  asserted  divine  right.  When  the  imperial  power  abated  in  the 
later  Empire,  government  lapsed  into  a  preliminary  sort  of  feudalism, 
in  which  the  great  landlords  were  the  dominant  class. 

There  were  two  substantial  contributions  to  democracy  during  the 
Middle  Ages.  One  was  the  social  democracy,  albeit  a  servile  democracy, 
which  was  developed  in  the  cooperative  life  on  the  communal  medieval 
manor.  The  other  was  the  contributions  to  representative  government 
made  in  the  medieval  communes,  in  the  system  of  estates  in  the  medieval 
monarchies,  and  in  the  Conciliar  Movement  in  the  Catholic  Church  at 
the  close  of  the  medieval  period. 

During  the  so-called  Renaissance,  the  importance  of  the  individual 


270  DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY 

gained  emphasis,  though  monarchy  and  tyranny  all  too  often  dominated 
the  political  scene.  Likewise,  while  the  Protestant  reformers  encouraged 
royal  power  and  sanctioned  divine  right,  the  Reformation  did  stress  the 
importance  of  individualism  in  the  religious  sphere.  But  it  remained  for 
the  expansion  of  Europe  and  the  Commercial  Revolution  to  lay  the  basis 
for  modern  democracy  through  the  growth  of  representative  government 
and  the  increased  power  of  the  middle  class. 

The  era  of  exploration  and  discovery  and  of  subsequent  colonization 
and  world  trade  increased  the  number  and  powers  of  the  mercantile 
middle  class  in  western  Europe.  At  first,  this  group  joined  with  the  ab- 
solute monarchs  in  crushing  their  mutual  enemy,  feudalism.  But  soon 
the  merchants  found  the  new  national  monarchs  as  oppressive  as  the 
feudal  lords  had  ever  been.  They  interfered  with  trade,  levied  arbitrary 
taxes,  and  confiscated  property.  So,  in  a  series  of  important  revolutions 
the  middle  class  subordinated  absolute  monarchy  to  representative  gov- 
ernment. They  realized  that  the  only  practical  way  of  controlling  the 
monarchs  was  to  make  the  representative  branch  of  the  government 
supreme.  The  first  permanent  success  was  in  the  English  Revolution 
of  1688-1689.  This  struggle  of  the  middle  class  to  create  representative 
government  and  to  give  it  a  constitutional  sanction  ran  through  the 
American  Revolution,  the  series  of  French  Revolutions  after  1789,  the 
Revolutions  of  1830  and  1848  in  continental  Europe,  and  the  Russian 
Revolution  of  1905. 

But  this  did  not  mean  democracy.  The  suffrage  was  exercised  mainly 
by  the  landed  gentry  and  the  merchant  class.  The  workers  and  the 
peasants  had  little  or  no  part  in  government.  But  the  creation  of  repre- 
sentative government  was  a  very  significant  contribution  to  democracy. 
It  was  only  through  making  the  representative  branch  of  the  government 
all-powerful  that  universal  suffrage  could  later  bring  about  true  democ- 
racy. It  accomplishes  nothing  to  elect  representatives  unless  they  have 
power  to  m^ke  laws. 

There  were,  however,  two  real  anticipations  of  democratic  doctrine  in 
the  seventeenth  and  eighteenth  centuries.  During  the  period  of  the 
Commonwealth  in  England,  in  the  middle  of  the  seventeenth  century,  a 
group  of  political  radicals  known  as  the  Levellers,  led  by  John  Lilburne, 
asserted  that  the  people  are  sovereign  and  held  that  the  whole  mass  of 
Englishmen  should  have  the  right  to  vote  and  thus  control  Parliament. 
They  foreshadowed  many  of  the  democratic  policies  of  the  English 
Chartists,  two  centuries  later.1  In  eighteenth-century  France,  Jean 
Jacques  Rousseau  asserted  that  all  laws  must  be  submitted  to  a  popular 
referendum;  if  approved,  they  became  expressions  of  the  general  will  and 
were  therefore  valid  and  binding  upon  the  whole  mass  of  the  people. 

In  the  nineteenth  century,  democracy  was  definitely  established  in 
the  progressive  states  of  the  western  world.  The  more  important  achieve- 
ments in  this  direction  were  (1)  extension  of  the  suffrage;  (2)  greater 


1 C/.  T.  C.  Pease,  The  Leveller  Movement,  American  Historical  Association,  1917. 


DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY  271 

importance  of  the  popular  or  legislative  branch  of  the  government,  as 
compared  with  the  executive;  (3)  growth  of  representative  institutions; 

(4)  a  broader  conception  of  the  scope  and  functions  of  government ;  and 

(5)  written  constitutions  that  acknowledge  and  guarantee  these  progres- 
sive accomplishments. 

As  the  Commercial  Revolution  created  representative  government,  so 
did  the  Industrial  Revolution  bring  about  political  democracy.  The 
merchants  had  felt  it  necessary  to  increase  the  powers  of  representative 
government  in  order  to  protect  their  interests.  In  the  nineteenth  century 
the  oppressed  urban  proletariat  and  the  farmers  believed  it  essential  to 
capture  the  right  to  vote  to  alleviate  the  distressing  conditions  under 
which  the  laborers  and  farmers  were  compelled  to  live  and  work. 

Since  England  was  first  thoroughly  affected  by  the  Industrial  Revo- 
lution, it  was  natural  that  European  democracy  would  show  its  first 
marked  developments  in  England.  The  famous  Reform  Bills  of  1832 
and  1835  strengthened  representative  government  in  Parliament  and  in 
the  cities,  respectively.  The  dramatic  and  comprehensive  Chartist  move- 
ment embodied  the  following  demands:  (1)  universal  manhood  suffrage; 
(2)  vote  by  ballot;  (3)  equal  electoral  districts;  (4)  removal  of  property 
qualifications  for  members  of  Parliament;  (5)  annual  elections  to  Parlia- 
ment; and  (6)  payment  of  members  of  Parliament.  While  the  Chartist 
movement  was  discredited  at  the  time  (1848),  five  out  of  six  of  its 
demands  have  since  been  realized.  Only  annual  elections  to  Parliament 
remain  to  be  realized.  Universal  suffrage  came  through  a  series  of  partial 
victories.  In  1867  Disraeli  extended  manhood  suffrage  to  the  majority 
of  urban  residents.  In  1884  Gladstone  did  as  much  for  the  rural  dwellers. 
But  down  to  the  first  World  War,  the  poorer  classes  in  both  city  and 
country  could  not  vote.  Finally,  in  February  1918,  a  suffrage  bill  was 
passed  which  granted  universal  suffrage  to  all  males  and  limited  suffrage 
to  women.  Universal  female  suffrage  was  finally  secured  in  1928. 

The  masses  won  the  right  to  vote  in  most  of  the  other  major  European 
states  during  the  course  of  the  nineteenth  century.  France  put  a  uni- 
versal male  suffrage  act  on  the  statute  books  in  1848,  being  the  first 
major  European  state  to  do  so.  The  law  was  never  repealed,  though 
under  Louis  Napoleon  and  the  Second  Empire  the  representatives  elected 
by  the  people  had  little  actual  power  in  law-making.  The  German  Em- 
pire provided  for  universal  manhood  suffrage  in  1871.  This  applied  to 
elections  to  the  Reichstag;  but  the  aristocratic  Bundesrat  was  more 
powerful  than  the  Reichstag,  and  the  aristocratic  government  of  Prussia 
dominated  the  empire  as  a  whole.  The  failure  to  recast  the  electoral  dis- 
tricts between  1871  and  1918  also  tended  to  frustrate  democracy  and 
representative  government. 

In  Austria-Hungary,  representative  government  was  assured  by  the 
Constitution  of  1861  and  the  legislation  governing  the  union  with  Hun- 
gary in  1867.  Universal  manhood  suffrage  was  secured  through  acts  of 
1896  and  1907.  Cavour  saw  to  it  that  representative  government  was 
created  in  Italy,  and  universal  manhood  suffrage  was  provided  for  in 


272  DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY 

laws  of  1882  and  1912.  The  lesser  European  states  provided  for  universal 
suffrage  late  in  the  nineteenth  century  or  early  in  the  twentieth. 

Russia  has  never  enjoyed  universal  suffrage.  The  Tsars  excluded  the 
masses  from  the  right  to  vote,  and  the  Bolsheviks  denied  the  right  of 
suffrage  to  the  aristocracy  and  the  capitalistic  classes.  Since,  however, 
the  aristocrats  and  capitalists  were  either  killed  off  or  driven  out  of 
Russia,  there  has  been  universal  suffrage  in  actual  practice  in  the  Soviet 
Union. 

In  Europe  the  growth  of  democratic  ideals  and  practices  depended  pri- 
marily upon  the  growth  of  industrialism  and  the  rise  of  an  urban  pro- 
letariat. In  the  United  States,  the  impulses  coming  from  the  proletariat 
were  very  powerfully  supplemented  by  the  influence  of  the  western 
frontier  upon  political  ideals.  Because  of  the  two  major  forces  making 
for  democracy  in  our  country,  democratic  developments  here  were  rather 
more  rapid  and  sweeping  than  in  the  Old  World.  Political  democracy 
was  thoroughly  realized  in  the  United  States,  at  least  in  a  legal  sense,, 
by  the  middle  of  the  nineteenth  century.  In  the  first  half  of  the  century 
the  main  achievements  consisted  in  the  abolition  of  the  aristocratic  prop- 
erty qualifications  for  the  exercise  of  the  suffrage,  the  termination  of 
imprisonment  for  debt,  and  the  popularization  of  the  concepts  and  prac- 
tices of  democracy  as  a  result  of  the  Jacksonian  system. 

The  political  theories  of  men  like  Jefferson  still  had  a  strong  Aristotelian^ 
flavor  and  they  laid  great  emphasis  upon  special  training,  high  intelli- 
gence, and  expert  direction  of  government.  With  the  advent  of  the; 
Jacksonians  in  1829,  the  "dangers"  of  special  preparation  for  office  were^ 
emphasized  and  supreme  faith  was  placed  in  "pure"  democracy.  Rota- 
tion in  office  and  the  "spoils  system"  became  characteristic  of  adminis- 
trative procedure.  Whatever  the  excesses  of  the  Jacksonians,  this  period1 
deserves  credit  for  the  institution  of  political  democracy  in  the  United! 
States.  The  Jacksonian  democrats  also  believed  in  the  equality  of  man, 
and  they  wiped  away  what  had  hitherto  been  powerful  vestiges  of  social 
aristocracy.  By  1840,  the  United  States  had  become  a  political  democ- 
racy, before  any  other  major  state  in  the  world. 

'  The  scandals  of  the  "spoils  system"  were  curbed  by  the  civil-service 
reform  begun  in  the  administrations  of  Grant,  Hayes,  and  Arthur  and 
supported  by  Cleveland,  particularly  in  his  second  term.  Though  it  was 
weakened  somewhat  by  McKinley,  it  was  revived  with  renewed  vigor 
by  Theodore  Roosevelt  and  Taft  and  has  been  extended  since  the  first 
World  War. 

A  powerful  impulse  to  democracy  in  the  latter  part  of  the  nineteenth 
century  came  as  a  result  of  the  various  radical  movements  which  sprang 
up  mainly  in  the  West  among  the  depressed  and  embattled  farmers.  Such 
were  the  Greenback,  Granger,  and  Populist  movements,  and  the  Bryan 
democracy,  which  was  strongly  supported  by  the  workers  in  the  East. 
In  these  movements  began  the  tendency  to  subject  private  corporations, 
especially  railroads,  to  public  control.  More  liberal  taxation  and  cur- 
rency policies  also  arose.  With  the  end  of  the  frontier,  in  1890,  rural 


DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY  273 

western  radicalism  began  to  decline,  but  it  left  a  heritage  that  remained 
for  a  generation  or  more.  It  gave  vigorous  support  to  Senator  La  Follette 
as  late  as  his  presidential  campaign  of  1924.  The  Eastern  workers  have 
developed  several  proletarian  political  movements  of  a  radically  demo- 
cratic character.  Such  are  the  Socialist  party,  the  Socialist-Labor  party, 
and  the  Communist  party.  Of  these  the  Socialist  party,  led  by  Eugene 
Victor  Debs,  and  Norman  Thomas,  was  for  long  the  most  important.  As 
we  noted  in  the  preceding  chapter,  these  third-party  movements  left  their 
main  permanent  impress  upon  American  political  life  by  forcing  the 
major  parties  to  adopt  some  of  their  radical  ideals  and  policies.  We  have 
already  mentioned  some  of  the  more  radical  democratic  devices,  such  as 
the  initiative,  referendum,  and  direct  primaries  in  dealing  with  attempted 
reforms  of  party  government. 

One  great  obstacle  to  social  democracy  in  America — Negro  slavery — 
was  removed  in  part  as  a  result  of  the  Civil  War.  But  because  of  race 
prejudice,  final  solution  of  the  Negro  question  is  not  likely  to  be  reached 
for  another  century.  The  strength  of  the  Progressive  party  in  1912  and 
the  victory  of  the  Democratic  party  in  1912,  1916,  1932  and  later  may  be 
regarded  as  gains  for  social  democracy.  They  were  symptoms  of  popular 
protest  against  the  domination  of  American  politics  and  legislation  by 
the  conservative  wing  of  the  capitalistic  class  that  arose  after  the  retire- 
ment of  President  Theodore  Roosevelt,  and  again  after  the  liberalism 
of  President  Wilson  had  collapsed. 

Unfortunately,  the  decline  of  morale  and  intellectual  alertness  in  the 
United  States  after  the  first  World  War  led  to  a  reign  of  the  corrupt 
plutocratic  interests  quite  unprecedented  in  our  national  history,  if  not  in 
the  whole- history  of  representative  government.  The  effort  of  the  late 
Senator  La  Follette  to  lead  the  people  in  a  crusade  against  this  national 
disgrace  in  1924  proved  a  humiliating  and  portentous  failure.  The  great 
economic  depression  beginning  in  1929  stimulated  a  revival  of  idealism 
and  progressivism. 

The  notable  achievements  all  too  briefly  enumerated  above  have  con- 
stituted great  strides  in  the  direction  of  political  democracy.  But  they 
have  left  still  unsolved  many  grave  problems  that  must  be  met  and 
conquered  before  democracy  can  be  finally  achieved.  Universal  suffrage 
and  representative  government  have  made  political  democracy  possible 
but  have  not  by  any  means  assured  its  existence.  As  Lord  Bryce  and 
Robert  Michels  have  well  pointed  out,  the  political  boss  is  as  much  an 
obstacle  to  democracy  as  was  the  feudal  lord  to  democratic  tendencies  in 
the  medieval  period.  Attempts  have  been  made,  which  are  as  yet  only 
partially  successful,  to  eliminate  his  sinister  influence  through  such  de- 
vices as  the  direct  primary  and'  the  civil-service  laws.  Archaic  forms  of 
political  institutions  are  often;  found  unsuited  to  achieve  the  desires  and 
needs  of  the  people.  Such  machinery  as  the  initiative,  the  referendum, 
and  the  recall  has  beerr  introduced  in  the  hope  ofc  making  government 
more  sensitive  and  Hflore  responsive  to  the  public  will. 

Many  of  the  pfioftlema  related,  ta  the  operation- afi  representative  insti- 


274  DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY 

tutions>are  yet  to  be  solved.  To  meet  this  need  such  schemes  as  minority 
and  proportional  representation  and  representation  of  occupational  groups 
have  been  proposed.  Then,  Sumner,  Hobhouse,  and  other  more  recent 
-publicists,  like  Norman  Angell  and  Frederick  Schuman,  have  reminded 
the  world  that  most  difficult  and  perplexing  problems  are  involved  in 
reconciling  political  democracy  at  home  with  the  repression  of  subject 
peoples  in  imperial  dominions. 

Finally,  no  one  can  seriously  maintain  that  social  and  economic  democ- 
racy exists  when  we  have  to  face  such  economic  and  social  inequalities  as 
are  revealed  in  the  sober  and  reliable  statistics  gathered  by  every  great 
modern  nation.  It  is  not  desirable  that  society  should  permanently  adopt 
any  method  of  determining  social  and  economic  reward,  other  than  that 
based  upon  services  rendered  to  society.  However,  the  prevailing  meth- 
ods of  deciding  the  value  of  services  are  sadly  in  need  of  revision,  partic- 
ularly in  the  direction  of  preventing  rewards  from  being  inherited  instead 
of  earned.  Further,  we  have  yet  to  make  sure  that  all  members  of  society, 
in  proportion  to  their  innate  ability,  shall  obtain  equal  opportunity  and 
reward  for  rendering  services  to  society. 

Real  and  practical  obstacles  to  democracy  are  the  rise  of  Fascism  and 
Communism,  and  the  growing  popularity  of  government  by  dictatorship. 
Whether  in  Germany,  in  Italy,  or  in  Russia,  dictatorship  has  appeared 
more  immediately  efficient  than  democracy.  The  strains  and  stresses  of 
the  world  in  the  economic  depression  have  made  many  persons  more 
impatient  of  the  relatively  inefficient  and  easy-going  ways  of  democracy. 
The  whole  social  set-up  today,  at  least  superficially,  seems  to  encourage 
the  propaganda  in  favor  of  Fascism  and  dictatorial  government. 

The  second  World  War  was  bound  to  deliver  a  heavy  blow  to  democ- 
racy. The  small  European  democracies  were  brought  within  totalitarian 
dominion.  Unoccupied  France  rapidly  put  off  her  democracy  in  favor  of 
totalitarianism.  England  adopted  wartime  totalitarianism,  in  order  to 
defend  herself  efficiently.  It  became  quite  obvious  that  the  restoration 
of  democracy  as  it  was  in  1938  would  be  difficult,  if  at  all  possible.  Even 
for  the  United  States,  the  prospect  was  not  too  bright.  As  William  Henry 
'Chamberlin  in  The  American  Mercury,  December,  1940,  put  it: 

It  is  a  familiar  teaching  of  history  that  men  learn  nothing  from  the  observation 
of  the  past.  Yet  America's  experience  in  the  World  War  is  surely  recent  enough 
to  afford  some  useful  guidance.  The  Dead  Sea  fruits  of  America/s  first  crusade 
to  make  the  world  safe  for  demqcracy  were  communism  and  fascism.  A  second 
crusade,  which  would  have  to  be  on  a  much  larger  scale  because  America  would 
have  fewer  allies,  could  have,  I  think,  only  one  certain  result:  the  definite  and 
perhaps  permanent  disappearance  of  liberalism  in  America. 

Some  Major  Assumptions  of  Democracy  in  the  Light 
of  Their  Historical   Background 

The  assumptions  of  the  democratic  movement  must  be  considered  in  the 
light  of  the  political  institutions  and  scientific  knowledge  between  fifty 
and  a  hundred  years  ago,  as  well  as  in  terms  of  the  political  experience 


DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY  275 

and  scientific  data  available  today.  Certain  premises  now  discredited 
might,  at  an  earlier  period,  have  been  legitimately  entertained  by  those 
not  in  possession  of  our  present  political  experience  or  our  contemporary 
scientific  knowledge  concerning  man  and  society. 

The  early  protagonists  of  democracy  assumed  the  essential  permanence 
of  a  simple  agrarian  type  of  society.  Jefferson  himself,  scarcely  a  de- 
fender of  any  extreme  type  of  democracy,  believed  that  even  republican 
government  could  coexist  only  with  a  society  founded  on  an  agricultural 
basis:  "I  think  our  governments  will  remain  virtuous  for  many  cen- 
turies ...  as  long  as  there  shall  be  vacant  lands  in  any  part  of  America. 
When  they  get  piled  upon  one  another  in  large  cities,  as  in  Europe,  they 
will  become  as  corrupt  as  in  Europe." 2 

Hence  we  can  scarcely  condemn  the  original  sponsors  of  democracy  if 
the  system  which  they  promulgated  has  failed  to  prove  adequate  to  prob- 
lems forced  upon  it  by  the  complex  urban  and  industrial  civilization  of 
the  present  day.  To  be  sure,  this  qualification  does  not  necessarily 
prove  that  democracy  would  have  been  fully  successful,  even  if  society 
had  remained  agricultural  in  character. 

Another  assumption  was  the  laissez-faire  theory  of  government.  Most 
of  the  earlier  exponents  of  democracy,  including  Godwin,  Jefferson,  Cob- 
den,  and  the  German  liberals  of  1848,  held  that  the  best  government  is 
the  one  that  governs  least.  One  exception,  however,  was  the  socialistic 
drive  for  democracy  and  universal  suffrage  under  such  leaders  as  Ferdi- 
nand Lassalle,  who  frankly  repudiated  the  laissez-faire  ideal.  There  also 
were  exceptions  to  Jefferson's  individualism,  as  there  were  to  his  strict 
constructionism  in  constitutional  theory,  but  he  certainly  believed  that 
there  should  be  no  more  governmental  intervention  than  absolutely  neces- 
sary. He  once  went  so  far  as  to  say  that  a  free  press  is  worth  more 
than  any  government. 

There  were  differences  of  opinion  among  Jacksonians,  but  the  Jack- 
sonian  era,  as  a  whole,  witnessed  a  retrenchment  of  the  public  activities 
sponsored  by  the  Whigs — especially  the  support  of  internal  improvements. 
The  tariff  was  progressively  lowered.  The  United  States  Bank  was 
brought  to  an  end.  Federal  aid  to  public  improvements  was  withdrawn, 
and  federal  loans  to  the  states  became  less  lavish.  It  was  the  Jacksonians 
who  prevented  public  control  or  ownership  of  transportation  facilities, 
such  as  developed  widely  in  Europe.  In  its  germinal  period,  democracy 
was  closely  intertwined  with  political  individualism.  It  will  be  con- 
ceded by  most  historians  that  a  form  of  government  that  was  successful 
under  a  Spencerian  brand  of  individualism  would  be  far  less  efficient  in 
a  society  dominated  by  ideals  of  extensive  state  interference. 

A  central  thesis  of  the  supporters  of  political  democracy  was  the  firm 
belief  in  the  essential  equality  of  all  men,  the  observed  existing  differences 
being  assigned  to  inequalities  of  opportunity.  The  earlier  American 


2  Thomas  Jefferson,   Writings,  ed.  by  Paul  Leicester  Ford,  Putnam,   1892-1899, 
10  vols.,  Vol.  IV.,  pp.  47&-480. 


276  DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY 

friends  of  a  more  liberal  or  republican  political  system  did  not  believe 
in  the  equality  of  man,  however  much  they  may  have  subscribed  to  the 
formal  equality  of  all  before  the  law  or  the  theological  equality  before 
God.  Jefferson,  for  example,  actually  accepted  with  minor  qualifications 
the  Aristotelian  dogma  that  some  are  born  to  rule  and  others  to  serve.  He 
only  believed  that  the  people  could  be  trusted  to  choose  the  wisest  men 
to  lead  them.  His  own  experience  seemed  to  vindicate  his  judgment,  for 
the  people  turned  out  his  aristocratic  opponents,  the  Federalists,  and 
elected  him,  and  then  his  disciples  Madison  and  Monroe  for  two  terms 
each.  The  Sage  of  Monticello  joined  his  "fathers"  just  after  Monroe  had 
been  succeeded  by  the  son  of  Jefferson's  old  Federalist  rival.  Jefferson's 
conception  of  the  natural  aristocracy  that  should  rule  society  is  well 
stated  in  the  following  passage  from  a  letter  to  John  Adams,  written  in 
1813; 

For  I  agree  with  you  that  there  is  a  liatural  aristocracy  among  men.  The 
grounds  of  this  are  virtue  and  talents.  Formerly  bodily  powers  gave  place  among 
the  aristoi.  But  since  the  invention  of  gunpowder  has  armed  the  weak  as  well 
as  the  strong  with  missile  death,  bodily  strength,  like  beauty,  good  humor,  polite- 
ness and  other  accomplishments,  has  become  but  an  auxiliary  ground  for  distinc- 
tion. There  is  also  an  artificial  artistocracy,  founded  on  wealth  and  birth,  with- 
out either  virtue  or  talents ;  for  with  these  it  would  belong  to  the  first  class.  The 
natural  aristocracy  I  consider  as  the  most  precious  gift  of  nature,  for  the  instruc- 
tion, the  trusts,  and  government  of  society.  And  indeed  it  would  have  been 
inconsistent  in  creation  to  have  formed  man  for  the  social  state,  and  not  to 
have  provided  virtue  and  wisdom  enough  to  manage  the  concerns  of  society. 
May  we  not  even  say,  that  that  form  of  government  is  the  best,  which  provides 
the  most  effectually  for  a  pure  selection  of  these  natural  aristoi  into  the  offices 
of  government  ?  The  artificial  aristocracy  is  a  mischievous  ingredient  in  govern- 
ment, and  provision  should  be  made  to  prevent  its  ascendency.3 

The  "honest-to-God"  democrats  of  the  Jacksonian  and  post-Jacksonian 
period,  however,  believed,  or  pretended  to  believe,  that  all  men  are  essen- 
tially equal  in  ability,  and  hence  are  uniformly  and  equally  fitted  to  cast 
their  votes.  It  was  also  held  that  no  special  training  or  experience  is 
essential  to  the  successful  execution  of  the  functions  of  any  political  office. 
Indeed,  some  of  the  Jacksonians  even  declared  that  a  long  and  successful 
career  in  office  is  a  serious  disqualification  for  political  life,  on  account 
of  the  potential  development  of  the  bureaucratic  spirit.  It  was  held  that 
a  general  system  of  education,  open  to  all,  would  produce  almost  complete 
cultural  and  intellectual  uniformity  in  society.  Hence  the  democratic 
movement  was  associated  with  a  strong  impetus  to  popular  education. 

The  theory  of  human  equality  and  the  equal  fitness  of  all  to  hold  office 
was  not  then  so  absurd  as  it  has  now  become,  as  a  result  of  our  differential 
psychology  and  the  complicated  nature  of  governmental  problems.  Par- 
ticularly in  the  frontier  society  of  Jackson's  day,  there  was  a  much 
closer  approximation  to  equality  than  in  most  modern  societies.  Severe 
selective  processes  made  the  surviving  frontier  settlers  relatively  uniform 


3  Jefferson,  op.  cit.,  Vol.  IX,  p.  425. 


DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY  277 

in  ability.  A  man  who  could  weather  the  dangers  and  hardships  of  west- 
ward migration,  and  contend  successfully  against  Indians  and  wild  beasts 
after  settling  on  the  frontier,  was  likely  to  be  able  to  shoulder  the  rela- 
tively simple  responsibilities  of  government  that  prevailed  in  these  areas. 

The  exponents  of  democratic  theory  also  believed  that  the  mass  of 
the  people  would  take  a  very  ardent  interest  in  all  phases  of  political  life, 
once  the  right  to  vote  was  extended  to  them.  It  was  believed  and  hoped 
that  the  people  would  veritably  mob  the  polls  at  daybreak  on  each  election 
morning,  in  order  to  exercise  the  God-given  privilege  of  casting  their 
ballots.  This  assumption  was  not  so  absurd  a  century  ago,  when  most 
of  the  functions  of  government  were  related  to  local  needs  and  the  daily 
life  of  the  people. 

Associated  with  this  premise  of  universal  interest  in  using  the  ballot  was 
the  crucial  hypothesis  that  the  people  would  carefully  examine  both 
candidates  and  policies,  size  up  all  political  situations,  and  then  register 
a  choice  based  upon  careful  reflection  on  all  the  salient  facts  available. 
Political  campaigns,  in  short,  were  expected  to  be  periods  of  intensive 
adult  education  in  the  field  of  public  affairs. 

The  democratic  dogmas  were  formulated  when  the  popular  type  of 
psychology  was  the  so-called  Benthamite  "felicific  calculus."  This  as- 
sumed that  man  is  a  cool  and  eminently  deliberative  animal  who  bases 
every  act  upon  the  relative  amount  of  pleasure  to  be  secured  and  the  pain 
to  be  avoided.  He  would  support  the  candidate  and  party  which  he 
believed  would  bring  him  the  greatest  benefits.  This  rationalistic  psy- 
chology dominated  political  thinking  from  Bentham  to  Bryce,  and  was 
not  thoroughly  laid  at  rest  until  the  appearance  of  Graham  Wallas's 
Human  Nature  in  Politics  in  1908.  This  view  was  not  so  ridiculous 
before  scientific  psychology  proved  the  fundamentally  nonrational  nature 
of  human  and  group  behavior. 

Some  appeared  to  mistrust  the  administrative  efficiency  of  democracy 
and  the  rational  qualities  of  the  masses,  but  believed  that,  even  if  the 
people  are  incapable  of  analytical  reasoning,  at  least  they  are  sensitive 
to  moral  issues ;  that  they  can  be  trusted  far  more  than  the  educated  and 
capable  minority  to  sense  injustice  and  promote  idealistic  causes.  As 
evidence  were  cited  the  popular  support  of  the  Abolitionist  movement 
against  slavery  and,  more  recently,  the  alleged  democratic  basis  of  the 
Prohibition  movement. 

The  democratic  theory  was  formulated,  for  the  most  part,  with  the 
exception  of  the  work  of  the  socialists,  in  an  age  that  held  to  the  theory 
of  political  determinism  in  history.  It  was  believed  that  political  insti- 
tutions are  of  basic  importance  in  social  causation  and  that  a  political 
system  could  determine  the  whole  character  of  civilization.  Majority 
rule  would  produce  a  completely  democratic  society. 

Madison,  Calhoun,  and  a  few  others  held  that  government  is  merely 
the  umpire  of  conflicting  social  and  economic  interests.  Jeffersonians 
and  the  agrarians  also  implied  that  politics  depends  upon  economics, 
when  they  held  that  an  agricultural  society  was  essential  to  the  success 


278  DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY 

of  republican  government.  But  the  general  tendency  of  the  age  was  to 
put  complete  trust  in  the  political  structure  of  society.  The  crusade 
for  universal  suffrage  and  democracy  was  based  mainly  upon  that  notion. 
The  ideas  and  program  of  the  English  Chartists  are  a  good  illustration 
of  this  attitude. 

The  democratic  theory  was  also  worked  out  in  harmony  with  the 
philosophy  of  unmitigated  nationalism,  with  little  consideration  for 
political  tendencies  abroad  or  the  state  of  international  relations.  Demo- 
cratic dogma  was  not  unique  in  this  respect,  for  the  nationalistic  obsession 
dominated  the  outlook  of  monarchs  and  aristocrats  as  well  at  this  time. 

Democracy  Put  to  the  Test 

Striking  and  extensive  have  been  the  changes  in  the  social  setting  of 
political  institutions  since  the  days  of  the  quasi-bucolic  New  England 
township  of  John  Quincy  Adams  and  the  crude  frontier  society  of 
Jackson.  We  have  now  our  urban  industrial  world  civilization,  which 
presents  an  ever  increasing  variety  of  conditions  that  must  be  regulated 
in  some  degree  by  political  action.  The  whole  set-up  of  life  conditions 
that  lay  back  of  the  democratic  movement  has  all  but  disappeared.  In 
the  words  of  Will  Durant: 

All  those  conditions  are  gone.  National  isolation  has  gone,  because  of  trade, 
communication,  and  the  invention  of  destructive  mechanisms  that  facilitate  inva- 
sion. Personal  isolation  is  gone,  because  of  the  growing  interdependence  of  pro- 
ducer, distributor,  and  consumer.  Skilled  labor  is  the  exception  now  that 
machines  are  made  to  operate  machines,  and  scientific  management  reduces  skill 
to  the  inhuman  stupidity  of  routine.  Free  land  is  gone,  and  tenancy  increases. 
Free  competition  decays;  it  may  survive  for  a  time  in  new  fields  like  the  auto- 
mobile industry,  but  everywhere  it  gravitates  towards  monopoly.  The  once 
independent  shopkeeper  is  in  the  toils  of  the  big  distributor;  he  yields  to  chain 
drug  stores,  chain  cigar  stores,  chain  groceries,  chain  candy  stores,  chain  restau- 
rants, chain  theaters — everything  is  in  chains.  Even  the  editor  who  owns  his 
own  paper  and  molds  his  own  mendacity  is  a  vestigial  remnant  now,  when  a 
thousand  sheets  across  the  country  tell  the  same  lie  in  the  same  way  every  day 
better  and  better.  An  ever  decreasing  proportion  of  business  executives  (and 
among  them  an  ever  decreasing  number  of  bankers  and  directors)  controls  the 
lives  and  labors  of  an  ever  increasing  proportion  of  men.  A  new  aristocracy  is 
forming  out  of  the  once  rebellious  bourgeoisie;  equality  and  liberty  and  brother- 
hood are  no  longer  the  darlings  of  the  financiers.  Economic  freedom,  even  in 
the  middle  classes,  becomes  rarer  and  narrower  every  year.  In  a  world  from 
which  freedom  of  competition,  equality  of  opportunity,  and  social  fraternity  have 
disappeared,  political  equality  is  worthless,  and  democracy  becomes  a  sham.4 

The  laissez-faire  theory  of  political  inactivity  has  given  way  before 
differing  degrees  of  state  intervention,  extending  all  the  way  to  overt  state 
socialism.  Even  in  the  United  States,  with  its  theoretical  individualistic 
philosophy,  a  degree  of  state  activity  was  accepted  that  would  have  filled 
Jefferson  with  greatest  alarm.  Modern  life  has  created  a  host  of  issues 


"Is  Democracy  a  Failure?"  Haiyer's,  October,  1926,  p.  557. 


DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY  279 

that  not  even  a  plutocratic  and  individualistic  political  organization  can 
ignore. 

Modern  biology  and  psychology  have  revealed  the  presence  of  marked 
individual  differences  of  ability  on  the  part  of  those  inhabiting  the  same 
community.  The  army  mental  tests  given  in  1917-1918,  which  covered 
the  unusually  large  and  representative  sample  of  1,700,000  recruits,5 
showed  that  only  about  13  per  cent  of  the  population  can  be  described  as 
superior  types  capable  of  distinguished  leadership.  The  majority  range 
from  intellectual  mediocrity  to  relative  incompetence.  Forty-five  per 
cent  have  a  mental  age  of  twelve  or  under,  once  regarded  as  sure  proof  of 
feeble-mindedness.  To  be  sure,  the  leaders  still,  on  occasion,  guide  the 
masses,  even  in  a  democracy;  but  we  cannot  expect  to  secure  sagacity  or 
wisdom  merely  by  counting  noses. 

Many  writers,  like  the  late  Charles  Horton  Cooley,  contend  that  the 
masses  possess  great  innate  shrewdness  in  selecting  their  leaders.  This 
thesis  is  hardly  borne  out  by  the  selection  of  presidents  of  the  United 
States  since  the  Jacksonian  period.  The  outstanding  ones — Lincoln, 
Cleveland,  the  two  Roosevelts,  and  Wilson — were  all  chosen  as  the  result 
of  an  accident,  a  political  fluke,  or  a  special  economic  crisis.  Herbert 
Agar  has  stressed  this  point  in  his  book  The  People's  Choice. 

Differential  biology  and  psychology  have  shown  that,  to  cope  with  the 
difficult  problems  of  today,  we  must  install  in  government  the  superior 
types  equipped  with  expert  knowledge,  and  not  trust  the  judgments  of 
the  common  people.  The  available  data  seem  to  justify  restriction  of 
the  suffrage  to  those  above  the  moron  level  or  a  weighted  system  in  which 
additional  voting  power  would  be  assigned  to  those  with  superior  intelli- 
gence quotients.  Men  of  high  intelligence  are  not  necessarily  always 
equipped  with  superior  social  morality  or  civil  idealism;  but  neither  are 
the  less  intelligent  any  more  endowed  with  these  qualities  than  with  in- 
tellectual talent.  Stupidity  and  integrity  are  certainly  not  inseparable. 
Certainly,  the  control  of  politics  must  be  associated  with  intelligence  and 
cogent  information.  The  solution  lies  in  socializing  the  elite,  not  in  defy- 
ing or  denouncing  intelligence. 

Most  political  posts  today  require  of  the  incumbent  a  technical  knowl- 
edge as  great  as  that  possessed  by  a  distinguished  economist,  technician, 
physican,  or  law  professor.  Yet,  as  Durant  has  well  said,  we  require 
much  more  technical  preparation  for  a  physician  or  druggist  than  we 
insist  upon  for  a  Congressman,  a  governor,  or  even  a  President: 

The  evil  of  modern  democracy  is  in  the  politician  and  at  the  point  of  nomina- 
tion. Let  us  eliminate  the  politicians  and  the  nomination. 

Originally,  no  doubt,  every  man  was  his  own  physician,  and  every  household 
prescribed  its  own  drugs.  But  as  medical  knowledge  accumulated  and  the 
corpus  prescriptionum  grew,  it  became  impossible  for  the  average  individual, 
even  for  solicitous  spinsters,  to  keep  pace  with  the  pharmacopoeia.  A  special 
class  of  persons  arose  who  gave  all  their  serious  hours  to  the  study  of  materia 

5Cf.  E.  G.  Boring,  "Intelligence  as  the  Tests  Test  It,"  New  Republic,  June  6, 
1923. 


280  DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY 

medica,  and  became  professional  physicians.  To  protect  the  people  from  un- 
trained practitioners,  and  from  those  sedulous  neighbors  who  have  an  interne's 
passion  for  experiment,  a  distinguished  title  and  a  reassuring  degree  were  given 
to  those  who  had  completed  this  preparation.  The  process  has  now  reached  the 
point  where  it  is  illegal  to  prescribe  medicines  unless  one  has  received  such  train- 
ing, and  such  a  degree,  from  a  recognized  institution.  We  no  longer  permit 
unprepared  individuals  to  deal  with  our  individual  ailments  or  to  risk  our 
individual  lives.  We  demand  a  lifetime's  devotion  as  a  preliminary  to  the  pre- 
scription of  pills. 

But  of  those  who  deal  with  our  incorporated  ills,  and  risk  our  hundred  million 
lives  in  peace  and  war,  and  have  at  their  beck  and  call  all  our  possessions  and  all 
our  liberties,  no  specific  preparation  is  required;  it  is  sufficient  if  they  are 
friends  of  the  Chief,  loyal  to  the  Organization,  handsome  or  suave,  hand-shakers, 
shotilder-slappers,  or  baby-kissers,  taking  orders  quietly,  and  as  rich  in  promises 
as  a  weather  bureau.  For  the  rest,  they  muy  have  been  butchers  or  barbers, 
rural  lawyers  or  editors,  pork-packers  or  saloon-keepers — it  makes  no  difference. 
If  they  have  had  the  good  sense  to  be  born  in  log  cabins  it  is  conceded  that 
they  have  a  divine  right  to  be  President.6 

We  can  provide  expert  guidance  for  ignorant  legislators  and  adminis- 
trators, but  some  modicum  of  education  is  essential  in  order  to  utilize 
expert  advice  with  any  competence  when  it  is  offered.  If  a  governmental 
official  becomes  merely  a  rubber  stamp  in  the  hands  of  his  expert  advisers, 
we  have  bureaucracy  instead  of  democracy.  The  average  Congressman 
or  state  legislator  can  decide  whether  or  not  a  new  plank  should  be  added 
to  a  bridge  or  whether  a  common  pound  should  be  repaired;  but  it  is 
impossible  for  an  untrained  man  to  exercise  expert  judgment  with  respect 
to  international  financial  problems,  the  tariff,  government  control  of  rail- 
roads, state  ownership  of  coal  mines,  public  health,  monopoly,  or  the 
regulation  of  radios  and  airplane  traffic.  The  day  is  over  when  govern- 
ment can  be  conducted  by  rule  of  thumb,  the  rhetorical  canons  of  Isocrates 
or  Quintilian,  or  the  spicy  parliamentary  repartee  of  seasoned  politicians. 
Democracy  cannot  be  "wisecracked"  out  of  its  current  difficulties. 

While  the  problems  requiring  government  control  or  supervision  have 
become  more  numerous  and  complex,  the  quality  of  our  public  officials 
has  declined.  Without  sharing  in  a  conventional  and  unthinking  eulogy 
of  tjie  "Fathers,"  no  informed  person  could  well  suggest  that  the  caliber  of 
our  public  servants  today  matches  that  of  officials  in  the  period  from  1790 
to  1828.  In  the  last  half-century  an  important  transformation  took 
place  in  American  political  practice,  as  a  result  of  which  we  seemingly  no 
longer  desire  or  expect  real  leadership  in  government.  The  great  eco- 
nomic interests,  for  all  practical  purposes,  took  over  the  government. 
Men  of  great  personal  ability,  real  dignity,  wide  learning,  and  inde- 
pendence of  character — even  if  conservative — were  no  longer  wanted  in 
political  offices,  for  such  persons  do  not  invariably  take  and  carry  out 
orders  with  complete  servility. 

These  considerations  may  explain  why  the  business  interests  were  long 
highly  suspicious  of  an  able  conservative  like  Herbert  Hoover;  and  why 


6Durant,  loc.  dt.,  p.  563. 


DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY 


281 


a  conservative  if  occasionally  independent  and  outspoken  scholar  like 
Nicholas  Murray  Butler  was  not  looked  upon  with  favor  by  the  business 
interests  as  presidential  material. 

Yet,  government  by  the  interests  is  not  so  simple  as  some  seem  to 
believe.  There  is  highly  divided  counsel  in  the  orders  given  to  their 
political  servants,  owing  to  the  diversification  and  conflict  of  economic 
policies  among  the  capitalists.  For  example,  international  bankers  want 
free  trade,  so  that  their  foreign  debtors  can  pay  in  goods,  while  indus- 
trialists favor  high  tariffs  to  protect  them  against  foreign  competition. 
Industrialists  may  desire  moderate  inflation  to  stimulate  business;  the 
main  powers  in  speculative  finance  usually  want  "sound  money"  to  insure 
full  payment  of  debts  due  them. 

Perhaps  the  chief  service  of  the  democratic  illusion,  at  present,  is  that 
it  enables  countries  such  as  the  United  States  to  operate  this  "bellhop" 
system  of  government  successfully  and  yet  keep  the  people  reasonably 
well  satisfied,  by  means  of  the  agreeable  fiction  that  they  themselves  are 
running  matters  through  their  elected  representatives.  However,  this 
artifice  does  not  constitute  any  permanent  solution  of  the  problems  of 
contemporary  political  control.  Cunningly  contrived  plutocracy  is  no 
suitable  substitute  for  democracy. 

The  old  assumption  that  the  masses  would  evince  an  all-absorbing 
interest  in  public  matters  the  moment  that  they  received  the  vote  has  been 
dissipated  by  political  experience  since  1828.  Studies  of  nonvoting  in  the 
United  States  by  Merriam,  Gosnell,  Schlesinger,  Eriksson,  and  others  show 
that,  even  in  presidential  elections  which  evoke  the  most  widespread 
interest,  only  about  half  of  the  qualified  voters  cast  ballots.  The  follow- 
ing statistics  illustrate  what  Professors  Schlesinger  and  Eriksson  well 
designate  as  "the  vanishing  voter": 


UNITED  STATES  ELECTION  DATA 

Year  Actual  Vote  Eligible  Vote 

1856  4,194,088  5,021,956 

1860  4,676,853  5,555,004 

1864 4,024,792  4,743,249 

1868  5,724,686  7,208,164 

1872  6,466,165  8,633,058 

1876  8,412,733  9,799,450 

1880  9,209,406  11,024,900 

1884  10,044,985  12,412,538 

1888  11,380,860  13,800,176 

1892  12,059,351  15,488,748 

1896  13,923,102  17,241,642 

1900  13,959,653  18,272,264 

1904 13,510,648  19,864,495 

1908  14,888,442  21,598,493 

1912  15,036,542  24,276,236 

1916  18,544,579  28,484,046 

1920  26,786,758  51,156,684 

1924  29,091,492  54,421,832 

1928  36,876,419  57,276,321 

1932  39,734,351  60,389,827 

1936  45,646,817 

1940  49,569,165 


Percentage  Voting 
83.51 
84.19 
84.8$ 
79.42 
74.90 
85.84 
83.53 
80.92 
82.46 
77.85 
80.75 
76.39 
68.00 
68.93 
61.95 
65.10 
52.36 
53.45 
63.86 
65.13 


282  DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY 

Even  the  excitement  of  the  first  opportunity  to  vote  did  not  bring  the 
expected  number  of  women  to  the  polls  in  1920,  their  record  apparently 
being  even  worse  than  that  of  the  men.  The  intense  economic  stake  of 
the  masses  in  the  New  Deal  did,  however,  lead  to  a  marked  increase  in 
the  turn-out  of  the  voters  to  re-elect  Franklin  D.  Roosevelt  in  1936 
and  1940.  The  vote  in  state  and  local  elections  and  in  congressional 
elections  in  "off  years"  is  far  smaller  than  in  presidential  contests.  The 
popular  vote  in  direct  primaries,  which  select  the  candidates  for  election, 
has  proved  so  small  as  often  to  make  the  whole  scheme  of  primaries,  once 
a  favorite  reform  hope,  a  travesty.  Those  plebiscites  in  which  important 
issues  are  submitted  to  the  people  in  the  form  of  the  referendum  seem 
to  evoke  less  enthusiastic  response  than  the  election  of  officials. 

The  distant,  large-scale,  and  complicated  nature  of  contemporary  poli- 
tics has  destroyed  that  sense  of  immediate  local  interest  and  that  per- 
sonal curiosity  about  candidates  which  were  characteristic  of  the  earlier 
type  of  neighborhood  politics.  A  sense  of  political  vagueness  and  futility 
has  today  superseded  the  once  keen  personal  interest  in  policies  that 
directly  and  visibly  concerned  the  everyday  life  of  the  individual,  and  in 
candidates  who  were  personal  acquaintances  of  most  of  the  voters. 
Political  indifference  is  also  due  to  the  cynicism  generated  by  the  un- 
reality of  modern  partisan  politics  and  the  accompanying  graft  and 
incompetence.  Sophisticated  voters  feel  that  it  makes  little  or  no  dif- 
ference which  party  or  policy  prevails.  The  seeming  absence  of  vital 
differences,  between  major  party  methods  and  policies  has  become  essen- 
tially the  fact  in  American  political  life  today.  This  state  of  affairs 
refutes  the  thesis  that  representative  government  is  always  bound  to 
create  parties  with  marked  differences  as  to  policy  and  procedure. 

A  disconcerting  aspect  of  the  democratic  debacle  is  the  popular  in- 
difference to  the  so-called  remedies  for  democratic  failures.  It  has  often 
been  held  that  "the  remedy  for  democracy  is  more  democracy";  namely, 
direct  primaries,  the  initiative  and  the  referendum,  and  the  recall  of 
officials  and  judicial  decisions.  The  unfortunate  fact  is  that  if  the 
people  could  develop  the  interest  and  intelligence  essential  to  any  effective 
use  of  such  mechanisms  as  the  initiative  and  the  referendum,  they  would 
be  able  to  govern  without  them.  The  experience  with  these  devices  of 
radical  democracy  in  the  last  generation  has  shown  that  they  fail  as 
often  as  democracy  of  a  more  moderate  type,  and  for  the  same  reasons. 

We  in  this  country  are  accustomed  to  the  unreality  of  political  life  and 
to  the  general  lethargy  of  the  public  thereunto.  But  we  assume  that  this 
is  the  exception  rather  than  the  rule.  Particularly  do  exponents  of 
democracy  point  to  the  popular  enthusiasm  and  intelligence  manifested 
in  politics  in  Great  Britain.  However,  William  G.  Peck,  an  English 
publicist,  shows  that  this  is  a  pious  illusion  in  his  article,  "The  Decline 
of  British  Politics."7  While  English  politics  were  both  exciting  and 


7  Virginia  Quarterly  Review,  winter,  1937-38. 


DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY  283 

popular  at  the  turn  of  the  century,  they  had  the  air  of  the  morgue  and 
the  intelligence  of  senile  dementia  from  1919  until  the  second  World  War: 

Such  scenes  [of  popular  excitement]  were  common  in  those  days  [of  the  Boer 
War].  They  no  longer  happen.  Our  politicians  have  no  magic.  The  quality 
of  political  debate  has  sadly  declined.  Pure  politics  is  no  longer  news  as  it 
once  was.  The  newspapers  dp  not  report  the  Parliamentary  proceedings  as  a 
tacred  duty — most  of  them  give  but  a  tabloid  summary  of  what  occurred  at 
Westminster  on  the  previous  day.  At  any  time  between  my  seventeenth  and 
thirty-fifth  birthdays,  I  could  have  given  you  at  a  moment's  notice  the  names 
of  all  the  cabinet  ministers  in  office  at  the  time.  Most  of  my  friends  could  have 
done  the  same.  Today  I  could  not  name  more  than  three  or  four  off-hand,  and 
I  think  there  is  none  of  my  friends  who  could  do  much  better. 

In  the  old  days  a  constituency  at  election  time  was  positively  ablaze  with  the 
rival  colours.  Nowadays,  it  is  quite  possible  to  walk  through  an  English  town 
a  few  days  before  an  election  and  to  find  few  visible  signs  that  the  inhabitants  are 
aware  of  what  is  going  on.  Crowds  of  people  no  longer  listen  quietly  to  long 
expositions  of  policy.  The  platform  is  more  suspect  than  the  pulpit. 

Down  to  the  close  of  the  first  World  War,  there  was  a  realistic  economic 
basis  for  English  political  activity.  From  the  Napoleonic  wars  through 
the  struggle  over  the  Reform  Bill  of  1832,  there  was  a  good  battle  on 
between  vested  agrarian  privilege  and  the  new  bourgeois  element  which 
formed  the  Liberal  party.  After  1832,  however,  capitalism  was  accepted 
by  both  Conservatives  and  Liberals.  From  1832  to  the  World  War,  these 
parties  fought  over  the  handling  of  capitalism  and  democracy,  Liberalism 
demanding  greater  rights  for  the  common  man  and  Conservatism  defend- 
ing imperialism  and  a  big  navy. 

After  1918,  the  only  real  economic  problem  was  the  drastic  reconstruc- 
tion of  capitalism  and  the  creation  of  a  new  economic  and  social  order. 
The  Liberal  party  was  killed  by  the  war,  and  the  Conservative  party  was 
moribund  and  stupid:  "There  fell  upon  English  politics  a  sense  of  un- 
reality. The  very  ground  of  the  long  party  controversy  had  disappeared. 
The  past  battles  took  on  the  appearance  of  a  sham  fight."  The  Labor 
party  had  something  of  a  chance  to  step  into  the  breach,  but  it  lacked 
decisive  leadership.  "It  was  their  misfortune  to  arrive  at  the  moment 
when  genius  and  resolution  of  the  highest  order  were  required  to  make 
decisions  at  one  of  the  supreme  turning  points  of  history;  and  their  leader 
was  the  verbose,  well-meaning,  and  totally  indecisive  Ramsay  Mac- 
Donald."  The  Labor  party  fell  down  notoriously  in  the  case  of  the 
general  strike  of  1926  and  in  the  crisis  which  preceded  the  formation  of 
the  Coalition  "National  Government."  As  a  result,  England  has  passed 
into  the  twilight  zone  of  politics:  "We  linger  in  this  twilight.  There  is 
no  voice  of  national  authority  pointing  a  path  to  the  new  morning.  The 
only  thing  we  can  do  is  to  build  a  mighty  navy  and  prepare  our  youth 
for  the  storm  and  terror  that  hover  the  not-distant  horizons."  The 
events  of  1938-39  offered  a  tragic  confirmation  of  Mr.  Peck's  dire  fore- 
bodings. 

No  less  mythical  in  practice  has  been  the  democratic  thesis  that  the 
people  have  high  capacity  for  calm  deliberation  in  choosing  candidates 


284  DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY 

and  for  sober  scrutiny  of  public  policies.  In  the  first  place,  only  about 
half  of  the  electorate,  on  the  average,  shows  enough  interest  in  either 
candidates  or  policies  to  turn  out  at  the  polls.  The  nonvoters  pre- 
sumably neither  deliberate  nor  scrutinize  and,  if  they  do  so,  it  is  of  no 
practical  significance.  It  can  hardly  be  held  that  the  actual  voters  do 
much  deliberating.  The  methods  of  modern  political  parties  during 
campaigns  are  not  designed  to  promote  calm  reflection  and  penetrating 
insight  into  the  real  facts,  issues,  and  personalities  involved,  but  are 
calculated  to  stimulate  emotion  and  to  paralyze  thought.  The  successful 
party  is  usually  the  one  that  develops  the  best  technique  for  stirring  the 
emotions  of  the  masses  rather  than  the  one  which  presents  the  most 
intelligent  candidates  or  platform. 

Further,  modern  social  psychology  has  amply  proved  that  man  is  not 
a  cool,  calculating  being,  invariably  choosing  that  line  of  conduct  which 
he  believes  is  sure  to  bring  him  a  maximum  of  benefit  and  a  minimum 
of  discomfort.  He  is,  rather,  a  creature  dominated  by  such  irrational 
factors  as  tradition,  custom,  convention,  habit,  and  the  passions  of  the 
mob.  These  irrational  influences  are  particularly  present  and  potent  in 
political  campaigns.  One's  political  preferences  are  determined  chiefly 
by  the  circumstances  of  birth  and  upbringing,  which  usually  lead  the 
child  to  adopt  the  politics  of  his  parents.  Most  of  us  are  "biological" 
Democrats  or  Republicans.  To  this  hereditary  background  are  added 
the  emotion-provoking  antics  of  those  who  plan  and  execute  campaigns, 
at  the  psychic  level  of  the  mob.  There  is,  therefore,  little  opportunity 
for  any  calm  deliberation  or  careful  scrutiny,  or  for  the  exercise  of  that 
shrewd  insight  into  the  qualities  of  candidates  which  was  long  believed  to 
be  the  particular  attribute  of  the  common  people. 

The  argument  that  democracy  is  vindicated,  if  on  no  other  grounds,  by 
the  special  capacity  of  the  masses  for  moral  judgments  and  support  of 
great  idealistic  causes,  is  easily  seen  to  be  mainly  specious.  In  the  first 
place,  we  now  realize  that  there  can  be  nothing  really  "moral"  that  is 
not  scientifically  sound.8  The  populace  has  neither  the  information  nor 
the  intelligence  to  ascertain  what  is  actually  valid  in  regard  to  moral 
situations.  The  only  way  in  which  the  public  can  be  useful  in  moral 
questions  is  through  the  development  of  popular  confidence  in  the  judg- 
ment of  trained  and  informed  leaders.  Most  of  the  great  moral  crusades 
have  not  had  a  popular  origin,  but  have  been  the  result  of  arousing 
popular  support  for  movements  begun  by  some  educated  and  intellectually 
superior  reformer.  The  two  great  moral  reforms  which  come  nearest  to 
reflecting  mass  pressure  in  the  United  States  have  been  Abolition  and 
Prohibition.  These  have  been  widely  regarded  as  ill-conceived  and 
disastrous  in  their  ultimate  social  results,  though  the  desirability  of 
freeing  the  slaves  and  arriving  at  a  more  rational  control  of  the  con* 
sumption  of  alcoholic  liquor  has  been  readily  conceded. 

Progress  in  political  science  and  economics  has  shown  that  the  old 


»  See  below,  pp.  714  ff . 


DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY  285 

theory  of  political  determinism  is  hopelessly  superficial  and  inadequate. 
The  laws  of  social  causation,  which  have  now  been  established,  have 
proved  that  political  institutions  are  derivative  and  not  primary.  A 
political  system  cannot  create  a  social  order.  A  given  pattern  of  economic 
and  social  conditions  produces,  in  time,  a  compatible  type  of  political 
structure,  making  due  allowance  for  divergences  in  detail  caused  by 
differences  of  historical  background  and  variations  in  culture.  Hence 
democracy  alone  cannot  be  relied  upon  to  mold  a  social  system  satis- 
factory to  its  needs.  It  can  only  thrive  where  social  conditions  are 
suitable  to  encourage  democratic  institutions. 

Another  obstacle  to  the  success  of  democracy  in  practical  experience 
has  been  the  rise  of  a  permanent  bureaucracy  in  the  official  civil  service. 
In  the  United  States,  democracy  has  been  weakened  by  the  inefficiency 
and  corruption  growing  out  of  our  lack — at  least,  until  recently — of  a 
well-trained  and  public-spirited  civil  service.  England  has  been  praised 
for  having  one.  But,  while  British  administrative  efficiency  has  gained 
as  a  result,  democracy  has  suffered.  So  powerful  has  the  permanent 
bureaucracy  become  that  the  initiative  and  authority  of  the  ministry 
and  the  Parliament  have  become  severely  curtailed.  The  elected  repre- 
sentatives in  Great  Britain  cannot  seriously  alter  the  policies  and 
procedure  of  the  permanent  civil  service.  It  would  require  a  political 
revolution  to  do  so.  Ramsay  MacDonald  and  the  Labor  government 
were  criticized  by  radicals  for  not  going  further  with  the  reconstruction 
of  England.  They  were  held  back,  not  only  by  their  failure  to  have  a 
clear  majority  in  the  House  of  Commons,  but  also  by  the  fact  that  they 
did  not  dare  to  challenge  the  civil-service  bureaucracy.  The  Foreign 
Minister  is1  usually  a  puppet  of  the  permanent  Under-secretary  of  Foreign 
Affairs.  In  short,  where  we  have  no  bureaucracy  we  have  inefficiency; 
and  where  we  have  bureaucracy  we  usually  cease  to  have  real  democracy. 

The  reasons  outlined  above  show  that  the  older  "nose-counting" 
democracy  is  hardly  suited  to  the  exacting  requirements  of  our  com- 
plicated industrial  civilization.  Indeed,  some  of  our  best  writers  on 
contemporary  society  doubt  the  adequacy  of  political  institutions  as  a 
mode  of  social  control.  They  are  demanding  a  new  form  of  social  con- 
trol, based  upon  and  conforming  to,  the  economic  and  social  realities  of 
the  present  age.  Technocracy  is  the  most  advanced  proposal  of  this 
sort.  W.  K.  Wallace's  The  Passing  of  Politics 9  is  a  representative 
example  of  the  advocacy  of  the  abandonment  of  political  institutions  by 
a  conservative  thinker.  Syndicalism  is  based  upon  the  assumption  of 
the  archaic  and  antiquated  character  of  political  institutions.  It  recom- 
mends a  simple  and  direct  process  of  government  through  the  economic 
groups  that  exist  today. 

The  nationalistic  obsession  has  proved  a  dangerous  doctrine  for 
democracy  in  a  world-society.  Democracy  cannot  ignore  international 
conditions.  A  great  war  in  an  age  of  "international  anarchy"  can 


oMacmillan,  1924. 


286  DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY 

destroy  the  political  institutions  that  have  been  evolving  and  approaching 
perfection  for  many  years.  The  system  of  government  and  reform  in 
England  at  the  outbreak  of  the  first  World  War  was  probably  the  highest 
pinnacle  that  democracy  has  attained — or  may  ever  attain — in  a  major 
state.  Yet,  the  .system  was  devastatingly  shocked,  if  not  permanently 
wrecked,  by  the  impact  of  the  first  World  War. 

Democracy  was  proved  an  inadequate  defense  against  going  to  war 
in  the  crisis  of  1914,  when  bellicose  political  leaders  of  England  and 
France  could  plunge  their  fundamentally  pacific  populations  into  the 
abyss.  Georges  Demartial's  The  War  of  1914-  How  Consciences  Were 
Mobilized,  Caroline  E.  Playne's  Society  at  War,  Irene  Cooper  Willis' 
England's  Holy  War,  C.  H.  Grattan's  Why  We  Fought,  Walter  Millis' 
Road  to  War,  and  Porter  Sargent's  Getting  U.  S.  into  War  present 
magnificent  clinical  pictures  of  the  futility  of  democracy  as  a  safeguard 
against  war. 

The  first  World  War  was  probably  the  greatest  blow  to  democracy 
since  the  dismal  failure  of  the  Revolutions  of  1848.  There  has  been,  at 
one  time  or  another  since  1918,  what  amounted  to  a  practical  dictatorship 
by  a  single  person  or  a  committee  in  Germany,  Italy,  Hungary,  Austria, 
Russia,  Spain,  Portugal,  Poland,  Yugoslavia,  Greece,  Rumania,  Bulgaria, 
and  Turkey.  In  other  European  states  emergency  governments  have 
ruled  with  quasidictatorial  methods.  The  fate  of  Czechoslovakia,  Den- 
mark, Norway,  Belgium,  Holland,  and  France  in  the  second  World  War 
further  demonstrates  the  fatal  impact  of  war  on  democracy.  William 
Henry  Chamberlin  is  probably  correct  in  declaring  that  war  is  the  most 
certain  "shortcut  to  Fascism." 

The  protagonists  of  autocracy  now  have  at  their  disposal  ample  evi- 
dence that  when  democracy  threatens  to  become  virile  and  efficient  it 
can  be  easily  checked  by  launching  another  war.  One  may  safely  say 
that  though  democracy  may  be  equal  to  the  requirements  of  a  peaceful 
society,  there  is  no  doubt  of  its  incapacity  to  endure  in  the  face  of  the 
strains  of  war.  To  point  to  the  efficiency  of  the  United  States  during 
the  first  World  War  is  no  refutation  of  this  statement.  This  efficiency 
was  purchased  by  disproportionately  greater  sacrifices  of  democratic 
institutions  and  intellectual  freedom. 

Lord  Bryce,  the  outstanding  student  of  the  rise  and  character  of  modern 
democracy,  was  compelled  to  admit,  at  the  end  of  his  studies,  that  democ- 
racy had  failed  to  achieve  the  main  results  that  had  been  hoped  from  it: 

It  has  brought  no  nearer  friendly  feeling  and  the  sense  of  human  brotherhood 
among  peoples  of  the  world  towards  one  another.  Neither  has  it  created  good- 
will and  a  sense  of  unity  and  civic  fellowship  within  each  of  these  peoples.  ...  It 
has  not  purified  or  dignified  politics  .  .  .  and  has  not  induced  that  satisfaction 
and  contentment  with  itself  as  the  best  form  of  government  which  was  expected.10 


10  James  Bryce,  Modern  Democracies,  new  ed.,  Macmillan,  1921,  2  vols.,  Vol.  II, 
p.  533.  Cf.  Wallace,  op.  cit.,  pp.  190  ff.,  and  C.  L.  Becker,  "Lord  Bryce  on  Modern 
Democracies,"  in  Political  Science  Quarterly,  December,  1921. 


DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY  287 

There  is,  perhaps,  no  other  summary  estimate  of  the  contributions  and 
failings  of  democratic  government  so  authoritative  or  inclusive  as  that 
presented  by  Bryce: 

I.  It  has  maintained  public  order  while  securing  the  liberty  of  the  individual 
citizen. 

II.  It  has  given  a  civil  administration  as  efficient  as  other  forms  of  govern- 
ment have  provided. 

III.  Its  legislation  has  been  more  generally  directed  to  the  welfare  of  the 
poorer  classes  than  has  been  that  of  other  Governments. 

IV.  It  has  not  been  inconstant  or  ungrateful. 
V.  It  has  not  weakened  patriotism  or  courage. 

VI.  It  has  often  been  wasteful  and  usually  extravagant. 
VII.  It  has  not  produced  general  contentment  in  each  nation. 
VIII.  It  has  done  little  to  improve  international  relations  and  ensure  peace, 
has  not  diminished  class  selfishness  (witness  Australia  and  New  Zealand),  has 
not  fostered  a  cosmopolitan  humanitarianism  nor  mitigated  the  dislike  of  men 
of  a  different  colour. 

IX.  It  has  not  extinguished  corruption  and  the  malign  influences  wealth  can 
exert  upon  government. 

X.  It  has  not  removed  the  fear  of  revolutions. 

XI.,  It  has  not  enlisted  in  the  service  of  the  State  a  sufficient  number  of  the 
most  honest  and  capable  citizens. 

XII.  Nevertheless,  it  has,  taken  all  in  all,  given  better  practical  results  than 
either  the  Rule  of  One  Man  or  the  Rule  of  a  Class,  for  it  has  at  least  extinguished 
many  of  the  evils  by  which  they  were  effaced.11 

.  However,  democracy  has  hardly,  as  Bryce  implies,  obliterated  class 
rule.  While  democracy  originated  in  an  agrarian  age,  the  growing 
dominion  of  the  capitalist  class  has  coincided  remarkably  with  the  prog- 
ress of  political  democracy.  Many  authorities,  such  as  Calvin  B.  Hoover, 
believe  that  capitalism  can  survive  only  in  association  with  a  democratic 
government. 

Democracy  and  the  Political   Future 

One  of  the  most  frequent  apologies  for  democracy  is  that  it  is  unfair  to 
say  that  democracy  is  a  failure,  since  it  has  really  never  been  tried. 
Though  we  have  long  enjoyed  universal  suffrage  in  the  United  States, 
it  is  pointed  out  that  the  real  power  in  government  is  concentrated  in 
the  hands  of  a  few  very  wealthy  individuals — that  we  have  plutocracy 
and  not  democracy.  James  W.  Gerard  stated  that  59  men  rule  America. 
Much  attention  was  given  to  Ferdinand  Lundberg's  book  America's  Sixty 
Families,  which,  he  said,  rule  our  country. 

There  could  be  no  more  effective  proof  of  the  futility  of  conventional 
democracy  than  the  fact  that  we  have  enjoyed  universal  suffrage  in  the 
United  States  for  a  hundred  years  without  realizing  true  democracy.  If 
we  have  not  been  able  to  establish  democracy  in  this  country  in  the  past 


n  Bryce,  op.  cit.,  Vol.  II,  p.  562. 


288  DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY 

century,  when  general  social  conditions  were  far  better  adapted  to  democ- 
racy than  they  are  today  or  probably  will  be  tomorrow,  what  hope 
is  there  that  we  shall  be  any  closer  to  real  democracy  a  hundred  years 
hence? 

Several  hundred  years  hence  the  historians  of  political  theory  and 
institutions  may  describe  conventional  democracy  as  the  most  interesting 
and  attractive  political  fiction  of  the  nineteenth  century.  It  may  be 
shown  to  be  something  that,  as  originally  understood,  never  did  and  never 
could  exist  on  a  large  scale.  For  the  conditions  that  promoted  conven- 
tional democracy  and  in  conjunction  with  which  it  might  have  existed — 
a  simple  agrarian  society  and  a  stable  civilization — were  already  passing 
away  when  the  democratic  dogmas  were  first  being  fashioned.  Before 
popular  government  was  realized  in  practice  those  social  conditions  which 
were  compatible  with  it  had  all  but  disappeared.  Likewise,  the  theoret- 
ical assumptions  upon  which  conventional  democracy  was  launched — 
the  equality  of  man,  high  potential  interest  in  public  affairs  on  the  part 
of  the  masses,  and  penetrating  rationality  of  the  populace  in  political 
matters — have  been  disproved  by  the  development  of  social  science  and 
the  test  of  political  experience.  Hence  the  political  problem  of  the 
future  is  not  to  vindicate  conventional  democracy,  but  seek  some  form 
of  social  control  more  tenable  in  theory  and  more  adapted  in  practice 
to  the  requirements  of  the  contemporary  age. 

There  is,  then,  no  inherent  reason  why  one  should  view  with  despair  the 
debacle  of  the  older  democratic  dogmas  and  practices.  We  are  today 
often  amused  when  we  read  of  the  dismay  with  which  the  autocrats  of 
previous  centuries  viewed  the  declining  strength  and  prestige  of  abso- 
lutism and  special  privilege.  We  should  learn  by  their  example  and 
recognize  that  it  is  just  as  foolish  to  be  staggered  by  the  current  break- 
down of  conventional  democracy.  There  is  no  reason  to  believe  that 
we  may  not  find  future  forms  of  government  that  are  far  superior  to 
conventional  democracy  in  efficiency  and  service  to  mankind. 

Some  of  the  disillusioned  friends  of  democracy,  contending  that  it  is 
manifestly  impossible  to  find  a  more  successful  form  of  government,  seek 
cqmfort  in  the  thought  that  all  other  forms  of  government  have  proved 
to  be  worse.  This  implies,  however,  a  retrospective  attitude.  The 
"worse"  forms  of  government  are  those  of  the  past.  We  have  no  means 
of  knowing  how  greatly  we  may  advance  beyond  those  earlier  methods 
and  devices,  all  of  which  were  worked  out  in  a  crude  manner,  on  the  basis 
of  limited  political  experience  and  very  little  scientific  knowledge.  There 
is  no  reason  why  we  should  not  exhibit  in  the  political  field  the  same 
originality  and  inventive  ability  that  we  have  displayed  in  the  techno- 
logical field. 

The  problem  is  really  one  of  getting  efficient  and  social-minded  leaders 
into  positions  of  authority  and  responsibility.  We  must  have  the  effi- 
ciency, training,  and  professional  political  spirit,  say,  of  the  old  Prussian 
bureaucracy,  divested  of  its  class  spirit,  its  arrogance,  and  its  oppressive- 


DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY  289 

ness.  Intelligence  tests,  information  tests,  special  professional  training, 
and  successful  experience  for  office-holding;  the  establishment  of  well- 
equipped  government  schools  for  the  training  of  officials  in  every  branch 
of  the  government  service,  both  domestic  and  foreign;  and  some  com- 
bination of  vocational  and  proportional  representation  to  give  justice 
and  rationale  to  representative  government — these  would  seem  to  be 
suggestions  that  are  surely  worthy  of  consideration  and  might  be  woven 
into  the  structure  of  the  new  democratic  state.  More  power  and  vitality 
in  local  government  units  would  doubtless  help  a  good  deal.  The  elimi- 
nation of  sumptuary  legislation  and  unnecessary  state  interference  would 
relieve  the  strains  upon  administration  and  decrease  the  burdens  of  polit- 
ical control.  Many  argue,  however,  that  the  fundamental  changes  in 
the  economic  and  social  structure  in  the  last  century  render  such  reforms 
as  these  superficial,  inadequate,  and  about  as  futile  as  the  old  fashioned 
democratic  ideals  and  practices. 

It  is  too  often  taken  for  granted  that  we  must  today  choose  between 
traditional  democracy  and  totalitarianism — that  there  is  no  alternative 
between  the  old  nose-counting  system  and  brutal  dictatorships.  This 
is  unfortunate.  By  representing  the  political  future  as  one  which  in- 
volves the  espousal  of  either  traditional  democracy  or  totalitarian  dicta- 
torship, we  limit  our  vision  and  paralyze  our  efforts.  Those  who  feel 
sure  that  they  must  choose  between  a  corrupt  and  inefficient  democracy 
and  a  Nazi  regime,  for  example,  naturally  prefer  even  the  archaic  democ- 
racy and  determine  to  stick  to  it  at  all  costs.  If  we  could  keep  clearly 
in  mind  the  fact  that  we  might  readily  find  new  types  of  democratic  gov- 
ernment which  avoid  both  the  inefficiency  of  the  older  democracy  and 
the  tyrannical  cruelty  of  dictatorships,  we  would  be  likely  to  devote  more 
energy  to  political  invention  and  have  greater  hope  for  the  political  future. 

Almost  invariably,  totalitarianism  has  succeeded  democracy  because 
of  the  inefficiency  of  the  latter.  If  we  simply  hang  on  to  an  outmoded 
democracy  in  blind  desperation  and  make  no  serious  effort  to  improve 
it  or  to  find  a  better  substitute,  we  are  bound,  sooner  or  later,  to  wind 
up  in  totalitarianism,  with  all  its  evils.  We  should  face  the  political 
future  with  sceptical  enthusiasm  and  not  imagine  that  we  must  accept 
either  those  past  forms  of  government  which  have  proved  inadequate  or 
undesirable,  or  those  more  novel  types  which  are  repugnant  to  all  liberty- 
loving  men. 

Among  the  most  interesting  suggestions  which  have  been  made  in 
recent  years  are  those  related  to  the  growing  interest  in  the  program 
of  Technocracy  and  in  "The  Managerial  Revolution."12  We  have  al- 
ready noted  that  the  problems  with  which  democracy  has  to  deal  in  our 
complicated  economic  age  are  far  beyond  the  capacity  of  the  average 


12  Harold  Loeb,  Life  in  a  Technocracy,  Viking  Press,  1933;  James  Burnham,  The 
Managerial  Revolution,  Day,  1941;  and  Carl  Dreher,  The  Coming  Showdown, 
Little,  Brown,  1942. 


290  DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY 

administrator  or  legislator,  when  they  have  to  be  handled  through  -the 
machinery  of  politics.  But,  viewed  as  an  engineering  problem,  and 
divorced  from  considerations  of  property,  profits,  and  politics,  they  are 
relatively  direct  and  simple.  A  corps  of  competent  industrial  engineers 
could  easily  determine  the  material  needs  of  the  American  population 
and  lay  out  an  effective  plan  for  producing  the  goods  and  services  needed. 
A  thorough  economic  regimentation  would  be  required,  but  it  would 
affect  most  people  for  only  a  few  hours  each  day.  Outside  of  the  eco- 
nomic realm,  unbounded  liberty  might  be  enjoyed  for  participation  in 
education,  discussion,  recreation,  leisure,  and  the  arts.  It  may  be  that 
the  future  solution  of  our  political  problems  will  involve  economic  regi- 
mentation under  experts  in  the  material  realm,  and  thorough-going 
democracy  in  the  "things  of  the  spirit" — the  realm  in  which  the  virtues 
and  values  of  democracy  chiefly  reside. 

The  most  frequently  proposed  plan  for  a  new  type  of  social  control, 
divorced  from  the  political  or  territorial  state  is  the  functional  state, 
governed  directly  by  the  natural  vocational  groups  which  exist  in  modern 
industrial  society.  We  presented  Professor  Overstreet's  program  for 
such  a  type  of  reform  in  the  preceding  chapter,  wherein  a  political  system 
would  not  be  injected  between  society  and  its  administration  of  public 
affairs.  The  various  vocations,  professions,  and  trades  would  govern 
directly  through  their  representatives.  The  Syndicalists  once  proposed 
this  form  of  government,  but  they  called  for  social  control  through  labor 
organizations  alone — a  proletarian  form  of  functionalism.  But  there  is 
no  reason  why  a  capitalistic  democracy  could  not  operate  a  functional 
state  without  accepting  any  proletarian  revolution. 

Some,  who  have  not  been  willing  to  go  this  far,  would  retain  the 
political  state  for  general  legislation,  dealing  with  broad  measures  of 
social  welfare,  and  then  leave  the  execution  of  such  measures  to  spe- 
cialized administrative  organizations,  who  would  possess  the  technical 
information  and  equipment  to  apply  these  general  measures  in  detail. 
We  may  note  a  trend  in  this  direction  in  the  United  States,  in  the  form 
of  the  increasing  number  and  importance  of  administrative  commissions. 

The  deficiencies  of  democracy  in  our  complicated  urban  industrial 
world-civilization  have  led  to  a  sweeping  repudiation  of  democratic  prac- 
tices in  the  last  twenty  years.  For  this  deplorable  development  the 
friends  of  democracy  have  been  in  part  to  blame  by  claiming  traditional 
democracy  to  be  perfect  and  eternal.  Had  they  candidly  admitted  its 
defects  and  made  a  strenuous  effort  to  remedy  them  before  it  was  too  late, 
the  recent  and  menacing  development  of  dictatorship  might  not  have 
taken  place. 

The  Struggle  for  Civil   Liberties 

The  Nature  of  Civil  Liberties.  Democracy  and  civil  liberties  are 
closely  associated.  Indeed,  democracy  has  been  defended  against  totali- 
tarianism primarily  because  it  is  likely  to  cherish  and  defend  liberty. 
Liberalism  is  the  chief  asset  of  the  democratic  system.  As  convenient 


DEMOCRACY   AND   LIBERTY  291 

a  panorama  of  the  whole  field  of  civil  liberties  as  is  likely  to  be  provided, 
has  been  gathered  together  by  Leon  Whipple: 

I.  THE  RIGHTS— PERSONAL  LIBERTY 

1.  The  Right  to  Security— life,  limb,  health. 

2.  The  Right  to  Liberty — freedom  of  the  body,  and  freedom  of  movement, 
with  the  privilege  of  emigration  or  immigration. 

3.  The  Right  to  Equality — protection  against  slavery,  involuntary  servitude, 
and  imprisonment  for  debt;  against  discriminations  on  account  of  color  or  sex, 
and  (in  general)  race;  and  against  special  or  hereditary  privileges.    These  are  the 
Civil  Rights,  or  rights  of  the  citizen. 

4.  The  Right  to  Reputation. 

5.  The  Right  to  Bear  Arms  and  to  Organize  the  Militia. 

6.  The  Right  to  Law: 

a.  Before  Trial: 
Justice  shall  be  free; 

The  accused  shall  have  the  right  to  the  common  law; 

No  unreasonable  search  or  seizure; 

The  right  to  the  writ  of  habeas  corpus  shall  not  be  denied; 

The  accused  shall  hear  the  accusation; 

Bail  shall  not  be  excessive; 

Trial  shall  be  on  indictment  after  investigation  by  a  grand  jury; 

Witnesses  shall  be  protected  in  their  rights; 

The  accused  shall  be  protected  against  "lynch  law." 

b.  During  Trial: 

The  accused  shall  have  "due  process  of  law,  law  of  the  land,  and  judgment 

by  his  peers;" 
He  shall  have  a  trial  by  a  jury  of  the  vicinage;  defined  as  to  size,  and 

the  need  for  unanimity; 
He  shah1  have  counsel ; 
He  may  summon  witnesses; 
No  inquisitorial  methods  shall  be  used; 
He  shall  not  be  put  twice  in  jeopardy  for  one  offense; 
The  crime  of  treason  shall  be  defined; 
There  shall  be  no  attainder. 

c.  After  Trial: 

No  excessive  fines,  or  cruel  or  unusual  punishments; 
No  ex  post  facto  law  shall  be  passed; 
Provision  for  pardoning  is  usually  made; 
There  shall  be  no  corruption  of  blood. 

II.  THE  FREEDOMS— SOCIAL  LIBERTY 

1.  Freedom  of  Conscience — especially  religious  liberty,  including  no  state  sup- 
port, tpr  enforced  individual  support  of  an  established  church;  and  no  religious 
tests  for  participation  in  the  government. 

2.  Freedom  of  Speech  and  Assemblage,  including  petition. 

3.  Freedom  of  the  Press — with  legal  provisions  against  tyrannical  coercion  by 
libel  proceedings  or  for  contempt  of  court.13 

18  Our  Ancient  Liberties,  H.  W.  Wilson  Company,  1927,  pp.  13-14.  Reprinted  by 
permission  of  the  publisher.  For  a  comprehensive  bibliography,  dealing  with  every 
phase  of  civil  liberties,  see  George  Seldes,  You  Can't  Do  That,  Modern  Age,  1938, 
pp.  254-301. 


292  DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY 

Most  of  these  rights  and  liberties  first  appeared  as  a  theory  in  the  six- 
teenth and  seventeenth  centuries.  They  were  the  subject  of  much  discus- 
sion as  the  "natural  rights  of  man,"  rights  which  were  not  regarded  as 
man-made,  or  a  product  of  human  institutions,  but  as  inherent  in  the 
cosmic  scheme — a  part  of  the  natural  and  divine  order.  According  to 
this  theory,  man  had  enjoyed  these  rights  when  he  lived  in  a  hypothetical 
state  of  nature  prior  to  formal  social  control.  When  man  placed  himself 
voluntarily  under  a  government,  the  continuation  of  his  rights  was  to 
be  guaranteed  by  the  state.  This  whole  doctrine  is  absurd  when  taken 
in  any  literal  historical  sense,  however  valuable  a  purpose  it  may  have 
served  as  propaganda  for  a  truly  noble  cause.  There  is  no  such  thing  as 
a  "natural  right"  to  anything — even  life  itself.  So  far  as  nature  is  con- 
cerned, we  have  only  the  rights  of  a  wild  animal — the  right  of  the  strong 
or  the  crafty  to  get  all  they  can  or  wish. 

In  the  course  of  time,  classes  and  individuals  have  wrested  from  society 
as  a  whole — the  herd — certain  rights  and  privileges.  These  remained 
valid  so  long  as  the  said  classes  and  individuals,  or  their  descendants, 
could  defend  them.  There  is  no  certainty  that  these  rights  have  always 
been  wise  concessions.  The  point  we  are  making  is  that  persons  or 
groups,  which  wanted  them  and  were  powerful  enough  to  get  them,  suc- 
ceeded in  establishing  certain  rights  and  immunities.  In  other  words, 
human  prerogatives  were  always  secured  in  the  give-and-take  process 
between  society,  classes,  and  individuals.  They  are  not  natural  rights. 
They  are  conferred  by  society,  willingly  or  not.  No  man  has  any  natural 
right,  even  to  keeping  his  jugular  vein  intact. 

The  Historical  Origins  of  Civil  Liberties.  In  primitive  society  there 
were  no  formal  guaranties  of  individual  right  or  immunities.  Custom 
and  usage,  however,  created  certain  personal  rights  which  were  usually 
observed  within  the  group.  In  the  ancient  Orient,  while  many  rights  of 
property  and  contract  were  protected,  there  was  little  personal  freedom. 
The  philosopher  of  history,  Hegel,  is  said  once  to  have  remarked  that  in 
this  Oriental  era  only  two  were  free — God  in  heaven  and  the  king  on 
earth.  Certainly,  there  was  no  freedom  of  religion,  conscience,  the  press, 
speech,  or  assemblage.  Even  semidivine  kings  found  it  impossible  to 
alter  the  religious  system  radically. 

Among  the  Attic  Greeks  and  the  Romans,  a  large  degree  of  personal 
liberty  was  enjoyed  by  the  artistocracy.  The  doctrine  of  criticism  and 
free  thought  arose  among  the  Greeks  and  continued  to  exist  in  Rome 
until  the  establishment  of  an  Oriental  despotism.  There  were  limitations 
in  practice,  to  be  sure,  but  its  legitimate  place  in  the  social  system  was 
well  established.  The  Greeks  introduced  the  custom  of  trial  by  jury. 
The  Romans  first  permitted  the  individual  to  emerge  as  a  recognized 
entity.  According  to  law,  he  had  certain  rights,  which  the  government 
was  bound  to  respect.  This  was  the  origin  of  the  legalistic  aspect  of 
our  civil  liberties,  for  in  the  eyes  of  the  law  these  legal  rights  are  our 
civil  liberties.  The  state,  acting  through  the  constitution,  announces  that 
there  are  certain  rights  and  immunities  which  the  individual  may.  enjoy 


DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY  293 

and  which  the  government  cannot  take  away.    Only  a  change  in  the 
constitution  can  deprive  the  individual  of  these  rights  and  immunities. 

In  the  Middle  Ages,  there  was  a  marked  reversion  to  a  cruder  type  of 
civilization,  politically  controlled  by  semibarbarous  kings  and  dominated 
by  a  church  absolute  in  its  power  over  religion  and  conscience — and  even 
over  life.  This  was  not  a  healthy  atmosphere  for  the  growth  of  human 
liberties.  Extensive  freedom  during  the  medieval  period  existed  only  in 
some  of  the  towns.  But  even  town  liberty  was  corporate  rather  than 
personal.  A  man  possessed  rights  as  a  member  of  a  class  or  a  group, 
like  the  gilds.  The  practice  of  setting  down  rights  in  charters  like  the 
Magna  Carta  and  town  charters  laid  the  basis  for  the  later  demand  for 
constitutions  to  safeguard  and  perpetuate  liberties. 

The  age  of  Humanism  during  the  Renaissance  promoted  the  sense  of 
individuality,  of  the  worth  of  man  as  man,  thus  providing  a  moral  founda- 
tion for  the  later  struggle  for  the  legal  rights  of  individuals.  The  Pro- 
testant revolution  carried  the  emancipation  further  by  proclaiming  the 
individual  basis  of  worship  and  religious  conscience.  To  be  sure,  indi- 
vidual conscience  had  to  be  harmonized  with  the  beliefs  of  the  majority 
in  any  Protestant  sect  and  with  the  approved  doctrines  of  the  religion 
supported  by  the  state.  But  the  theory  was  promulgated  in  the  Protes- 
tant revolution  that  the  individual  could  go  directly  to  God,  according 
to  the  dictates  of  his  own  conscience. 

The  circumstances  which  gave  rise  to  our  civil  liberties  were,  however, 
primarily  associated  with  the  Commercial  Revolution,  the  rise  of  capi- 
talism, the  growth  of  the  bourgeoisie  and  its  desire  to  protect  private 
property  and  business  rights.  During  the  Middle  Ages,  the  feudal  lords 
were  ruthless  enemies  of  the  merchants,  robbing  and  exploiting  them 
shamefully.  Hence  when  the. kings  turned  against  the  barons  in  early 
modern  times,  they  found  willing  allies  in  the  merchant  class.  It  was  not 
long,  however,  before  'lie  merchant  class  discovered  that  the  kings  were 
as  arbitrary  and  avaricious  as  the  barons  had  been.  They  levied  exces- 
sive and  arbitrary  taxes,  threw  men  into  prison  without  trial,  confiscated 
property,  and  quartered  soldiers  in  the  merchants'  homes. 

Therefore,  the  bourgeoisie  set  about  to  overthrow  arbitrary  royal  rule. 
They  had  to  have  the  right  to  carry  on  a  campaign  of  propaganda  in 
order  to  promote  their  cause  and  gain  followers.  Thus,  they  became 
ardent  supporters  of  free  speech,  a  free  press,  and  the  right  of  assemblage. 
The  sanctity  of  property  rights  furnished  an  argument  against  the  prac- 
tice of  royal  confiscation.  Trial  by  jury  would  help  to  avert  arbitrary 
imprisonment,  and  the  right  of  habeas  corpus  would  save  them  from 
rotting  in  jail  at  the  pleasure  of  some  king  or  autocrat.  Freedom  from 
the  quartering  of  soldiers  in  homes  would  remove  one  particularly  ob- 
noxious manifestation  of  royal  arrogance  and  oppression.  Since  most  of 
the  middle  class  were  Protestants,  often  dissenting  Protestants,  they  were 
in  danger  of  persecution  by  Catholics  and  Anglicans.  Hence,  they  laid 
much  stress  upon  the  virtues  of  religious  liberty.  Along  with  these  spe- 
cific goals  went  the  more  generalized  ambition  to  create  representative 


294  DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY 

government,  so  that  arbitrary  royal  rule  could  be  ended  and  the  sov- 
ereignty of  the  people  made  supreme. 

Our  civil  liberties,  then,  were  created  on  the  basis  of  a  set  of  class 
interests  and  aspirations.  Between  the  age  of  Elizabeth  and  the  reign 
of  William  and  Mary — approximately  a  century — our  fundamental  civil 
liberties  were  won  in  England. 

The  English  middle  class  embodied  their  precious  civil  liberties  in  the 
Bill  of  Rights  of  1689,  but  the  foundations  of  this  "bill"  rested  upon  a 
number  of  English  charters.  First  in  point  of  time  was  the  Magna  -Carta 
of  1215,  a  reactionary  feudal  document  which  was,  fortunately,  never 
completely  enforced.  Misinterpreted  in  the  seventeenth  century  by  the 
opponents  of  Stuart  absolutism,  it  was  elevated  to  the  position  of  a 
major  shibboleth  in  the  campaign  for  English  civil  liberties.  Though 
the  Magna  Carta  had  originally  been  wrested  from  the  king  by  and  for 
the  feudal  lords,  it  was  exploited  by  the  seventeenth-century  bourgeoisie 
as  a  manifesto  of  the  middle  classes  against  the  king  and  his  lords. 

More  literally  in  harmony  with  later  democracy  was  the  legislation 
of  Edward  I  which  confirmed  the  rights  of  Parliament  in  1295-1297  and 
made  that  body  representative  of  the  nobility,  clergy,  and  burghers. 
Henceforth,  Parliament  had  a  real  right  to  voice  the  wishes  of  the  realm. 

A  milestone  in  the  struggle  for  civil  liberties  was  the  Petition  of  Right, 
exacted  from  Charles  I  in  1628.  It  secured  the  promise  that  there 
would  be  no  further  arbitrary  taxation  or  confiscation  of  property,  that 
no  freeman  would  be  imprisoned  without  show  of  cause,  that  soldiers 
would  not  be  billeted  in  private  homes,  and  that  martial  law  would  not 
be  used  in  time  of  peace.  The  famous  Bushel  case  of  1670  and  the  Fox 
Libel  Act  of  1792  strengthened  the  right  of  trial  by  jury.  The  Habeas 
Corpus  Act,  passed  in  1679,  directed  speedy  trial  and  made  it  impossible 
to  hold  a  prisoner  for  more  than  twenty  days  without  trial  or  bail.  After 
the  "Glorious  Revolution"  of  1688,  most  of  the  contents  of  earlier  charters 
of  English  liberties  were,  as  we  noted,  collected  in  the  famous  Bill  of 
Rights  of  1689.  This  Bill  included  the  following  important  articles: 

1.  That  the  pretended  power  of  suspending  laws,  or  of  execution  of  laws,  by 
regal  authority  without  consent  of  parliament,  is  illegal. 

2.  That  the  pretended  power  of  dispensing  with  laws,  or  the  execution  of  laws, 
by  regal  authority,  as  it  hath  been  assumed  and  exercised  of  late,  is  illegal. 

3.  That  the  commission  for  erecting  the  late  court  of  commissioners  for  eccle- 
siastical causes,  and  all  other  commissions  and  courts  of  like  nature,  are  illegal 
and  pernicious. 

4.  That  levying  money  for  or  to  the  use  of  the  crown  by  pretense  of  pre- 
rogative, without  grant  of  parliament,  for  longer  time  or  in  other  manner  than 
the  same  is  or  shall  be  granted,  is  illegal. 

5.  That  it  is  the  right  of  the  subjects  to  petition  the  king,  and  all  commit- 
ments and  prosecutions  for  such  petitioning  are  illegal. 

6.  That  the  raising  or  keeping  a  standing  army  within  the  kingdom  in  time 
of  peace,  unless  it  be  with  consent  of  parliament,  is  against  law. 


DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY  295 

7.  That  the  subjects  which  are  Protestants  may  have  arms  for  their  defense 
suitable  to  their  conditions,  and  as  allowed  by  law. 

8.  That  election  of  members  of  parliament  ought  to  be  free. 

9.  That  the  freedom  of  speech,  and  debates  or  proceedings  in  parliament, 
ought  not  to  be  impeached  or  questioned  in  any  court  or  place  out  of  parliament. 

10.  That  excessive  bail  ought  not  to  be  required,  nor  excessive  fines  imposed, 
nor  cruel  and  unusual  punishments  inflicted. 

11.  That  jurors  ought  to  be  duly  impaneled  and  returned,  and  jurors  which 
pass  upon  men  in  trials  for  high  treason  ought  to  be  freeholders. 

12.  That  all  grants  and  promises  of  fines  and  forfeitures  of  particular  persons 
before  conviction  are  illegal  and  void. 

13.  And  that  for  redress  of  all  grievances,  and  for  the  amending,  strengthening, 
and  preserving  of  the  laws,  parliament  ought  to  be  held  frequently. 

The  Bill  of  Rights  was  supplemented  by  the  Toleration  Act  of  1689, 
which  extended  civil  and  religious  liberties  to  all  save  Catholics  and  Uni- 
tarians; and  by  the  Mutiny  Act  of  the  same  year,  which  gave  Parliament 
control  over  appropriations  for  the  army.  Finally,  in  1701,  the  Act  of 
Settlement  gave  Parliament  power  to  dispose  of  the  crown  and  to  deter- 
mine the  line  of  succession. 

The  essentials  of  the  English  Bill  of  Rights  were  embodied  in  the  state 
constitutions  of  11  of  the  13  American  commonwealths  after  the  procla- 
mation of  the  Declaration  of  Independence  in  1776.  Then,  at  the  in- 
sistence of  the  Jeffcrsonian  liberals,  the  same  general  list  of  liberties  was 
incorporated  in  our  Federal  Constitution,  in  the  form  of  the  first  ten 
amendments. 

France  adopted  these  English  and  American  liberties  in  the  Declara- 
tion of  the  Rights  of  Man  of  1789,  and  in  the  revolutionary  charters  and 
constitutions  which  followed.  In  the  nineteenth  century,  the  heritage  of 
civil  liberties  was  claimed  by  most  European  countries.  Russia  was  a 
notable  exception. 

Thus  the  bourgeoisie  won  those  rights  which  at  least  hypothetically 
deliver  citizens  of  democratic  countries  from  arbitrary  imprisonment, 
censorship  and  religious  discrimination,  and  guarantee  free  speech,  press, 
and  assemblage.  In  due  time,  the  proletariat  invoked  the  same  civil 
liberties  in  order  to  protect  itself  from  the  mercantile  and  industrial 
classes  and  secure  such  rights  as  collective  bargaining.  Since,  however, 
employers  usually  controlled  the  governments  of  industrialized  nations, 
the  proletariat  has  met  with  much  difficulty  in  attaining  equality  with 
the  bourgeoisie  in  the  enjoyment  of  the  conventional  civil  liberties.  As 
Arthur  W.  Calhoun  points  out,  the  Supreme  Court  would  not  intervene  to 
save  the  lives  of  Sacco  and  Vanzetti  but  it  would  eagerly  have  intervened 
to  protect  a  utility  company  in  a  small  Massachusetts  town  from  what 
it  regarded  as  a  stringent  state  or  municipal  rate  regulation.14  Indeed, 


14  See  above,  p.  184. 


296  DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY 

the  bourgeois  civil  liberties  have  frequently  been  utilized  as  a  defense 
against  legislation  designed  to  give  the  workers  liberty  and  security.  It 
is  a  strange  irony  of  history  that  the  liberties  established  by  seventeenth- 
century  merchants  in  England  were  invoked  in  twentieth-century  America 
to  outlaw  such  things  as  child  labor  laws,  minimum  wage  legislation,  and 
the  right  of  labor  to  organize. 

The  fact  that  our  conventional  civil  liberties  were  a  bourgeois  product, 
designed  primarily  to  protect  private  property  and  capitalistic  enterprise, 
helps  to  explain  the  attitude  of  Soviet  Russia  towards  them.  Americans 
frequently  wonder  how  Russians  can  submit  to  the  extinction  of  these 
liberties.  The  fact  is  that  the  Russians  never  enjoyed  them  and  hardly 
know  what  they  mean.  Under  the  tsars,  the  Russians  had  few  civil 
liberties.  In  spite  of  the  revolution  of  1905,  the  bourgeois  movement  in 
Russia  was  not  strong  enough  and  did  not  endure  long  enough  to  promote 
civil  liberties.  When  the  Marxian  Bolsheviks  came  into  power,  in  1917, 
they  had  no  interest  in  establishing  typically  bourgeois  legal  devices  and 
safeguards.  Russia  thus  skipped  almost  entirely  the  bourgeois  stage  of 
civilization  through  its  precipitous  progress  from  quasi-feudalism  to  col- 
lectivized industrialism  in  one  generation.  There  is  as  little  likelihood 
that  the  Soviet  rulers  will  ultimately  establish  all  the  bourgeois  civil 
liberties  of  the  seventeenth  and  eighteenth  centuries  as  that  they  will 
introduce  other  basic  elements  of  bourgeois  culture. 

The  mercantile  classes  were  not  content  to  have  civil  rights  and  guar- 
anties of  liberty  enacted  into  statute  law;  they  also  wished  to  have  them 
written  into  constitutional  law,  since  it  is  far  more  difficult  for  a  govern- 
ment to  modify  a  constitution  than  to  alter  ordinary  laws.  This  explains 
the  inordinate  enthusiasm  of  the  bourgeoisie  for  written  constitutions  in 
the  seventeenth,  eighteenth  and  nineteenth  centuries.  The  latter  were 
not  the  product  of  mass  clamor  for  freedom  and  democracy,  but  the  result 
of  bourgeois  demands  for  an  extreme  form  of  protection  of  the  liberties 
which  put  their  property  rights,  business  practices,  and  religious  beliefs 
beyond  the  reach  of  the  law.15 

In  time,  the  proletariat  learned  the  same  trick.  Hence,  in  the  first 
proletarian  constitution,  that  of  Soviet  Russia,  we  find  the  tables  turned. 
The  Russian  constitution,  which  outlaws  capitalist  ideals  and  practices, 
is  surrounded  by  the  same  halo  of  sanctity  that  envelops  capitalistic 
constitutions  in  other  countries. 

Contemporary  Crisis  of  Civil  Liberties.  Mussolini  has  cynically  re- 
marked that  liberty  is  a  wasteful  luxury.  Hitler  has  made  it  an  ex- 
tremely dangerous  luxury  in  Germany.  But  Americans  must  not  be  too 
arrogant  or  contemptuous  of  totalitarian  countries.  If  Italy  and  Ger- 
many had  a  Supreme  Court,  which  could  set  aside  laws  distasteful  to 
reactionary  interests,  they  would  not  need  to  suppress  legislatures.  The 
firm  belief  of  Americans  that  the  Federal  Constitution  protects  them 


See  above,  pp.  221  ff. 


DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY  297 

comprehensively  in  all  of  their  classic  civil  rights — freedom  of  speech, 
religion,  assembly,  and  so  on — and  guarantees  them  immunity  from  search 
and  seizure,  summary  justice,  and  discrimination  before  the  law  is  but 
one  of  their  great  illusions.  The  first  ten  amendments  relate  almost 
wholly  to  prohibitions  on  the  federal  government.  They  do  not,  for  the 
most  part,  protect  one  against  invasion  of  his  rights  by  state  legislation 
and  state  officers.  It  is  the  Fourteenth  Amendment  which  affords  Amer- 
ican citizens  their  main  federal  protection  against  arbitrary  state  action. 

The  value  of  this  amendment  to  personal  liberties  has,  however,  been 
exaggerated.  The  Supreme  Court  has  been  far  more  solicitous  about 
state  encroachments  upon  property  rights  than  over  state  violations  of 
personal  liberties. 

When  the  Court  does  take  an  interest,  under  the  Fourteenth  Amend- 
ment, in  intervening  to  protect  personal  liberties  against  violations  by 
the  states,  it  can  act  only  when  these  violations  are  executed  by  state 
officials  or  embodied  in  state  legislation.  The  history  of  the  violations 
of  civil  liberties  shows,  however,  that  the  most  frequent  and  serious  viola- 
tions of  civil  liberties  are  not  official  acts  at  all.  They  are  violations 
carried  out  by  private  forces  and  groups  which  the  state  will  not  act  to 
check.  The  Supreme  Court  holds  itself  and  Congress  to  be  powerless  in 
such  cases.  As  stated  by  a  lawyer,  Osmond  K.  Fraenkel,  in  a  compre- 
hensive pamphlet  "The  Supreme  Court  and  Civil  Liberties,"  prepared  for 
the  American  Civil  Liberties  Union: 

So  long  as  the  Court  adheres  to  the  principle  of  the  Civil  Rights  Cases,  Congress 
can  prohibit  only  official,  not  individual  action;  and  its  help  to  the  cause  of  civil 
liberties  will  .therefore  be  correspondingly  limited.  The  greatest  infringements 
of  personal  rights  come  not  from  direct  state  action  but  from  private  forces 
which  the  state  is  unwilling  to  check 

The  Supreme  Court  has  come  out  boldly  and  dramatically  in  behalf 
of  civil  liberties  only  once  in  our  history.  That  was  in  the  case  of  the 
suspension  of  civil  justice  during  the  Civil  War.  But  it  did  so  a  year 
after  the  War  was  over  and  after  the  damage  had  been  done.  But  its 
pronouncement  in  the  famous  case  of  Ex  Parte  Milligan  is  worth  re- 
peating: 

The  Constitution  of  the  United  States  is  a  law  for  rulers  and  people,  equally 
in  war  and  peace,  and  covers  with  the  shield  of  its  protection  all  classes  of  men, 
at  all  times,  and  under  all  circumstances.  No  doctrine,  involving  more  pernicious 
consequences,  was  ever  invented  by  the  wit  of  man  than  that  any  01  its  pro- 
visions can  be  suspended  during  any  of  the  grdat  exigencies  of  government. 

Yet,  when  the  World  War  came  along,  when  the  Red  scare  followed 
the  War,  and  when  Prohibition  was  highly  popular,  the  Court  forgot  both 
letter  and  spirit  of  the  Milligan  decision.  The  following  summary  of 
characteristic  violations  of  civil  liberties  in  the  United  States  since  the 
World  War,  prepared  a  few  years  ago  by  Lowell  Mellett,  Ludwell  Denny, 


298  DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY 

and  Ruth  Finney  will  show  that  there  is  ample  reason  for  American 
friends  of  civil  liberties  to  arouse  themselves: 

LAWS  AND  COURT  DECISIONS  DESTROYING  CIVIL  LIBERTIES 

By  U.  S.  Supreme  Court : 

Sustaining  right  of  Congress  to  penalize  expressions  of  opinions. 
Sustaining  right  of  Post  Office  to  bar  publications  from  mail. 
Sustaining  state  syndicalism  laws  making  mere  opinions  crimes. 
Denying  citizenship  to  alien  pacifists. 
Limiting  labor's  right  to  picket. 
Sustaining  "yellow  dog  contract." 
Permitting  tapping  of  telephones  to  secure  evidence. 
Holding  unconstitutional  state  laws  abolishing  anti-labor  injunction. 

By  Labor  Department,  with  authority  of  Congress: 
Forbidding  entry  of  aliens  holding  unorthodox  moral  or  political  views. 
Deporting  aliens  holding  unorthodox  moral  or  political  views. 

By  Post  Office  Department,  with  authority  of  Congress: 

Barring  from  mails  matter  "held  to  be"  obscene  or  defamatory. 
Prohibiting  dissemination  of  birth-control  information. 

Barring  under  a  section  of  the  war-time  Espionage  Act  still  in  force,  during 
peace  time,  all  matter  "held  to  be"  seditious. 

By  Customs  officials: 

Power  to  seize  imported  literature  which  they  hold  to  be  obscene  or  seditious. 

By  Radio  Commission: 
Controlling  establishment  and  conduct  of  radio  stations. 

By  Federal  Courts: 

Power  to  issue  injunctions  violating  the  rights  of  labor  to  strike  and  picket. 
Power  to  imprison  for  contempt  of  court  those  who  publish  criticisms  of  a 
judge's  action  on  pending  issues. 

By  State  Department: 

Refusal  of  visas  to  aliens  whose  political  views  are  held  objectionable. 
Refusal  of  passports  for  travel  to  American  citizens  whose  views  or  activities 
are  objectionable. 

State  Governments: 

Defining  sedition,  criminal  syndicalism  and  criminal  anarchy — 32  states. 

Punishing  display  of  red  flag — 28  states. 

Old  laws  of  reconstruction  days  in  the  South  punishing  incitements  to  insur- 
rection and  rebellion  (used  recently  against  strikers  and  communists). 

Power  of  governors  to  send  militia  into  strike  areas  and  without  martial  law 
to  suspend  civil  rights. 

State  police  systems  in  20  states,  frequently  used  to  curtail  labor's  rights. 

Power  of  state  courts  to  issue  injunctions  suspending  civil  liberties  of  labor, 
and  to  jail  for  contempt  for  published  criticisms  of  issues  pending  before 
a  court. 

Teaching  evolution — prohibited  m  three  states. 

Requiring  or  permitting  reading  of  the  Bible  in  public  schools  in  17  states. 

Prohibiting  atneists  from  testifying  in  court  or  holding  office,  six  states. 

Preventing  Negroes  from  voting,  in  10  states. 

Laws  punishing  "enticement"  of  Negroes  from  their  employment,  passed  in 
southern  states  to  obstruct  migration  to  the  North. 

Segregating  Negroes  in  schools  or  in  public  conveyances,  17  states. 

Censorship  of  movies,  six  states. 


DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY  299 

Defining  the  crime  of  obscenity — all  states. 

Making  a  crime  of  giving  information  on  birth  control,  13  states. 

Violating  the  traditional  rights  of  defendants  in  criminal  cases — among  them, 
for  example,  by  laws  permitting  juries  to  return  verdicts  on  three-quarter 
vote,  compelling  defendants  to  testify,  and  denying  jury  trials  even  in  serious 
cases  carrying  long  sentences  in  prison. 

Unique  in  a  jew  states  are: 

Coal  and  iron  police. 

Private  employment  of  publicly  deputized  sheriffs. 

Power  of  sheriffs  to  issue  proclamations  suspending  civil  liberties  in  "emer- 
gencies." 

Power  given  to  judges  to  enjoin  publication  of  newspapers  held  to  be 
"scurrilous  or  defamatory." 

Municipal  Legislation: 

Police   exercise  wide   discretion  in   denying   freedom   of   speech,   press   and 

meetings;  controlling  picketing. 
Requiring  permits  for  meetings  in  private  halls. 

In  addition  to  the  above-mentioned  specific  provisions  of  the  law  interefering 
with  civil  liberties  are: 

Decisions  of  many  courts  denying  to  aliens  the  same  civil  liberties  as  citizens; 
Unequal  civil  rights  of  women  with  men  in  most  states; 
Denial  of  civil  rights  to  Indians,  despite  their  admission  to  citizenship; 
Various  devices  by  which  Negroes  are  kept  off  juries;  held  in  practical  peonage 

for  debt; 
Denial  of  civil  liberties  by  various  devices  in  the  American  colonies  (Philippines, 

Porto  Rico,  Virgin  Islands). 

Some  of  these  abuses  have  since  been  corrected  in  part  and  new  forms 
of  intolerance  have  appeared  since  this  summary  was  prepared,  but  the 
general  picture  remains  essentially  as  outlined.  We  may  illustrate  a  little 
more  completely  the  invasions,  and  attempted  invasions,  of  American 
civil  liberties  in  the  twentieth  century. 

Our  country  was  founded  on  a  two-fold  revolution — the  Revolutionary 
War  and  the  legal  revolution  carried  through  by  the  members  of  the 
Constitutional  Convention  of  1787  who  exceeded  their  instructions.  Our 
leaders,  down  through  the  time  of  Abraham  Lincoln,  prided  themselves 
upon  our  revolutionary  tradition.  Even  so  conservative  a  person  as 
John  Adams  once  stated  that  no  people  should  regard  themselves  at  fit 
for  self-government  unless  they  had  carried  through  at  least  one  suc- 
cessful revolution.  Jefferson  held  that  we  should  have  very  frequent 
revolutions,  in  order  to  clear  the  political  atmosphere  and  fertilize  the  tree 
of  liberty  by  the  blood  of  tyrants.  Today,  there  is  a  different  attitude. 
At  the  close  of  the  first  World  War,  Benjamin  Gitlow  was  convicted  in 
New  York  state  for  uttering  Jeffersonian  doctrines  and  his  conviction  was 
upheld  by  the  Supreme  Court.  As  we  have  seen,  some  32  states  have 
passed  criminal  syndicalism  laws  outlawing  revolution.  Even  so  liberal 
a  federal  judge  as  John  Munro  Woolsey,  noted  for  his  broadmindedness 
in  censorship  cases,  upheld  the  Post  Office  ban  on  the  radical  periodical, 
The  Revolutionary  Age,  on  the  ground  that  it  advocated  revolution.  The 
Daughters  of  the  American  Revolution  placed  the  famous  preacher,  Harry 


300  DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY 

Emerson  Fosdick,  on  their  blacklist  because  he  used  the  word  "revolu- 
tion" in  one  of  his  sermons.  Some  of  the  Southern  states  have  revived 
old  slavery  statutes  which  impose  the  death  penalty  for  revolutionary 
doctrines. 

Nor  were  we  especially  afraid  of  economic  radicalism  in  former  days. 
Patrick  Henry  and  his  associates  frequently  denounced  "the  rich  and  the 
well-born/'  and  declared  that  the  Constitution  represented  an  attempt 
to  deprive  the  people  of  their  liberties.  Abraham  Lincoln  stated  that  the 
economic  bond  joining  together  the  working-class  of  the  world  is  the 
strongest  and  most  sacred  sentiment  to  be  found  in  human  life,  with  the 
sole  exception  of  family  relationships.  This  is  a  thoroughly  Marxian 
sentiment.  But  we  have  been  greatly  worried  about  economic  radicals 
since  the  first  World  War.  Injunctions  against  labor  have  been  extremely 
frequent  and  sweeping.  Even  peaceful  picketing  has  been  outlawed  by 
many  injunctions.  The  Supreme  Court  long  upheld  "yellow  dog"  con- 
tracts. Contempt  procedure  in  injunction  cases  denies  labor  the  right 
of  trial  by  jury. 

Wo  have  already  referred  to  the  many  criminal  syndicalism  laws  which 
outlaw  Communists  and  other  radical  revolutionaries,  such  as  the  I.W.W., 
and  the  fact  that  it  is  a  felony  in  28  states  to  fly  a  red  flag.  In  other  states 
it  is  a  crime  to  possess  radical  literature.  Such  cases  as  those  of  Angelo 
Herndon  and  Marcus  Graham  turned  about  this  point.  Repeated  efforts 
have  been  made  to  put  a  ban  on  the  Communist  party  and  keep  it  off  the 
ballot.  Employers  have  been  permitted  to  keep  private  police,  which 
have  defied  the  law  and  intimidated  laborers  in  wholesale  fashion.  This 
abuse  was  particularly  notable  in  Pennsylvania,  where  industrial  and 
mining  districts  were  dominated  by  the  notorious  Coal  and  Iron  Police.16 
Some  of  these  abuses  have  been  mitigated  by  the  Wagner  Labor  Relations 
act,  the  Norris-La  Guardia  act,  restricting  the  freedom  of  federal  judges 
in  granting  restrictions  against  labor,  and  in  certain  liberal  Supreme 
Court  decisions  relative  to  convictions  under  the  criminal  syndicalism 
and  red  flag  laws.  But  an  ominous  precedent  has  already  been  set,  which 
could  be  easily  revived  by  a  reactionary  administration. 

In  President  Roosevelt's  administration  the  persecution  of  Communists 
has  eased  off  but  local  violence  against  labor  unionism  has  been  revived. 
This  form  of  local  vigilantism  was  well  illustrated  by  the  procedure  in 
the  Little  -Steel  Strike  of  1937,  and  particularly  by  the  Chicago  massacre 
in  May,  1937.  This  showed  that,  even  under  a  federal  administration 
sympathetic  with  the  program  of  equal  rights  for  labor,  local  authorities 
can  develop  a  most  menacing  campaign  of  opposition  and  violence.  A 
senatorial  committee,  headed  by  Senator  Robert  M.  LaFollette,  carried 
on  extensive  investigations,  beginning  in  1936,  and  revealed  that  a  large 
amount  of  industrial  espionage  was  being  carried  on  among  union  workers 
by  employers,  who  paid  large  sums  of  money  to  private  detective  agencies 
to  spy  on  unionists,  foment  violence,  and  in  other  ways  discredit  the 


1<JSee  J.  P.  Shalloo,  Private  Police,  Annals  of  the  American  Academy,  1933. 


DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY  301 

labor  movement.  The  exposure  had  at  least  a  temporarily  beneficial 
effect  in  discouraging  wholesale  industrial  espionage. 

The  United  States  once  prided  itself  upon  the  right  of  asylum.  George 
Washington,  as  President,  protected  "Citizen"  Genet  against  his  enemies 
in  France,  though  Genet  had  flagrantly  defied  Washington's  neutrality 
proclamation  and  other  presidential  policies.  Since  the  World  War,  how- 
ever, we  have  shown  apprehensiveness  lest  we  be  harmed  or  contaminated 
by  admitting  to  our  shores  persons  with  too  progressive  ideas.  The  height 
of  this  absurdity  was  reached  in  the  case  of  Count  Michael  Karolyi,  a 
distinguished  Austro-Hungarian  nobleman,  who  was  for  years  denied 
entry  to  the  United  States  because  he  held  mildly  socialistic  doctrines 
and  had  favored  legislation  breaking  up  the  great  Hungarian  estates. 
English  labor  leaders  have  been  prevented  from  landing  here  because  they 
entertained  a  friendly  regard  for  Soviet  Russia.  Even  in  President 
Roosevelt's  administration,  the  distinguished  English  publicist,  John 
Strachey,  was  compelled  to  cut  short  his  lecture  trip  and  return  to  England 
because  of  radical  views.  Emma  Goldman,  the  anarchist,  was  allowed  to 
return  to  the  country  only  temporarily  to  vist  friends  and  relatives,  with 
the  stipulation  that  she  make  no  public  address.  In  the  days  of  President 
Jefferson,  if  we  may  judge  by  well-known  instances  of  his  procedure,  such 
persons  as  Count  Karolyi,  John  Strachey  and  Emma  Goldman,  would  not 
only  have  been  admitted  freely  to  the  country  but  would  have  been 
promptly  invited  to  the  White  House  for  conference  and  a  discussion  on 
the  state  of  the  world.  It  is  worthy  of  note  that,  prior  to  the  second  World 
War  no  person  had  been  even  momentarily  delayed  in  entering  the 
United  States  because  he  entertained  extremely  reactionary  opinions. 
Anti-republican  views  have  been  no  bar  to  entry  to  this  republic. 

Pacifism  was  at  one  time  extremely  respectable.  Jefferson  expressed 
such  convictions  with  great  vigor.  The  famous  Massachusetts  Senator, 
Charles  Sumner,  once  stated  that  there  had  never  been  a  good  war  or  a 
bad  peace.  But  the  federal  Congress  and  courts  have  taken  a  different 
attitude  in  our  day.  Citizenship  has  been  denied  to  highly  intelligent 
persons,  including  some  who  showed  great  bravery  on  the  Allied  front 
during  the  World  War,  because  they  would  not  agree  to  bear  arms  under 
any  and  all  conditions  in  the  event  of  another  war.  This  reached  its 
reductio  ad  absurdum  in  the  case  of  Madame  Rosika  Schwimmer,  an 
elderly  and  cultured  lady,  utterly  incapable  of  bearing  arms  in  any 
military  situation.  Other  notorious  instances  of  this  sort  were  the  Mac- 
intosh and  Bland  cases.  Justice  Oliver  Wendell  Holmes  rebuked  his 
conservative  brethren  on  the  Supreme  Court  by  contending  that  they 
presumed  to  deny  citizenship  to  those  who  take  the  Sermon  on  the  Mount 
seriously.  But  the  Court  remained  adamant,  and  pacifists  are  not  re- 
garded as  suitable  material*  for  American  citizenship. 

Despite  the  fact  that  we  had  no  legislation  suppressing  freedom  in 
regard  to  sex  candor  until  after  the  Civil  War,  there  has  since  been  a 
remarkable  development  of  repressive  legislation  and  procedure  in  this 
field.  The  Comstock  laws  outlawed  birth-control  information,  and  state 


302  DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY 

legislation  of  a  similar  sort  has  been  widespread.  There  has  been  much 
extreme  state  legislation  condemning  what  has  been  regarded  as  lewd 
and  lascivious  books,  pictures,  plays  and  the  like.  Books  have  been  sup- 
pressed by  the  Post  Office  authorities  and  the  Customs  officials.  Theatres 
have  been  padlocked,  in  violation  of  the  right  of  a  jury  trial.  Vice  squads 
have  freely  defied  the  legislation  and  court  procedure  regulating  the 
right  of  visit  and  search.  A  rigorous  sex  censorship  is  exerted  over 
moving-pictures.  The  Countess  Cathcart  and  others  have  been  denied 
entry  to  the  country  because  their  moral  code  did  not  square  with  that 
of  Anthony  Comstock,  John  S.  Sumner,  and  the  New  York  Society  for 
the  Suppression  of  Vice.  Liberal  court  decisions  have  recently  relieved 
somewhat  this  situation  in  the  field  of  sex  censorship  and  obscurantism. 
But  in  states  like  Massachusetts,  where  there  is  a  strong  Catholic  in- 
fluence, a  persistent  attempt  has  been  made  to  invoke  existing  obscenity 
statutes  and  to  pass  new  obscenity  legislation  directed  against  radical 
literature,  which  may  have  no  relation  whatsoever  to  sex  and  moral  sub- 
jects. Communist  literature  would  be  classed  with  pornography  in  such 
laws. 

Academic  freedom  is  still  frequently  violated,17  two  notable  cases  being 
those  of  Professor  Ralph  Turner  of  the  University  of  Pittsburgh  and 
Jerome  Davis  of  Yale  University,  very  able  teachers  who  were  turned  out 
because  of  mildly  progressive  economic  and  social  views.  There  is  no 
instance  on  record  of  a  college  professor  being  dismissed  for  ultra- 
reactionary  opinions.  The  latter  are  more  likely  to  win  a  promotion 
for  the  professor,  even  to  the  presidency  of  his  institution. 

Perhaps  the  most  ominous  case  of  the  violation  of  academic  freedom 
in  American  academic  history  was  that  of  Bertrand  Russell.18  The  dis- 
tinguished British  baron  and  philosopher  was  appointed  to  a  professorship 
of  philosophy  in  the  College  of  the  City  of  New  York  in  1940.  Imme- 
diately, an  impassioned  protest  was  made  by  Bishop  Manning  of  the 
Cathedral  of  St.  John  the  Divine.  After  much  acrimonious  discussion, 
a  woman  taxpayer  brought  suit  to  prevent  Professor  Russell  from  taking 
his  post.  Her  motion  was  granted  and  Russell  was  barred,  though  he  was 
supported  by  a  majority  of  the  Board  of  Higher  Eduation.  The  Court 
of  Appeals  of  New  York  State  denied  Russell's  appeal.  The  menacing 
character  of  this  procedure  was  emphasized  by  Chancellor  Harry  Wood- 
burn  Chase  of  New  York  University  in  a  letter  to  The  New  York  Times: 

However  much  one  may  disagree  with  the  Russell  appointment,  however 
repugnant  one  may  find  his  opinions,  the  basic  fact  remains  that,  if  the  juris- 
diction of  the  court  is  upheld,  a  blow  has  been  struck  at  the  security  and  in- 
tellectual independence  of  every  faculty  member  in  every  public  college  and  uni- 
versity in  the  United  States.  Its  potential  consequences  are  incalculable. 

Remember  we  are  dealing  with  opinions.  If  a  southern  court  on  a  taxpayer's 
suit  can  dismiss  a  state  university  professor  because  of  his  opinions  on  racial 
matters;  if  a  midwestern  judge  can  declare  a  university  chair  vacant  because  of 
its  occupant's  heretical  opinions  on  agriculture;  or  a  western  court  can  take 


i'See  below,  pp.  784  ff. 

18  See  John  Dcwey  and  H.  M.  Kallen,  The  Bertrand  Russell  Case,  Day,  1941. 


DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY  303 

cognizance  of  faculty  attitude  toward  the  Townsend  plan — then  indeed  we  have 
taken  a  long  step  toward  the  regimentation  of  our  public  institutions.19 

We  have  already  noted  that  revolutionary  publications  are  frequently 
put  under  the  ban  of  either  legislation  or  Post  Office  regulations.  In 
order  to  protect  the  freedom  of  the  press,  the  Chicago  Tribune  waged  an 
expensive  battle  to  prevent  the  suppression  of  a  scandal  sheet  in  Minne- 
apolis, but  no  paper  of  comparable  repute  has  ever  raised  its  finger 
against  wholesale  suppression  of  radical  papers. 

The  most  impressive  challenge  to  American  civil  liberties  before  the 
outbreak  of  the  second  World  War  was  probably  the  creation  of  a  Con- 
gressional Committee  under  Congressman  Martin  Dies  of  Texas  to 
investigate  "un-American  activities."  The  threat  to  American  liberty 
contained  in  the  activities  of  this  Committee  has  been  presented  by  the 
distinguished  educator,  William  H.  Kilpatrick,  in  an  article  "The  Dies 
Committee  and  True  Americanism,"  in  Frontiers  of  Democracy  for  Janu- 
ary 15,  1940. 

In  the  first  place,  the  Dies  Committee  has  failed  to  remember  that  it 
was  appointed  to  investigate  un-American  activities  and  not  "un-Ameri- 
can opinions."  This  is  a  distinction  of  capital  importance.  The  right  to 
hold  any  opinion,  however  conservative  or  radical,  is  the  essence  of  Amer- 
icanism. Congressman  Dies  has  as  much  right  to  his  opinions  as  Earl 
Browder,  and  vice  versa.  Any  person  or  group  of  persons  is  "free  to  pro- 
pose and  advocate  any  change  in  our  government  or  other  institutions, 
however  radical  or  sweeping."  To  oppose  this  freedom  of  opinion  is 
obviously  un-American,  and  it  has  been  so  recognized  from  Jefferson  and 
Lincoln  to  Theodore  Roosevelt  and  Woodrow  Wilson.  Jefferson  was  a 
passionate'  republican,  but  he  advocated  complete  freedom  of  speech 
and  opinion  for  those  who  wished  to  set  up  a  monarchy  here. 

It  is  always  essential  to  keep  clearly  in  mind  the  fact  that  the  American 
doctrine  of  free  thought  and  speech  means  freedom  of  expression  for  those 
whom  we  dislike  and  with  whom  we  disagree.  The  Holy  Inquisition, 
Ivan  the  Terrible,  Louis  XIV,  Napoleon,  Bismarck,  Mussolini,  Hitler, 
Stalin,  Diaz,  and  the  Mikado  have  all  permitted  freedom  of  expression 
for  those  who  agreed  with  them.  As  the  late  Justice  Oliver  Wendell 
Holmes  put  it:  "If  there  is  any  principle  of  the  Constitution  that  more 
imperatively  calls  for  attachment  than  any  other,  it  is  the  principle  of  free 
thought — not  free  thought  for  those  who  agree  with  us  but  freedom  for 
the  thought  we  hate." 

Dr.  Kilpatrick  finds  that  truly  un-American  activities  are  those  which 
interfere  with  orderly  discussion  and  voting  and  direct  allegiance  to 
powers  outside  the  United  States.  He  lists  five  groups  which  engage  in 
distinctly  un-American  activities:  (1)  those  which  sow  hatred  of  group 
against  group  upon  the  basis  of  race,  religion,  economic  status,  and  the 
like;  (2)  groups  that  practice  deceit  and  dishonesty  in  their  relations  with 

1°  The  New  York  Times,  April  20,  1940.  "From  The  Bertrand  Russell  Case  edited 
by  John  Dewey  and  Horace  M.  Kallen.  Copyright  1941.  By  permission  of  The 
Viking  Press,  Inc.  of  New  York." 


304  DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY 

others;  (3)  groups  which  acknowledge  allegiance  to  authorities  outside  the 
United  States  (these  are  not  limited  to  Communists) ;  (4)  groups  which 
deliberately  sow  dissension  in  social  organizations  to  exploit  them  for 
their  own  benefit;  and  (5)  groups — vested  interests — so  firmly  wedded 
to  things  as  they  are  that  they  resist,  by  force  if  necessary,  the  study  and 
discussion  of  existing  social  institutions.  It  is  interesting  that,  while 
the  totalitarian  revolutions  have  sprung  from  the  stupid  reactionary  re- 
sistance of  the  last  group  to  orderly  and  gradual  change,  the  Dies  Com- 
mittee has  never  summoned  to  Washington  any  leading  representative  of 
such  reactionaries  for  examination  and  exposure. 

According  to  Kilpatrick,  certain  items  in  Mr.  Dies'  activities  require 
special  criticism;  (1)  the  "smearing"  of  the  public  reputation  of  public 
men  and  movements  without  adequate  evidence  and  without  opportunity 
for  rebuttal;  (2)  the  outrageous  implication  that  those  on  the  Washington 
mailing  list  of  the  League  for  Peace  and  Democracy  were  Communists; 
(3)  Mr.  Thomas1  comparable  charge  of  Communism  against  prominent 
Washington  officials;  and  (4)  giving  to  J.  B.  Matthews,  an  ex-radical, 
a  public  aura  in  which  to  give  vent  to  his  private  grouches  against  certain 
consumer  organizations. 

It  is  well  to  remember,  Dr.  Kilpatrick  concludes,  that  "most  of  these 
so-called  un-American  practices  [of  radicals]  have  their  root  in  economic 
distress  and  inequalities.  We  shall  never  have  true  Americanism,  in  any 
full  sense,  until  we  can  remedy  the  unjust  inequalities  of  an  outmoded 
economic  system."*  Dr.  Kilpatrick  does  not  object  to  a  Congressional 
committee  to  investigate  un-American  activities,  provided  it  sticks  to 
activities.  But  he  does  not  think  Mr.  Dies  is  the  man  for  the  job:  "If 
the  work  is  to  be  continued  it  should  be  under  other  management.  If 
there  is  more  work  to  be  done,  Mr.  Dies  is  not  the  one  to  do  it."  20 

It  was  one  of  the  colossal  ironies  of  democratic  politics  that  the  same 
Congress  which  voted  billions  in  1942  to  help  us  spread  the  Four  Freedoms 
throughout  the  world  also  made  a  large  appropriation  to  enable  Mr.  Dies 
to  continue  his  reactionary  inquisition.  Mr.  Dies'  effort  to  "smear"  35 
members  of  the  Board  of  Economic  Warfare  as  "Reds"  and  "fellow  trav- 
elers" in  the  spring  of  1942  led  to  a  sharp  rebuke  by  Vice  President 
Wallace,  as  reported  in  Time  of  April  6,  1942: 

If  Mr.  Dies  were  genuinely  interested  in  helping  our  war  effort  he  would  have 
discussed  this  matter  with  me  as  soon  as  it  came  to  his  attention.  He  did  not ; 
rather,  he  is  seeking  to  inflame  the  public  mind  by  a  malicious  distortion  of  facts 
which  he  did  not  want  to  check  with  me.  If  we  were  at  peace,  these  tactics  might 
be  overlooked  as  the  product  of  a  witchcraft  mind.  .  .  .  The  doubts  and  anger 
which  this  and  similar  statements  of  Mr.  Dies  tend  to  arouse  in  the  public  mind 
might  as  well  come  from  Goebbels  himself  so  far  as  their  practical  effect  is  con- 
cerned. .  .  .  The  effect  on  our  morale  would  be  less  damaging  if  Mr.  Dies  were 
on  the  Hitler  payroll. 

20  For  another  excellent  analysis  of  the  work  of  the  Dies  Committee,  see  the 
Institute  for  Propaganda  Analysis  Bulletin,  "Mr.  Dies  Goes  to  Town,"  January  15, 
1940;  and  "Help  Stop  the  Dies  Committee,"  American  Civil  Liberties  Union,  Janu- 
ary, 1941. 


DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY  305 

It  is  an  interesting  commentary  upon  our  regard  for  civil  liberties  in 
the  United  States  that  a  self-constituted  and  self-supporting  organization, 
the  American  Civil  Liberties  Union,  had  to  be  brought  into  existence  to 
prevent  Americans  from  depriving  themselves  of  the  very  liberties  for 
which  our  revolutionary  forefathers  fought  and  bled.  It  was  created  by 
Roger  Baldwin  at  the  close  of  the  first  World  War,  when  an  unprecedented 
wave  of  intolerance  and  official  lawlessness  swept  the  country.  It  has 
even  had  to  labor  strenuously  to  save  the  "principles  of  76"  from  the 
Daughters  of  the  American  Revolution.  American  citizens  have  been 
notoriously  lax  and  indifferent  with  respect  to  their  historic  rights.  Had 
it  not  been  for  the  activities  of  the  American  Civil  Liberties  Union,  we 
would  be  far  closer  to  the  conditions  which  prevail  in  Germany  and  Italy 
than  we  now  are.  The  occurrences  since  the  first  World  War  have  served 
to  emphasize  more  strikingly  than  ever  before  that  the  price  of  liberty 
is,  veritably,  eternal  vigilance. 

The  capitalist  crisis  and  the  challenge  offered  to  capitalism  by  the 
industrial  proletariat  have  thus  brought  liberty  into  jeopardy  throughout 
the  western  world  as  in  no  previous  time  in  the  present  century.  This 
fact  is  presented  in  eloquent  and  authoritative  fashion  by  Harold  J. 
Laski  in  his  article  "Liberty  in  an  Insecure  World"  in  the  Survey 
Graphic.  He  points  out  in  colorful  fashion  the  alarming  developments 
of  the  last  decade  or  so: 

What  H.  G.  Wells  has  termed  the  "raucous  voices"  seem  able,  over  vast  areas 
of  mankind,  to  dragoon  men  to  their  will.  They  dismiss  freedom  of  thought  as 
worthless.  They  forbid  freedom  of  association.  The  normal  rule  of  law  is  bent 
to  the  service  of  their  arbitrary  discretion.  They  refuse  respect  to  interna- 
tional obligation.  They  impose  restrictions,  unthinkable  a  generation  ago,  upon 
freedom  of  movement.  They  abandon  ideals  of  social  reform  and  individual 
happiness  in  the  search,  at  any  cost,  for  power.  They  have  revived  the  law  of 
hostages.  They  have  been  guilty  of  cruelties  so  gross,  of  infamies  so  unspeakable, 
that  ordinary  men  have  bowed  their  heads  in  shame  at  the  very  mention  of  their 
crimes.  In  a  sense,  far  more  profound  than  any  to  which  Louis  XIV  or  Napoleon 
could  venture  to  claim,  they  have  exacted  an  admission  that  they  are  the  state; 
and  they  have  compelled  a  worship  of,  and  a  service  to,  its  compulsions  unknown 
in  western  civilization  since  the  Dark  Ages."  21 

This  was  the  condition  even  before  1939  in  Germany,  Italy,  and  other 
fascist  states,  which  occupy  a  considerable  portion  of  continental  Europe 
outside  of  Russia.  And  even  in  Russia,  democracy  and  liberty  fared 
little  better  than  in  fascist  states.  In  the  major  democratic  states  before 
1939 — France,  Great  Britain  and  the  United  States — there  were  ominous 
signs  of  the  impending  suppression  of  freedom.  The  social  reforms  of 
the  Popular  Front  under  Leon  Blum,  together  with  the  financial  and 
international  crises,  placed  liberty  in  jeopardy  through  the  incitement 
furnished  to  reactionary  forces.  In  England,  in  the  fifteen  years  before 
the  second  World  War,  there  was  the  most  alarming  symptoms  of  reaction 
to  occur  there  in  a  century — the  solidification  of  Tory  political  power, 


Laski,  loc.  cit.,  October,  November,  1937. 


306  DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY 

the  1927  legislation  hostile  to  labor,  the  Incitement  to  Disaffection  Act 
of  1934,  the  militarization  of  the  police,  the  savage  sentences  imposed 
upon  striking  miners,  and  the  imprisonment  of  Tom  Mann.  In  the 
United  States,  the  very  moderate  efforts  of  the  Roosevelt  administration 
to  reform  and  preserve  capitalism  raised  even  the  leading  beneficiaries 
of  the  Roosevelt  program  to  a  pitch  of  fury  against  their  benefactor. 
What  may  happen,  if  really  sweeping  reforms  are  proposed,  is,  as  Pro- 
fessor Laski  observes,  appalling  to  consider: 

Anyone  who  reads  the  record  of  the  American  labor  spy,  of  the  activities  of 
hired  armies  of  thugs  employed  by  business  men  in  industrial  disputes,  of  the 
gigantic  scale  upon  which  tax  evasion  is  practiced  by  eminent  financial  leaders, 
of  the  opposition  of  college  presidents  and  Cardinals  to  such  elementary  decencies 
as  the  prohibition  of  child  labor,  will  wonder  exactly  what  habits  American  capi- 
talism will  display  if  and  when  its  authority  is  seriously  challenged.2- 

The  major  cause  of  this  tidal  wave  of  reaction  against  freedom  and 
democracy  is  the  threat  to  capitalism  involved  in  social  reforms  which 
democracy  makes  possible.  The  capitalists  were  willing  to  make  some 
concessions  in  the  way  of  reform  in  a  period  of  capitalistic  expansion  and 
growth.  In  an  age  of  capitalistic  maturity  and  contraction,  reforms  have 
placed  unrepentant  capitalism  in  greater  jeopardy,  and  its  defense- 
mechanism  is  the  current  war  on  liberty  and  the  suppression  of  democracy. 
While  we  need  to  watch  the  rabble-rousers,  it  is  the  Economic  Royalists 
who  constitute  the  major  enemies  of  the  American  system  of  freedom  and 
democracy. 

Much  more  menacing,  however,  than  any  prewar  capitalistic  alarm 
and  reaction  is  the  outbreak  of  the  second  World  War.  This  has  meant 
totalitarian  expansion,  the  inauguration  of  totalitarianism  in  France,  the 
establishment  of  wartime  censorship  everywhere,  the  threat  of  the  ulti- 
mate extinction  of  civil  liberty  in  the  Old  World,  and  extensive  limitations 
on  liberty  in  the  New  World. 

The  Crisis  in  Liberty.  To  those  who  consider  historical  facts  and  have 
a  sound  historical  perspective  there  is  little  cause  for  surprise  that  liberty 
-may  be  going  into  eclipse.  Only  the  middle  class,  or  bourgeoisie,  have 
ever  had  any  great  regard  for  liberty,  and  this  middle  class  is  now  losing 
its  dominant  position  in  society.  The  laboring  classes  have  had  little 
interest  in  liberty,  except  insofar  as  it  meant  freedom  to  unionize.  The 
individualism  of  the  pioneer  farmer  is  disappearing  in  the  face  of  the 
farm  crisis  and  the  craving  for  government  subsidies.  There  is  no  liberty- 
loving  background  in  the  cultural  tradition  of  those  who  are  fashioning 
our  totalitarian  states.  Unless  the  middle-class  love  of  liberty  is 
espoused  by  those  groups  and  classes  in  whose  hands  the  future  resides, 
our  civil  liberties,  as  we  have  known  them  in  the  past,  are  certainly 
doomed.  The  destruction  of  our  middle  classes  by  the  economic  strains 
of  warfare  will  leave  us  without  even  that  tottering  bulwark  of  liberty 
which  we  possess  today. 


22  Laski,  loc.  cit. 


DEMOCRACY  AND   LIBERTY  307 

Many  thoughtful  persons  contend  that,  since  the  United  States  has 
entered  the  second  World  War,  we  shall  set  up  wartime  totalitarianism, 
which  is  likely  to  be  continued  long  after  peace  is  made.  But  it  is 
usually  taken  for  granted  that  our  fascism  will  be  of  a  nice  kindly  type — 
and  exercise  a  benevolent  authority. 

We  have  been  warned  against  any  such  "pipe  dreams"  by  E.  B.  Ashton 
and  Sinclair  Lewis,  both  of  whom  have  suggested  that  the  American 
totalitarianism  will  be  more  cruel  and  brutal  than  any  European  brand 
thus  far  known.  This  timely  warning  is  emphasized  by  Stewart  H.  Hoi- 
brook  in  an  article  on  "Our  Tradition  of  Violence"  in  The  American 
Mercury:23 

For  some  years  we  Americans  have  been  reveling  in  a  rather  superior  smug- 
ness. Viewing  the  various  species  of  savagery  in  Europe  and  Asia,  we  speak 
complacently  about  the  foreign  barbarians  slipping  back  to  medievalism;  about 
the  Dark  Ages  again  settling  down  over  the  world — except,  of  course,  in  these 
United  States.  What  has  been  going  on  beyond  our  borders  is  enough  to 
make  anyone  shudder,  it  is  true.  But  it  need  scarcely  evoke  feelings  of  superi- 
ority in  a  country  which  has  had  KKK's,  Molly  Muguires,  Black  Legions,  Ludlow 
massacres,  Palmer  raids,  and  countless  mobs  of  vigilantes  in  its  history,  if  not 
on  its  conscience.  In  sober  fact,  no  race  of  people  on  earth  has  gone  in  so 
joyfully  and  efficiently  for  violence  as  the  residents  of  these  United  States  of 
America.  Ours  is  an  amazing  record. 

Most  of  our  land  was  taken  by  conquest:  "To  begin  with,  most  of  our 
land  was  got  in  the  manner  of  the  Huns,  Italians,  Japanese,  British,  and 
French;  that  is,  we  took  it  forcibly  and  with  a  maximum  of  bloodshed 
from  a  weaker  people."  After  we  had  seized  the  land  on  which  we  lived, 
we  developed  the  habit  of  taking  the  law  into  our  own  hands:  "Once  we 
had  the  land,  we  went  into  an  era  of  mob-law.  The  habit  stuck:  we  are 
still  inclined  to  take  the  'law'  into  our  own  hands." 

For  generations  we  warred  against  the  Indians.  Then,  for  other 
generations,  the  frontier  was  ruled  all  too  commonly  by  mobsters  and 
vigilantes.  The  spirit  was  well  expressed  in  the  old  slogan  that  "there  is 
more  law  in  a  six-shooter  than  in  all  the  law  books."  This  sort  of  mob 
rule  reached  its  extreme  in  the  various  gold  rushes — to  California,  Mon- 
tana, and  Alaska. 

During  the  Civil  War  occurred  the  most  systematic  and  widespread 
rioting  in  our  history,  most  striking  being  the  draft  riots  in  New  York 
City.  Over  1,500  were  killed,  many  more  wounded,  and  a  vast  amount 
of  property  destroyed.  After  the  Civil  War,  the  violence  continued  in 
the  Reconstruction  era.  Southern  Negroes  and  northern  carpetbaggers 
led  a  reign  of  terror  in  the  South,  which  was  answered  by  the  defensive 
violence  of  the  Ku  Klux  Klan. 

When  this  epoch  of  violence  was  ended,  the  war  between  capital  and 
labor  began.  We  had  the  terrorism  of  the  "Molly  Maguires"  in  Penn- 
sylvania ;  the  railroad  riots  of  the  late  70's ;  the  Homestead  battle  in  the 
steel  area  of  Pittsburgh;  the  riots  in  the  western  mining  regions;  the 


23  November,  1939. 


308  DEMOCRACY  AND  LIBERTY 

bombing  of  the  Los  Angeles  Times;  the  great  strikes  at  Lawrence  and 
Patterson;  the  use  of  detective  armies  and  coal  and  iron  police;  and  the 
war  on  the  I.W.W.  that  lasted  into  the  first  World  War,  to  mention  only 
a  few  of  the  striking  examples  of  this  form  of  warfare  and  violence.  The 
first  World  War  stimulated  mob  action  on  a  vast  scale.  At  its  close, 
Attorney  General  A.  Mitchell  Palmer  launched  a  reign  of  terror  which 
made  peacetime  Germany  under  the  Kaiser  seem  "a  sweet  land  of  lib- 
erty.'* 

After  the  war  was  over,  Prohibition  encouraged  lawlessness,  both  in 
enforcing  and  in  evading  the  law.  It  also  launched  upon  their  careers 
the  racketeers  and  gangsters  who  have  created  a  new  era  of  lawlessness 
and  violence.  In  the  last  twenty-five  years  police  strikes,  strikes  in  coal 
and  steel,  race  riots,  lynchings,  strike-breaking,  the  revival  of  the  Klan, 
and  the  golden  age  of  racketeers  have  amply  proved  that  American  vio- 
lence did  not  end  with  the  termination  of  the  frontier.  All  this — and  a 
great  deal  more  could  be  listed  of  like  character — emphasizes  the  desira- 
bility of  solving  our  domestic  problems  by  democratic  methods.  If  and 
when  American  Fascism  does  come,  it  is  likely  to  write  a  new  chapter  in 
American  lawlessness  which  will  make  the  antics  of  the  frontier  vigilantes 
seem  like  peaceful  picnics.  Mr.  Holbrook  concludes: 

In  short,  Americans  have  no  reason  to  be  smug  about  the  foreign  barbarians. 
God  help  Uncle  Sam  and  those  cool,  calm  whiskers  of  his  if  a  sizeable  American 
mob  ever  finds  its  Man  on  Horseback!  We  have  a  long  and  lusty  tradition  of 
violence.  The  paranoiac  supermen  in  our  midst,  those  who  would  inflame  hatreds 
and  shatter  the  structure  of  civilized  legality,  are  the  more  dangerous  for  that 
reason.  If  the  dreaded  moment  comes,  the  doings  of  the  sissy  French  in  '89, 
the  Russians  in  1917,  and  the  Nazi  Germans  in  1933,  will  look  like  kindergarten 
brawls  by  comparison.  We  Americans  have  got  what  it  takes.24 


24  For  a  brilliant  statement  of  the  probable  stimulation  of  American  Fascism  by  the 
.second  World  War,  see  W.  H.  Chamberlin,  "War— Shortcut  to  Fascism,"  in  The 
American  Mercury,  December,  1940. 


CHAPTER  X 
War  as  a  Social  Institution 

How  War  Complicates  National   Problems 

BY  1941  THE  nations  of  the  world  were  locked  in  the  most  desperate  war 
of  all  human  history.  Our  own  country  entered  the  conflict,  fighting  a 
"war  against  war"  and  "a  war  to  end  war."  It  was  plain  that  we  could 
not  battle  with  complete  understanding  and  enthusiasm  unless  we  compre- 
hended the  extent  to  which  war  menaces  orderly  civilization  and  decency. 
We  must  fight  a  war,  but  we  would  fail  in  our  purpose  if  we  gradually 
come  to  believe  that  war  is  a  good  in  itself.  Such  a  philosophy  is  the  ideal 
of  the  aggressor  nations  that  attacked  us.  For  us  to  espouse  it  would 
mean  that  they  had  really  conquered  us,  even  though  we  might  overcome 
them  on  the  battlefield. 

When  we  fully  understand  how  great  a  challenge  war  is  to  human 
culture  and  security,  we  shall  be  the  more  willing  to  make  the  sacrifices 
needed  to  root  it  out  of  human  experience  and  the  less  likely  to  capitulate 
to  the  enemy  dogma  that  war  is  a  noble  pursuit  that  brings  out  all  the 
best  qualities  of  mankind.  We  shall  then  be  able  to  understand  the 
nobility  of  a  crusade  to  end  war  and  be  better  able  to  keep  the  present 
World  War  devoted  to  this  goal. 

The  lag  between  our  machines  and  our  domestic  social  institutions  con- 
stitutes enough  of  a  problem  for  man  to  solve  in  our  generation  without 
having  the  situation  further  complicated  by  war.  Our  social  thinking  is 
slow  enough  even  when  not  handicapped  by  the  mob  mentality  that  domi- 
nates public  attitudes  in  war  time,  and  our  democracy  and  party  gov- 
ernment are  already  inadequate.  However,  man  might  have  muddled 
through  his  present  difficulties  and  secured  a  fairly  efficient  utilization  of 
his  technological  equipment  if  the  second  World  War  had  been  averted. 

In  many  ways,  war  and  preparation  for  war  complicate  the  social  scene 
and  obstruct  social  progress.  As  we  have  already  seen,  even  in  normal 
times,  from  half  to  three-quarters  of  the  budgets  of  modern  states  are 
absorbed  in  some  direct  or  indirect  form  of  military  expense.  In  1938, 
the  nations  of  the  world  spent  over  $17,000,000,000  in  armaments,  getting 
ready  for  the  second  World  War.  The  United  States  appropriated  bil- 
lions more  for  defense  in  1941  than  was  involved  in  the  total  outlay  for 
relief  of  all  forms  between  1933  and  1940.  These  expenditures  for  war 
activities  leave  little  in  the  treasury  for  social  insurance,  public  works, 

309 


310  WAR  AND  PEACE 

education,  and  so  on.  And  war  finances  threaten  the  credit  and  financial 
integrity  of  any  state. 

Further,  war  upsets  social  reforms  and  can  destroy  the  results  of  years 
of  patient  and  constructive  statesmanship.  A  good  example  is  what  the 
first  World  War  did  to  the  program  of  the  Liberal  party  and  to  the 
remarkable  achievements  of  England  in  the  way  of  orderly  social  progress 
and  efficient  democracy  from  1905  to  1914.  An  equally  good  example  is 
the  memory  of  what  happened  to  Woodrow  Wilson's  "New  Freedom" 
when  Wilson  was  beguiled  into  entering  the  World  War  in  1917.  Domes- 
tic reform  stopped  forthwith.  Leading  plutocrats  who  had  been  deliber- 
ately excluded  from  the  White  House  prior  to  1917  were  thereafter  called 
into  frequent  consultation  and  were  given  key  positions  in  the  wartime 
government.  What  had  been  an  ultra-liberal  administration  ended  in 
the  reactionary  and  oppressive  orgy  conducted  by  Attorney  General  A. 
Mitchell  Palmer,  which  made  the  Alien  and  Sedition  laws  of  John  Adams' 
time  seem  almost  like  a  venture  in  civil  liberties. 

Many  competent  observers  believed  that  a  second  World  War  would 
mean  the  end  of  private  capitalism  and  democratic  government  through- 
out the  civilized  world.  To  them  it  seemed  possible  that  our  system 
of  society  would  be  followed  by  a  more  just  and  efficient  regime  of 
production  for  use  and  of  social  democracy.  But  this  was  no  more  than 
wishful  thinking.  In  any  event,  such  a  happy  result  would  be  gained  only 
with  much  loss  of  life  and  money.  The  second  World  War  might  well  be 
followed  by  a  peace  settlement  even  more  stupid  and  short-sighted  than 
that  of  Versailles,  thus  heading  the  world  for  a  third  World  War.  Or  the 
second  World  War  might  be  followed  by  rather  interminable  chaos  and 
the  extinction  of  civilization,  as  we  now  know  it.  The  elaborate  machines 
which  are  our  main  claim  to  a  superior  civilization  will  not  save  us  unless 
they  can  be  made  to  serve  rather  than  to  destroy  mankind.  When  the 
second  World  War  began,  mankind  faced  a  future  more  unpredictable  and 
more  ominous  than  at  any  other  time  in  the  experience  of  humanity. 

The  demands  of  war  on  the  United  States  are  appalling.  At  the  outset 
of  our  national  government,  in  1789,  our  annual  expenditures  for  defense 
were  $632,000.  Even  in  1810,  when  we  were  in  danger  of  war  with  both 
France  and  England,  we  spent  only  $4,000,000  annually.  In  the  middle 
of  the  nineteenth  century,  our  annual  defense  appropriation  was  less  than 
$20,000,000.  By  1880,  it  had  increased  to  $51,000,000.  A  new  high  level 
was  reached  in  1900  when  the  defense  budget  mounted  to  $190,000,000. 
On  the  eve  of  the  World  War,  in  1913,  it  had  jumped  to  $335,000,000.  By 
1930,  the  figure  was  $702,000,000,  and  in  1938  it  was  well  in  excess  of 
$1,000,000,000.  We  were  then  spending  more  than  any  other  country 
except  Soviet  Russia  and  Germany.  Between  June,  1940,  and  April, 
1942,  Congress  appropriated  over  160  billion  dollars  for  armaments. 

Those  groups  who  were  most  critical  of  the  modest  New  Deal  expendi- 
tures for  humanitarian  purposes  had  nothing  but  praise  for  our  war 
budget  in  1941  and  1942,  and  some  spokesmen  of  reactionary  groups  held 
that  it  should  be  far  larger. 


WAR  AND   PEACE  311 


Outstanding   Phases  of  the  Evolution  of  Warfare 

Changing  Methods  and  Techniques  of  Warfare.  Man  came  upon 
the  scene  of  recorded  history  already  well  experienced  in  warfare  and 
armed  with  flint-pointed  javelins,  bows  and  arrows,  stone  axes,  and  other 
fairly  formidable  weapons.  The  early  Egyptians,  Sumerians,  and  Baby- 
lonians gave  us  our  first  metallic  weapons,  of  copper  and  bronze.  Mak- 
ing use  of  organized  governments,  they  brought  mass  warfare  into  exist- 
ence. Greater  mobility  in  war  came  when  the  Kassites  brought  in  the 
horse,  about  2000  B.C.,  from  the  grassy  plateau  to  the  east  of  Mesopo- 
tamia. This  occasioned  the  first  appearance  of  cavalry  in  warfare. 
When  the  horse  was  attached  to  the  chariot,  this  brought  into  existence 
what  constituted  the  "artillery"  until  the  invention  of  gunpowder  in  early 
modern  times.  The  cavalry  and  chariots  made  possible  the  conquests 
that  led  to  the  establishment  of  the  impressive  Egyptian  and  Babylonian 
empires. 

A  great  forward  step  in  military  history  of  the  ancient  Orient  was  the 
invention  of  iron  weapons,  probably  by  the  Hittites  of  Anatolia  in  the 
fourteenth  century  B.C.  The  Hittites  built  up  an  impressive  temporary 
empire,  but  even  more  important  were  the  Assyrian  conquests,  which  were 
due  as  much  to  iron  weapons  as  to  the  military  prowess  of  Assyrian 
soldiers.  Their  army  was  made  up  of  heavy  and  light  infantry,  cavalry, 
and  an  engineer  corps.  Armor  was  fairly  well  developed.  The  chariots 
charged  in  line  as  a  sort  of  movable  fort,  and  in  certain  ways  were  the 
forerunners  of  our  tanks.  In  fact,  the  Assyrians  actually  worked  out  the 
principles  of  the  modern  tank,  or  armored  battle  car.  The  Assyrian 
military  engineers  contributed  much  to  the  science  of  sieges.  Their 
battering-rams  crumbled  the  brick  walls  which  surrounded  the  cities  of  the 
ancient  East.  The  fierce,  efficient  warfare  of  the  Assyrians  became  a 
tradition  which  has  lasted  to  our  time.  The  brutality  of  the  Assyrians, 
in  battle  and  in  their  treatment  of  captives,  has  rarely  been  equaled. 
More  than  any  other  people  down  to  their  time,  the  Assyrians  developed 
mass  warfare  by  conscripting  a  considerable  portion  of  the  vigorous  and 
warlike  peasants  who  formed  the  backbone  of  the  Assyrian  state. 

In  ancient  Greece  the  Spartans  developed  the  military  psychology  and 
the  military  cult  more  thoroughly  than  any  other  people  known  before  the 
Greek  age.  The  whole  culture  of  Sparta  was  subordinated  to  the  produc- 
tion of  brave,  well-trained  soldiers.  Valor  in  warfare  was  the  supreme 
personal  virtue  and  social  achievement.  Perhaps  it  was  only  their  limited 
number  that  kept  the  Spartans  from  developing  a  vast  empire.  As  it  was, 
the  great  contribution  to  conquering  warfare  during  the  Greek  age  was 
made  by  two  kings  of  Macedonia,  a  Balkan  state  lying  to  the  north  of 
Thessaly.  This  region  was  inhabited  by  a  hardy  and  warlike  people 
much  given  to  horsemanship. 

The  triumph  of  Philip  and  Alexander  over  the  Greeks  and  then  that  of 
Alexander  over  the  armies  of  the  Orient  were  due  to  military  methods 


312  WAR  AND  PEACE 

introduced  by  Philip.  Having  plenty  of  horses  and  warriors,  he  made  the 
cavalry  an  important  unit  in  his  plan  of  battle.  He  curbed  their  former 
undisciplined  fighting  and  drilled  them  thoroughly  to  advance  in  a  close 
mass  upon  the  enemy.  Even  more  important  was  the  creation  of  the 
famous  Macedonian  phalanx — a  dense  mass  of  infantry  armed  with 
eighteen-foot  spears  which  moved  irresistibly  forward  against  the  enemy. 
Ranks  were  eight  men  deep.  The  pikes  carried  by  the  last  line  extended 
even  with  the  front  line,  thus  making  an  ideal  offensive  presentation  for 
shock  tactics.  Philip  worked  out  a  military  scheme  that  placed  his 
massed  cavalry  on  each  wing  of  the  phalanx,  so  that  cavalry  and  infantry 
operated  as  a  single  impressive  unit.  With  this  military  machine  Philip 
crushed  the  Greeks  and  Alexander  defeated  the  forces  of  the  oriental 
monarchs,  in  spite  of  great  numerical  odds  against  him.  The  Macedonian 
army  was  the  finest  fighting  organization  from  the  days  of  the  great 
Assyrian  warrior-kings  until  the  armies  of  the  conquering  Romans. 

Home,  with  consistently  effective  military  methods,  conquered  most  of 
the  known  world.  The  basic  unit  in  the  Roman  army  was  the  legion,  of 
approximately  3,000  men.  Increased  to  about  6,000  men  by  the  cavalry 
and  light-armed  auxiliaries,  it  formed  a  brigade.  The  brigade  was  di- 
vided into  thirty  companies,  each  made  up  of  two  "centuries"  of  100  men 
each. 

At  first  the  Roman  infantry  operated  in  phalanx  formation,  much  as 
the  Macedonian  had  done.  The  defects  of  this  formation  were  revealed 
in  the  wars  against  Pyrrhus  of  Epirus  and  his  fighting  elephants  in  the 
third  century  B.C.  The  Roman  army  then  was  gradually  adapted  to 
fighting  in  open  formation,  and  with  this  plan  of  battle  the  legions  con- 
quered the  world.  In  battle,  the  Roman  army  advanced  in  three  lines,  in 
each  of  which  the  ranks  were  eight  deep.  The  third  line  was  usually  held 
in  reserve.  When  a  small  force  of  Romans  was  attacked  by  superior 
numbers,  the  Roman  soldiers  were  usually  arranged  in  a  semicircle  or  a 
full  circle,  so  they  could  face  the  enemy  on  all  sides.  The  very  flexible 
open  formation  could  be  shifted  to  meet  special  circumstances;  for  ex- 
ample, it  could  be  moved  apart  to  allow  fighting  elephants  to  pass  through 
with  little  damage.  Against  a  close-formed  phalanx,  elephants  were  very 
deadly. 

The  main  weapon  of  the  Roman  infantry  was  the  two-edged  sword,  used 
for  cutting  and  thrusting.  Javelins  and  often  slings  were  also  widely 
used.  The  front  ranks  hurled  javelins  at  the  enemy  and  then  closed  in 
with  their  swords.  Then  the  rear  ranks  threw  javelins  into  the  enemy 
ranks  over  the  heads  of  the  front  Roman  lines,  who  were  engaged  in 
sword  fighting.  The  infantry  was  protected  by  metal  and  leather  armor, 
which  covered  tho  body  and  part  of  the  legs.  Infantrymen  wore  sturdy 
helmets  and  carried  metal  and  leather  shields.  The  cavalry  was  armed 
with  long  lances,  javelins,  and  long  swords.  After  Marius's  time  the 
Roman  cavalry  was  recruited  mainly  from  foreign  mercenaries. 

Most  Roman  warfare  was  aggressive,  for  an  enemy  commander  could 
rarely  be  induced  to  attack  a  fortified  Roman  camp.  Heavy  loss  was 


WAR  AND   PEACE  313 

inevitable  if  a  Roman  camp  was  assaulted,  and  the  Romans  never  stopped 
even  for  a  single  night  without  fortifying  their  camp.  The  layout  of  their 
camps  was  derived  from  the  early  pile  villages  of  the  Terremare  peoples  of 
northern  Italy.  The  Romans  were  also  very  effective  in  siege  warfare. 
They  would  build  a  covered  terrace  up  to  the  walls  of  the  beleaguered  city 
and  then  move  in  the  battering-rams.  They  also  built  towers  against 
the  walls  from  which  javelins,  stones,  and  other  missiles  could  be  hurled 
into  the  city,  and  often  used  catapults  to  hurl  larger  stones  against  the 
walls. 

The  two  major  drawbacks  to  Roman  warfare,  especially  in  early  days, 
came  from  politics  and  religion.  The  commanders  under  the  Republic 
owed  their  position  to  political  rank  rather  than  military  ability,  and 
armies  were  sometimes  led  in  battle  by  grossly  incompetent  men.  More- 
over, religion  often  proved  a  handicap.  Campaigns  were  delayed  and 
strategic  moments  were  lost  because  the  auguries  were  not  right,  and  it 
was  believed  that  the  gods  did  not  favor  an  advance  at  the  moment. 
When  the  auguries  were  favorable,  however,  the  troops  had  an  added 
confidence  in  victory,  since  they  felt  that  the  gods  were  on  their  side.  The 
Roman  armies  proved  all  but  invincible.  Only  Hannibal  was  able  to 
outgeneral  the  Romans  for  any  long  period  of  time. 

The  Roman  world-conquest  and  pacification  of  many  peoples  by  sheer 
force  of  arms  had  far-reaching  consequences  for  the  Roman  age  and  for 
the  subsequent  history  of  mankind.  It  was  the  chief  source  of  that  tradi- 
tion of  the  prestige  and  glory  of  warfare  which  has  cursed  society  since 
Roman  days.  Oriental  monarchs  had  their  great  military  triumphs,  but 
Rome  symbolized,  far  better  than  any  other  ancient  state,  the  glorious 
achievements  of  armies  and  generals  and  the  subjection  of  civilizations 
to  the  rule  of  an  alien  conqueror.  David  S.  Muzzey  has  brilliantly  sum- 
marized the  effects  of  the  Roman  military  tradition  upon  subsequent  gen- 
erations : 

The  Roman  spirit  was  bequeathed  to  Europe.  Beneath  all  the  art  and  letters, 
all  the  industry  and  commerce,  all  the  advance  in  humanity  throughout  European 
history,  that  Roman  ideal  remains.  When  the  old  nations  speak  of  patriotism 
they  mean  the  memory  of  their  glorious  wars.  War  has  been  their  constant  occu- 
pation and  pre-occupation.  Not  a  generation  that  has  passed  since  Virgil  .  .  . 
but  has  paid  its  terrible  toll  on  the  field  of  carnage  to  the  ideal  of  pacifying  the 
world  by  arms. 

It  is  not  alone  Germany,  with  the  celebration  of  its  men  of  blood  and  iron  from 
Otto  the  Great  to  Otto  von  Bismarck.  The  French,  too,  rejoice  in  the  Napoleonic 
legend.  They  have  their  glorious  wars  of  the  Grand  Monarque.  They  bow 
before  the  white  plume  of  Henry  of  Navarre,  and  thrill  to  the  echo  of  Roland's 
horn  at  Roncevalles.  The  English  have  their  proud  memories  of  Agincourt  and 
Blenheim  and  Crecy  and  Waterloo,  and  celebrate  their  Napiers  and  Nelsons,  and 
"Little  Bobs." 

All  these  nations  of  old  Europe  have  their  glorious  traditions  of  war,  and  each 
one  can  find  enough  victories  in  the  uninterrupted  course  of  slaughter  through  the 
Christian  ages  to  justify  its  belief  in  its  own  invincible  prowess — nay,  even  in  its 
divine  mission  to  rule  the  rest.  The  Roman  ideal  still  lives  in  them  all.  Great 
Caesar's  ghost  still  walks  as  at  Philippi.  He  stalks,  gaunt  and  terrifying,  before 


314  WAR  AND  PEACE 

the  chancelleries  at  London,  St.  Petersburg,  and  Berlin,  at  Vienna,  Paris  and 
Rome.1 

One  of  the  most  important  contributions  to  military  science  in  the 
Middle  Ages  came  from  the  Greek  or  Byzantine  Empire,  centered  in 
Constantinople.  The  Byzantines  greatly  improved  upon  the  methods  of 
fortifying  castles  and  cities.  From  their  contact  with  the  Byzantine 
realms,  the  feudal  lords  gained  the  knowledge  which  led  to  the  remarkable 
advances  in  the  fortifications  of  feudal  castles  in  the  later  Middle  Ages. 
It  is  believed  by  many  authorities  that  feudal  warfare  represented  a 
regression  from  the  level  of  Roman  military  achievements,  and  that  the 
Roman  legions  could  readily  have  defeated  any  army'  of  comparable  size 
in  the  age  of  chivalry.  Without  entering  this  controversial  question,  we 
shall  describe  briefly  the  character  of  feudal  warfare. 

Down  to  the  thirteenth  century,  the  core  of  the  feudal  armies  was  the 
assemblage  of  mounted  knights,  aided  by  crude  infantry,  which  might  be 
armed  with  knives,  spears,  or  even  clubs  and  flails.  Mounted  knights 
were  protected  by  armor,  which  from  about  1000  to  1200  was  mainly  the 
so-called  coat  of  mail  or  hauberk,  made  of  interlaced  iron  rings  or  chain- 
work.  It  was  introduced,  in  part,  by  the  Northmen  and,  in  part,  by  con- 
tact with  the  Eastern  Empire,  where  it  was  in  use  at  an  earlier  period  than 
in  western  Europe. 

The  coat  of  mail  weighed  heavily  on  the  shoulders  and  arms  and  made 
it  difficult  to  use  weapons  with  full  force,  especially  the  sword  or  ax,  which 
required  a  good  deal  of  arm  motion.  Moreover,  a  blow  from  a  weapon 
drove  the  rings  into  the  flesh  of  the  wearer  even  though  they  did  not  cut 
through.  Cumbersome  pads  were  used  to  overcome  this  defect,  but  these 
further  impeded  the  use  of  the  arms.  The  superior  metal  working  of  the 
Muslims  produced  a  lighter  and  more  effective  coat  of  mail.  The  helmet 
used  in  this  period  was  usually  a  conical  metal  cap  with  iron  rings  pro- 
tecting the  face  and  neck.  The  disadvantages  of  the  coat  of  mail  led  to 
the  general  introduction,  after  1200,  of  elaborate  plate  and  jointed  armor 
and  intricate  helmets  with  effective  visors. 

The  horse  also  was  protected  by  armor,  which  changed  as  did  that  worn 
by  the  rider.  Archers  wore  less  armor  but  still  were  fairly  well  protected. 
The  rabble  of  peasantry,  which  occasionally  fought  in  the  wars,  were  able 
to  provide  little  or  no  protection  of  their  persons — only  crude  quilted 
garments. 

The  weapons  of  the  mounted  knight  were  the  long  lance,  a  heavy  sword, 
the  ax,  and  the  mace.  Foot  soldiers  other  than  archers  were  armed  with 
heavy  swords  for  cutting,  short  spears,  the  ax,  and  the  mace.  The 
mounted  force  was  far  more  important  than  the  foot  soldiers  until  the 
fourteenth  century.  By  that  time,  the  Swiss  pike  and  halberd  had  been 
introduced.  The  halberd  was  a  combination  of  lance,  ax,  and  hook  on  a 
long  handle.  After  these  had  been  introduced,  the  foot  soldiers  fought 


i  D.  S.  Muzzey,  The  Menace  of  Patriotism,  Ethical  Culture  Society,  1915,  pp.  4-5. 


WAR  AND  PEACE  315 

as  massed  infantry,  flanked  by  archers,  and  the  late  medieval  infantry 
became  far  more  important  than  it  had  been.  A  rudimentary  tank  ap- 
peared in  the  Bohemian  armored  wagon  of  the  early  fifteenth  century,  but 
it  was  never  widely  used. 

The  archers  became  more  and  more  important  as  the  Middle  Ages  wore 
along,  especially  in  the  English  armies.  The  brilliant  victories  of  the 
English  armies  over  the  larger  French  forces  in  the  later  Middle  Ages  were 
due  chiefly  to  the  superiority  of  the  English  bowmen.  The  ordinary  bow 
was  in  use  fairly  early,  but  the  crossbow  first  became  popular  in  the 
twelfth  century,  when  it  was  introduced  by  the  Genoese  archers.  The 
Church  opposed  it,  but  its  first  extended  use  was  against  the  infidel  in  the 
Crusades.  While  it  became  very  popular  outside  of  England,  the  cross- 
bow had  many  disadvantages.  It  had  to  be  set  or  "cocked"  before  each 
discharge  of  the  missile,  thus  losing  a  good  bit  of  time  in  which  a  longbow- 
man  could  be  discharging  several  arrows.  Further,  it  had  to  be  carried 
all  strung  up,  which  made  it  useless  in  wet  weather.  The  longbowman 
could  unstring  his  bow  and  keep  the  bowstring  dry  until  he  wished  to  use 
it.  Later  the  crossbow  was  strung  with  a  chain  instead  of  gut.  English 
archery  excelled,  in  part,  because  it  relied  chiefly  upon  the  longbow  in  the 
later  Middle  Ages. 

At  the  height  of  the  medieval  period,  the  mounted  force  was  the  back- 
bone of  the  feudal  armies,  aided  by  the  foot  soldiers  and  archers.  The 
feudal  horsemen,  about  whom  so  much  romance  has  collected,  were  actu- 
ally an  extremely  cumbersome  and  ineffective  fighting  force,  except  in 
massed  attacks  on  other  armies  similarly  equipped.  Assembled  from  all 
over  the  realm,  they  had  little  training,  discipline,  or  unity.  They  ad- 
vanced on  the  enemy  in  mass  formation,  so  close  that,  as  the  old  saying 
went,  "an  apple  thrown  into  their  midst  would  not  have  fallen  to  the 
ground."  This  made  it  difficult  to  move  rapidly  or  execute  brilliant 
maneuvers.  Moreover,  as  archery  became  more  highly  developed,  great 
confusion  was  introduced  into  the  massed  knights  as  their  horses  were  shot 
down  or  were  rendered  frantic  and  uncontrollable  by  arrow  wounds.  The 
undermining  of  the  preeminence  of  the  armored  and  mounted  knight  in 
warfare,  as  a  result  of  the  increased  importance  of  the  foot  soldiers,  armed 
with  pikes  and  halberds,  and  of  the  archers,  was  not  only  a  military 
change  of  great  importance.  It  was  also  one  of  the  more  decisive  factors 
in  the  destruction  of  feudalism.  The  kings  could  hire  their  own  infantry 
and  were  no  longer  so  dependent  upon  the  feudal  nobility  for  their 
military  retinue. 

Because  of  the  universality  of  fortified  castles  and  towns  in  the 
medieval  period,  siege  warfare  was  very  important.  There  was  little 
improvement  here  over  the  siege  equipment  of  the  Roman  armies — or  of 
the  Assyrians,  for  that  matter.  In  some  respects,  the  medieval  siege 
engineering  was  inferior  to  that  of  the  Romans.  The  usual  crude  wooden 
tower,  testudines,  scaling  ladders,  mangonels,  battering-rams,  and  cata- 
pults, were  the  main  offensive  weapons  before  the  age  of  gunpowder. 
Archers  would  also  discharge  showers  of  arrows  over  the  walls  of  be- 


316  WAR  AND  PEACE 

leaguered  cities.  The  lack  of  sanitation  in  the  camps  of  the  besieging 
armies  made  the  medievals  far  inferior  to  the  Romans.  Epidemics  fre- 
quently broke  out  and  either  greatly  weakened  the  attacking  army  or 
actually  compelled  the  raising  of  the  siege. 

The  use  of  gunpowder  came  more  slowly  than  is  usually  imagined.  We 
hear  of  cannon  being  used  at  the  battle  of  Agincourt  in  1415,  but  any 
cannon  used  in  the  fifteenth  century  were  quasi-harmless  curiosities.  Not 
until  the  sixteenth  century  were  there  any  cannon  effective  against  feudal 
fortifications.  The  matchlock  was  the  first  effective  small  arm  using 
gunpowder.  Next  came  the  flintlock.  On  this  was  placed  the  bayonet, 
thus  combining  the  old  pike  with  the  newer  musket.  But  the  medieval 
weapons  were  slowly  abandoned.  Bows  and  arrows  were  used  by  some 
of  the  infantry  in  the  battle  of  Leipzig  in  1813.  In  the  wars  in  central 
Europe  in  the  middle  of  the  last  century  not  a  few  soldiers  were  armed 
with  pikes,  spears,  and  axes. 

The  invention  of  gunpowder  restored  the  infantry,  for  a  time,  to  the 
position  of  predominant  importance  it  had  among  the  Romans.  This 
development  in  warfare  gave  a  special  source  of  strength,  all  other  things 
being  equal,  to  those  states  which  had  a  large  population  and  could  pro- 
vide an  impressive  army  of  infantry.  In  the  French  Revolutionary  wars 
and  the  wars  of  Napoleon,  a  new  stress  was  laid  upon  artillery  fire,  though 
the  infantry  remained  the  backbone  of  the  army. 

We  usually  associate  the  rise  of  conscription  with  the  absolutistic  gov- 
ernments, but  to  do  so  is  historically  inaccurate.  The  old  monarchies 
relied  upon  small  armies  of  hired  soldiers.  The  French  Republic  first 
introduced  conscription  on  a  national  scale  in  1793.  It  was  imitated  later 
by  the  Prussian  monarchy.  Democracy  introduced  mass  armies,  restored 
the  ascendency  of  the  infantry,  and  promoted  mass  murder  in  warfare.2 

In  the  first  half  of  the  nineteenth  century,  the  most  important  advance 
in  the  art  of  warfare  was  the  rifling  of  muskets  and  cannon,  increasing 
their  range  and  making  them  more  accurate  than  the  crude  firearms 
of  the  Napoleonic  period.  Percussion  caps  replaced  flints  in  the  firing 
mechanism.  Revolvers  became  popular  after  1850,  particularly  among 
the  cowboys  of  the  West.  Most  of  the  rifles  used  in  the  Mexican  War 
and  the  Civil  War  were  muzzle-loaders  fired  by  percussion  caps.  Very 
few  breech-loaders  were  then  in  use.  The  Austro-Prussian  War  of  1866 
was  the  first  conflict  in  which  they  played  an  important  part.  The 
Prussians  were  armed  with  the  so-called  "needle  gun."  Mortars,  canister 
and  shrapnel  came  into  use  in  this  period.  Repeating  rifles  were  not 
generally  used  until  the  Spanish-American  War,  when  smokeless  powder 
was  also  introduced.  Machine  guns  came  in  at  the  close  of  the  century. 

From  the  time  of  the  Anglo-Dutch  wars  in  the  seventeenth  century  to 
the  first  World  War,  the  command  of  the  seas  and  naval  power  played  a 
large,  perhaps  a  predominant,  role  in  deciding  the  outcome  of  inter- 
national conflicts.  This  fact  was  rationalized  in  the  vastly  influential 


2  See  Hoffman  Nickerson,  Can  We  Limit  War?  Stokes,  1934,  chap,  vii;  also  his 
later  book,  The  Armed  Horde,  Putnam,  1940. 


WAR  AND   PEACE  317 

writings  of  an  American  naval  officer,  Captain  Alfred  T.  Mahan,3  whose 
works,  incidentally,  were  most  faithfully  followed  in  Japan.  The  long- 
range  air-bomber  nosed  out  the  naval  vessel  in  the  second  World  War  as 
the  key  to  ascendency  in  warfare.  But,  so  deep  was  the  hold  of  the 
doctrines  of  Mahan  and  others,  that  England  and  other  countries  placed 
a  fatal  trust  in  their  naval  superiority  until  it  was  too  late  to  readjust 
their  pattern  of  warfare  without  sustaining  frightful  losses.  Even  bright 
newspapermen  were  able  to  write,  after  more  than  two  years  of  the  second 
World  War,  as  though  air  power  had  not  outmoded  Mahan's  doctrines, 
sound  as  they  have  been,  even  as  late  as  1900.4 

The  first  World  War  produced  the  most  striking  changes  in  warfare 
since  the  invention  of  gunpowder.  Because  of  the  great  technical  ad- 
vances that  had  made  machine  guns  and  artillery  efficiently  deadly,  open 
fighting  was  abandoned,  except  for  brief  attacks.  Long  and  elaborate 
scries  of  trenches  were  constructed.  These  formed  linked  zigzag  lines, 
and  had  subterranean  rooms  for  the  storage  of  war  supplies  and  for  the 
resting-quarters  of  the  soldiers.  Some  of  these  trench  lines  were  durably 
built — notably  the  famous  Hindenburg  Line. 

Separating  the  opposing  trenches  was  "No  Man's  Land,"  a  mass  of 
barbed  wire  and  artificial  banks  of  earth  and  stone.  The  impasse  reached 
in  trench  warfare  during  the  first  World  War  should  have  proved  to  the 
experts  that  the  ascendancy  of  the  infantry  was  at  an  end.  But  the 
generals  were  too  stupid  or  too  much  victimized  by  their  stereotypes  to 
recognize  this  fact.  Hence  we  had  horrible  mass  murder,  which  reached 
its  height  in  the  ill-fated  German  attack  upon  Verdun  and  in  the  mas- 
sacre of  the  Russian  soldiers  by  the  armies  of  Hindenburg  and  Ludendorff 
in  1914. 

Artillery  was  developed  with  scientific  acumen.  The  "barrage" — a 
terrific  wall  of  coordinated  artillery  fire — was  used  for  the  protection  of 
troops  advancing  behind  it.  Large  numbers  of  machine  guns,  the  most 
effective  single  instrument  of  the  war,  were  used  by  both  sides.  Huge 
cannon  placed  behind  the  trenches  destroyed  the  enemy's  towns  and 
fortifications.  Explosives,  both  grenades  and  mines,  were  added  to  the 
shrapnel  and  shot.  Poison  gas,  a  deadly  innovation,  was  first  used  by 
the  Germans,  but  shortly  by  the  Allies  as  well.  Camouflage — the  art  of 
concealing  vulnerable  objects  both  at  sea  and  on  land — became  a  wide- 
spread practice. 

Gasoline  engines  played  a  significant  role  in  this  conflict  as  driving 
power  for  tanks,  automobiles,  and  airplanes.  The  tank,  first  used  by 
the  British  and  probably  the  most  remarkable  of  the  many  new  instru- 
ments of  warfare  improvised  during  the  struggle,  was  a  huge  caterpillar 
affair  protected  by  an  iron  covering,  crawling  over  the  battlefield  un- 
stopped by  ditches,  barbed  wire,  or  mounds,  spewing  forth  bullets,  and 
bringing  death  and  havoc  in  its  path. 


8  W.  D.  Puleston,  Mahan,  Yale  University  Press,  1939. 

*E.g.  Forrest  Davis,  The  Atlantic  System,  Reynal  and  Hitchcock,  1942. 


318  WAR  AND  PEACE 

The  air  fighting  caught  the  interest  of  all  peoples.  One-man  airplanes 
were  used  in  the  first  year  of  the  war  as  a  means  of  discovering  the  posi- 
tion of  the  enemy  and  as  a  guide  for  the  artillery.  Later,  two-seaters 
having  an  unprecedented  swiftness  were  employed  for  bombing  purposes, 
and  for  the  use  of  the  photographers,  spies,  and  scouts.  Hydroplanes 
developed  by  the  British  assailed  German  submarines,  and  by  1916  squads 
and  formations  of  airships  were  organized  and  the  battles  of  the  air 
were  regarded  as  extraordinary  feats  of  courage  and  valor.  The  emer- 
gence of  air  "aces,"  survivors  of  a  succession  of  air  duels,  furnished  much 
of  the  heroics  of  a  war  that  was  otherwise  characterized  by  a  lack  of 
romantic  color. 

The  sea  operations  during  the  World  War  were  less  decisive  in  the 
form  of  battles  than  they  were  in  their  bearing  upon  the  control  of  the 
commerce  of  the  world.  Great  Britain's  naval  superiority  never  proved 
of  more  critical  importance.  German  commerce  was  swept  from  the  sea 
and,  very  quickly  also,  the  German  warships  outside  of  the  North  Sea 
were  captured  or  sunk,  and  their  raids  upon  British  commerce  terminated. 
A  water-tight  blockade  was  imposed  on  Germany,  which  did  more  than 
British  arms  ultimately  to  bring  that  country  to  its  knees.  Admiral 
von  Spee  destroyed  a  small  British  squadron  off  the  coast  of  Chile  on 
November  1,  1914,  but  his  fleet  was  soon  wiped  out  by  the  British  in  a 
battle  off  the  Falkland  Islands. 

There  was  only  one  major  naval  conflict  during  the  war,  the  Battle  of 
Jutland,  on  May  31,  1916.  While  the  Germans  were  ultimately  com- 
pelled to  retreat  before  overwhelming  odds  to  their  fortified  cover,  they 
inflicted  heavy  losses  upon  the  British.  Not  since  the  rise  of  the  British 
navy  in  the  seventeenth  century  had  the  British  come  off  so  badly  in  a 
major  naval  battle.  It  is  possible  that  Admiral  Jellicoe  might  have 
repeated  the  feat  of  Nelson  at  Trafalgar  had  he  been  less  timid  or 
cautious.  So  the  Germans  had  one  brilliant  exploit  to  their  credit  on 
the  sea  during  the  World  War,  but  it  proved  only  a  futile  show  of  superior 
bravery  and  strategy.  The  German  fleet  never  again  risked  its  fate. 

The  two  outstanding  innovations  in  the  second  World  War  were  the 
aifplanes  and  the  tanks.  These  had  been  introduced  during  the  first 
World  War  but  were  used  so  slightly  as  to  be  more  dramatic  than  effec- 
tive. In  the  second  World  War,  they  became  the  most  important  arm 
of  the  offensive. 

The  appalling  losses  of  the  Polish  and  Dutch  armies  in  a  few  days 
of  warfare  showed  that  the  best  infantry,  lacking  mechanized  equipment, 
was  hopelessly  ineffective.  "Mass  armies  merely  meant  mass  ceme- 
teries." 

The  outstanding  strategic  change  in  the  second  World  War  was  the 
so-called  Blitzkrieg,  or  lightning  war.  In  this,  the  airplanes  led  off,  ter- 
rorizing and  bombing  the  enemy.  They  prepared  the  way  for  the 
mechanized  forces,  equipped  with  tanks  and  motorized  divisions.  Be- 
hind these  came  the  infantry,  to  occupy  the  penetrated  territory  and 
consolidate  the  gains.  In  two  weeks,  the  German  Blitzkrieg  overcame 


WAR  AND   PEACE  319 

a  Polish  army  which  might  have  stood  ground  for  many  months  against 
the  German  army  which  conquered  the  Russians  in  1914.  We  may  now 
briefly  describe  the  organization  and  operation  of  these  mechanized 
troops,  recognizing  that  they  varied  somewhat  as  the  war  went  on  and 
opened  up  new  contacts  and  enemies. 

A  German  mechanized  division  is  known  as  a  Panzer  division.  •  It  is 
made  up,  usually,  of  two  regiments  of  break-through  tanks  and  two 
regiments  of  assault  tanks,  along  with  the  supporting  motorized  infantry. 
There  are  normally  around  four  hundred  tanks  in  such  divisions.  In  the 
first  World  War,  the  artillery  laid  down  the  barrage  that  preceded  an 
attack.  In  the  second  World  War,  the  barrage  was  supplied  by  German 
dive  bombers.  They  blasted  the  enemy  troops  with  machine  gun  fire, 
dropped  bombs  on  cities  and  fortifications,  and  laid  down  smoke  screens 
to  hide  the  advancing  break-through  tanks.  The  latter  were  usually 
twenty-ton  tanks,  carrying  8  to  16  men  and  armed  with  machine  guns  and 
small  cannon.  Moving  along  with  these  tanks  were  giant  amphibian 
tanks,  which  were  watertight  and  could  go  through  any  river. 

Behind  the  break-through  tanks  came  the  assault  tanks,  which  were 
smaller  tanks  of  6  to  10  tons,  also  carrying  machine  guns  and  small 
cannon.  The  assault  tanks  fanned  out  in  the  wake  of  the  big  break- 
through tanks  to  attack  and  demoralize  troops  in  trenches,  machine-gun 
nests,  and  pill  boxes.  They  could  also  shoot  flames  out  to  a  distance  of 
70  yards. 

The  third  wave  of  mechanized  assault  was  provided  by  the  motorized 
infantry  carried  in  armored  trucks,  followed  by  motorized  field  artillery. 
The  motorized  infantry  and  artillery  widened  the  breach  made  by 
the  tanks  and  held  it  until  the  ordinary  infantry  could  come  up  and 
consolidate  the  gains.  The  big  break-through  tanks  could  make  a 
speed  of  18  miles  an  hour  and  the  assault  tanks  were  much  faster.  For 
clean-up  work  and  special  assaults,  each  Panzer  division  included  a 
number  of  high-speed  Diesel  tanks,  which  could  go  as  fast  as  85  miles 
per  hour  on  the  road  and  50  miles  an  hour  across  country.  A  few  big 
eighty-ton  tanks  were  also  included.  These  were  literally  moving  for- 
tresses, carrying  field  guns  and  howitzers,  to  be  used  against  especially 
stubborn  obstructions. 

While  the  French  army  was  considered  the  best  in  Europe  for  partic- 
ipation in  ordinary  infantry  operations,  it  was  almost  helpless  before 
the  German  mechanized  divisions.  Fire  from  rifles,  machine  guns,  and 
light  anti-tank  guns  rattled  off  the  German  tanks  like  so  many  peas. 
And  while  the  French  75's  were  effective  against  the  tanks,  there  were 
too  few  of  them  to  accomplish  much  against  the  seemingly  limitless  re- 
plenishment of  the  German  mechanized  units.  In  the  Riom  trials  of 
1942,  former  Premier  Daladier  contended  that  the  French  had  more  tanks 
than  the  Germans  on  the  western  front  in  1940,  but  the  French  generals 
were  too  stupid  and  stubborn  to  make  use  of  them.  If  this  be  true,  it  is 
a  sad  indictment  of  the  French  military  mind. 

The  German  invasion  of  Russia  proved,  however,  that  the  Blitzkrieg 


320  WAR  AND  PEACE 

methods  and  the  Panzer  divisions  were  not  invincible.  Over  short  dis- 
tances, where  the  blow  could  be  struck  with  lightning  speed,  and  against 
poorly  mechanized  forces,  these  new  methods  were  indeed  overpowering. 
But  in  the  Russian  campaign  the  element  of  surprise  could  not  be  long 
sustained  over  a  great  front;  vast  distances  prevented  any  speedy 
knockout;  and  the  extensive  mechanization  of  the  Russian  forces  pro- 
vided a  worthy  foe.  The  novel  and  appalling  character  of  war  between 
fairly  well  matched  mechanized  forces  is  thus  summarized  by  W.  H. 
Chamber  lin,  in  describing  a  battle  between  thousands  of  Russian  and 
German  tanks: 

It  was  like  some  battle  of  the  gods  and  giants  in  Norse  mythology.  Houses 
were  overturned  like  ninepins.  Trees  were  uprooted,  hills  torn  up  in  such  a  way 
that  the  entire  contour  of  the  battlefield  was  completely  changed.  New  heights 
and  new  valleys  appeared.  And  the  crash  of  fifty-ton  tanks  ramming  each  other 
head-on  sounded  like  the  crash  of  doom.5 

In  addition  to  their  use  in  the  Blitzkrieg,  airplanes  were  extensively 
employed  in  bombing  cities  and  industrial  centers.  Most  notable  after 
the  summer  of  1940  was  the  German  bombardment  of  British  cities. 
Serious  damage  was  done  in  single  nights,  as  in  the  case  of  the  bombard- 
ment of  Coventry  in  December,  1940.  The  British  retaliated  by  bombing 
German  cities,  but  they  were  relatively  unsuccessful,  because  their  bases 
were  further  removed  from  the  area  to  be  bombed,  and  their  bombers 
could  not  be  adequately  protected  by  fighter-planes.  Airplanes  also  did 
much  damage  to  shipping,  and  were  able  to  sink  the  largest  warships 
and  airplane  carriers.  The  torpedo  plane  proved  especially  deadly  to 
the  heaviest  warships,  as  was  dramatically  shown  when  the  Japanese 
sank  the  giant  British  battle  cruisers  Prince  of  Wales  and  Repulse  in 
December,  1941. 

A  most  impressive  use  of  artillery  was  the  Russian  bombardment  of 
the  Mannerheim  Line  in  the  war  against  Finland  in  February,  1940. 
Here  the  bombardment  equaled  in  intensity  and  volume  that  of  any  of 
the  major  engagements  on  the  western  front  in  the  first  World  War. 

.The  submarines  were  most  successful  in  aggressive  naval  action,  while 
light  cruisers  and  destroyers  were  most  efficient  in  protecting  merchant- 
men against  submarines.  British  sea  power  still  remained  important  in 
enabling  Britain  to  maintain  her  blockade  of  Germany.  The  fall  of 
France  and  German  economic  relations  with  Russia  served,  however,  to 
make  the  British  blockade  less  effective  than  in  the  first  World  War.  But 
such  things  as  the  speedy  collapse  of  the  British  and  Dutch  holdings  in 
Malaya  and  the  East  Indies  in  1941-42  showed  that  the  day  of  sea 
power,  as  the  key  to  world  power,  was  at  an  end.  Sea  power  has  come 
to  mean  little  unless  supplemented  by  air  power.  Perhaps  the  airplane 
carrier  will  provide  an  effective  union  of  sea  and  air  power  for  a  far- 
flung  offensive. 


e  New  York  Times  Book  Review,  March  1,  1942,  p.  3. 


WAR  AND   PEACE  321 

Mechanized  and  total  warfare  has  become  a  far  more  brutal  affair 
than  even  the  first  World  War.  As  Gregory  Zilboorg  points  out,  the 
realities  of  the  second  World  War  are  as  bad  as  the  fanciful  "atrocities" 
of  the  first  World  War: 

We  were  almost  "chivalrous"  in  those  days  [the  first  World  War] ;  guerrillas 
and  franc-tireurs  were  considered  illegal,  illegitimate.  Today,  the  guerrillas  are 
a  worthy  part  of  our  "totality."  The  sinking  of  the  Limtania  aroused  the  world ; 
the  torpedoing  of  the  Zam-Zam  raised  but  an  infinitesimal  diplomatic  ripple,  for 
the  sinking  of  tankers  and  passenger  boats  and  the  bombardment  of  peaceful  cities 
have  become  a  part  of  our  totality  war  effort.  We  need  no  Lord  Bryce  to 
investigate  and  make  a  report  on  atrocities.  We  read  about  them  every  day,  for 
they  are  an  integral  part  of  the  atrocity  propaganda  made  by  modern  warfare 
and  life  itself.6 

Leading  Aspects  of  the  Evolution  of  War  as  a  Social  Institution.  As 
civilization  has  developed,  was  has  played  an  ever  more  important  role. 
However  it  may  have  started  originally,  it  has  become  a  vested  social 
interest.  The  use  of  modern  technology  and  economic  organization  has 
made  warfare,  more  destructive  of  life  and  property  than  ever  before. 
The  German-Russian  campaign  of  1941  proved  that  mechanized  warfare 
takes  a  tremendous  toll  of  human  life. 

Another  important  fact  about  war  is  that,  in  general,  the  large  countries 
are  much  more  given  to  fighting  than  the  smaller  countries : 

Countries  differ  greatly  in  the  frequency  with  which  they  have  been  at  war. 
Since  the  beginning  of  the  Seventeenth  Century,  there  have  been  about  2,300 
battles  among  European  states.  In  these  2,300  battles,  France  participated  in 
49  per  cent;  Austria-Hungary  in  35  per  cent,  Prussia  in  26  per  cent;  Great 
Britain  and  Russia  each  in  23  per  cent;  Turkey  in  15  per  cent;  Spain  and  The 
Netherlands  each  in  11  per  cent,  Sweden  in  4  per  cent  and  Denmark  in  1  per  cent. 
These  percentages  are  for  the  whole  period  of  three  centuries.  If  we  tabulate 
by  50  year  periods,  it  appears  that  the  percentage  of  participation  by  France, 
Austria,  Great  Britain  and  Turkey  has  been  constant,  that  by  Prussia  and  Russia 
has  tended  to  increase,  and  that  by  Spain,  The  Netherlands,  Sweden  and  Den- 
mark has  decreased  to  almost  nothing  in  the  last  century.  Clearly  the  great 
powers  are  great  fighters.7 

Out  of  950  years  of  French  history,  the  French  were  at  war  in  over 
80  per  cent  of  these  years,  and  only  one  quarter-century  was  free  of  an 
important  war.  Out  of  875  years  in  English  history,  72  per  cent  were 
war  years  and  only  one  quarter-century  was  free  from  war.  Of  275  years 
of  German  history,  29  per  cent  were  war  years,  but  no  quarter-century 
was  free  from  war.8 

Warfare  seems  to  concentrate  in  periods  about  fifty  years  apart, 
though  in  the  nineteenth  and  twentieth  centuries  a  hundred-year  period 


6  Saturday  Review  of  Literature,  March  7,  1942,  p.  7. 

7Quincy  Wright,  The  Causes  of  War  and  the  Conditions  of  Peace,  Longmans, 
Green,  1935,  p.  29.  Much  of  the  material  in  this  section  is  drawn  from  Professor 
Wright's  important  book. 

8  P.  A.  Sorikin,  Social  and  Cultural  Dynamics,  3  vols.,  American  Book  Company, 
1937,  Vol.  Ill,  Part  IL 


322  WAR  AND  PEACE 

for  major  wars  seemed  noticeable,  at  least,  before  the  second  World  War 
broke  out.  If  warfare  predominates  at  fifty-year  intervals,  the  usual 
duration  of  a  war  has  been  four  or  five  years.  In  modern  times,  the 
increasing  intensity  of  warfare  has  made  it  ever  more  difficult  to  prolong 
a  war  beyond  five  years.  The  fifty-year  period  for  the  concentration 
of  warfare  is  explained  by  the  fact  that  it  takes  about  that  long  to  get 
over  a  major  war  and  get  ready  for  another.  Further,  it  requires  about 
this  length  of  time  for  people  to  forget  the  horrors  of  war  and  accept 
another.  The  fact  that  our  generation  was  toughened  by  the  first  World 
War  and  that  new  machines  hasten  war  preparations  may  account  for 
the  world's  being  willing  to  take  on  a  second  world  war  in  less  than  25 
years  after  the  end  of  the  first  one. 

A  typical  technique  of  warfare  used  to  last  for  about  250  years.  In 
the  centuries  before  Charlemagne,  wars  in  western  Europe  were  fought 
mainly  by  armed  champions  supported  by  the  rabble.  From  the  era 
of  Charlemagne  to  that  of  William  the  Conqueror,  wars  were  fought  by 
royal  knights  and  footsoldiers,  who  were  able  to  maneuver  rather  freely. 
From  the  days  of  William  the  Conqueror  to  the  Battle  of  Crecy,  in  1346, 
wars  were  fought  mainly  by  heavily  armored  feudal  knights,  who  charged 
on  horses  in  mass  formation.  From  the  Battle  of  Crecy  to  the  introduc- 
tion of  firearms,  about  1600,  wars  were  fought  chiefly  by  the  infantry, 
armed  with  missile  weapons,  particularly  the  longbow  and  the  cross- 
bow. From  1600  through  the  Napoleonic  wars,  highly  mobile  forces, 
organized  as  national  armies,  dominated  the  scene.  The  infantry  was 
most  important,  but  the  artillery  came  to  be  of  great  significance.  From 
the  American  Civil  war  through  the  first  World  War  the  infantry  pre- 
dominated, the  army  making  use  of  ever  improved  firearms,  such  as 
breech-loading  rifles,  machine  guns,  rapid  fire  artillery  and  long  range 
cannons.  The  rapid  development  of  modern  technology  has  now  short- 
ened the  period  of  dominant  war-techniques.  In  the  second  World  War 
airplanes  and  mechanized  forces  had  come  into  their  own.  The  Polish 
army,  well  equipped  in  1939  to  fight  the  war  of  1914,  was  obsolete  and 
helpless  before  the  German  mechanized  forces.  A  change  in  technique, 
requiring  250  years  in  earlier  days,  had  been  brought  about  in  twenty-five. 

Leaving  aside  ancient  Rome,  there  has  been  a  great  increase  in  the 
size  of  standing  armies.  In  the  seventeenth  century,  the  larger  armies 
had  only  fifty  or  sixty  thousand  men.  In  the  Napoleonic  period,  France 
had  armies  as  large  as  500,000  men.  Before  the  second  World  War  broke 
out,  the  major  countries  each  had  over  a  million  men  in  their  standing 
armies,  and  Russia  had  an  army  of  several  millions.9  In  the  1930's  the 
standing  armies  of  the  major  European  states  were  twice  as  large,  in 
proportion  to  population,  as  the  Roman  army  under  Augustus. 

Another  historical  trend  in  warfare  has  been  the  decline  in  the  duration 
of  wars  and  in  the  proportion  of  war  years  to  peace  years.  In  the 
seventeenth  century  the  major  European  states  were  at  war  about  75 


9  England,  relying  on  her  sea  power,  was  an  exception. 


WAR  AND   PEACE  323 

per  cent  of  the  time,  in  the  eighteenth  century  about  50  per  cent  of  the 
time,  and  in  the  nineteenth  century  about  25  per  cent  of  the  time.  The 
twentieth  century  may  reverse  this  trend  and  increase  the  percentage  of 
time  the  nations  were  at  war. 

One  can  also  note  a  new  trend  in  the  increased  duration  of  battles 
and  an  increase  in  the  number  of  battles  in  a  war  year.  In  the  seven- 
teenth century,  there  were  about  four  battles  in  a  war  year,  in  the 
eighteenth  about  15,  in  the  nineteenth  about  28,  and  in  the  twentieth 
over  50. 

Before  the  first  World  War,  campaigns  usually  lasted  one  season,  and 
since  the  Middle  Ages  over  80  per  cent  of  all  campaigns  have  taken  place 
in  summer  months.  The  normal  battle  period  was  one  day.  Trench 
warfare  in  the  first  World  War,  however,  introduced  almost  constant 
battles  periodically  increasing  to  a  pitch  of  major  fury. 

Another  noticeable  trend  has  been  the  increasing  economic  cost  of  war, 
even  in  proportion  to  the  population.  In  Caesar's  time  it  cost  75  cents 
to  kill  a  soldier;  in  Napoleon's  time,  about  $3,000;  in  the  first  World  War, 
$21,000;  and  in  the  second  World  War,  about  $50,000.10  The  number  of 
killed  has,  however,  mounted  with  the  use  of  more  expensive  and  deadly 
war  equipment. 

There  had  been  a  tendency  for  the  ravages  on  the  civilian  population 
to  decline,  but  the  second  World  War  reversed  the  process.  Air  bombard- 
ment wrought  vast  damage  on  civilians  and  the  Blitzkrieg  produced 
millions  of  refugees. 

An  important  change  in  war  is  the  decreased  role  of  battles  in  determin- 
ing the  outcome  of  wars.  Economic  resources  and  organization,  and 
propaganda  activities,  have  become  relatively  more  important  in  win- 
ning wars  than  activities  on  the  battle  field,  though  the  latter  are  still  of 
primary  significance.  In  final  analysis,  wars  still  have  to  be  won  by 
fighting  rather  than  talking,  though  good  propaganda  may  reduce  the 
amount  of  fighting  needed  for  victory. 

Finally,  at  least  until  the  rise  of  totalitarianism,  wars  seemed  to  be 
getting  less  important  as  an  instrument  in  controlling  world  politics. 
With  the  increasing  cost  of  war  in  human  life  and  economic  equipment, 
the  nations  became  more  reluctant  to  start  wars  and  more  given  to  reli- 
ance upon  diplomacy  and  bluffing  in  promoting  their  policies  and 
ambitions. 

The  Development  of  the  Military  System.  The  origins  of  militarism 
go  back  to  ancient  history.  The  Assyrians  used  to  conscript  an  army, 
mainly  from  farmers  and  herdsmen,  for  the  war  season.  Sparta  first 
developed  a  thorough-going  military  system,  in  which  all  the  adult  male 
Spartans  were  compelled  to  be  perpetually  liable  for  military  service. 
Sparta  was  veritably  an  armed  camp.  In  the  early  Republic,  the  Romans 
conscripted  their  farmers.  By  the  late  Republic  and  during  the  imperial 


10  J.  H.  S.  Bossard,  "War  and  the  Family,"  American  Sociological  Review,  June. 
1941,  p.  339. 


324  WAR  AND  PEACE 

period,  Rome  had  a  large  standing  army  of  about  three  soldiers  to  each 
thousand  of  the  population.  From  the  decline  of  the  Roman  Empire  to 
the  rise  of  feudalism,  there  was  no  real  military  system.  This  faded  out 
along  with  other  ancient  institutions. 

In  the  period  of  feudalism  there  was  a  permanent  warrior  class  but 
no  national  standing  army.  The  feudal  lords  and  knights  were  sum- 
moned to  war  and  then  returned  to  their  castles  when  it  was  over.  At 
first  the  townsmen  of  the  Middle  Ages  fought  their  own  wars,  but  they 
soon  hired  mercenaries  to  fight  their  battles. 

The  first  standing  army  arose  at  the  close  of  the  Hundred  Years  War, 
when  King  Charles  VII  of  France  hired  a  small  standing  army  to  help 
demobilize  the  host  of  warriors  at  the  end  of  the  war.  From  the  fifteenth 
century  to  the  French  Revolution,  the  royal  standing  army  dominated 
the  military  scene.  But  the  king  did  not  usually  assemble  or  control  his 
army  directly.  He  contracted  with  private  individuals,  chiefly  the  lesser 
nobility,  to  collect,  train,  and  feed  the  army.  Very  frequently,  the  latter 
was  made  up,  in  considerable  part,  of  foreigners,  mercenaries  and  vaga- 
bonds. The  officers  were  drawn  mainly  from  the  nobility,  and  this  preva- 
lence of  a  caste  system  among  the  officers  lessened  the  efficiency  of  the 
army.  Later  on,  especially  in  Prussia,  military  schools  were  provided 
for  officers  and  a  more  direct  and  rigorous  state  control  was  established 
over  the  army. 

The  next  important  development  in  the  military  system  was  the  rise 
of  a  popular  army  and  the  introduction  of  conscription.  The  example  of 
the  American  Revolutionary  army,  an  army  of  embattled  farmers  and 
militia,  entirely  devoid  of  military  caste,  had  a  considerable  effect  upon 
European  military  thought  and  practice.  The  marked  success  of  the 
armies  of  Frederick  the  Great  also  led  to  serious  criticism  of  mercenary 
armies  led  by  incompetent  noblemen. 

As  early  as  1770,  the  Count  de  Guibert,  in  his  General  Essay  on  Tactics, 
emphasized  the  virtues  of  a  popular  army,  raised  from  the  citizens,  and 
imbued  with  a  spirit  of  patriotism.  In  February,  1790,  a  law  was  passed 
by  the  French  revolutionists  directing  the  technical  training  of  officers  and 
their  promotion  according  to  a  system  of  merit.  In  February  and 
August,  1793,  conscription  was  ordered,  to  provide  a  strong  national  army 
and  repel  the  invasion  of  France  by  the  reactionary  powers.  The  old 
noble  officers  were  thrown  out  and  revolutionary  generals  were  installed. 
The  result  was  the  first  national  army  on  a  mass  scale: 

Given  mass  armies  inspired  to  frenzy  by  the  passions  and  ideas  of  the  Revolu- 
tion, warfare  took  on  novel  aspects.  Within  and  around  the  regular  troops  of 
the  old  style  were  large  numbers  of  men,  more  individualized  and  more  ruthless 
in  combat  than  any  soldiers  of  a  standing  army,  drilled  and  commanded  by  noble 
officers  accustomed  to  the  conceptions  and  customs  of  feudal  honor.  Recruiting 
under  the  February  Law  brought  180,000;  the  levee  en  masse  some  250,000  men. 
By  January  1,  1794,  some  770,000  men  belonged  to  the  diverse  armies  and 
500,000  of  them  stood  along  the  exterior  front.11 

11  Alfred  Vagts,  A  History  of  Militarism,  Norton,  1937,  p.  116. 


WAR  AND   PEACE  325 

Napoleon  improved  and  extended  this  system  of  national  armies.  He 
developed  the  notion  of  the  "total  war,"  as  the  business  of  the  whole 
people.  Mr.  Hoffman  Nickerson,  in  his  essay  on  "Democracy  and  Mass 
Massacre" 12  and  his  more  recent  book,  The  Armed  Horde,™  has  shown  the 
great  significance  of  this  change.  The  losses  of  life  in  the  French  Revo- 
lutionary and  the  Napoleonic  wars  vastly  exceeded  those  of  any  earlier 
war.  Only  5,000  men  had  been  killed  in  1704,  the  year  of  the  Battle  of 
Blenheim.  With  so  many  men  at  his  disposal,  Napoleon  was  prodigal 
of  men  in  battle.  He  lost  about  40,000  men  in  the  Battle  of  Borodino 
in  1812.  This  waste  of  manpower  was  one  reason  for  his  ultimate  defeat. 
Finally,  disease  in  these  mass  armies,  without  scientific  provision  for 
sanitation  and  medical  treatment,  killed  even  more  than  gunfire.  There 
is  no  doubt  that  conscription  and  the  national  army  enormously  increased 
the  deadliness  and  ferocity  of  war.  Another  effect  of  conscription  was 
to  make  armies  revolutionary  and  devoted  to  extending  the  new  system 
of  society  by  force  of  arms.  This  fact  was  not  realized  by  American 
conservatives,  when  they  so  enthusiastically  recommended  peacetime 
conscription  for  the  United  States  in  1940. 

Conscription  and  universal  military  service,  even  in  peace  time,  are 
frequently  confused.  We  may  conscript  a  large  number  of  persons  for 
a  given  war,  but  have  no  system  of  universal  military  service,  in  which 
all  the  able-bodied  male  population  have  to  submit  to  military  training 
for  one  or  more  years,  in  peace  time  as  well  as  war.  Soldiers  conscripted 
for  a  war  may  be  allowed  to  return  home  as  soon  as  the  war  is  over.  It 
was  Prussia  which  introduced  universal  military  service  in  modern  times. 
After  Napoleon  had  conquered  the  Prussians  at  Jena,  in  1806,  he  ordered 
the  Prussian  army  reduced  to  42,000  men.  But  the  Prussians  got  around 
his  restrictions  by  subterfuge.  They  trained  42,000  men,  then  returned 
them  to  private  life  and  trained  another  42,000,  thus  building  up  a  large 
well-trained  army.  Scharnhorst,  Boyen,  and  other  Prussian  military 
reformers  recommended  drawing  all  able-bodied  Prussians  into  army 
service.  Preliminary  laws  were  passed  in  1812-1813  and  finally,  in 
September,  1814,  universal  military  service  was  established.  It  was 
extended  to  the  German  Empire  after  1870. 

After  the  Franco-Prussian  War,  the  Third  French  Republic  succumbed 
to  the  system  of  universal  military  service  and  created  a  national  mass 
army  with  the  law  of  1872.  Since  France  had  a  smaller  population  than 
Germany,  but  wished  to  have  just  as  strong  an  army,  she  had  to  have  a 
larger  proportion  of  her  population  under  arms.  The  majority  of  other 
Continental  states  had  either  established  a  system  of  universal  military 
service  before  the  Franco-Prussian  War  or  followed  in  the  wake  of 
France  after  1872.  Great  Britain  held  out  against  conscription  until  the 
first  World  War.  During  this  conflict  all  the  major  powers  involved, 
including  the  United  States,  resorted  to  conscription. 

12  Originally  published  in  The  American  Mercury,  and  reprinted  as  chap,  vii  of 
his  Can  We  Limit  War? 

13  Putnam,  1940. 


326  WAR  AND  PEACE 

In  the  1930's  the  Nazis,  in  Germany,  set  up  a  military  system  more 
thoroughgoing  and  efficient  than  anything  ever  envisaged  by  Scharnhorst, 
Bismarck,  Moltke,  or  the  Kaiser.  They  not  only  provided  for  universal 
service  but  essentially  conscripted  the  whole  civilian  population  in  "total 
war"  preparations: 

Both  Fascism  and  Communism,  depending  more  than  democracies  for  their 
daily  existence  on  their  armies,  attempt  a  greater  penetration  of  their  peoples 
by  military  ideas ;  the  masses  are  organized  in  a  quasi-military  way  in  uniformed 
formations  under  leaders  whom  the  rank  and  file  recognize  as  permanent,  not 
merely  temporary,  superiors.  Military  metaphors  abound  in  directions  and 
exhortations,  such  as  "victories  on  the  harvest  front,"  the  "butter  battle/'  the 
"March  on  Rome."  But  there  is  some  difference  in  aim  between  them:  the 
Bolshevist  state  indeed  offers  the  theoretical  promise  that  the  military  bondage 
of  the  present  is  only  a  transition  period  on  the  way  to  a  millennium  in  which 
all  force  will  be  ended;  it  does  not  exalt  military  exertion  and  expenditure  as 
good  in  themselves.  By  contrast,  the  militarism  of  the  Third  Reich  is  expected 
even  theoretically  to  endure  one  or  two  thousand  years,  for  it  is  the  essence  of 
that  Empire;  there,  as  Sieburg  says,  "the  population  sees  in  the  carrier  of  arms 
a  symbol  of  itself."  14 

Another  interesting  aspect  of  totalitarian  militarism  is  that,  like  the 
military  situation  in  the  French  Revolution,  the  conscript  mass  armies 
have  once  again  become  revolutionary  armies,  spreading  revolution  by 
military  force.  They  will  spread  revolution,  even  though  they  may  be 
defeated,  just  as  Napoleon's  armies  promoted  the  rise  of  nationalism  and 
other  revolutionary  changes  in  the  countries  which  he  overran. 

The  Underlying  Causes  of  War  in 
Contemporary  Society 

Biological  Causes  of  War.  There  can  be  no  hope  of  ending  war  unless 
we  thoroughly  understand  the  complex  forces  which  lead  mankind  to 
continue  this  savage  and  archaic  method  of  handling  the  relations  among 
states.  War  can  be  disposed  of  only  through  an  understanding  of,  and  a 
consistent  attack  upon,  those  material  conditions  and  those  attitudes 
of  mind  which  make  them  possible  in  contemporary  society.  Any  limited 
conception  of  the  causes  of  war  or  any  tendency  to  overemphasize  one 
set  of  causes  must  be  guarded  against: 

The  motives  which  have  led  to  aggression  by  human  populations  are  too 
numerous  to  mention.  Leaders  have  sought  wealth,  revenge,  prestige,  dynastic 
expansion,  the  deflation  of  internal  revolt,  adventure  and  the  propaganda  of 
religions;  and  the  masses  have  supported  them  with  the  expectation  of  adven- 
ture, plunder,  sadistic  orgies,  relief  from  boredom,  better  lands,  higher  wages, 
loyalty  to  the  leader,  religious  enthusiasm,  feminine  approval.15 

The  biological  causes  of  war  include  those  that  represent  biological 
realities  and  those  which  rest  upon  a  mistaken  application  of  biological 


14  Vagts,  op.  cit.,  p.  442. 

15  Wright,  The  Causes  of  War  and  the  Conditions  of  Peace,  p.  108. 


WAR  AND  PEACE  327 

and  pseudo-biological  principles  to  social  processes.  The  most  important 
potential  biological  cause  of  war  is  that  tendency  of  the  human  species 
to  increase  more  rapidly  than  the  means  of  subsistence,  a  fact  perceived 
by  Malthus  more  than  a  century  ago.  This  tendency  makes  it  necessary 
for  the  surplus  population  to  look  elsewhere  for  new  homes.  There  was, 
however,  down  to  the  first  World  War,  a  large  amount  of  relatively  un- 
occupied space,  to  which  the  surplus  populations  of  the  more  congested 
districts  of  the  world  might  freely  migrate.  Hence  there  was  no  direct 
biological  cause  of  war  inherent  in  population  increases  down  to  1914. 

Yet  population  pressure  was  a  contributing  cause  in  producing  the 
world  catastrophe  of  1914,  because  that  popular  biological  doctrine  had 
become  inseparably  linked  with  a  dangerous  political  dogma.  It  was 
commonly  believed  to  be  disastrous  both  to  the  mother  country  and  to 
the  emigrants  for  any  large  number  of  people  to  take  up  residence  under 
the  political  authority  of  another  country.  It  was  held  that  migrating 
citizens  should  retain  their  citizenship  and  carry  the  glories  of  their  native 
land  overseas. 

Such  an  aspiration  was  possible  only  in  conjunction  with  the  develop- 
ment of  colonies.  While  much  of  the  earth's  surface  was  still  available 
for  occupation  by  individuals,  relatively  little  remained  open  for  the 
colonial  dominion  of  any  state  at  the  close  of  the  nineteenth  century. 
England,  Russia,  France  and  Holland  had  appropriated  the  larger  portion 
of  the  earth's  surface  not  already  under  the  dominion  of  independent 
sovereign  states. 

The  desire  to  obtain  colonies  for  population  outlet,  particularly  on  the 
part  of  Germany,  Italy,  and  Japan,  and  the  hard  fact  that  potential 
colonial  areas  were  constantly  diminishing,  precipitated  many  of  the 
international  crises  which  constituted  the  diplomatic  background  of  the 
wars  between  1900  and  1920.  Had  not  the  patriotic  and  colonial 
psychosis  existed,  however,  the  population  increases  would  not  have  been 
an  important  factor  in  producing  international  problems  and  promoting 
war. 

Though  population  increase  may  not,  in  the  past,  have  constituted  a 
vital  cause  of  conflict,  it  may  be  an  important  cause  of  war  in  the  future. 
There  are  actually  some  areas  which  are  now  becoming  overpopulated, 
when  taken  in  conjunction  with  their  limited  resources  or  technological 
lag.  Writers  like  W.  S.  Thompson  have  referred  to  these  areas  as 
"danger  spots  in  world  population."  It  has  been  held  that  the  recent 
tendency  for  the  rate  of  population  growth  to  slow  down  in  western 
countries  removes  this  cause  of  war  and  war  sentiment.  This  is  not  true, 
so  long  as  the  population  is  growing  rapidly  elsewhere  and  pressing  on 
the  means  of  subsistence,  and  so  long  as  western  states  have  colonial, 
imperialistic,  and  diplomatic  interests  in  eastern  regions  which  are  directly 
affected  by  rapid  population  growth.  Only  a  universal  slowing  down 
would  remove  this  biological  impulse  to  war. 

Another  important  biological  fact  in  the  war  pattern  is  that  man  has 
developed  to  his  present  state  of  ascendancy  in  part  by  operating  as  a 


328  WAR  AND  PEACE 

fighting  animal.  War  and  physical  struggles  have  unquestionably  played 
an  important  role  in  the  biological  history  of  man,  and  have  left  their 
impress  upon  him  in  his  instinctive  tendencies,  physiological  processes, 
and  traditional  values: 

Men  *like  war.  They  often  fight  for  the  love  of  excitement  or  the  mere  lust 
of  fighting.  While  it  is  true,  as  someone  has  said,  that  anyone  will  fight  when 
he  is  mad  enough,  it  is  also  a  fact  that  men  will  fight  when  they  are  not  aroused, 
but  just  for  the  fun  of  it.  War  offers  diversion  and  relief  from  ennui.  It  pro- 
vides a  mode  of  escape  from  the  monotony  of  a  dull  existence.  Primitive  life 
seems  to  afford  scanty  amusements  and  means  of  recreation;  the  savage  is  so 
engrossed  in  a  severe  struggle  for  existence  that  his  life  leaves  little  room  for 
diversion.  Hence  men  like  to  fight.  The  most  exciting  things  they  know  are 
hunting,  herding,  and  warfare.  These  are  the  occupations  they  enjoy,  and  their 
pursuit  affords  a  considerable  measure  of  satisfaction  and  pleasure. 

War  also  furnishes  a  ready  means  of  bringing  distinction  to  one's  self,  for  the 
military  virtues  have  ever  been  honored  and  extolled.  The  women,  as  we  have 
seen,  prefer  men  who  have  given  proof  of  their  prowess,  they  receive  the  returning 
warrior  with  songs  of  praise,  they  feast  him  and  crowd  around  to  listen  to  his 
exploits.  All  this  appeals  to  man's  vanity  and  gives  him  additional  motives  for 
fighting.16 

It  would  be  nonsense  to  contend,  as  some  have  done,  that  man  is  pre- 
eminently a  fighting  animal,  but  it  is  equally  absurd  to  maintain  that  he 
is  wholly  pacific  and  characterized  chiefly  by  a  sweet-tempered  spirit  of 
brotherly  love.  The  sane  procedure  for  the  friends  of  peace  is  to  provide 
an  educational  system  which  will  promote  the  pacific  and  cooperative 
tendencies  of  man  and  sublimate  or  divert  his  warlike  proclivities.  Any 
scheme  for  peace  which  ignores  the  inherent  human  capacity  for  blind 
rage  toward  citizens  of  other  states  is  likely  to  be  wrecked.  This  fact 
was  well  driven  home  by  the  example  of  the  international  Socialists  of 
the  various  European  countries  who,  before  the  first  World  War,  had 
sworn  to  an  eternal  brotherhood  based  on  the  international  solidarity 
of  the  working  classes,  but  who  rallied  to  the  standards  of  their  several 
fatherlands  in  the  summer  of  1914  with  a  gusto  which,  in  many  cases, 
exceeded  that  evidenced  by  the  monarchists  and  capitalists.  It  was  also 
demonstrated  amply  by  the  American  liberals  and  radicals,  who  had  been 
the  backbone  of  the  peace  movement  from  1920  to  1939.  They  took  the 
lead  in  stirring  up  war  sentiment  in  the  United  States  from  1939  to  1942. 

Among  the  erroneous  dogmas  about  war  is  the  doctrine  that  war,  in 
human  society,  is  the  social  analogue  of  the  biological  struggle  for  exist- 
ence in  the  realm  of  organic  evolution.  This  is  the  doctrine  which  is 
sometimes  known  as  "social  Darwinism."  It  is  incorrect  to  hold  Darwin 
responsible  for  any  such  dogma,  as  he  frankly  admitted  that  he  did  not 
know  how  far  the  processes  of  biological  evolution  could  be  applied  in 
explaining  the  problems  of  social  development.  But  a  number  of  biolo- 
gists and  sociologists  have  warmly  espoused  the  view  that  the  chief  factor 
in  social  and  cultural  progress  has  been  the  wars  between  human  groups, 
from  the  days  of  tribal  society  to  the  world  wars  of  the  present  age. 


16  M.  R.  Davie,  The  Evolution  of  War,  Yale  University  Press,  1929,  p.  147. 


WAR  AND   PEACE  329 

The  fallacies  underlying  this  view  have  been  relentlessly  exposed  by 
such  writers  as  Jacques  Novicow,  G.  M.  Nicolai,  and  D.  S.  Jordan.  In 
the  first  place,  the  theory  is  not  valid  in  a  strictly  biological  sense,  since 
the  active  struggle  for  existence  in  the  biological  world  is  rarely  a  battle 
within  the  same  species.  The  selective  process  that  goes  on  within  any 
single  species  is  normally  one  which  leads  the  weaker  members  of  the 
species  to  succumb  more  quickly  than  their  more  vigorous  associates  in 
the  joint  struggle  for  food  and  protection.  In  fact,  the  human  animal 
is  almost  the  only  animal  that  preys  upon  his  own  species.  This  he  has 
come  to  do,  not  because  of  any  inherent  biological  necessity,  but  primarily 
because  of  perverted  mental  attitudes  and  cultural  traditions,  which  have 
made  him  look  upon  war  as  the  only  honorable  method  of  solving  some 
of  his  problems. 

War  has  provided  a  sort  of  institutional  cannibalism,  which,  in  higher 
cultures,  has  been  substituted  for  the  bald  physical  cannibalism  of 
savages.  But  the  slaughter  in  modern  warfare  is  far  more  revolting  and 
indefensible  than  primitive  cannibalism.  Savages  killed  sparingly  and 
made  good  use  of  those  whom  they  killed.  Modern  warfare  is  far  more 
purposeless,  imbecilic,  and  wasteful  than  primitive  cannibalism.  Indeed, 
cannibals  have  contempt  for  our  "civilized"  wars.  An  old  cannibal  chief 
in  New  Guinea  once  observed  to  the  eminent  anthropologist,  Bronislaw 
Malinowski:  "You  tell  me  that  thousands  of  people  are  killed  in  one  day 
and  left  rotting  and  uneaten  on  the  fields.  We  never  did  such  a  dastardly 
thing  to  our  enemies.  We  ate  them  honorably,  and  thus  satisfied  our 
hunger,  and  then  paid  our  respects  to  their  souls." 

Even  if  the  theory  of  nature  "red  in  tooth  and  claw"  were  valid  in  a 
biological  sense,  it  would  not  by  any  means  follow  that  this  doctrine  is 
sociologically  sound.  Biological  processes  are  not  usually  directly  trans- 
ferable to  the  social  realm,  but  must  be  modified  in  the  light  of  the 
widely  different  factors  and  situations  which  distinguish  society  from 
the  biological  organism. 

Hence,  while  war  in  primitive  society  may  have  been  an  integrating 
and  disciplinary  factor  making  possible  the  origins  of  orderly  political 
society,  war  at  the  present  time  is  both  an  institutional  anachronism  and 
an  unmitigated  menace  to  culture  and  social  welfare.  In  our  day,  an 
efficient  technology  and  the  mechanization  of  warfare  have  made  war  a 
test  of  technical  genius  and  capacity  for  organization  rather  than  of 
biological  superiority.  As  Nicolai  and  Jordan  have  shown,  war  is  today 
biologically  counter-selective,  the  better  physical  types  being  drained  off 
and  decimated  as  "cannon-fodder,"  while  the  task  of  future  procreation  is 
passed  on  to  the  inferior  types  which  remain  safely  preserved  at  home. 
Added  to  this  are  the  biological  ravages  of  disease,  suffering,  starvation, 
and  mutilation  which  war  inevitably  brings  in  its  train. 

Among  the  socio-biological  causes  of  war  are  the  various  race  dogmas 
which  have  prevailed  in  the  last  half-century  or  so.  For  a  long  time,  we 
labored  under  the  menace  of  the  "white  man's  burden"  doctrine,  namely, 
that  the  white  races  are  superior  and  must  bring  the  blessings  of  higher 


330  WAR  AND   PEACE 

civilization  to  the  inferior  races,  by  force  if  necessary.  This  dogma 
lent  support  to  imperialism  and  imperialistic  wars  and  to  the  slaughter 
of  natives  not  capable  of  grasping  and  voluntarily  accepting  the  higher 
logic  of  the  white  man's  burden.  More  recently,  especially  in  Nazi 
Germany,  the  notion  of  the  superiority  of  the  so-called  "Aryan"  branch 
of  the  white  race  has  been  growing  in  popularity.  This  has  been  made 
a  foundation  of  Nazi  anti-Semitism  and  of  plans  for  conquering  and 
ruling  "non-Aryan"  peoples.  But  the  father  of  this  doctrine  was  Joseph 
Arthur  de  Gobineau,  a  Frenchman;  Hitler  derived  his  social  notions 
mainly  from  Houston  Stewart  Chamberlain,  a  Scotchman;  Madison 
Grant  popularized  such  dogmas  in  the  United  States  nearly  twenty  years 
before  Hitler  came  to  power  in  Germany;  and  Grant's  aberrations  re- 
ceived the  pontifical  blessings  of  the  eminent  American  naturalist,  Henry 
Fairfield  Osborn. 

The  exponents  of  world  peace  must  recognize  both  the  realities  and  the 
fallacies  in  these  biological  factors  involved  in  war.  A  fallacious  dogma 
may  be  quite  as  potent  in  causing  war  as  a  biological  reality.  Education 
must  be  designed  to  eliminate,  so  far  as  possible,  both  the  actually  biolog- 
ical and  the  pseudo-biological  causes  of  conflict. 

Psychological  Causes  of  War.  The  second  main  type  of  funda- 
mental causes  of  war,  as  we  shall  classify  them  here,  is  the  psychological. 
One  psycho-cultural  cause  of  war  closely  related  to  social  Darwinism  is 
the  "cult  of  war,"  which  represents  military  and  naval  achievement  as 
the  most  noble  activity  to  which  a  people  may  devote  itself,  and  elevates 
the  military  classes  to  a  position  of  social  ascendancy.  It  is  held  that 
war  brings  forth  the  noblest  and  most  unselfish  of  human  sentiments,  as 
well  as  the  most  heroic  manifestations  of  devotion  to  the  group.  Those 
who  have  done  the  most  to  bring  glorious  victories  in  time  of  war  are 
looked  upon  as  the  great  heroes  in  the  country's  past. 

Inseparably  related  to  this  war  cult  is  pride  in  territorial  aggression. 
It  emerges  in  what  has  been  called  the  "mapitis  psychosis."  Maps  of  the 
national  states  and  of  the  world  are  so  drawn  as  to  indicate  in  impressive 
coloration  territory  wrested  from  neighboring  or  enemy  states. 

•  The  main  propaganda  technique  exploited  by  exponents  of  the  war  cult 
in  securing  popular  support  is  the  alarmist  "bogey,"  and  the  allegation, 
whether  well-founded  or  not,  that  we  must  "prepare"  against  supposed 
threats  of  aggression.  This  was  a  basic  apology  for  the  great  armaments 
of  the  decade  before  the  first  World  War,  which  were  alleged  to  be  merely 
preparations  for  peace.  But  Professor  W.  G.  Sumner  correctly  prophe- 
sied that  they  would  inevitably  lead  to  war.  Yet  the  illusion  was  used 
just  as  effectively  in  the  propaganda  that  led  to  the  second  World  War. 

Since  readers  are  familiar  enough  with  the  first  World  War,  it  will  not 
be  necessary  to  refute  the  fundamental  contentions  of  the  exponents  of 
the  war  cult.  War,  instead  of  promoting  the  noblest  of  our  emotions, 
evokes,  for  the  most  part,  the  most  base  and  brutal  traits  in  human 
behavior.  Lust,  cruelty,  pillage,  corruption,  profiteering,  and  intolerance 
are  among  the  attitudes  invariably  generated  by  military  activity.  As 


WAR  AND   PEACE  331 

Elmer  Davis  has  done  well  to  point  out,  the  first  World  War  struck  a  blow 
at  western  civilization  from  which  we  may  never  recover: 

Spiritually  and  morally,  civilization  collapsed  on  August  1,  1914 — the  civiliza- 
tion in  which  people  now  middle-aged  grew  up,  a  culture  which  with  all  its  short- 
comings did  give  more  satisfaction  to  more  people  than  any  other  yet  evolved. 
Young  people  cannot  realize  how  the  world  has  been  coarsened  and  barbarized 
since  1914;  they  may  feel  the  loss  of  the  security  into  which  their  parents  were 
born  but  they  cannot  appreciate  how  much  else  has  been  lost;  even  we  who  once 
had  it  cannot  recall  it  now  without  an  effort.  But  the  collapse  of  a  great  cul- 
ture is  a  long  process;  it  took  the  Roman  world  four  or  five  centuries  to  hit 
bottom.  Since  1914  we  have  slipped  back  as  far  perhaps  as  the  Romans  slipped 
between  the  Antonine  age  and  the  days  of  Alexander  Severus.17 

Yet,  fallacious  as  the  theory  of  the  war  cult  may  be,  it  is  still  power- 
ful and  constitutes  one  of  the  chief  obstacles  to  any  sane  discussion  of 
war  or  much  practical  achievement  in  the  cause  of  peace.  There  is  no 
intention  in  this  book  to  criticize  or  disparage  existing  military  and 
naval  establishments  which  are  essential  to  national  protection  while  the 
war  system  continues.  We  are  merely  attacking  the  philosophy  which 
defends  and  perpetuates  the  war  system  and  renders  armies  and  navies 
necessary.  At  the  same  time,  military  and  naval  authorities  have  no 
legitimate  right  to  interefere  unduly  in  the  affairs  of  the  civil  govern- 
ment or  to  dominate  educational  policy. 

Akin  to  the  cult  of  war  is  the  sentiment  which  is  usually  christened 
"patriotism."  In  discussing  this  matter  we  must  distinguish  between 
two  altogether  different  concepts.  One  is  that  noble  ideal  of  devotion  to 
the  social  community,  which  was  first  extensively  developed  by  the  an- 
cient Greek  philosophers  and  expounded  more  thoroughly  by  the  modern 
German  and  English  Idealists.  This  is,  perhaps,  the  highest  of  human 
socio-psychological  achievements  and  is  one  of  the  things  which  most 
distinctly  separates  us  from  the  animal  kingdom. 

On  the  other  hand,  we  have  that  quasi-savage  sentiment  of  group 
aggression  and  selfishness,  known  as  "Hundred-Percentism."  This  is  a 
projection  into  modern  civilization  of  the  psychology  of  the  animal 
hunting-pack  and  the  savagery  of  primitive  tribesmen.  It  is  certainly 
one  of  the  lowest,  most  brutal,  and  most  dangerous  of  psychic  attitudes 
and  behavior  patterns.  The  scientific  and  industrial  revolutions  have 
given  it  a  technological  basis  for  nation-wide  expression  and  made  it  a 
world  menace. 

Down  to  the  outset  of  the  nineteenth  century  there  could  be  little 
national  patriotism,  because  the  majority  of  mankind  knew  little  beyond 
the  neighborhood  or  local  group.  Suddenly,  the  telephone,  the  telegraph, 
the  cable,  the  railroad,  the  printing  press,  the  cheap  daily  newspaper,  free 
city  and  rural  delivery  of  mail,  the  movies,  and  the  radio  spread  neighbor- 
hood superstitution,  narrow-mindedness,  provincialism,  and  savagery 


17  Elmer  Davis,  "We  Lose  the  Next  War,"  Harper's  Magazine,  March,  1938,  p.  342. 


332  WAR  AND  PEACE 

throughout  the  entire  limits  of  a  great  national  state.18  Thus  we  may 
all  simultaneously  pick  up  our  morning  papers  at  the  breakfast  table  and 
have  our  group  pride  inflated  by  the  record  of  the  doings  of  the  American 
marines  in  Australia  or  Eritrea,  or  have  our  passions  aroused  by  an 
alleged  insult  to  our  national  honor  in  Persia  or  Timbuktu.  The  citizens 
of  an  entire  state  may  now  be  stirred  as  rapidly  and  completely  by  the 
press,  radio,  and  newsreels  as  a  neighborhood  was  a  century  ago  by  a  visit 
of  a  messenger  from  the  battle-front.  The  potentialities  of  the  movies 
and  the  radio  in  the  service  of  patriotic  fanaticism  almost  transcend  imagi- 
nation. Until  we  are  able  to  deflate  and  suppress  a  narrow  patriotism 
and  to  substitute  for  it  the  constructive  sentiment  of  civic  pride  and 
international  good-will,  there  can  be  little  hope  of  developing  those 
cooperative  attitudes  and  agencies  upon  which  the  program  of  world 
peace  depends. 

A  powerful  stimulant  to  savage  patriotism  has  been  national  history 
and  literature.  In  the  first  place,  our  histories  have  been  filled  primarily 
with  records  of  battles  and  the  doings  of  military  and  naval  heroes.  A 
country's  importance  and  prestige  have  been  held  to  depend  primarily 
upon  its  warlike  achievements.  The  activities  of  scientists,  inventors, 
or  artists,  who  have  been  the  real  architects  of  civilization,  receive  scant 
notice.  Hence  it  is  not  surprising  that,  as  children,  we  develop  the 
opinion  that  war  is  the  most  significant  and  important  of  all  human 
activities. 

Even  worse,  the  record  of  wars  and  diplomatic  intrigues,  has  been 
notoriously  distorted  in  school  textbooks.  The  country  of  the  writer  is 
usually  represented  as  having  been  invariably  right  in  all  instances  of 
international  dispute,  and  all  wars  are  represented  as  gloriously  fought 
defensive  conflicts.  In  this  way,  fear,  hatred,  and  intolerance  of  neigh- 
boring states  are  generated  in  the  minds  of  school  children,  to  be  continued 
later  through  the  biased  and  prejudiced  presentation  of  international 
news  in  the  press  and  on  the  air  and  screen.  Little  training  is  afforded  in 
the  development  of  a  judicious  and  reflective  consideration  of  interna- 
tional issues,  though  a  few  textbook  writers  have,  of  late,  attempted  to 
improve  both  the  subject-matter  and  the  tone  of  our  school  textbooks. 
Their  salutary  efforts  have,  however,  been  savagely  attacked  by  innum- 
erable patriotic  and  hyphenated  societies  which  endeavor  to  stir  up 
international  hatreds  and  prejudices.  Such  attention  as  is  given  to  the 
questions  of  national  culture  in  many  textbooks  is  usually  devoted  to  a 
demonstration  of  the  superiority  of  the  culture  of  the  author's  country 
to  that  of  any  adjoining  political  group. 

In  recent  years,  writers  have  called  our  attention  to  the  dangers  in  the 
super-patriotic  teachings  in  the  history  textbooks  in  the  United  States. 
But,  as  J.  F.  Scott  has  amply  demonstrated,  the  school  textbooks  in  most 
European  states  have  been  far  more  chauvinistic  and  bigoted  than  the 
worst  of  the  school  texts  in  this  country  even  a  generation  ago.  When 


i*See  above,  pp.  219-221. 


WAR  AND  PEACE  333 

the  minds  of  children  are  thus  poisoned  with  suspicion,  fear,  arrogance, 
bigotry,  and  intolerance,  there  is  little  hope  that  they  will  develop  a  sense 
of  calmness  and  justice  in  their  scrutiny  of  international  affairs.  The 
foregoing  psychological  causes  of  war  are  regarded  by  the  author  as  of 
transcendent  importance,  because  all  other  factors — biological,  social, 
economic,  or  political — become  active  only  through  their  psychological 
expression. 

In  practice,  nearly  all  the  psychological  causes  of  war  emerge  in  direct 
relation  to,  or  as  some  mode  of  manifestation  of,  nationalism.10  There- 
fore, nationalism  is,  unquestionably,  one  of  the  most  dangerous  menaces 
to  world  peace,  and  the  attacks  upon  nationalism  by  Carlton  J.  H.  Hayes 
and  others  is  a  most  promising  way  to  undermine  the  war  system.  We 
do  not  ignore  or  minimize  the  economic  factors  underlying  international 
rivalry  and  war,  but  we  do  contend  that  contemporary  economic  processes 
produce  or  threaten  war,  in  part,  because  they  are  interwoven  with  the 
"nationalism"  complex. 

Finally,  one  of  the  most  dangerous  and  stubborn  psychological  causes 
of  war  is  the  semi-fatalistic  assumption  that  war  is  "inevitable,"  and  that 
it  must  be  resorted  to  frequently,  as  a  means  of  solving  both  domestic 
and  international  problems.  This  attitude  is  well-expressed  in  Colonel 
Robert  Stockton's  big  book,  Inevitable  War,20  and  more  learnedly  and 
moderately  in  Hoffman  Nickerson's  Can  We  Limit  War?  21  So  long  as 
mankind  goes  on  assuming  that  war  is  inevitable,  it  surely  will  be  such. 

Sociological  Causes  of  War.  Of  the  alleged  sociological  causes  of  war, 
the  most  important  rests  upon  the  tendency  of  groups  to  develop  conflict- 
ing interests  and  to  struggle  for  their  realization,  by  physical  force  if 
necessary.  It  is  alleged  that  this  inevitable  conflict  of  interests  can 
scarcely  be  eliminated  by  any  degree  of  social  progress. 

Gustav  Ratzenhofer,  A.  W.  Small,  A.  F.  Bentley,  and  others  have 
convincingly  shown  that  the  struggle  of  conflicting  interest-groups  is 
even  more  prominent  within  each  state  than  between  different  states. 
Yet  this  struggle  of  groups  within  the  state  does  not  take  the  form  of 
physical  conflict,  but  rather  tends  toward  adjustment,  and  compromise. 
If  we  developed  the  same  degree  of  legal  control  in  world  society  that 
prevails  within  the  boundaries  of  each  state,  there  would  no  longer  be 
any  need  for  national  groups  to  resort  to  war  to  obtain  their  legitimate 
desires.  The  constructive  forms  of  social  conflict  must  become  economic, 
cultural,  and  intellectual.  This  sort  of  competition  may  prove  a  stimulant 
to  progress,  but  physical  combat  will  inevitably  throw  mankind  back 
toward  primitive  barbarism  and  misery. 

Economic  Causes  of  War.  The  Industrial  Revolution  produced  an 
enormous  increase  in  the  volume  of  commodities  available  for  sale.  The 
older  home  markets  proved  inadequate  for  the  increasing  flood  of  goods. 


I*  See  above,  pp.  219  ff. 

20  Perth,  1932. 

21  Stokes,  1934. 


334  WAR  AND  PEACE 

It  seemed  necessary  to  find  new  markets  overseas.  In  part,  these  markets 
might  be  discovered  among  highly  civilized  peoples  in  distant  lands,  but 
the  industrialized  countries  also  endeavored  to  develop  or  exploit  colonies 
as  potential  customers  for  goods  manufactured  in  the  mother  country. 

Next  to  the  quest  for  markets,  probably  the  most  dynamic  incentive 
to  imperialism,  particularly  in  the  last  generation,  has  been  the  struggle 
for  control  over  the  sources  of  raw  materials.  The  zeal  exhibited  in  the 
effort  to  get  command  of  oil  and  rubber  supplies  was  but  the  most  con- 
spicuous contemporary  manifestation  of  this  struggle.  As  a  result,  most 
of  the  areas  which  were  not  already  under  the  dominion  of  independent 
modern  states  by  1870  have  been  parceled  out  among  the  British,  French, 
Russians,  Dutch,  and  Americans.  This  revived  scramble  for  overseas 
territory  was  one  of  the  most  potent  causes  of  international  disputes  in 
the  fifty  years  before  1914. 

The  Industrial  Revolution,  in  due  time,  created  an  extensive  supply 
of  surplus  capital  that  sought  investment  in  overseas  dominions.  This, 
in  itself,  was  legitimate  enough.  But  the  investors  demanded  special  pro- 
tection and  unique  rights,  independent  of  the  laws  and  customs  of  the 
country  in  which  the  investments  were  made.  Extra-territorial  rights 
were  established,  which  made  the  resident  investors  and  their  agents 
free  from  the  laws  and  courts  of  the  exploited  country.  Each  imperial- 
istic state,  in  administering  its  laws  abroad,  is,  naturally,  biased  in  favor 
of  its  own  nationals. 

In  many  cases,  when  the  exploited  state  was  weak  enough  in  a  political 
or  military  sense  to  facilitate  such  oppression,  foreign  investors  have 
even  induced  their  home  governments  to  impose  severe  economic  handi- 
caps upon  the  country  undergoing  economic  penetration.  A  notorious 
example  of  such  procedure  was  the  limitation  of  the  customs  duties  which 
might  be  imposed  on  imports  by  the  Chinese  government.  Chinese  mer- 
chants, shipping  goods  into  foreign  countries,  were  compelled  to  pay  the 
often  extortionately  high  customs  duties  imposed  on  Chinese  exports, 
while  the  Chinese  were  themselves  limited  to  notoriously  low  customs 
rates  on  goods  shipped  into  China.  The  Boxer  Rebellion  of  1900  and 
other  uprisings  in  China  were  very  largely  caused  by  the  oppressive 
activities  of  foreign  investors,  supported  by  the  armed  forces  of  their 
home  governments. 

Even  more  serious  has  been  the  psychic  intimidation  and  the  military 
or  naval  occupation  of  weaker  states  at  the  behest  of  investors.  A  man 
who  invests  capital  in  some  weak  state  may  believe  that  his  interests  are 
not  adequately  protected  by  the  laws  and  institutions  of  the  state  in 
which  he  is  carrying  on  business,  or  he  may  find  it  difficult  to  collect  his 
debts  in  that  country.  He  then  hastens  to  the  State  Department  or 
Foreign  Office  of  his  home  government  and  demands  that  his  economic 
and  financial  interests  be  protected  by  the  army  or  marines  of  the  mother 
country.  This  procedure  is  a  direct  repudiation  of  the  long  established 
practice  in  regard  to  domestic  debts  within  any  state.  An  investor  at 
home  would  never  for  a  moment  dream  of  requesting  so  preposterous 


WAR  AND   PEACE  335 

a  thing  as  the  use  of  the  standing  army  to  enable  him  to  collect  a  debt. 
The  forceful  occupation  of  weaker  or  dependent  states  in  order  to  protect 
investments  or  to  collect  the  debts  due  to  private  citizens  has  produced 
a  large  number  of  irritating  and  oppressive  incidents  in  modern  interna- 
tional relations.  Perhaps  the  most  notorious  have  been  our  own  relations 
with  various  weak  Latin-American  countries,  where  our  foreign  policy 
has  been  extensively  dictated  by  the  interests  of  our  investors.  But  our 
behavior  is  only  a  representative  illustration  of  a  nearly  universal  practice 
on  the  part  of  the  more  powerful  states  of  the  modern  world  and  their 
financial  moguls. 

The  economic  causes  of  war  will  never  be  eliminated  so  long  as  the 
archaic  principle  of  the  protective  tariff  remains  an  unabated  nuisance. 
In  the  late  eighteenth  and  early  nineteenth  centuries  there  was  a  steady 
movement  toward  free  trade,  but  the  rise  of  modern  industrialism,  na- 
tionalism, and  imperialism  produced  a  strong  reaction  after  1870  in 
favor  of  economic  nationalism.  However,  even  the  most  extreme  ex- 
ponents of  the  protective  tariff  then  contended  that  it  was  desirable  only 
when  it  might  help  a  developing  industrial  state  to  establish  itself  in  a 
condition  of  relative  economic  equality  with  more  advanced  states.  As 
Friedrich  List  himself  admitted,  there  is  no  valid  justification  for  pro- 
tective tariffs  among  well-developed  industrial  states.  Yet  modern  poli- 
ticians and  special  economic  interests  have  secured  a  nearly  universal 
adoption  of  the  protective  tariff  system,  which  is  nothing  less  than  a  form 
of  economic  warfare.  Particularly  has  this  been  true  of  the  discrimi- 
natory tariff  arrangements  which  were  common  in  Europe  before  the  first 
World  War  and  which,  in  most  cases,  were  continued  in  an  even  more 
irritating  form  after  that  conflict  officially  terminated.  The  effort  of 
Secretary  of  State  Cordell  Hull  to  negotiate  for  agreements  providing 
for  a  mutual  lowering  of  tariff  rates  has  been  highly  commendable.  But, 
so  far,  it  is  a  mere  idealistic  bubble  on  the  surface  of  the  vast  ocean  of 
protectionism. 

The  basest  of  all  the  economic  causes  of  war  are  those  related  to  the 
propaganda  of  munitions  manufacturers — the  "merchants  of  death." 
Such  organizations  subsidize  militaristic  propaganda,  support  patriotic 
societies,  and  contribute  enthusiastically  to  the  maintenance  of  speakers 
and  periodicals  that  are  devoted  to  keeping  the  military  cult  forcefully 
before  the  people.  It  has  not  been  uncommon  for  munitions  manufac- 
turers to  bribe  foreign  newspapers  to  print  highly  alarmist  news  in  order 
to  stir  up  fear  in  their  own  country.  This  makes  possible  a  larger  appro- 
priation for  armament  and  munitions  and  thus  increases  government 
orders. 

Then  there  are  the  economic  vultures  who  see  in  war  an  opportunity 
for  unique  pecuniary  profit,  and  are  willing  to  urge  a  policy  which  leads 
to  enormous  loss  of  life  and  an  increase  of  general  misery.  Such  persons 
were  particularly  active  in  urging  the  United  States  to  enter  the  first 
World  War  and  in  demanding  the  continuance  of  the  War  until  the  Allied 
troops  stood  in  Berlin.  A  generation  later  they  enthusiastically  sup- 


336  WAR  AND  PEACE 

ported  the  program  for  a  great  armament  and  urged  our  entry  into  the 
second  World  War  long  before  the  attack  on  Pearl  Harbor. 

It  has  long  been  apparent  to  intelligent  economists  that  modern 
methods  of  communication  and  transportation  have  tended  to  make  the 
world  ever  more  an  economic  unit,  characterized  by  interdependence  and 
a  necessity  for  cooperation.  But  the  archaic  economic  practices  and 
dogmas  and  the  bellicose  attitudes  which  have  come  down  from  an  earlier 
era  prevent  us  from  thinking  and  acting  sanely  in  the  field  of  world 
economic  relations. 

Further,  as  Norman  Angell  warned  before  the  first  World  War  and  fully 
proved  upon  the  basis  of  its  results,  a  great  war  can  no  longer  be  a  profit- 
able one,  even  for  the  victors.  The  main  hope  for  the  mitigation  of  the 
economic  forces  making  for  war  is,  on  the  one  hand,  the  development 
of  an  educational  program  designed  to  reveal  the  menace  of  economic 
imperialism  and  the  high  protective  tariff  system  and,  on  the  other  hand, 
the  gradual  recognition  on  the  part  of  the  more  intelligent  and  farsighted 
bankers  and  businessmen  that  the  old  system  is  wrong-headed  in  its 
notions  and  must  be  modified,  if  ultimate  disaster  is  to  be  averted. 

Economic  maladjustment,  poverty,  misery  and  personal  insecurity 
contribute  in  various  ways  to  the  danger  of  war.  These  conditions  en- 
courage discontent,  rioting,  and  threats  of  rebellion.  Rulers  are  prone 
to  resort  to  war  to  distract  attention  from  domestic  discontent  and  to 
galvanize  the  populace  in  patriotic  support  of  a  foreign  war.  Further, 
a  sense  of  insecurity,  oppression,  and  desperation  makes  the  under- 
privileged willing  to  accept  or  gamble  on  the  outcome  of  a  war.  They 
reason  that  nothing  could  be  worse  than  the  present,  while  a  war  may 
bring  better  times  at  its  end.  While  it  lasts,  it  provides  excitement  and 
some  kind  of  living.  Hence,  wars  are  likely  to  be  most  frequent  when  a 
socio-economic  system  is  disintegrating  and  misery  is  most  rampant. 
This  cause  of  war  also  suggests  that  the  elimination  of  war  is  intimately 
linked  up  with  the  provision  of  social  and  economic  justice. 

Political  Games  of  War.  Among  the  most  important  of  the  political 
causes  of  war  is  the  modern  national-state  system,  the  psychological 
results  of  which  were  mentioned  above  in  connection  with  the  military 
cult  and  conventional  patriotism.  Largely  as  a  result  of  the  rise  of 
modern  capitalism  and  the  Protestant  Reformation,  the  benign  medieval 
ecclesiastical  dream  of  a  great  international  organization,  uniting  most 
of  Europe,  was  replaced  by  the  actuality  of  the  modern  national  state. 
The  national  state  was  first  thoroughly  legalized  in  European  public  law 
in  the  Treaty  of  Westphalia  in  1648.  The  sovereign  independence  of 
nationalities,  in  a  political  sense,  was  at  first  confined  primarily  to  the 
greater  European  states.  The  aspiration  to  attain  independence  soon 
spread  to  the  lesser  peoples,  and  the  nineteenth  century  was,  in  part, 
taken  up  with  their  struggles  for  emancipation. 

Because  subject  nationalities  were  frequently  oppressed  by  the  greater 
states,  political  independence  became  regarded  by  these  oppressed  peoples 
as  necessary  for  the  expression  of  the  purely  cultural  fact  of  nationality. 


WAR  AND   PEACE  337 

The  acceptance  of  this  view  promoted  the  creation  of  a  large  number  of 
small  national  states,  which  constitute  just  so  much  greater  invitation  to 
war,  unless  brought  within  some  world  organization  or  some  European 
federation.  The  Treaty  of  Versailles  carried  to  the  logical  extreme  this 
recognition  of  political  nationalism — "international  anarchy" — without 
safeguarding  the  process  by  creating  a  strong  international  organization. 
It  is  possible  that  nationalism  may  be  adjusted  to  world  organization, 
but  it  must  be  a  nationalism  more  temperate  and  conciliatory  than  that 
which  motivated  and  conditioned  European  psychology  in  the  century 
before  the  first  World  War  and  headed  us  toward  the  present  conflict. 

Next  to  its  psychological  expression  in  fanatical  patriotism,  the  chief 
reason  why  the  national  state  has  menaced  peace  and  world  order  is  the 
fact  that  nationalism  has  been  linked  up  with  the  conception  of  absolute 
political  sovereignty.22  This  was  a  notion  derived  vaguely  from  Roman 
law,23  but  primarily  developed  by  political  philosophers  from  Bodin  in 
the  sixteenth  century,  through  Hobbes,  Blackstone,  Bentham,  and  Austin 
to  J.  W.  Burgess  in  our  own  day.  In  the  words  of  Burgess,  it  means  the 
"original,  absolute,  unlimited,  universal  power  of  the  state  over  the 
individual  subject  and  all  associations  of  subjects."  Such  a  political  con- 
cept, held  to  be  the  bulwark  of  the  modern  political  order,  has  naturally 
proved  a  nasty  theoretical  stumbling-block  to  any  movement  for  world 
organization.  It  has  been  maintained  that  any  such  plan  would  involve 
some  sacrifice  of  sovereignty  and  independence,  and  would,  therefore, 
pull  down  the  whole  edifice  of  modern  political  society  in  its  wake. 
Added  to  this  metaphysical  fetish  has  been  the  even  more  dubious  notion 
of  "national  honor" — a  phrase  normally  used  to  cover  supposedly  non- 
judicable  topics  and  disputes. 

This  view  of  absolute  political  sovereignty  is  a  purely  metaphysical 
fiction,  the  power  of  the  state  being,  in  both  theory  and  practice,  limited 
by  every  treaty  and  international  arrangement,  as  well  as  by  the  social 
power  exerted  by  various  groups  within  the  state.  The  concepts  and 
practices  of  political  pluralism  are  already  severely  challenging  the 
theory  of  the  omnipotent  sovereign  state.24  We  may  safely  hold  that 
there  is  nothing  in  sound  political  science  of  the  present  time  which  con- 
stitutes any  obstacle  to  plans  for  an  effective  society  of  states.  Yet  the 
fetish  of  the  absolutely  sovereign  state  still  persists,  to  give  pathological 
sensitivity  to  many  contemporary  statesmen,  when  any  program  of 
world  unity  is  brought  up  for  discussion. 

The  view  that  there  are  disputes  which  a  state  cannot  submit  to  adjudi- 
cation without  a  lesion  of  "national  honor"  is  as  misleading  as  it  is  to 
contend  that  there  are  matters  which  a  private  individual  should  not 
submit  to  the  courts  of  law.  The  concept  of  "national  honor"  is  not  an 


22  Cf.  P.  W.  Ward,  Sovereignty:  A  Study  of  a  Contemporary  Notion,  Routlcdge, 
1928. 

23  See  M.  P.  Gilmore,  Argument  from  Roman  Law  iti  Political  Thought,  1200-1600, 
Howard  University  Press,  1941. 

24  See  C.  E.  Merriam  and  H.  E.  Barnes,  History  of  Political  Theories:  Recent  Times,. 
MacmUlan,  1924,  chap,  iiu 


338  WAR  AND   PEACE' 

asset  to  national  dignity  or  world  order,  but  an  evidence  of  international 
lawlessness,  comparable  to  duelling  and  lynch-law  within  the  state. 

From  a  more  dynamic  point  of  view,  Quincy  Wright  finds  that  there 
are  three  main  political  causes  of  war:  (1)  an  unjust  or  archaic  legal 
system,  which  fails  to  promote  or  protect  the  basic  social  and  economic 
interests  within  a  state,  thus  giving  rise  to  class  or  group  resentment,  and 
producing  a  state  of  opinion  hostile  to  the  given  situation  and  eager  to 
remedy  it,  by  war  if  necessary;  (2)  an  unstable  equilibrium  among  the 
states  with  a  division  of  countries  into  "haves"  and  "have-nots";  and  (3) 
the  lack  of  an  adequate  international  organization  to  deal  with  conflicts 
by  legal  rather  than  warlike  methods. 

An  excellent  schematic  outline  of  the  causes  of  war  has  been  presented 
by  Carl  V.  Herron.  It  does  not  differ  markedly  from  that  of  the  fore- 
going discussion  of  the  so-called  war  system: 

ECONOMIC 

1.  The  "profit  motive"  (munitions  manufacturing,  commercial  discrimination,  high 
tariffs,  etc.) 

2.  Unequal  distribution  of  wealth,  international  envy  and  greed,  natural  or  artificial 
disasters  such  as  famines,  etc. 

POLITICAL 

1.  Imperialism 

2.  Nationalism 

3.  Dictatorship 

4.  Tyranny 

RELIGIOUS 

1.  Prejudice,  intolerance,  etc. 

2.  Paganism 

RACIAL 

1.  Prejudice 

2.  Minority  problems 

SOCIAL 

1.  Anti-social  acts  or  ideologies 

2.  Treaty-breaking  (or  the  imposition  of  unfair  treaties) 

3.  Over-population 

INTELLECTUAL 

1.  Ignorance 

2.  False  propaganda 

3.  Mental  slavery 

4.  The  war  cult. 

The  foregoing  discussion  of  the  more  obvious  fundamental  causes  of 
war  should  show  how  broad  any  adequate  program  for  securing  world 
peace  must  be.25  The  pacifist  has  normally  been  a  single-track  reformer, 
putting  his  trust  in  some  one  panacea,  such  as  disarmament,  outlawry  of 
war,  international  arbitration,  international  conferences,  international 
discussion  clubs,  religious  unity,  leagues  of  nations,  free  trade,  non- 
resistance,  and  so  on.  While  every  one  interested  in  the  cause  of  peace 


25  See  Quincy  Wright,  "The  Causation  and  Control  of  War,"  in  American  Socio- 
logical Review,  August,  1938,  pp.  461-474. 


WAR  AND   PEACE  339 

should  be  allowed  to  affiliate  himself  with  whatever  branch  of  the  general 
peace  movement  arouses  his  most  enthusiastic  support,  he  should  under- 
stand that  his  particular  scheme  will  be  helpful  only  as  a  part  of  a  larger 
whole.  The  more  effectively  we  reduce  the  causes  of  war,  the  more  likely 
is  outlawry  or  renunciation  to  succeed. 

The   Impact  of  War  upon  Society  and  Culture 

The  Axis  powers  have  glorified  war  as  a  noble  human  enterprise.  It 
is  held  to  purify  our  minds,  to  buck  up  our  moral  fiber  and  resolution,  to 
strengthen  our  bodies,  to  improve  the  quality  of  the  race,  and  to  bring 
economic  benefits  which  far  outweigh  the  costs  of  war. 

There  is  no  denying  the  fact  that  war  did  bring  certain  important 
benefits  to  mankind  in  the  early  days  of  social  evolution.  War  put  an 
end  to  small  primitive  groups  and  was  a  powerful  influence  in  creating 
great  states,  which  could  introduce  order  on  a  large  scale  and  secure 
cooperative  enterprise  from  extensive  populations.  No  doubt  war  con- 
tributed a  good  deal  to  the  improvement  of  social  discipline  in  early 
historic  society.  In  certain  cases,  war  also  paved  the  way  for  a  greater 
degree  of  peace  than  normally  prevailed.  This  is  illustrated  by  the 
widespread  peace  brought  to  the  realms  within  the  Persian  and  Roman 
empires.  War  also  helped  to  put  an  end  to  feudalism  and  to  create 
national  states  in  early  modern  times,  thus  making  possible  more  orderly 
existence  and  better  protection  of  life  and  property. 

War  has  also  done  something  to  stimulate  the  growth  of  science  and 
invention,  from  the  days  of  stone  weapons  to  those  of  the  modern  air- 
bombers  and  submarines.  Some  examples  are  the  Bessemer  process  of 
making  steel,  to  find  a  cheaper  metal  for  cannon  and  other  firearms,  the 
discovery  of  latent  heat  from  boring  out  cannon,  the  origins  of  mass- 
production  in  Eli  Whitney's  use  of  standardized  parts  in  the  manufacture 
of  muskets,  the  search  for  new  alloys  in  recent  times,  and  the  progress 
in  antisepsis  and  surgery  stimulated  by  the  urgency  of  war.  But  prob- 
ably all  these  contributions  of  war  to  scientific  and  technological  progress 
have  been  far  more  than  offset  by  the  destruction  which  war  has  wrought 
through  improved  weapons. 

Moreover,  it  may  fairly  be  said  that  such  benefits  as  war  has  brought 
to  society,  outside  of  science  and  invention,  were  made  mainly  in  centuries 
prior  to  our  own.  Even  then,  it  is  probable  that  the  advantages  conferred 
by  war  were  outweighed  by  the  damage  to  life,  property,  and  human 
happiness.  War  today  is  surely  an  almost  unmitigated  liability  to  con- 
temporary civilization.  If  in  the  following  pages  we  may  present  an 
almost  unrelieved  picture  of  the  disasters  accompanying  war,  it  is  only 
because  we  cannot  discover  any  benefits  which  war  brings  to  twentieth- 
century  society  and  culture. 

War  affects  society  in  a  profound  and  diversified  fashion.  It  shifts 
notably  the  relative  prestige  and  power  of  leading  social  institutions. 
The  state  and  the  army  are  elevated  to  a  supreme  position  of  reputation 


340  WAR  AND  PEACE 

and  authority.  Those  institutions  which  are  most  important  in  peace 
time,  such  as  the  family,  community,  church,  school,  and  property,  are 
subordinated.  Elevation  of  the  state  and  the  army  to  a  position  of 
supremacy  carries  with  it  the  necessity  of  unreasoning  obedience  to  the 
dictates  of  government.  In  extreme  cases,  the  military  establishment 
may  actually  take  over  and  dominate  the  government. 

The  institutions  subordinated  by  war  arc  also  disrupted  in  various 
ways.  The  family  is  especially  hard  hit  through  the  withdrawal  of  males 
into  the  army,  the  death  of  wage  earners  on  the  battlefield,  privation  and 
poverty  among  those  who  remain  at  home,  and  an  all  too  frequent  de- 
moralization within  the  family.  Prewar  families  are  undermined  or 
broken  up,  and  a  large  number  of  unstable  war  marriages  are  contracted, 
which  are  often  followed  by  divorce,  desertion,  and  misery  in  the  postwar 
period. 

The  first  World  War  demoralized  the  school  system  in  a  number  of 
ways.  Interest  was  diverted  to  war-time  activities.  Sceptical  tend- 
encies were  suppressed  by  war  propaganda.  Academic  freedom  was 
lost,  teachers  were  taken  into  war  service,  and  excessive  expenditures  for 
war  purposes  led  to  severe  curtailment  of  appropriations  for  education. 

The  church  is  also  perverted  and  degraded  by  war.  In  the  first  World 
War,  ministers  of  the  gospel  contributed  their  part  to  war  propaganda 
and  brought  the  sanction  of  Christ  to  blood-letting.  Preachers  who  in- 
sisted on  remaining  true  to  their  prewar  convictions  and  continuing  to 
advocate  pacific  and  tolerant  notions  got  into  serious  difficulties.  War- 
mongering on  the  part  of  the  church  undermined  its  standing  with 
thoughtful  persons  when  peace  returned.  There  was  a  feeling  that  the 
church  had  forfeited  its  claim  to  respect  and  trust. 

Community  attitudes  and  activities  change  notably  during  war.  In- 
terest in  education,  relief,  music,  and  other  community  projects  declines, 
while  various  forms  of  war  activities  absorb  the  community.  It  devotes 
itself  to  supporting  the  Red  Cross,  making  bandages,  promoting  the  sale 
of  government  bonds,  and  carrying  on  war  propaganda. 

In  peace  time,  property  is  the  most  sacred  of  all  human  institutions 
in  Capitalistic  states.  But  war  can  even  lessen  the  sanctity  of  property. 
In  war  time,  the  state  controls  industry  much  more  thoroughly  than  in 
peace.  The  government  determines  the  armament  program  and  demands 
that  industry  shall  conform  to  it,  even  to  the  extent  of  ceasing  the 
production  of  peace-time  commodities.  Capital  and  labor  may  both  be 
regimented.  The  plants  of  stubborn  employers  are  taken  over,  while 
striking  laborers  may  be  threatened  with  prison  terms.  While  it  is  rare 
that  a  war  produces  outright  confiscation  of  property,  property  rights 
and  holdings  may  be  threatened  by  crushing  taxation,  limitation  of 
profits,  and  inflation. 

Wars  produce  a  tremendous  waste  of  natural  resources  and  productive 
effort.  The  amount  of  the  economic  losses  during  the  first  World  War, 
about  350  billion  dollars,  was  enough  to  have  furnished:  (1)  every 
family  in  England,  France,  Belgium,  Germany,  Russia,  the  United  States, 


WAR  AND  PEACE  341 

Canada,  and  Australia  with  a  $2,500  house  on  a  $500  one-acre  lot,  with 
$1,000  worth  of  furniture;  (2)  a  $5,000,000  library  for  every  community 
of  200,000  inhabitants  in  these  countries;  (3)  a  $10,000,000  university 
for  every  such  community;  (4)  a  fund  that  at  5  per  cent  interest  would 
yield  enough  to  pay  indefinitely  $1,000  a  year  to  an  army  of  125,000 
teachers  and  125,000  nurses,  and  (5)  enough  left  over  to  buy  every  piece 
of  property  and  all  wealth  in  France  and  Belgium  at  a  fair  market  price. 

Where  the  business  classes  are  strong  enough  to  maintain  their  control 
over  the  government,  even  in  war  time,  we  are  likely  to  have  orgies  of 
profiteering  at  the  expense  of  the  government,  the  public,  and  the  army. 
Most  of  the  great  wars  in  the  last  century  have  produced  war  millionaires, 
and  the  first  World  War  created  thousands  of  them. 

Unfortunately,  even  the  staggering  initial  cost  of  war  is  only  the  start. 
Pensions,  war-risk  insurance,  veterans'  bonuses,  and  other  economic 
charges  often  far  exceed  the  original  cost  of  war.  We  paid  out  much 
more  in  pensions  to  Civil  War  veterans  and  their  dependents  than  the 
war  cost  us  from  1861  to  1865.  The  same  is  proving  true  of  the  financial 
aftermath  of  the  first  World  War.  To  June  30,  1941,  the  United  States 
Veterans'  Administration  had  disbursed  over  25  billion  dollars. 

Another  serious  economic  result  of  war  is  the  industrial  dislocation  it 
produces.  When  wars  are  over,  there  is  always  great  difficulty  in  shifting 
from  war-time  activities  to  peace-time  production,  and  in  transforming 
soldiers  from  a  military  to  an  industrial  army.  War  may  bring  about 
a  sweeping  economic  revolution,  as  in  Russia  during  the  first  World  War. 
Most  other  countries  in  western  Europe  narrowly  escaped  a  similar  post- 
war revolution  in  1918-1919;  the  revolution  in  Italy,  in  1922,  and  in 
Germany,  in  1933,  may  be  attributed  to  the  impact  of  the  first  World  War. 

War  conditions  stimulate  the  major  social  evils.  The  moral  break- 
down in  war  time,  the  growth  of  a  war-time  morality,  and  the  disruption 
of  family  relations  increase  the  extent  of  prostitution  and  unconventional 
sex  relations.  Crime  is  increased  as  a  result  of  the  breakdown  of  normal 
social  control,  the  disorganization  of  family  life,  the  increase  of  poverty, 
and  the  demoralizing  associations  of  war  time.  The  loss  of  breadwinners 
and  the  rise  in  the  price  of  the  necessities  increase  human  misery  and 
swell  the  ranks  of  dependents.  Their  condition  is  rendered  still  more 
deplorable  by  the  fact  that  relief  agencies  are  crippled  during  war  time, 
through  the  concentration  of  public  interest  and  community  expenditures 
upon  war  projects.  Wars  leave  in  their  wake  a  great  mass  of  miserable 
and  maladjusted  persons  who  create  new  and  challenging  problems  for 
social  workers  in  the  period  of  readjustment. 

During  war  time  the  army  tends  to  develop  a  morality  all  its  own. 
When  sex  relations  within  the  family  are  disrupted,  the  soldiers  substi- 
tute loose  sexual  relations  with  "charity  girls"  and  prostitutes.  Even 
normally  virtuous  girls  frequently  consort  with  soldiers,  under  the  illusion 
that  they  are  rendering  a  patriotic  service  to  their  country.  The  new 
laxity  is  often  justified  on  the  ground  that  it  is  contributing  to  the  defeat 
of  the  enemy.  But  perhaps  the  intolerance,  cruelty,  and  brutality  of 


342  WAR  AND   PEACE 

war  psychology  and  war  conduct  may  be  regarded  as  greater  breaches 
of  morality  than  sexual  laxity. 

Perhaps  the  most  disastrous  effect  of  war  on  human  society  is  the 
brutalization  of  the  human  race,  as  a  result  of  ruthless  massacres  on 
the  battlefield,  the  starvation  of  women  and  children  through  blockades, 
the  irresponsible  lying  involved  in  war  propaganda,  and  so  forth.  The 
brutalizing  effect  of  war  has  been  impressively  described  by  Andre 
Maurois  in  an  article  on  "The  Tragic  Decline  of  the  Humane  Ideal"  in 
the  New  York  Times  Magazine,  June  19,  1938: 

These  completely  useless  massacres  [of  Chinese  civilians]  shock  us,  but  we  feel 
powerless  to  stop  thorn.  We  have  lost  not  only  our  courage  but  our  desire  to 
a<;t.  The  humane  ideal,  whose  noble  aims  were  generally  respected  before  the 
World  War,  has  declined  during  the  last  ten  years  to  a  condition  of  primitive 
violence  and  cruelty.  We  are  again  becoming  accustomed  to  the  ferocity  of 
which  several  centuries  of  civilization  had  seemed  to  cure  the  human  race;  and  this 
new  barbarity  is  far  more  dangerous  than  that  of  the  savages  because  it  is  armed 
by  science. 

Picture  a  European  couple  who  got  married  in  1913.  In  the  present  year, 
1938,  they  are  celebrating  their  silver  wedding.  Compare  the  world  as  it  ap- 
peared to  this  couple  at  the  time  of  their  marriage  with  the  world  that  they  now 
live  in,  and  you  will  realize  what  a  terrifying  decline  has  taken  place.  At  nearly 
every  point  the  forces  of  civilization  seem  to  be  sounding  a  retreat.  In  1913, 
physical  security  for  Europeans  was  assured.  The  idea  that  a  town  could  be 
half  destroyed  in  a  single  night  without  declaration  of  war,  that  thousands  of 
women  and  children  could  be  killed  by  bombs,  nuns  massacred  by  rioters,  non- 
belligerent ships  torpedoed  in  the  Mediterranean  by  pirates  would  have  seemed 
mad. 

Civil  and  religious  liberty,  at  least  in  western  Europe,  seemed  to  be  safe  from 
attack.  In  no  civilized  country  at  that  time  would  a  man  have  been  persecuted 
for  his  beliefs.  Only  his  actions,  if  they  were  against  the  law,  would  have 
exposed  him  to  punishment.  Between  country  and  country  the  movements  of 
persons  and  goods  were  free,  trade  was  regular  and  profitable  and  currencies 
maintained  a  more  or  less  stable  purchasing  power. 

A  man  who  had  saved  during  his  working  life  could  be  confident  that  he  would 
be  secure  against  poverty  in  his  old  age;  fathers  took  steps  to  safeguard  the 
future  of  their  children;  in  every  class  of  society  reasonable  people  made  plans, 
looked  forward  to  their  realization  and  believed  in  man's  power  over  material 
things  and  events.  At  the  same  time,  moral  influences  were  strong;  even  those 
whd  did  not  practice  goodness  and  tolerance  would  not  have  dared  to  say  in 
public  that  these  virtues  were  crimes;  the  growing  wealth  of  society  made  social 
reforms  fairly  easy;  violence  was  praised  only  by  a  few  fanatics  and  a  few 
theorists.  The  peace  of  Europe  protected  a  great  civilization.  .  .  . 

During  the  war  of  1914,  humanity  once  more  served  a  gruesome  apprenticeship 
to  violence.  The  tiger  which  has  tasted  blood  no  longer  hesitates  to  attack  man; 
men  who  have  learned  to  kill  no  longer  have  the  same  respect  for  human  life.  To 
bombard  an  open  town  would  have  been  criminal  lunacy  in  1913.  But  to  us,  in 
193S,  who  have  become  familiar  with  the  idea  through  war  itself  and  through 
photographs  and  films  of  warfare,  it  has  become  no  more  than  an  "unavoidable 
necessity."  26 

Wars  can  bring  about  profound  changes  in  the  mentality  of  popula- 
tions. War  propaganda  stirs  up  emotions  and  arouses  passions,  some- 


26  The  New  York  Times  Magazine,  June  19,  1938. 


WAR  AND  PEACE  343 

times  to  such  a  degree  that  whole  nations  are  turned  into  veritable  mobs, 
so  that  people  become  absorbed  in  war  issues  and  are  savagely  intolerant 
even  of  slight  deviations  of  opinion.  In  the  first  World  War,  the  most 
ruthless  and  conscienceless  lying  was  indulged  in  by  those  who  directed 
war  propaganda;  and  the  censorship  in  war  time  prevented  any  counter- 
propaganda  and  eliminated  any  opportunity  for  truth  to  make  itself  felt. 
Many  civil  liberties  are  suspended  in  war  time  and  repressive  laws  are 
passed,  often  contrary  to  the  most  fundamental  principles  of  the  country 
in  peace  time.  Conscientious  objectors  to  war  are  often  harshly  dealt 
with  and  in  some  instances  have  been  slain. 

War  has  disastrous  effects  on  culture.  The  mind  is  distracted  from 
literature,  music,  and  art  and  is  directed  to  killing  enemies  and  to  sup- 
porting the  morale  of  those  devoted  to  killing.  Even  such  artistic  effort 
as  continues  is  primarily  devoted  to  arousing  and  sustaining  hatred  and 
to  bolstering  army  morale.  Matters  in  point  here  are  war  music,  war 
posters,  war  drama,  movies  and  the  like.  The  war  pictures  and  posters 
of  George  Bellows  in  the  first  World  War  and  of  Thomas  Hart  Benton 
in  the  second  World  War  are  good  examples  of  the  exploitation  of  art  in 
war  time.  Many  cathedrals,  libraries,  and  other  great  architectural  mon- 
uments may  be  ruthlessly  bombed  and  burned,  and  art  museums  may  be 
destroyed  or  rifled.  Scholarship  tends  to  be  debased.  Even  the  ablest 
scholars  may  descend  to  lying  and  misrepresentation  in  war  propaganda. 
Scholarly  endeavor  is  devoted  to  the  discovery  of  more  efficient  methods 
of  destruction,  such  as  laboratory  research  into  the  potentialities  of  "germ 
warfare"  and  the  like. 

It  is  often  contended  that,  whatever  the  disastrous  effects  of  war,  at 
least  it  hfl-s  a  beneficial  biological  influence  upon  the  human  race;  that 
it  intensifies  the  struggle  for  existence  and  thus  insures  the  survival  of 
the  fittest.  Such  a  contention  might  have  been  true  of  the  wars  among 
savages,  where  physical  strength  and  bravery  played  a  major  role  in  the 
outcome  of  battle.  Today,  however,  our  mechanized  war  is  no  biological 
struggle;  it  is  a  conflict  of  technology  and  psychology.  A  battalion  of 
dwarfs,  with  armored  tanks,  could  put  to  flight  tens  of  thousands  of 
brave  giants  armed  only  with  rifles  or  cutlasses.  In  fact,  war  tends  to 
reduce  the  physical  quality  of  the  population  by  drawing  off  the  best 
types  among  the  males  of  the  population,  to  be  murdered  in  mass  by  our 
contemporary  instruments  for  dealing  out  death. 

Wars  also  increase  the  frequency  and  deadliness  of  disease.  The  con- 
gregation of  soldiers  from  various  parts  of  the  world  starts  epidemics. 
Typhus  is  essentially  a  war  epidemic.  Some  say  the  influenza  epidemic 
of  1918  killed  more  persons  than  the  Black  Death  of  the  late  Middle  Ages. 
Venereal  disease  and  dysentery  become  more  frequent  in  war  time.  In 
the  first  World  War  some  7  million  days  of  service  were  lost  by  American 
soldiers  as  a  result  of  venereal  disease.  Some  339,000  soldiers,  the  equiv- 
alent of  23  divisions,  were  treated  for  venereal  disease.  The  reduction 
of  vitality,  through  impoverishment  and  through  starvation  due  to  block- 
ades and  the  like,  tends  to  make  disease  more  deadly.  Many  doctors  are 


344  WAR  AND  PEACE 

drawn  away  for  army  service  and  medical  care  becomes  inadequate  for 
civilians. 

Mental  disorders  also  become  more  numerous  in  war  time.  What  was 
called  "shell-shock"  in  the  first  World  War  is  a  mental  disease  caused  by 
tense  war-time  conditions.  Nearly  a  quarter  of  a  million  soldiers  were 
discharged  from  the  British  army  alone  during  the  first  World  War  be- 
cause of  mental  disease.  Many  of  the  shell-shocked  and  deranged 
soldiers  failed  to  recover  and  became  chronically  insane.  Thousands  of 
such  cases  are  segregated  in  veterans'  hospitals  and  other  institutions  for 
the  mentally  ill. 

Battlefield  mortality  and  disease  enormously  increase  the  death  rate. 
At  the  same  time,  the  birth  rate  is  usually  lowered  because  the  more 
vigorous  males  in  the  procreative  ages  are  taken  away  from  home  for 
long  periods.  Other  males  are  wounded,  maimed,  and  reduced  in  vitality. 
In  northern  and  western  Europe,  the  birth  rate  dropped  from  24.2  for  the 
years  1911-1914  to  17.0  for  the  years  1915-1919,  a  falling  off  of  about 
30  per  cent.  The  effect  is  continued  as  the  younger  and  more  vigorous 
males  are  killed  off.  In  the  first  World  War,  72  per  cent  of  German 
military  deaths  and  55  per  cent  of  the  French  were  of  men  under  30 
years  of  age.  Malnutrition  and  poverty  decrease  the  fertility  of  women 
and  increase  infant  mortality.  One  of  the  reasons  for  the  marked 
slowing-up  of  population  growth  after  1920  was  the  impact  of  the  first 
World  War  upon  population  trends. 

War  hastens  social  change  and  promotes  social  revolutions.  Wars 
ended  tribal  society  and  hastened  the  decline  of  the  Roman  Empire. 
They  ended  Feudalism  and  set  up  the  national  state.  They  spread  the 
principles  of  the  French  Revolution.  They  brought  Communism  to 
Russia  and  Fascism  to  Italy  and  Germany.  The  second  World  War 
may  bring  about  the  destruction  of  many  of  our  modern  institutions. 
While  social  change  is  not  always  to  be  deplored,  it  is  certainly  far  better 
to  have  it  brought  about,  if  possible,  by  orderly  and  civilized  reforms 
instead  of  the  violence  and  hysteria  of  war  time.  Social  change  pro- 
duced by  war  is  not  only  cruel  and  wasteful  but  it  may  also  promote 
reaction  and  counter-revolutions  that  place  in  jeopardy  whatever  gains 
have  been  made. 

One  of  the  worst  results  of  war  is  its  effect  upon  peace.  The  state  of 
mind  produced  by  war  makes  it  almost  impossible  to  negotiate  a  just  and 
constructive  peace  treaty  at  the  war's  end.  Hatreds  are  so  intense  that 
the  victors  are  impelled  to  impose  a  vindictive  peace  upon  the  vanquished, 
producing  resentment  and  a  desire  for  revenge.  In  this  way,  the  peace 
which  follows  one  war  becomes  a  cause  of  the  next  war.  This  was  not- 
ably the  case  with  the  first  World  War,  though  Woodrow  Wilson  had 
sought  to  avoid  any  such  result.  While  many  other  factors  contributed 
to  the  coming  of  the  second  World  War,  no  informed  and  fair-minded 
person  can  very  well  doubt  that  the  fundamental  cause  of  the  second 
World  War  was  the  postwar  treaties  of  1919.  Thus  wars  tend  to  breed 
wars,  in  endless  succession  and  confusion. 


WAR  AND   PEACE  345 

Prelude  to  the  Second  World  War 

The  threat  of  war,  which  hung  over  the  world  between  the  the  two 
world  wars,  was  by  far  the  most  ominous  single  aspect  of  the  world- 
crisis.  If  peace  could  be  preserved,  there  was  some  chance  that  we  might 
bridge  the  gulf  between  machines  and  institutions  and  preserve  civiliza- 
tion. But  another  devastating  world  war  intervened. 

The  war  threat  of  the  last  decade  rested  on  many  stubborn  foundations. 
There  was  the  old  war  system,  compounded  of  nationalism,  imperialism, 
secret  diplomacy,  and  the  like,  which  brought  about  the  World  War  of 
1914.  This  system  was  not  modified  in  any  important  way  after  1919. 
Its  spirit  permeated  the  peace  settlement  at  Paris  and  postwar  diplomacy. 

The  basis  for  a  new  war  was  laid  by  the  Treaty  of  Versailles  in  1919. 
Never  was  a  greater  opportunity  presented  to  man  to  use  generosity  and 
statesmanship  in  the  interest  of  permanent  peace,  and  never  was  an 
opportunity  for  good  turned  down  more  completely  and  ruthlessly.  All 
the  war  ideals  of  the  Entente  were  brazenly  betrayed.  The  defeated 
nations  were  shamefully  treated,  both  morally  and  materially.  In  the 
end,  the  handicaps  placed  by  the  victorious  Allies  upon  the  German 
Republic  destroyed  it.  The  resentment  over  the  Versailles  settlement 
encouraged  the  German  people  to  rally  to  Hitler  when  he  promised  to 
destroy  the  Versailles  system — a  promise  which  he  kept,  only  to  replace 
it  by  something  which  soon  appeared  to  be  far  worse  for  both  Germany 
and  the  world. 

We  had  been  promised  that  the  War  would  end  great  armaments, 
terminate  secret  diplomacy,  curb  nationalism,  create  a  world-state, 
outlaw  war,  and  make  the  world  safe  for  democracy. 

The  armament  race  after  the  first  World  War  was  more  feverish  and 
extensive  than  before  1914.  In  1938,  the  world  spent  about  sevenfold 
more  on  armaments  than  in  1913,  the  last  prewar  year.  In  1913  the 
armament  expenditures  were  about  $2,500,000,000.  By  1932  they  stood 
at  $4,000,000,000;  in  1936,  at  $11,000,000,000;  in  1938  at  $17,000,000,000; 
and  in  1939  at  about  $20,000,000,000.  But  the  armament  expenditures 
during  the  second  World  War  made  those  of  1939  seem  almost  a  disarm- 
ament budget.  The  United  States,  alone,  appropriated  $160,000,000,000 
between  June,  1940,  and  March,  1942. 

A  number  of  conferences  on  disarmament,  such  as  that  in  Washington 
in  1921-1922,  the  Geneva  conference  of  1927,  the  London  conferences  of 
1929-1930  and  1935-1936,  and  the  Geneva  conference  of  1932-1934,  all 
proved  completely  futile.  As  we  just  pointed  out,  the  world  was  in  1939 
spending  nearly  ten  times  as  much  on  armaments  as  in  1913.  Never 
before  did  the  world  spend  as  much  in  getting  ready  for  mass  murder. 

In  the  period  after  the  first  World  War,  much  attention  was  devoted 
to  the  armament  industries  and  to  their  propaganda  against  disarma- 
ment and  world  peace.  These  industries  included  the  manufacturers  of 
powder,  high  explosives,  bullets,  shells,  cannon,  rifles,  and  other  materials, 
used  directly  in  battle,  and  also  shipbuilding  firms,  steel  companies,  and 
the  like,  that  build  war  vessels  and  similar  instruments  of  combat. 


346  WAR  AND   PEACE 

Public  interest  was  aroused  by  the  senatorial  investigation  of  the 
activities  of  one  W.  B.  Shearer  at  the  Geneva  Arms  Conference  of  1927.27 
It  was  revealed  that  Mr.  Shearer  had  been  engaged  in  propaganda  for 
steel  and  shipbuilding  interests  that  were  pushing  the  "big  navy"  cam- 
paign. He  wrote  articles  and  made  speeches  in  behalf  of  naval  expan- 
sion, conducted  a  lobby  at  Geneva  against  disarmament  and  in  support 
of  a  large  American  navy,  attempted  to  manipulate  American  politics  in 
favor  of  armament  expansion,  and  organized  a  comprehensive  campaign 
of  propaganda  against  the  League  of  Nations,  the  World  Court,  and  other 
pacific  agencies.  Shearer  actually  boasted  that  he  was  largely  respon- 
sible for  breaking  up  the  Geneva  Disarmament  Conference. 

Even  more  excitement  was  produced  in  the  summer  of  1934  when 
Senator  Gerald  P.  Nye's  investigating  committee  revealed  the  activities, 
among  others,  of  the  international  "mystery  man,"  Sir  Basil  Zaharoff, 
who  was  shown  to  have  received  large  sums  for  his  multifarious  and 
devious  doings  in  promoting  the  sale  of  various  munitions  of  war,  espe- 
cially submarines.  Much  popular  interest  was  also  promoted  during 
the  same  year  by  the  publication  of  two  forceful  books  on  the  armament 
industry,  Merchants  of  Death  28  by  H.  C.  Engelbrecht  and  F.  C.  Hanig- 
hen,  and  Iron,  Blood  and  Profits  29  by  George  Seldes. 

There  is  little  doubt  about  the  extensive  character  of  the  armament 
industry,  its  powerful  propaganda,  its  insidious  lobby,  and  its  utter  un- 
scrupulousness  in  search  of  profits,  not  stopping  short  of  selling  munitions 
that  were  obviously  destined  to  deal  out  death  to  fellow  citizens.  Yet, 
as  Engelbrecht  and  Hanighen  make  clear,  it  is  a  mistake  to  blame  the 
armament  manufacturers  alone  for  keeping  alive  the  war  system  or  to 
imagine  that  the  closing  of  every  armament  factory  in  the  world  would 
end  war.  It  is  deeper  forces,  such  as  patriotism,  imperialism,  national- 
istic education,  and  capitalistic  competition,  that  really  cause  wars. 

Nor  is  the  greed  of  armament  manufacturers  at  all  unique.  They 
simply  follow  the  universal  principles  of  finance  capitalism,  the  theory 
of  business  enterprise,  and  the  profit  system.  If  British  tank-makers 
hastened  to  sell  Soviet  Russia  tanks  when  the  British  government  was 
about  to  break  off  relations  with  Russia,  so  did  leading  moguls  of  finance 
capitalism  sell  short  the  stock  of  their  own  banks.  If  British  airplane 
companies  were  ready  to  sell  airplanes  to  Hitler,  so  did  certain  American 
corporation  presidents  make  vast  profits  at  the  expense  of  their  own  stock- 
holders. The  armament  propaganda  and  its  serpentine  manipulations 
should  be  relentlessly  exposed,  but  friends  of  disarmament  will  have  to  go 
further  afield  if  they  wish  to  achieve  success  in  ending  war. 

Secret  diplomacy  and  international  duplicity  went  on  as  before,  despite 
the  formal  requirement  that  treaties  must  be  registered  with  the  League 
of  Nations.  There  were  thirty  national  states  in  Europe  in  1939,  as 


2TSee  C.  A.  Beard,  Navy:  Defense  or  Portent?  Harper,  1932,  chap.  v. 
28  Dodd,  Mead,  1934. 
»  Harper,  1934. 


WAR  AND   PEACE  347 

against  eighteen  in  1914.  And  each  of  these  was  as  blatantly  patriotic 
as  were  the  fewer  countries  existent  in  1914.  Not  only  had  psychological 
nationalism  been  intensified;  economic  nationalism  had  grown  apace. 
The  League  of  Nations  was  only  a  weak  preliminary  step  toward  a 
world-state,  and  it  is  today  completely  discredited  by  its  failure  to  stand 
steadfastly  against  the  aggression  of  Japan,  of  Italy,  and  of  Germany. 
War  was  not  outlawed,  and  the  Kellogg  Pact  turned  out  to  be  colossal 
international  hypocrisy.  The  reservations  to  the  Pact  made  its  terms 
inapplicable  to  any  probable  type  of  war.  Democracy  was  in  greater 
eclipse,  both  in  theory  and  in  practice,  before  the  second  World  War 
started  than  at  any  time  since  the  collapse  of  the  Revolutions  of  1848. 

Economic  factors  since  1918  played  their  part  in  drawing  Europe 
nearer  to  war.  Tariff  walls  became  ever  higher  and  more  numerous. 
Certain  countries,  such  as  Britain,  France,  and  the  United  States,  had 
large  colonial  empires  or  many  areas  of  "special  interest."  This  gave 
them  markets  and  raw  materials.  Other  great  states — Japan,  Italy, 
and  Germany — had  no  comparable  outlets  and  resources.  After  1930, 
Japan  and  Italy,  by  bluffing  their  antagonists,  carved  out  for  themselves 
more  extensive  colonial  possessions.  Then  Germany  moved  in  1938,  and 
her  attempt  to  expand  supplied  the  spark  which  set  off  the  long-threatened 
war.  Certainly,  as  Simonds  and  Emeny  have  done  well  to  emphasize,  so 
long  as  the  great  powers  were  divided  relatively  into  the  "haves"  and  the 
"have-nots,"  there  could  be  little  hope  of  permanent  peace.  And  it  seems 
that  the  situation  could  not  be  remedied  without  war. 

The  Spanish  civil  war  showed  how  preliminary  wars  could  be  fought 
without  formally  involving  all  of  Europe.  The  Spanish  rebel  campaign 
would  have  amounted  to  little  without  the  aid  of  Germany  and  Italy. 
Since  the  Loyalist  forces  received  some  assistance  from  Russia  and 
France,  there  is  some  justification  for  calling  the  Spanish  civil  war  the 
"little  world  war."  It  was  a  "try  out"  for  what  came  after  September, 
1939. 

In  the  light  of  these  developments,  it  would  have  required  almost  a 
miracle  to  have  prevented  war.  Powerful  forces  made  for  war,  while 
almost  none  of  any  consequence  worked  against  it.  The  usual  argument 
against  the  prospect  of  war  was  based  on  the  belief  that  the  great  powers 
would  not  fight,  for  fear  of  the  frightful  consequences  of  the  new  war 
machinery.  But  this  was  a  futile  argument — one  which  has  been  vainly 
advanced  ever  since  the  invention  of  gunpowder. 

It  is  probable  that  a  firm  alliance  of  Britain,  France,  Russia,  and  the 
United  States  at  any  time  before  1939  could  have  preserved  peace.  Hitler 
and  Mussolini  could  scarcely  have  been  so  foolish  as  to  risk  war  against 
such  a  formidable  coalition  of  powers.  But  not  even  the  threat  of  a  fatal 
war  could  drive  these  great  liberal  and  radical  powers  into  effective 
alliance.  Indeed,  the  British  government  and  ruling  classes  deliberately 
strengthened  and  encouraged  Hitler,  so  that  he  would  be  a  bulwark 
against  Soviet  Russia. 

The  second  World  War  came  in  1939,  and  so  incalculable  appeared 


348  WAR  AND   PEACE 

its  potential  consequences,  that  no  dependable  prediction  could  be  made 
regarding  man's  future,  except  that  it  was  likely  to  be  far  different  from 
the  present. 

The  Social   Revolution   Behind  the  Second  World  War 

If  we  want  to  understand  what  caused  the  second  World  War  and 
where  it  is  leading  us  we  must  dig  deeper  than  the  diplomatic  stupidity 
of  the  democracies  or  the  bellicosity  of  the  dictators.  The  war  came  in 
1939  because  of  the  failure  to  bring  our  institutional  life  up  to  date 
through  applying  to  it  the  same  degree  of  intelligence  that  we  have 
made  use  of  in  the  scientific  laboratory  and  in  the  realm  of  mechanical 
invention. 

The  gulf  between  our  machines  and  institutions  had  suggested  the 
need  of  readjustment  even  before  the  close  of  the  nineteenth  century. 
The  first  notable  effort  to  accomplish  something  along  this  line  took 
place  in  the  German  Empire  under  Otto  von  Bismarck.  Bismarck  intro- 
duced a  comprehensive  program  of  social  legislation — social  insurance, 
labor  laws,  and  the  like — which  was  designed  to  adjust  German  society 
to  the  Industrial  Revolution  and  reduce  the  appeal  of  Socialism.  His 
program  was  continued  and  extended  under  William  II.  The  growth  of 
the  Social  Democrats  held  some  promise  of  a  trend  towards  democracy 
in  imperial  Germany. 

In  England,  a  Liberal-Labor  coalition  carried  through  comparable 
reforms  under  democratic  auspices  between  1905  and  1914.  English 
government  diiring  this  decade  may  well  be  held  to  represent  the  most 
successful  attempt  of  democracy  in  bridging  the  gulf  between  machinery 
and  society.  In  France,  stimulated  by  a  great  socialist,  Jean  Jaures, 
there  was  also  a  considerable  effort  to  bring  institutions  up  to  date  through 
progressive  social  legislation.  In  the  United  States,  there  was  a  rever- 
beration of  this  same  trend  in  the  so-called  "Square  Deal"  program  of 
Theodore  Roosevelt.  In  the  Australasian  colonies  of  Great  Britain  there 
were  advanced  experiments  in  progressive  social  legislation.  Consider- 
able progress  was  also  being  made  in  approaching  war  in  a  rational 
fashion.  Civilized  persons  were  coming  to  understand  that  war  is  the 
most  dangerous  anachronism  among  all  our  institutional  vestiges,  and 
that  a  better  method  of  adjusting  world  affairs  must  be  provided.  The 
Hague  Court  encouraged  arbitration.  Norman  Angell  was  telling  us,  in 
his  The  Great  Illusion,  that  wars  are  too  expensive  to  fight.  Andrew 
Carnegie  was  giving  away  his  millions  to  promote  the  cause  of  peace. 
Nicholas  Murray  Butler  was  carrying  on  peace  propaganda.  William 
Jennings  Bryan  was  negotiating  arbitration  treaties. 

It  is  possible  that  then  the  gulf  between  machines  and  institutions  might 
have  been  bridged  by  gradual  and  civilized  reforms.  But  the  war  of 
1914  rudely  put  an  end  to  peaceful  domestic  reforms,  brought  about  the 
most  deadly  conflict  of  all  time,  and  set  the  stage  for  social  revolutions 
of  unprecedented  scope  and  violence. 

In  Great  Britain,  the  Liberal  party  was  destroyed  as  a  major  political 


WAR  AND  PEACE  349 

force.  The  Labor  party  did  not  have  the  strength  or  experience  to  take 
over  England.  Britain  lapsed  into  ineptitude  and  stagnation  under  a 
smug  and  blind  Tory  domination.  Jaures  was  assassinated  in  France  just 
before  the  war  broke  out  and  no  other  great  French  leader  stepped  into 
his  shoes.  France  became  more  nationalistic  and  reactionary.  It  was 
devoted  primarily  to  holding  the  ill-gotten  gains  of  Versailles  rather  than 
to  solving  the  problems  of  the  French  economy.  Even  the  well-inten- 
tioned Popular  Front  under  Leon  Blum  came  too  late  to  accomplish 
anything  significant  and  it  lacked  both  courage  and  realism.  The  old 
monarchial  government  in  Germany  was  overthrown ,  and  the  new 
Republic  was  too  severely  handicapped  by  the  penalties  of  defeat  to 
carry  on  effectively.  In  the  United  States  we  passed  from  the  promising 
"New  Freedom"  of  Woodrow  Wilson  into  the  shockingly  inefficient  and 
corrupt  "normalcy"  of  Warren  Harding  and  the  Ohio  Gang,  and  the  even 
more  dangerous  "sleeping  sickness"  of  the  Coolidge  era. 

The  economic  cost  of  the  first  World  War,  amounting  to  the  astronom- 
ical figure  of  $350,000,000,000,  piled  up  great  war  debts.  Crushing  taxa- 
tion to  pay  these  off  left  little  money  for  reform  measures.  The  reaction- 
aries in  control  of  European  states  became  more  fearful  of  change  and 
more  adamant  in  their  stupid  resistance  to  reform.  The  Tories  in  Eng- 
land and  the  Conservatives  in  France  became  hysterical  in  their  fear  of 
Russia,  and  actually  supported  Hitler  in  the  hope  that  he  would  present 
a  formidable  bulwark  against  Bolshevism.  The  victors  in  the  first  World 
War  decided  to  hold  their  gains,  even  of  they  had  to  fight  a  second  world 
war  to  do  so.  They  spent  more  money  than  ever  on  armament,  even 
though  they  had  disarmed  Germany  and  were  not  faced  with  any  imme- 
diate danger. 

It  is  in  this  frustration  of  reform  and  orderly  progress  by  the  first 
World  War  that  we  must  seek  the  fundamental  causes  of  the  second 
World  War.  Since  the  Industrial  Revolution,  whenever  any  country  has 
been  reduced  to  desperation  and  crisis,  it  must  resort  to  rapid  and  violent 
efforts  to  bridge  the  gulf  between  machines  and  institutions.  Since  the 
first  World  War,  the  result  has  been  what  we  know  as  Totalitarianism — 
the  crisis  form  of  government  and  economy.  As  Lindsay  Rogers  pointed 
out  long  ago,  totalitarianism  is  the  natural  and  all-but-inevitable  response 
to  social  desperation  in  our  day.30 

The  impact  of  the  first  World  War  upon  the  rotten  imperialism  and 
feudalism  of  Tsarist  Russia  brought  this  archaic  system  down  in  ruins 
in  1917.  The  Bolsheviks  took  advantage  of  the  crisis  and  set  up  a 
thoroughgoing  Totalitarianism  of  the  Left.  After  1917,  the  Bolsheviks 
made  a  terrific  effort  rapidly  to  bridge  the  gulf  between  machines  and 
institutions  under  Marxian  guidance. 

Italy  was  impoverished  and  disillusioned  by  the  first  World  War,  and 
its  government  after  the  war  lacked  the  courage,  resolution  and  vision 
to  take  matters  in  hand  under  socialist  auspices.  The  response  there  to 


80  Lindsay  Rogers,  Crisis  Government,  Norton,  1934. 


350  WAR  AND   PEACE 

desperation  and  disintegration  was  the  Fascist  program  of  Mussolini 
and  his  Black  Shirts.  They  set  up  the  first  Totalitarianism  of  the  Right 
and  sought  earnestly  to  bridge  the  gulf  according  to  Fascist  patterns. 

The  German  Republic  was  broken  mainly  by  the  vindictive  penalties 
imposed  upon  it  at  Versailles  in  1919.  But  the  inefficiency  and  waste  of 
the  government  itself  must  share  the  responsibility  for  the  failure.  When 
it  was  reduced  to  economic  desperation  by  1932,  the  natural  response  was 
Hitler,  with  his  brown  shirts  and  Swastikas.  The  Nazis  have  bridged  the 
gulf  between  machines  and  institutions  with  a  speed  and  ruthlessness  un- 
matched elsewhere.  But  they  also  revived  and  extolled  the  war  system 
to  a  degree  unequaled  since  early  modern  times.  Thus,  their  achieve- 
ment in  bridging  the  gulf  has  been  an  expensive  failure,  since  war  is  the 
institutional  antiquity  most  disastrous  to  existing  society. 

The  first  World  War  thus  produced  three  ruthless  totalitarian  experi- 
ments which  forcefully  challenged  what  we  regard  as  the  fundamental 
modern  institutions  of  nationalism,  democracy,  and  capitalism.  To  meet 
the  challenge,  there  was  only  an  unrivaled  collection  of  dry  rot  and 
dead  wood,  the  natural  outcome  of  frustrated  progress. 

In  the  great  democracies  of  England  and  France,  there  was  a  disheart- 
ening spectacle  of  economic  decline,  the  lack  of  a  united  front  in  facing 
public  problems,  stupid  resistance  to  reform,  and  internal  corruption. 
Diplomatic  ineptitude  and  feebleness  predominated.  Foreign  policies 
were  dictated  by  the  desire  to  protect  the  financial  interests  of  a  wealthy 
and  effete  minority  rather  than  by  a  determination  to  render  the  country 
immune  to  military  attack.  Reckless  gambling  in  world  affairs  took  the 
place  of  rational  diplomacy. 

Orderly  progress,  following  the  prewar  pattern,  was  to  be  observed  only 
in  the  small  Scandinavian  states  and  in  Finland  and  Czechoslovakia. 
The  achievements  of  these  states  along  the  so-called  "Middle-Way" 
patterns  of  social  change  were  impressive  indeed,  but  these  countries 
were  too  small  to  count  in  determining  the  trend  of  world  affairs  in 
Europe. 

In  its  most  fundamental  sense,  the  second  World  War  represents  the 
inevitable  clash  of  totalitarian  desperation  with  democratic  dry  rot. 
The  democracies  were  too  stupid  and  fearful  either  to  get  on  living  terms 
with  the  totalitarians  and  make  reasonable  concessions  to  them,  or  to 
crush  them  by  military  force  while  it  was  still  possible. 

Had  Europe  been  able  to  avoid  the  second  World  War,  the  bridging  of 
the  gulf  between  machines  and  institutions  might  have  proceeded  more 
slowly  and  the  violence  attendant  thereupon  might  have  been  greatly 
reduced.  As  it  is,  the  second  World  War  has  not  only  brought  on  the 
crisis  far  more  quickly,  but  it  has  greatly  accelerated  the  tempo  of  social 
change.  It  seems  likely  that  the  decade  following  1939  will  bring  about 
or  set  in  motion  social  transformations  more  vital  and  far-reaching  than 
those  which  have  taken  place  in  any  previous  century.  It  required  two 
centuries  to  bring  about  the  change  from  medievalism  to  modern  society 
in  England,  where  the  transformation  was  the  most  rapid.  It  may  turn 


WAR  AND  PEACE  351 

out  that  the  transition  from  modern  society  to  whatever  new  era  lies 
ahead  will  be  effected  in  a  very  few  years,  perhaps  less  than  a  decade. 

So  far  as  Europe  and  the  Old  Word  are  concerned,  it  already  appears 
that  the  new  era  will  be  fashioned  according  to  totalitarian  patterns,  no 
matter  which  side  wins  the  second  World  War.  France,  in  defeat,  has 
already  taken  long  strides  towards  totalitarianism.  In  order  to  conduct 
the  war  efficiently,  Britain  has  gone  over  to  an  extreme  form  of  state 
control  in  all  phases  of  life.  Win  or  lose,  there  is  not  much  prospect  of 
Britain's  return  to  the  type  of  democratic  and  capitalistic  form  of  social 
organization  that  existed  in  1939. 

As  we  entered  the  war,  we  adopted  a  totalitarian  way  of  life  in  order 
to  wage  war  more  effectively,  with  only  slight  probability  that  we  could 
put  off  the  totalitarian  coat  at  the  war's  end.  Thus,  whatever  the  out- 
come of  the  current  conflict  in  Europe,  we  face  a  new  world  pattern. 
The  society  and  civilization  of  the  future  is  likely  to  differ  as  greatly  from 
that  of  Jeffersonian  democracy  or  Gladstonian  liberalism  as  these  did 
from  the  society  and  culture  of  Louis  XIV. 

It  would  require  a  reckless  man  to  dogmatize  on  what  will  emerge 
when  the  war  is  over  and  the  world-revolution  of  our  day  is  relatively 
complete.  Had  Britain  won  a  fairly  rapid  victory  with  our  aid,  it  would 
have  been  possible  to  revamp  democracy  and  capitalism  on  a  just  and 
efficient  pattern,  an  achievement  already  made  by  Sweden.  It  would 
also  have  been  possible  to  create  a  federation  of  Europe  which  might 
assure  world  peace  for  generations. 

A  quick  victory  by  the  Nazis  would  have  brought  a  ruthless  but  effi- 
cient consolidation  of  the  Old  World,  with  spheres  of  interest  assigned  to 
the  main  Axis  powers.  The  military  socialism  of  the  Nazis  would  prob- 
ably have  been  replaced  by  a  "bread-and-circus"  regime  unparalleled  in 
human  history.  This  would  probably  raise  living  standards,  but  at  the 
price  of  eliminating  the  blessings  of  liberty  and  free  government. 

A  long  war  and  a  stalemate  might  lead  to  a  virtual  triumph  for  Soviet 
Russia  and  state  socialism,  unless  Russia  were  exhausted.  If  the  war  is 
long  drawn  out  and  it  ends  in  a  stalemate,  with  no  power  or  group  of 
powers  strong  enough  to  make  and  execute  a  constructive  peace  settle- 
ment, then  only  chaos  could  be  the  immediate  result. 

If  chaos  is  averted,  the  war  is  likely  to  bring  about  a  far  greater  degree 
of  state  control  over  economic  life,  more  expert  but  more  bureaucratic 
government,  the  extinction  of  the  full  independence  of  small  states,  inter- 
national consolidation,  and  a  hard-boiled  public  psychology  which  will 
retard  the  restoration  of  the  finer  humane  values  for  many  years  to 
come.81 


81  For  the  most  competent  forecast  of  the  probable  results  of  the  second  World 
War,  see  W.  H.  Chamberlin,  "The  Coming  Peace,"  in  The  American  Mercury, 
November,  1940;  and  by  the  same  author,  "War — Shortcut  to  Fascism,"  ibid., 
December,  1940. 


352  WAR  AND  PEACE 

We  may  well  conclude  this  chapter  on  war  in  our  time  by  quoting  the 
ringing  denunciation  of  war  as  a  system  by  Mrs.  Franklin  D.  Roosevelt 
in  the  spring  of  1942: 

It  is  still  difficult  for  me  to  see  any  reason  for  a  war  among  peoples  in  this 
twentieth  century,  when  human  beings  are  supposed  to  have  progressed  in  in- 
telligence arid  civilization.  The  ramifications  of  war  arc  so  enormous  many 
innocent  people  will  suffer  and  we  will  all  pay  the  price  in  one  way  or  another. 
It  chills  me  to  my  soul  to  think  of  the  best  of  our  young  men  going  off  to  die  or 
to  return  crippled  in  mind  and  body. 

Out  of  this  terrific  waste  of  human  life  must  come  a  realization  and  a  determi- 
nation on  the  part  of  people  all  over  the  world  that  no  one  really  wins  a  war, 
and  that  today's  territorial  gains  provide  the  fertile  field  for  a  future  war.  No 
peoples  want  war.  It  is  the  governments  who  precipitate  them,  and  for  future 
peace  the  peoples  must  govern  themselves.  We  must  all  work  for  universal 
understanding.82 

ss  Quoted  in  The  Arbitrator,  May,  1942.  p.  3. 


CHAPTER  XI 
Law  and  Justice  as  a  Social  Problem 

Our  Lawyer-Made  Civilization 

IN  THIS  and  the  following  chapter  we  shall  deal  with  some  of  the  more 
important  social  problems  which  arise  out  of  law  and  its  administration 
in  the  United  States  in  our  day.*  The  most  pressing  social  problems 
related  to  law  and  the  administration  of  justice  are,  of  course,  the  out- 
growth of  weaknesses  and  deficiencies  in  our  legal  and  judicial  system. 
Hence,  we  shall  be  primarily  concerned  with  defects  in  law  and  current 
legal  procedure.  Good  laws  and  their  efficient  execution  do  not  usually 
create  serious  problems.  We  take  for  granted  the  important  social  serv- 
ices rendered  by  law  and  the  courts,  and  freely  concede  the  indispensable 
social  functions  of  wise  legislation  and  the  fair  and  competent  adminis- 
tration of  justice.  The  surest  way  to  secure  better  laws  and  more  equable 
and  certain  justice  is  to  expose  fearlessly  the  prevalence  of  foolish  and 
unjust  laws  and  the  arbitrary,  incompetent,  and  unfair  administration  of 
law  by  our  courts. 

As  in  treating  public  health  we  have  to  deal  chiefly  with  the  problem  of 
disease  and  the  defects  in  medical  service,  so  here  we  must  treat  mainly 
the  grievous  deficiencies  of  our  system  of  laws  and  their  execution.  We 
do  not  propose  to  terminate  medicine  because  disease  still  persists ;  we  do, 
however,  criticize  inadequacies  in  medical  service  which  make  possible  a 
far  greater  volume  of  disease  and  death  than  is  at  all  necessary  in  our  day. 
Likewise,  we  recognize  the  indispensable  character  of  law  and  legal  insti- 
tutions. But  society  cannot  profit  to  the  maximum  by  their  services  so 
long  as  the  present  weaknesses  and  corruption  in  legal  procedure-  continue. 
We  are  not  at  all  concerned  with  sensational  muck-raking  or  scandal- 
mongering.  We  are  only  interested  in  exposing  the  usual  and  common- 
place defects  in  the  administration  of  law  which  are  well-known  to  all 
competent  students  of  the  problem  and  are  universally  recognized  and 
condemned  by  upright  lawyers.  Unusual  cases  of  legal  incompetence  and 
corruption  make  good  reading,  but  they  cannot  be  fairly  regarded  as 
prevalent  and  extremely  significant  examples  of  legal  deficiencies. 

This  discussion  is  merely  a  restrained  description  of  the  legal  process  as 
it  goes  on  in  our  day.  Having  had  an  unusual  opportunity  to  enjoy  the 
friendship  and  confidence  of  lawyers,  from  some  of  the  most  eminent  law 
school  deans,  jurists  and  judges  of  the  day  to  others  who  are  frankly 
associated  with  racketeers  and  ambulance-chasing,  the  writer  has  had 

*This  chapter  has  been  read  and  criticized  by  an  eminent  student  of  legal  pro- 
cedure, two  distinguished  professors  of  law,  and  a  brilliant  law  school  student. 

353 


354  LAW  AS  A  SOCIAL  PROBLEM 

special  advantages  in  obtaining  an  account  of  the  present  state  of  the  law 
from  those  who  are  in  the  best  possible  position  to  know  about  it.  But 
the  material  in  these  pages  is  chiefly  derived  from  printed  sources,  readily 
accessible  and  set  forth  by  legal  scholars  of  the  highest  reputation. 

Law  and  lawyers  are  today  the  most  important  directive  element  in  our 
civilization.  Our  technique  of  production,  transportation,  and  commu- 
nication may  be  determined  and  controlled  by  science  and  machinery,  but 
our  institutional  life  is  dominated  by  law  and  lawyers.  We  hear  much 
talk  about  "our  scientific  age/'  "our  industrial  society,"  "our  mechanical 
civilization/'  and  "our  empire  of  machines."  Nevertheless,  ours  is  still  a 
lawyer-made  civilization,  and  one  made  by  jurisprudence  which  reached 
its  present  character  by  1825,  before  most  of  the  great  scientific  and 
mechanical  advances  had  taken  place.  But  lawyers  today  stand  in  awe 
and  reverence  before  these  laws  that  reflect  an  earlier  civilization,  one 
which  resembled  that  of  Rameses  II  and  Bargon  more  than  it  does  our 
urban-industrial  world  culture.  In  other  words,  we  are  bound  down,  in 
the  second  third  of  the  twentieth  century,  by  legal  theories  and  practices 
that  accumulated  in  the  vast  reach  of  time  between  the  Swiss  Lake- 
dwellers  and  Andrew  Jackson.  There  have  been  many  new  laws  passed 
since  1825,  but  "The  Law/'  as  Fred  Rodell  calls  it,  has  not  changed.  A 
good  lawyer  of  1825  could  appear  effectively  in  any  ordinary  court  today 
without  any  additional  legal  education.  A  surgeon  of  1825  would  hardly 
qualify  for  admission  to  one  of  our  better  butcher-shops,  to  say  nothing  of 
a  first-class  city  hospital. 

Ours  is  as  much  a  lawyer-made  civilization,  on  its  institutional  side,  as 
the  civilization  of  Assyria  and  Rome  was  a  military  one,  and  that  of  the 
Middle  Ages  a  religious  one.  The  lawyers  of  today  are  the  political 
priests  who  control  our  civilization  as  thoroughly  as  the  Catholic  priests 
dominated  medieval  institutional  life.  The  United  States  Supreme 
Court  in  1930  could  fairly  be  compared  with  the  medieval  papacy  under 
Innocent  III.  That  it  is  now  headed  towards  the  declining  status  of  the 
papacy  under  Boniface  VIII  is  not  so  certain,  though  it  seems  probable. 

Lawyers  made  our  government  in  1787  and  they  have  run  it  ever  since. 
Mogt  of  our  presidents  and  legislators,  and  nearly  all  judges,  have  been 
lawyers.  Lawyers  not  only  administer  and  interpret  our  laws  after  they 
are  made,  but  they  take  the  lead  in  making  them.  These  lawyer-made 
laws  control  our  institutions  and  conduct,  from  corporations  to  divorce 
and  from  real  property  to  prohibition  and  gambling.  The  utilization  of 
the  machines  in  our  factories  is  controlled  as  much  by  constitutional  and 
statutory  law  as  by  the  laws  of  mechanics.  Laws  have  organized  and 
directed  capitalism  and  thus  supplied  the  pattern  of  our  economic  life. 
The  basic  economic  problems  of  our  age,  which  we  discussed  at  the  outset 
of  Chapter  V,  arise  mainly  because  our  potential  mechanical  economy 
of  abundance  is  transformed  by  archaic  laws  into  an  actual  economy 
of  scarcity.  Many  of  the  problems  of  property  which  we  analyzed 
pearlier  grow  out  of  law  and  lawyers,  though  we  need  not  ignore  the  social 
and  economic  issues  involved.  Our  moral  values  and  personal  behavior 
are  mainly  determined  and  executed  by  means  of  law. 


LAW  AS  A  SOCIAL  PROBLEM  355 

Since  legal  education  and  court  practice  are  based  on  the  theory  of,  and 
adherence  to,  precedents,  the  tendency  is  to  keep  the  law  fixed  and  rigid 
and  to  encourage  lawyers  to  exert  their  influence  to  prevent  our  civili- 
zation from  changing.  Yet,  to  keep  pace  with  new  social  concepts  and 
scientific  discoveries,  we  have  to  alter  our  laws  and  adapt  them  to  new 
conditions.  If  we  are  to  avoid  revolution,  we  must  achieve  orderly  re- 
form through  adequate  laws.  Law  will  need  to  be  transformed  from  a 
priesthood  of  stagnation  and  privilege  into  a  science  of  social  and  eco- 
nomic engineering.  This  view  and  function  of  law  is  urged  by  progres- 
sive jurists  like  Dean  Roscoe  Pound  and  Jerome  Frank.  Ferdinand 
Lundberg  clearly  emphasizes  the  preeminent  role  exerted  by  law  and 
lawyers  in  shaping  our  life  today: 

The  small  body  of  approximately  175,000  practitioners,  active  and  inactive,  that 
constitutes  the  legal  profession  in  the  United  States  probably  plays,  in  its  softly 
insinuating  fashion,  a  much  more  weighty  social  role  than  do  editors  or  publishers, 
physicians  or  surgeons,  educators  or  labor  leaders,  and  perhaps  even  financiers  or 
politicians.  Lawyers  may  not  in  many  cases  make  the  final  decisions  that  are  of 
great  moment  to  society;  but  they  do  give  the  final  decisions  of  financiers,  indus- 
trialists, labor  leaders  and  politicians  intellectual  implementation  to  the  end  that 
they  shall  be  accepted  by  a  public  conditioned  to  react  favorably  to  the  legalistic 
vocabulary.1 

He  quotes  approvingly  the  opinion  of  Edward  S.  Robinson  to  the  effect 
that  "the  lawyers,  whether  judges,  counsellors  or  scholars,  represent  the 
dominant  social  philosophy  of  our  day."  2 

Leading  Stages  in  the  Evolution  of  Law 

Primitive  Law.  There  are  innumerable  definitions  of  law,  but  prob- 
ably as  clear  and  serviceable  a  one  as  we  could  find  would  regard  law  as 
the  publicly  enforceable  rules  of  human  conduct  and  social  behavior  which 
prevail  in  any  country  at  any  given  time.  Certain  of  the  folkways  and 
mores  governing  conduct  may  be  enforced  merely  by  the  pressure  of  pub- 
lic opinion.  Others  have  behind  them  the  power  of  the  state.  The  latter 
are  what  we  customarily  regard  as  law.  There  are  many  theories  as  to 
the  source  of  law,  some  regarding  it  as  the  product  of  divine  wisdom, 
others  as  a  universal  expression  of  natural  norms,  and  still  others  as  the 
outgrowth  of  legislation  and  judicial  opinions.  The  latter  is  the  only 
practical  definition  which  need  concern  us,  though  we  recognize  that  legis- 
lation is  invariably  the  outgrowth  of  social  customs  and  public  opinion.8 

Primitive  peoples,  properly  speaking,  possessed  no  written  law.4  Prim- 
itive law  existed  in  the  form  of  customary  usages  transmitted  orally  and 


1  "The  Legal  Profession,"  Harper's,  December,  1938,  p.  2. 

2  Ibid.    For  more  details  on  this  matter,  see  E.  S.  Robinson,  Law  and  the  Lawyers, 
Macmillan,  1935. 

8  For  good  introductory  accounts  of  the  history  of  law,  see  J.  M.  Zane,  The  Story 
of  Law,  Ives  Washburn,  1927;  and  W.  A.  Robson,  Civilization  and  the  Growth  of 
Law,  Macmillan,  1935.  Somewhat  more  scholarly  is  William  Seagle,  The  Quest 
for  Law,  Knopf,  1941. 

4  Cf .  Robson,  op.  cit.,  Chaps.  VIII-XI. 


356  LAW  AS  A  SOCIAL  PROBLEM 

rigorously  enforced  by  the  pressure  of  the  groups.  Primitive  law  was  any 
social  rule  or  usage  that  imposed  a  penalty  for  any  infringement  of  group 
rules.  It  was  the  general  assumption  by  primitives  that  their  customary 
usages  were  revealed  by  the  gods.  These  customs  were,  thus,  believed  to 
represent  the  divine  will  with  respect  to  all  the  details  of  human  conduct. 
Since  primitive  man  regarded  his  gods  as  the  dispensers  of  all  the  "luck" 
and  good  fortune  which  he  experienced,  he  could  not  very  well  afford  to 
ignore  any  infractions  of  the  social  codes  of  the  group.  Such  infractions 
were  insults  to  the  benevolent  masters  of  the  spiritual  world. 

Thus  the  unwritten  primitive  codes  of  usages  were  usually  obeyed  far 
more  literally  and  meticulously  than  are  our  modern  legal  codes;  prim- 
itives punished  crimes  with  expedition  and  ferocity ;  and  many  interesting 
ceremonies  were  connected  with  the  punishment  of  violations  of  group 
rules.  Penalties  were  designed  to  show  the  gods  that  the  group  in  no 
sense  tolerated  criminal  acts  which  evoked  divine  displeasure  and  thus 
threatened  the  safety  and  security  of  the  group. 

In  primitive  times  criminal  law  was  more  important  than  civil  law. 
The  crimes  in  primitive  society  fell  into  three  main  classes:  (1)  those 
which  violated  the  taboos  or  usages  of  the  local  community  or  the  gentile 
group  as  a  whole;  (2)  the  crimes  which  primarily  concerned  the  smaller 
family  group;  and  (3)  injuries  wrought  by  one  group  upon  another. 

Among  crimes  of  the  first  class  were  the  violation  of  exogamy  (incest) , 
witchcraft,  treason,  and  cowardice.  Parricide  and  adultery  illustrate  the 
second  class  of  crimes.  The  third  class  of  crimes  included  any  form  of 
injury  done  by  a  member  of  an  adjoining  clan  or  gens.  It  comprised, 
besides  the  normal  crimes  of  contemporary  society,  some  relatively  slight 
modern  offenses.  Slander,  for  example,  was  a  very  serious  offense  in 
primitive  times.  An  injury  to  members  of  an  adjoining  clan  was  not 
regarded  as  a  crime  by  the  group  to  which  the  perpetrator  of  the  crime 
belonged.  The  punishment  for  such  an  act  was  inflicted  by  the  members 
of  the  group  of  the  injured  person,  according  to  the  principles  of  blood 
feud. 

Among  primitive  peoples,  the  systems  of  evidence  with  which  we  are 
familiar  today  were  lacking.  Only  among  certain  African  tribes  do  there 
seem  to  be  traces  of  a  practice  resembling  the  modern  jury  trial  for  ascer- 
taining guilt  or  innocence.  Even  among  the  ruder  primitive  peoples, 
however,  definite  methods  of  ascertaining  the  truth  of  an  accusation  or  the 
merits  of  a  dispute  were  in  evidence.  Such  methods  usually  bore  a  heavy 
magico-religious  coloring.  Guilt  or  innocence  was  usually  determined  by 
oaths,  the  ordeal,  or  trial  by  battle. 

Always  the  problem  of  guilt  was  indirectly  referred  to  the  gods.  Oaths 
did  not  involve  direct  testimony,  but  simply  a  declaration  on  the  part  of 
the  oath-taker  of  the  innocence  or  guilt  of  the  accused.  It  was  widely 
believed  that  a  perjurer  would  be  punished  by  the  gods.  The  ordeal  was 
carried  out  in  various  ways.  A  man  might  be  required  to  carry  a  heated 
stone  in  his  bare  hand.  If  the  burns  healed  rapidly,  the  gods  were  sup- 


LAW  AS  A  SOCIAL  PROBLEM  357 

posed  to  have  intervened  to  prove  his  innocence.  If  the  wounds  healed 
slowly,  the  gods  were  regarded  as  having  indicated  the  guilt  of  the  ac- 
cused. Likewise,  in  trial  by  battle,  victory  was  awarded  by  the  gods  to 
the  innocent  party,  irrespective  of  his  personal  strength  or  skill. 

We  may  be  contemptuous  of  such  crude  institutions  as  the  ordeal,  but 
the  modern  jury  is  hardly  more  likely  to  bring  accurate  conclusions  as  to 
guilt  or  innocence  in  important  criminal  cases.  The  present  jury  system 
rests  on  psychological  and  logical  fallacies  as  glaring  as  any  religious 
superstitions  which  earlier  supported  the  primitive  ordeal. 

Primitive  punishments  were,  for  the  most  part,  either  exile  or  some  form 
of  corporal  punishment.  They  were  designed  to  deter  others  from  subse- 
quent commission  of  crimes,  and  also  to  show  to  the  gods  the  group's  dis- 
approval of  the  violation  of  its  customary  usages.  Exile  was  extremely 
terrifying  to  the  one  dismissed  from  the  group,  for  he  was  at  the  mercy  of 
human  enemies  as  well  as  of  the  spiritual  world.  Corporal  punishments 
were  usually  based  upon  the  lex  talionis  principle  of  "an  eye  for  an  eye 
and  a  tooth  for  a  tooth."  Often,  when  the  penalty  was  imposed  through 
a  method  identical  with  that  employed  in  the  execution  of  the  crime,  the 
practice  went  to  ludicrous  extremes.  L.  T.  Hobhouse  tells  of  a  case  where 
a  man  was  killed  by  another  who  jumped  out  of  a  tree  upon  his  victim. 
As  punishment  for  the  crime,  the  culprit  was  taken  beneath  the  same  tree. 
A  representative  of  the  kin  of  the  deceased  mounted  the  tree  and,  to  his 
own  imminent  peril,  repeatedly  jumped  down  upon  the  murderer  until  the 
latter  was  killed. 

Where  the  practice  of  blood  feud  existed,  crimes  committed  by  a 
member  of  one  clan  against  a  member  of  another  might  lead  to  prolonged 
disastrous  consequences.  For  example,  if  an  offense  was  committed  by  a 
member  of  clan  A  against  a  member  of  clan  B,  the  latter  clan  was 
entitled  to  avenge  itself  against  any  member  of  clan  A.  In  turn,  clan  A 
would  then  avenge  itself  in  the  same  manner  upon  clan  B.  As  a  conse- 
quence of  one  initial  crime,  whole  groups  might  be  wiped  out.  The  blood 
feud  was,  to  say  the  least,  a  wasteful  process.  It  was  an  epoch-making 
step  when  the  practice  of  blood  feud  came  to  be  averted  by  composition — 
that  is,  the  payment  of  a  definite  fine  in  compensation  for  the  injury 
suffered.  This  fine  was  called,  among  the  primitive  Germans,  wergeld. 
Many  primitive  societies  had  a  fully  worked-out  schedule,  imposing  a 
definite  wergeld  for  any  and  all  possible  injuries  done  to  every  class  in 
society  from  nobles  to  slaves.  It  was  also  applied  to  injuries  within  the 
group. 

With  the  development  of  writing  and  the  rise  of  political  society,  inevi- 
table and  sweeping  changes  followed  in  the  nature  of  the  law.  Public 
justice  gradually  supplanted  private  justice,  and  codes  of  oral  custom 
were  transformed  into  imposing  bodies  of  written  law. 

Let  us  not  be  too  contemptuous  of  primitive  law.  A  large  element  of 
chance  exists  in  our  present  administration  of  justice.  In  fact,  we  have 
largely  lost  a  praiseworthy  element  of  primitive  law,  namely,  restitution 


358  LAW  AS  A  SOCIAL   PROBLEM 

to  the  party  injured  by  a  crime.  In  modern  society  this  can  be  secured 
only  by  the  institution  of  a  civil  suit  against  the  criminal — a  rather  rare 
procedure,  though  it  is  becoming  increasingly  prevalent. 

The  Code  of  Hammurabi.  The  next  important  stage  in  the  evolution 
of  law  is  found  in  the  legal  ideals  and  practices  in  the  ancient  Near  Orient. 
Here  the  great  monument  to  legal  history  is  the  Code  of  Hammurabi,  the 
leading  king  of  early  Babylonia.5  His  code  was  found  at  Susa  in  1901  by 
the  French  scholar  Jacques  de  Morgan.  Hammurabi  and  his  scribes  were 
not  its  authors.  Their  work  was  that  of  compilers.  This  oldest  pre- 
served code  of  ancient  law  was  basically  a  compilation  of  Sumerian  (and 
perhaps  Semitic)  laws  of  previous  ages.  Many  old  strains  are  recog- 
nizable in  the  code,  some  of  them  dating  back  thousands  of  years  before 
Hammurabi's  compilation  (2000  B.C.). 

The  laws  are  grouped  systematically,  and  we  find  a  differentiation 
between  laws  dealing  with  things — such  as  those  concerning  real  estate, 
personal  property,  trade  and  business  relations — and  those  dealing  with 
persons.  Though  the  code  is  in  many  respects  a  harsh  one  and  reflects 
some  primitive  elements,  there  is  in  it  a  radical  departure  from  clan  and 
tribal  law.  For  example,  blood  feud  and  marriage  by  capture  were  no 
longer  recognized  in  the  code.  Punishment  was  withdrawn  from  the 
hands  of  the  injured  party  or  his  kin  and  placed  in  the  control  of  the  king 
and  the  judges.  The  king's  law  supplanted  clan  law.  As  yet,  however, 
no  regular  notaries  or  public  prosecutors  existed.  In  general,  it  may  be 
said  that  the  code  did  not  admit  the  oath  and  the  ordeal  unless  witnesses 
and  documentary  evidence  were  lacking. 

The  "eye  for  an  eye"  principle  was  applied  to  injuries  and  torts,  and 
also  to  the  mistakes  of  a  laborer  or  of  a  professional  man,  such  as  a 
physician.  Death  was  a  common  punishment;  offenders  were  also  pun- 
ished by  burning,  impaling,  and  the  amputation  of  limbs.  A  distinction 
was  often  made  between  premeditated,  accidental,  and  unintentional  in- 
juries, and  the  penalties  varied  accordingly.  There  seems  to  have  existed 
a  tolerably  competent  court  system,  and  the  procedure  in  the  courts,  it 
appears,  was  not  entirely  different  from  that  of  today.  The  whole  code 
gives  testimony  to  the  intimate  tie  between  religion  and  the  law.  The 
laws  were  assumed  to  be  of  divine  derivation;  the  temples  were  also  the 
law  courts;  and,  although  they  were  appointed  by  the  king,  the  priests 
were  the  judges. 

Despite  the  claim  that  its  purpose  was  to  prevent  the  strong  from 
oppressing  the  weak,  the  code  of  Hammurabi  was  unmistakably  partial 
to  the  strong  and  the  rich — to  the  "vested  interests"  of  the  day.  How- 
ever, it  did  offer  to  the  poor  and  the  weak  some  measure  of  protection — 
an  advance  over  the  total  lack  of  redress  common  in  many  other  areas. 

Roman  Law.  The  greatest  legal  product  of  the  ancient  world  was  the 
famous  system  of  Roman  Law.6  A  Frenchman  has  said  that  "Rome's 


5  Zane,  op.  cit.,  Chap.  IV. 

0  Joseph   Declareuil,   Rome    the   Law-giver,   Knopf,    1926;    and   Zane,    op. 
Chap.  IX. 


LAW  AS  A  SOCIAL   PROBLEM  359 

mission  was  war  and  her  vocation  law."  It  was  in  the  field  of  legal  theory 
and  practice  that  Rome  made  some  of  its  most  enduring  contributions  to 
the  civilization  of  western  Europe.  Rome  succeeded  in  creating  both  a 
science  and  an  art  of  law  in  the  course  of  the  thousand  years  of  its  legal 
development.  The  body  of  Roman  legal  theory  and  practice  has  been  the 
basis  for  the  regulations  by  which  a  considerable  part  of  the  human  race 
has  governed  itself.  It  was  the  basis  of  the  law  in  all  Romanic  lands 
throughout  the  Middle  Ages.  It  influenced  canon  law — the  law  of  the 
Roman  Catholic  Church.  It  was  of  extreme  importance  towards  the  close 
of  the  Middle  Ages  throughout  western  Europe.  Its  influence  is  seen  in 
the  legal  codes  of  modern  European  countries  since  the  close  of  the 
eighteenth  century,  and  in  English  law,  especially  the  law  merchant. 

Broadly  speaking,  there  were  no  a  priori  principles  upon  which  the  whole 
body  of  Roman  law  was  erected.  Roman  law,  having  slowly  developed 
from  practical  needs  and  considerations,  was  distinctly  not  a  product  of 
theoretical  legalistic  conceptions.  Roman  private  law  rescued  the  indi- 
vidual from  the  associations  of  one  kind  or  another  in  which  he  had  been 
obscured,  and  recognized  him  as  a  distinct  entity.  Secular  law  became 
the  form  of  social  control  par  excellence  in  Rome,  and  the  Roman  jurists 
insisted  upon  the  subordination  of  all  citizens  and  their  activities  to  the 
reign  of  law.  The  Roman  lawyers  later  derived  from  imperialistic  experi- 
ences and  international  contacts  the  theory  of  the  universality  of  funda- 
mental legal  principles,  which  they  believed  to  be  common  to  all  rational 
men. 

A  most  important  source  of  Roman  law  was  primitive  custom.  Since 
the  earliest  regulation  of  custom  was  intrusted  to  the  priests,  for  many 
generations  law  was  not  distinguished  from  religion.  It  was  at  first 
entirely  a  matter  of  ritual.  The  religious  law — jus  divinum — was  for 
some  centuries  about  the  only  law  the  Romans  knew.  The  chief  aim  was 
to  keep  the  peace  with  their  gods,  and  a  violation  of  taboos  was  the  chief 
crime.  The  law  was  in  the  hands  of  the  priests  and  this  gave  the  priestly 
class  great  power.  The  impact  of  the  Etruscans  seems  to  have  been  the 
vital  influence  in  breaking  down  this  priestly  monopoly,  secularizing 
Roman  law,  and  opening  the  way  for  its  evolution. 

Religious  custom,  however,  is  only  one  of  the  sources  from  which  the 
body  of  Roman  law  grew.  The  jurists  themselves  recognized  that  stat- 
utes, plebiscites,  decisions  of  the  Senate,  decisions  and  edicts  of  magis- 
trates, imperial  decrees,  and  the  interpretations  of  jurists  entered  into  its 
composition.  The  sources  that  gave  Roman  law  its  most  original  charac- 
teristics, and  explain  at  the  same  time  its  fertility  and  flexibility,  were  the 
edicts  of  the  magistrates  and  the  interpretations  of  the  lawyers.  These 
influences  did  not  always  operate  at  the  same  time,  nor  did  they  all  persist 
throughout  the  thousand  years  of  Roman  legal  development.  They  made 
themselves  felt  at  different  times  and  in  varying  degrees. 

The  Laws  of  the  Twelve  Tables  were  the  first  step  in  the  development 
of  written  law.  The  civil  law — jus  civile — which  first  appeared  in  the 
Twelve  Tables  was  suited  to  a  relatively  simple  society  not  far  ad- 
vanced economically.  It  contained  many  primitive  religious  elements; 


360  LAW  AS  A  SOCIAL  PROBLEM 

nevertheless,  it  remained  the  written  private  law  which  regulated  the  life 
of  the  Romans  until  the  last  quarter  of  the  second  century  B.C.  This 
was  made  possible  by  the  fact  that  the  provisions  of  the  Laws  of  the 
Twelve  Tables  were  not  at  all  rigid,  but  were  constantly  being  modified 
and  expanded  by  the  interpretations  of  trained  jurists  who  adapted  them 
to  new  conditions.  Before  a  lawsuit  was  tried,  both  parties  to  the  case 
consulted  students  of  the  law,  who  rendered  advice  to  the  litigants  which 
was  supposed  to  be  wholly  impartial  in  nature.  Some  of  these  men  kept 
records  of  the  cases,  and  thus  there  developed  a  body  of  legal  litera- 
ture. Having  received  advice,  the  parties  to  the  suit  appeared  before  the 
praetor.  This  magistrate  did  one  of  two  things:  he  settled  the  case  then 
and  there  by  handing  down  his  final  interpretation  of  the  law  involved, 
or  he  passed  the  casaon  with  instructions  to  a  trial  judge  (judex) ,  usually 
a  Senator,  who  then  determined  its  outcome.  In  a  broad  way,  it  may  be 
said  that  the  praetor  ruled  on  matters  of  law  and  the  judge  on  the  facts 
in  the  case. 

As  Rome  expanded  by  conquest  and  became  a  cosmopolitan  city, 
necessity  demanded  the  creation  of  a  new  magistracy.  The  office  of 
praetor  peregrinus  was  instituted  (242  B.C.)  to  take  care  of  cases  in 
which  a  foreigner  was  a  participant.  The  praetor  peregrinus,  unlike  the 
older  praetor  urbanus,  was  free  from  the  restraints  of  the  Laws  of  the 
Twelve  Tables,  and  he  was  able  to  introduce  new  principles  in  the  settle- 
ment of  lawsuits.  In  time,  it  became  customary  for  the  praetor  to  issue 
an  edict  when  he  assumed  office.  In  this  he  enunciated  the  working  rules 
which  were  to  guide  him  in  settling  disputes.  These  edicts  were  some- 
times modified  by  the  succeeding  praetor  and  sometimes  reissued  without 
change.  They  made  up,  in  time,  a  considerable  body  of  legal  theory  and 
practice.  The  governors  in  the  provinces  reproduced  the  legal  functions 
and  procedure  of  the  praetor  peregrinus  in  Rome. 

In  the  new  legal  procedure  that  developed  and  was  applied  in  cases 
involving  foreigners,  the  magistrates  were  not  averse  to  adopting  legal 
practices  of  non-Roman  origin,  especially  when  the  latter  were  better 
suited  to  problems  arising  from  more  advanced  economic  conditions  than 
were  the  provisions  of  the  Twelve  Tables.  In  many  ways,  the  legal 
practice  covering  cases  that  involved  foreigners  was,  thus,  far  in  advance 
of  that  which  obtained  in  disputes  between  Roman  citizens.  Toward  the 
close  of  the  second  century  B.C.,  the  mode  of  procedure  of  the  peregrin 
praetors  was  transferred  to  the  urban  praetors — an  existing  remedy  was 
adopted  to  meet  changing  conditions — and  many  dogmas  and  methods  of 
the  Twelve  Tables  were  thus  given  their  deathblow.  As  a  result  of  this 
praetorian  legal  theory  and  practice  and  of  contacts  with  the  many  cul- 
tures of  the  Empire,  there  developed  what  is  known  as  the  jus  gentium — 
the  composite  law  of  the  nations  in  the  Empire — which  was  distinguished 
from  the  jus  civile,  the  law  of  Rome  and  its  citizens.  In  time,  the  more 
advanced  jus  gentium  was  even  accepted  by  citizens  in  their  dealings 
among  themselves  and  became  an  integral  part  of  the  whole  body  of 
Roman  law.  From  it  there  developed  the  notion  of  the  jus  naturale,  those 


LAW  AS  A  SOCIAL  PROBLEM  361 

basic  legal  principles  believed  to  be  common  to  all  mankind.  In  this 
process  of  assimilating  foreign  laws  to  Roman  usage,  the  contribution  of 
Greece  was,  as  VinogradorT  has  suggested,  very  important. 

A  most  important  role  in  the  development  of  Roman  law  was  played  by 
the  jurists  with  their  close  reasoning  and  their  examination  and  interpre- 
tation of  legal  problems.  The  most  outstanding  early  jurist  was  Sextus 
Aelius  Paetus,  who  was  consul  in  197  B.C.  The  really  great  names  in 
Roman  law,  however,  date  from  a  later  time.  Papinian,  Paulus,  Gaius, 
Ulpian,  and  Modestinus  all  lived  under  the  Empire.  The  later  jurists 
incorporated  into  their  legal  thought  the  Stoic  conception  of  a  natural  law 
governing  all  mankind.  The  particular  function  of  the  jurists,  as  well  as 
the  fundamental  achievement  of  Rome  in  the  field  of  law,  is  set  forth  in 
the  following  sentences: 

No  people  have  drawn  a  clearer  distinction  than  the  Romans  between  the  abso- 
lute and  the  relative,  or  better  understood  that  every  legal  solution  belongs  to 
the  sphere  of  contingency.  Their  endeavour  was  to  make  apparent  in  each  par- 
ticular case  what  appeared  to  them  to  be  Law,  and  then,  better  still,  what  with 
greater  moral  refinement  they  called  Equity.7 

Just  as  the  transition  from  city-state  to  Empire  is  reflected  in  the 
development  of  Roman  law,  so  the  appearance  of  an  absolute  Emperor 
resulted  in  the  tendency  towards  codification.  Two  compilations  of 
imperial  legislation  were  undertaken  at  the  close  of  the  third  century  A.D. 
Then,  in  439  A.D.,  the  first  portion  of  the  code  of  Theodosius  II  showed 
the  influence  of  Christianity.  The  most  important  and  complete  codifi- 
cation of  both  ancient  and  imperial  law  was  the  product  of  extensive 
labors  initiated  by  the  Byzantine  emperor  Justinian.  This  enterprise 
resulted  in:  (1)  the  Code,  in  529  (a  revised  edition  appeared  five  years 
later) ,  in  which  the  earlier  codes  were  recast  and  brought  together;  (2)  the 
Digest,  in  533,  consisting  of  cogent  excerpts  from  the  same  year.  The 
name  Novels  is  given  to  the  laws  of  Justinian  which  were  promulgated 
after  the  Code  was  completed.  The  codification  by  Justinian,  while  it 
put  an  end  to  the  further  development  of  Roman  law,  at  the  same  time 
served  as  one  of  the  most  important  agencies  in  its  preservation  for 
subsequent  ages. 

Roman  law,  as  we  have  noted,  was  the  basis  for  the  canon  law  of  the 
Roman  Catholic  Church.  At  the  height  of  the  Middle  Ages,  Roman  law 
was  revived  and  exploited  by  the  secular  monarchs  in  their  struggle 
against  the  Church.  Roman  law  laid  great  stress  upon  the  supremacy  of 
the  royal  and  imperial  authority  over  all  contending  groups  and  classes. 
Hence,  it  buttressed  the  claim  of  the  monarchs  to  dominion  over  the 
Church  when  the  two  came  into  conflict.  Roman  lawyers  flocked  to  the 
courts  and  were  patronized  by  the  monarchs  whom  they  served.  Law 
schools,  of  which  the  most  famous  was  the  one  at  Bologna,  developed  to 
give  adequate  training  in  Roman  and  canon  law.  Even  the  Christian 


7  Declareuil,  op.  cit.,  p.  25. 


362  LAW  AS  A  SOCIAL  PROBLEM 

Church  was  rent  by  a  great  dispute  (the  Conciliar  Movement)  which 
turned  about  the  application  of  Roman  law  to  the  principles  and  problems 
of  ecclesiastical  administration.  Finally,  Roman  law  became  a  powerful 
bulwark  of  secular  absolutism  when  the  latter  came  into  being  along  with 
the  rise  of  the  national  state  in  early  modern  times. 

Early  Medieval  Law  Among  the  Franks.  Early  medieval  civilization 
represented  a  reversion  from  classical  civilization  to  more  primitive  types 
of  culture.  This  was  reflected  in  law.  The  best  example  of  early  medi- 
eval law  is  afforded  by  the  laws  of  the  Franks  in  the  Age  of  Merovingians.8 

A  striking  feature  of  Frankish  law  was  the  multiplicity  of  laws  actually 
in  force.  The  Gallo-Romans  retained  the  Roman  law;  the  various  con- 
quered Germanic  peoples  kept  the  laws  of  their  own  groups;  and  the 
Franks  had  both  the  Salic  and  the  Ripuarian  law.  In  a  conflict  between 
a  Frank  and  a  person  of  some  other  group,  the  legal  systems  of  both 
received  consideration.  This  respect  of  the  Franks  for  the  laws  and 
customs  of  those  they  had  conquered  resulted  in  a  situation  where  no 
system  of  law  had  precedence  over  any  other,  and  where  the  party  to  a 
case  usually  defended  himself  by  the  law  of  his  birth.  Thus  law  was 
essentially  personal  in  its  application,  and  not  territorial.  Foreigners  and 
Jews  had  to  purchase  protection  from  the  king. 

The  laws,  as  a  rule,  enumerated  and  described  the  offenses  against 
persons,  the  family,  and  the  tribe;  listed  the  punishments  for  such  crimes; 
provided  for  judicial  procedure;  and  covered  a  great  many  other  questions 
nonpolitical  in  nature.  The  Franks,  like  the  other  German  peoples, 
regarded  most  crimes  not  as  public  but  as  personal  offenses,  and  the 
punishment  was  in  the  hands  of  the  kin  group.  Even  after  kinship  rela- 
tions were  abolished  by  law  at  the  close  of  the  sixth  century,  the  blood 
feud  persisted  for  a  time. 

The  sections  of  the  Salic  law  dealing  with  wergeld  reveal  both  the  new 
social  relations  that  had  come  about  since  the  time  of  Clovis  and  the 
frequency  of  violence  in  Merovingian  society.  For  all  injuries  there 
existed  a  carefully  worked-out  scale  of  "prices." 

If  any  one  have  wished  to  kill  another  person,  and  the  blow  have  missed,  he  on 
whom  it  was  proved  shall  be  sentenced  to  2500  denars,  which  make  63  shill- 
ings. ...  If  any  person  have  wished  to  strike  another  with  a  poisoned  arrow, 
and  the  arrow  have  glanced  aside,  and  it  shall  be  proved  on  him:  he  shall  be 
sentenced  to  2500  denars,  which  make  63  shillings.  ...  If  any  person  strike 
another  on  the  head  so  that  the  brAin  appears,  and  the  three  bones  which  lie 
above  the  brain  shall  project,  he  shall  be  sentenced  to  1200  denars,  which  make 
30  shillings. 

Evidently,  it  was  cheaper  actually  to  assault  someone  than  to  pre- 
meditate murder.  The  distinction  between  Roman  and  Frank  appears 
in  the  table  of  wergeld.  It  cost  a  Roman  63  shillings  to  plunder  a  Frank: 
"but  if  a  Frank  have  plundered  a  Roman,  he  shall  be  sentenced  to  35  shil- 


8  See  Munroe  Smith,  The  Development  of  European  Law,  Columbia  University 
Press,  1928,  pp.  115ff. 


LAW  IN  ACTION  395 

Formal  propriety  and  technical  exactness  in  legal  jargon  are  frequently 
viewed  as  far  more  important  than  the  actual  facts  of  guilt  or  innocence. 
This  is  best  illustrated  by  the  tendency  to  throw  out  of  court  cases  which 
may  clearly  demonstrate  guilt  but  which,  at  the  same  time,  involve  some 
trivial  error  in  statement  or  procedure.  Mark  0.  Prentiss  once  brought 
together  an  interesting  anthology  of  cases  illustrating  what  has  been 
called  "pinhead  jurisprudence": 

A  defendant  was  convicted  under  an  indictment  charging  the  theft  of  $100, 
"lawful  money."  The  conviction  was  set  aside  because  the  indictment  did  not 
say  "lawful  money  of  the  United  States."  The  court  gave  as  the  reason  for 
granting  the  defendant  a  new  trial  that  the  victim  might  have  been  carrying 
around  Mexican  money. 

A  defendant  was  convicted  of  stealing  a  pistol  under  an  indictment  which 
described  the  pistol  as  a  "Smith  &  Weston"  revolver.  A  new  trial  was  granted 
because  the  proof  showed  that  the  defendant  stole  a  "Smith  &  Wesson"  revolver. 

In  Chicago,  a  notorious  criminal  known  as  "Eddie  the  Immune"  was  convicted 
of  stealing  $59.  There  was  never  the  shadow  of  a  doubt  as  to  his  guilt.  The 
verdict  was  set  aside  on  appeal  because  the  jury  did  not  find  [i.e.  state]  the 
exact  amount  stolen. 

In  Georgia  a  defendant  was  convicted  under  an  indictment  which  charged  that 
he  stole  a  hog  that  had  a  slit  out  of  its  right  ear  and  a  clip  out  of  the  left.  The 
appellate  court  granted  the  defendant  a  new  trial  because,  while  it  was  proved 
that  the  defendant  stole  the  hog,  the  evidence  disclosed  that  it  was  a  hog  with 
a  slit  out  of  its  left  ear  and  a  clip  out  of  its  right  ear. 

In  another  case  where  a  defendant  was  convicted  of  a  serious  crime  the  con- 
viction was  set  aside  by  the  higher  court  because  the  word  "the"  was  left  out  of 
the  concluding  phrase  of  the  indictment,  "against  the  peace  and  dignity  of  the 
State." 

In  another  case  a  defendant  was  convicted  of  stealing  a  pair  of  boots.  The 
judgment  of  the  trial  court  was  set  aside  by  the  higher  court,  because  it  appeared 
that  while  the  defendant  had  stolen  two  boots,  he  had  stolen  two  rights. 

In  yet  another  case  a  conviction  for  larceny  was  set  aside  because  the  indict- 
ment averred  that  it  occurred  in  a  "storehouse"  when  it  should  have  used  the 
word  "storeroom." 

In  a  Montana  case  a  verdict  of  guilty  of  larceny  was  set  aside  on  appeal  because 
the  trial  judge  instructed  the  jury  that  it  must  find  intent  to  steal  instead  of  a 
criminal  intent. 

Under  another  absurd  ruling  a  conviction  for  stealing  was  set  aside  because 
there  was  no  proof  that  800  pounds  of  cotton  was  a  thing  of  value. 

In  yet  another  case  involving  some  offense  along  a  public  road  the  conviction 
was  set  aside  because,  while  the  proof  showed  that  the  road  had  been  used  for 
thirty  years  as  a  public  road,  it  did  not  show  that  the  road  had  ever  been 
formally  dedicated  to  the  public. 

There  is  an  Alabama  case  which  held  that  the  omission  of  the  letter  "i"  from 
the  word  "malice"  in  an  indictment  for  assault  with  intent  to  murder  rendered 
the  indictment  bad,  and  the  conviction  of  a  defendant  under  that  indictment 
was  set  aside. 

In  another  Alabama  case  it  was  held  that  an  indictment  charging  that  murder 
had  been  committed  "with  malice  aforethou"  did  not  allege  "malice  aforethought," 


396  LAW  IN  ACTION 

and  that  the  indictment  was  legally  insufficient.  The  court  noted  in  that  case: 
"Great  precision  should  be  observed  in  matters  which  vitally  affect  the  life  and 
liberty  of  the  citizen."  In  England  the  judge  would  simply  have  corrected  the 
indictment  with  his  pen  and  gone  on  with  the  case. 

In  another  Alabama  case  a  defendant  was  charged  in  the  indictment  with 
stealing  a  cow.  The  evidence  proved  him  guilty  of  stealing  a  bull.  In  cither 
event  the  defendant  was  guilty  of  grand  larceny.  The  higher  court,  however, 
set  aside  the  judgment  of  conviction. 

In  another  case  the  defendant  was  charged  with  stealing  eleven  cow  hides.  The 
higher  court  said:  "There  was  a  total  absence  of  evidence  that  the  hides  stolen 
were  cow  hides.  Non  constat,  they  were  horse  hides,  or  hides  of  some  other 
animal  than  that  of  the  cow  kind."  The  sentence  of  the  lower  court  in  that 
case  was  set  aside,  although  the  evidence  showed  that  the  defendant  in  that  case 
was  guilty  of  grand  larceny.6 

Probably  the  most  spectacular  example  of  the  distortion  of  justice  by 
adherence  to  pinhead  technicalities  was  the  granting  of  a  mistrial  by 
Judge  Ferdinand  Pecora  in  the  trial  of  the  political  boss,  James  J.  Hines, 
in  New  York  City.  After  over  a  month  of  an  expensive  and  elaborate 
trial  a  mistrial  was  granted  over  what  Mr.  Jackson  rightly  describes  as 
"the  merest  technicality."  The  prosecutor,  Mr.  Dewey,  had  merely  asked 
a  witness  whether  Hines  had  been  mentioned  before  a  former  grand  jury 
as  having  some  connections  with  the  poultry  racket.  This  action  of 
Judge  Pecora  aroused  bitter  newspaper  criticism  and  is  not  likely  to.be 
repeated  for  some  time.7 

The  same  excessive  regard  for  technical  correctness  controls  the  matter 
of  appeal.  Gross  injustice  may  be  clearly  evident  from  any  thorough 
study  of  the  case.  But,  if  the  procedure  is  entirely  correct  from  the 
standpoint  of  legal  etiquette,  the  defendant  will  be  regarded  as  having 
had  an  entirely  fair  trial,  and  the  demand  for  a  new  trial  will  be  uncere- 
moniously denied.  In  some  states,  the  judge  who  tried  the  case  will 
be  permitted  to  decide  upon  the  matter  of  appeal.  This  was  the  case 
when  the  notoriously  biased  Judge  Webster  Thayer  passed  upon  the 
petitions  for  appeal  from  the  conviction  of  Sacco  and  Vanzetti.  The 
success  of  the  magician  among  primitive  peoples  depended  very  largely 
upon  the  exactness  of  his  technique  in  following  the  prescribed  magic 
formulas.  The  contemporary  judge  and  lawyer  run  him  a  close  second. 
No  other  profession,  not  even  that  of  the  Fundamentalist  theologian,  has 
such  regard  for  jargon,  phraseology,  and  procedural  niceties.8 

To  make  matters  worse,  a  considerable  portion  of  the  testimony  actu- 
ally admitted  in  cases  is  perjured.  An  exposition  of  the  appalling  preva- 
lence of  perjury  in  the  courts  of  the  United  States  was  set  forth  by 
Dorothy  Dunbar  Bromley  in  an  article  "Perjury  Rampant." 9  The  situ- 
ation which  she  describes  is  almost  incredible  to  the  layman.  John  M.  F. 


6  The  New   York   Times  Current  History  Magazine,  October,   1925.    For  more 
material  on  technicalities  in  court  procedure,  see  Jackson,  op.  cit.,  pp.  126  ff.,  147  ff. 

7  Cf.  Jackson,  op.  cit.,  pp.  17  ff. 
*  Cf.  Ibid.,  Chap.  IV. 

»  Harper's,  June,  1931. 


LAW  IN  ACTION  397 

Gibbons,  one  of  the  most  eminent  lawyers  of  our  generation,  states  that 
in  over  twenty  years'  experience  in  the  courts  of  the  United  States  he  was 
aware  of  only  two  cases  in  which  perjury  had  not  figured.  And  he  stated 
that  "in  reaching  this  shocking  conclusion,  I  have  been  most  careful  to 
distinguish  between  malignant  false  swearing  and  benign  inaccuracy." 
A  Supreme  Court  Justice  of  the  State  of  New  York  told  Mrs.  Bromley 
that  the  courts  of  the  State  took  perjury  for  granted,  and  said  that  "we 
have  reached  the  point  where  we  are  merely  trying  to  find  out  which  side 
is  lying  the  least."  Perjured  evidence  is  particularly  common  in  connec- 
tion with  the  so-called  negligence  cases.  These  are  the  accident  and 
similar  cases  which  lawyers  take  on  a  contingent  basis,  namely,  the  agree- 
ment that  they  will  collect  a  fee  only  if  they  succeed  in  getting  damages 
awarded  to  the  plaintiff.  During  Prohibition,  one  of  our  most  distin- 
guished attorneys,  I.  Maurice  Wormser,  remarked  that  "a  negligence  law- 
suit without  perjury  is  almost  as  rare  today  as  a  glass  of  good  Pilsner."  10 
One  reason  why  perjury  is  so  frequent,  that,  in  the  words  of  Samuel 
Untermeyer,  "it  has  become  so  general  as  to  taint  and  well-nigh  paralyze 
the  administration  of  justice,"  is  that  it  is  rarely  prosecuted.  As  former 
United  States  attorney,  Charles  H.  Tuttle,  observed,  "the  practice  of  per- 
jury has  come  to  be  surrounded  with  a  practical  immunity."  In  1923, 
there  were  109,000  persons  confined  in  state  and  federal  prisons,  but  only 
171  were  there  for  perjury.  From  the  statements  of  distinguished 
lawyers,  it  would  seem  reasonable  that  there  must  have  been  at  least  one 
instance  of  perjured  testimony  for  each  person  convicted  and  imprisoned. 
Indeed,  in  the  average  important  case  there  may  be  a  dozen  or  more 
examples  of  perjured  testimony.  In  New  York  City,  where  it  is  very  rare 
for  a  case  to  be  tried  without  perjured  evidence,  there  were  in  the  three 
years,  1925,  1926,  1927,  only  103  arrests  for  perjury  and  15  convictions. 
In  Chicago,  where  perjury  is  presumably  more  common  than  in  New 
York,  only  three  persons  were  sentenced  for  perjury  in  the  five  years  1926 
to  1930,  inclusive.  An  interesting  perjury  case  on  record  is  that  of  Edith 
St.  Glair.  We  shall  let  Mrs.  Bromley  tell  the  story: 

The  difficulty  of  getting  a  conviction  for  perjury  on  the  basis  of  a  witness's  con- 
tradictory sworn  statements  may  be  illustrated  by  the  following  story.  Miss 
Edith  St.  Clair,  an  actress,  a  number  of  years  ago  sued  Mr.  Abraham  Erlanger, 
the  former  theatrical  producer,  for  having  failed  to  fulfill  the  terms  of  a  contract 
under  which  he  had  agreed  to  pay  her,  "for  services  unspecified^"  twenty-five 
thousand  dollars  in  ten  yearly  installments.  She  was  able  to  convince  the  judge 
and  jury  of  the  authenticity  of  her  claim  and  accordingly  won  a  judgment  in  the 
Supreme  Court  of  New  York,  which  ordered  Mr.  Erlanger  to  make  the  yearly 
payments.  Subsequently,  however,  she  appeared  at  the  office  of  Mr.  Erlanger's 
attorney  and  for  some  unknown  reason  confessed  that  she  had  lied  about  the 
contract,  and  that  her  attorney,  Mr.  Max  D.  Steuer,  a  New  York  lawyer  whose 
name  is  now  much  in  the  public  print,  had  put  her  up  to  the  story.  Her  state- 
ment was  reduced  to  an  affidavit,  and  the  judgment  which  she  had  obtained  was 
accordingly  set  aside.  As  a  result  of  Miss  St.  Clair's  revelations,  disbarment 

10  For  a  comprehensive  survey  of  the  prevalence  of  perjury  among  witnesses,  see 
Jackson,  op.  cit.,  Chap.  XI. 


398  LAW  IN  ACTION 

proceedings  were  instituted  against  Mr.  Steuer  by  the  Appellate  Division  of  the 
New  York  Supreme  Court  at  the  instance  of  the  New  York  City  Bar  Association. 
But  when  she  was  called  as  a  witness  she  once  again  recanted  and  said  that  she 
had  told  the  truth  the  first  time  and  that  Mr.  Stcuer  had  not  been  responsible 
for  her  claim  against  Mr.  Erlanger.  The  charge  against  Mr.  Steuer  was  accord- 
ingly dismissed,  and  the  State's  next  move  was  to  try  Miss  St.  Clair  for  perjury. 
But  the  prosecution  suffered  from  the  disadvantage  of  not  being  able  to  prove 
at  which  time  she  had  sworn  falsely,  and  so  the  jury  failed  to  convict.  Here  was 
a  case  where  the  courts  were  shamelessly  exploited  arid  yet  no  one  was  punished.11 

Mr.  Jackson  confirms  in  detail  this  picture  of  the  prevalence  of  perjury: 

Deep  down  in  his  heart  the  average  witness  believes  that  his  job  is  to  out- 
trick  tnc  other  side  and  that  he  is  put  on  the  witness  stand  not  to  tell  the  truth, 
but  to  help  win  the  case,  lie  undertakes  to  do  so  even  if  he  has  to  lie  in  the 
process.  ... 

Under  our  present  system,  perjury  is  viewed  as  an  ineradicable  evil — and  it 
probably  is.  Like  Jupiter  who  laughs  at  lover's  lies,  we  applaud  the  success  of 
legal  liars.  Perjury  has  come  to  be  accepted  as  one  of  the  counters  inevitably 
found  in  the  legal  game  of  the  courtroom.  Tt  took  over  twenty  years  to  free 
Mooney,  although  the  pur  jury  that  convicted  him  was  proven  beyond  doubt. 

There  is  little  protection  against  perjury.  We  are  all  too  tolerant  of  it.  We 
not  only  view  it  as  an  ineradicable  evil  but  we  come  to  expect  it.  In  criminal 
and  divorce  cases,  everybody  expects  lying.  A  man  who  is  fighting  for  his  life 
or  his  liberty  is  not  expected  to  sacrifice  either  one  for  an  undue  sense  of  honor 
respecting  a  mere  oath.  A  defendant  in  a  divorce  suit  is  never  expected  to  confers 
fault;  a  corespondent  is  considered  a  cad  if  he  fails  to  lie  like  a  gentleman  in 
defense  of  his  paramour's  honor.  In  such  case,  the  lesser  legal  crime  of  perjury 
yields  to  the  greater  demands  of  the  so-called  moral  code.12 

Not  only  witnesses  but  lawyers  in  court  cases  may  lie  shamelessly. 
The  clever  lawyer  will  rarely  take  the  stand  and  swear  to  his  lie,  and  thus 
render  himself  liable  to  prosecution  for  perjury.  Rather,  he  will  include 
the  false  statements  in  his  address  to  the  jury  and  thus  escape  any  legal 
liability  for  his  lying.13 

Whereas  perjury  is  usually  overlooked  in  normal  court  practice,  it  is 
eagerly  seized  upon  to  persecute  representatives  of  unpopular  causes. 
The  classic  case  was  the  conviction  of  Earl  Browder  of  technical  perjury 
in  the  course  of  an  application  for  a  passport.  Another  notorious  ex- 
ample was  the  conviction  of  Morris  Schappes,  a  former-Communist 
instructor  at  the  College  of  the  City  of  New  York,  in  the  spring  of  1941. 
The  prosecutor  did  not  produce  reasonable  proof  that  Schappes  com- 
mitted perjury.  It  was  sufficient  for  the  case  that  he  admitted  former 
membership  in  the  Communist  party.  Perjury  prosecution  and  con- 
viction were  also  imposed  on  George  Hill,  secretary  of  the  isolationist 
Congressman,  Hamilton  Fish,* 

The  office  of  judge  is  truly  a  noble  public  position  and  eminently  de- 
serving of  the  respect  of  citizens.  The  term  "judicious"  has  come  to 


11  Bromley,  loc.  tit.,  pp.  41-42.    See  also  Harry  Hibschman,  "That  Perjury  Prob- 
lem," American  Journal  of  Criminal  Law  and  Criminology,  January,  February,  1934. 

12  Jackson,  op.  cit.,  pp.  316,  323. 

is  For  a  good  example  of  such  lying  by  an  attorney,  see  Ibid.,  p.  268. 


LAW   IN   ACTION  399 

connote  the  essence  of  wisdom,  combined  with  fairness.  We  frequently 
extol  the  "judicial  mind"  as  a  type  of  mentality  which  is  not  swayed 
by  favoritism,  partisanship,  or  a  desire  for  personal  gain.  It  is  the  sort 
of  mentality  which  weighs  the  facts  and  conies  to  decision  on  the  basis 
of  these  facts  without  fear  or  favor.  This  idealized  conception  of  the 
judge  and  the  judicial  mind  cannot  be  too  highly  regarded  or  accorded 
too  much  respect.  Unfortunately,  the  human  material  which  occupies 
judges'  shoes  all  too  frequently  does  not  measure  up  to  the  stature  of 
ability,  integrity,  and  wisdom  which  is  associated  in  the  popular  mind 
with  the  judicial  role.  Perhaps  the  two  eminent  judges  of  our  generation 
who  have  possessed  to  the  full  the  imaginary — or  legendary — "judicial 
mind"  have  been  Oliver  Wendell  Holmes  and  Benjamin  Cardozo.  It 
may  not  be  remiss  to  suggest  that  this  is  why  they  were  regarded  as  such 
unusual  judges. 

We  have  no  special  training  for  judges  and  no  particular  qualifications 
designed  to  bring  about  a  situation  where  the  incumbents  of  the  judicial 
office  will  qualify  for  the  responsibilities  imposed  upon  them.  The 
majority  of  judges  are  practicing  lawyers  before  they  are  elevated  to  the 
bench,  and,  more  often  than  not,  are  political  lawyers  who  have  played 
fast  and  loose  in  the  sordid  game  of  politics.  They  usually  owe  their 
nomination,  election,  or  appointment  to  the  bench  to  prominent  politi- 
cians. They  have  to  pay  their  political  debts.  Moreover,  judges  are 
human  beings,  with  their  personal  likes  and  dislikes  and  their  convictions 
and  prejudices  in  regard  to  political,  economic,  and  social  matters.  They 
are  no  more  able  to  divest  themselves  of  such  attitudes  than  is  a  minister, 
or  a  college  professor.  But  their  professional  indulgence  of  prejudices, 
and  of  likes  and  dislikes,  carries  with  it  more  disastrous  consequences  than 
is  the  case  with  any  other  profession.  A  minister  may  condemn  a  parish- 
ioner to  hell,  but  the  execution  of  the  penalty  is  not  certain  and,  in  any 
event,  is  a  long  way  off.  A  college  professor  may  flunk  an  over-sceptical 
student,  but  he  cannot  ruin  him.  Only  the  most  irresponsible  physician 
would  think  of  poisoning  his  patient.  But  a  judge  can  handle  a  law  case 
in  such  a  fashion  as  to  jail  an  innocent  person  for  many  years  or  send  him 
to  the  death  house.  The  case  of  Judge  Webster  Thayer  and  the  judicial 
assassination  of  Sacco  and  Vanzetti  immediately  come  to  mind  in  this 
connection.  Or,  the  judge  may  so  'conduct  a  trial  as  to  let  loose  upon 
society  a  vicious  and  guilty  criminal  if,  for  some  reason  or  another,  the 
judge  wishes  this  to  be  done.  The  life  and  liberty  of  almost  any  citizen 
in  the  community  may,  at  some  time  or  another,  hang  upon  the  economic 
prejudices,  the  personal  eccentricities,  or  the  current  state  of  the  digestive 
tract  of  some  judge.  For  this  reason  it  is  particularly  unfortunate  that 
the  theoretical  qualifications  of  our  judges  are  so  rarely  equaled  by  the 
actual  attainments  of  incumbents  of  this  high  and  noble  office. 

It  is  difficult  for  some  to  understand  how  a  judge  can  markedly  affect 
the  conduct  of  the  case.  True,  courtroom  procedure  is  pretty  rigorously 
prescribed  and,  in  many  cases,  the  law  which  applies  is  fairly  precise  and 
reasonably  well  known.  Admittedly,  the  judge  has  no  such  leeway  for 


400  LAW  IN  ACTION 

personal  eccentricity  and  doctrinal  interpretations  as  a  college  professor. 
But  he  constantly  has  to  interpret  the  law  and  its  application,  to  rule  on 
innumerable  objections  in  the  courtroom,  to  maintain  order,  and  to 
control  the  behavior  of  the  lawyers.  While  the  judge  may  be  overruled 
in  superior  courts  upon  appeal,  he  is,  for  the  time  being,  the  absolute 
monarch  of  the  courtroom.  No  one  save  an  army  or  an  armed  mob  can 
challenge  his  dominion.  His  rulings  are  frequently  unrestrained  by 
specific  legal  or  procedural  enactments.  He  can  readily  favor  one  side 
or  another,  though  some  care  has  to  be  exercised  in  this  matter,  lest  he  run 
into  the  danger  of  a  rebuke  from  the  courts  of  review. 

Lawyers  frankly  admit  the  difficulty  of  winning  a  case,  even  though 
the  evidence  is  wholly  favorable  to  their  side,  if  they  have  to  deal  with 
a  hostile  judge.  On  such  an  occasion,  their  only  chance  is  to  get  a  re- 
versal in  the  upper  courts.  This  is  sometimes  rendered  difficult  because 
the  court  record  may  give  the  impression  of  impartiality  and  legal  pro- 
priety. The  judge's  words  may  be  formally  correct,  but  the  tone  of  his 
voice,  his  inflections,  and  the  like,  may  most  effectively  convey  the  im- 
pressions he  desires  to  register  on  the  jury.  Only  a  phonographic  record- 
ing of  the  judge's  rulings  and  charges  and  a  moving-picture  film  of  the 
courtroom  during  the  trial  would  enable  a  reviewing  court  to  form  an 
accurate  impression  of  the  actual  conduct  of  a  judge  in  any  particular 
case.  Such  recordings  may  be  demanded  in  the  future,  but  they  have  not 
thus  far  figured  in  courtroom  procedure,  though  some  administrative 
agencies  in  Washington,  notably  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission, 
often  do  make  such  recordings. 

The  judge's  charge  to  the  jury  is  of  extreme  importance.  Only  an 
exceptionally  clever  attorney  can  offset  the  effect  upon  a  jury  which  is 
made  by  the  judge's  charge.  The  judge  gets  the  last  opportunity  to 
address  the  jury,  which  naturally  holds  him  in  greater  awe  than  it  does 
the  average  attorney.  Only  a  Clarence  Darrow  may  impress  a  jury  more 
than  a  judge.  It  is  so  rare  as  to  be  almost  revolutionary  for  a  jury 
to  ignore  entirely  the  tone  or  import  of  a  judge's  charge.  But  the  judge 
may  frequently  ignore  the  more  cogent  evidence  and  attempt  to  influence 
the1  jury  by  general  considerations  arising  out  of  his  particular  prejudices. 
The  judge's  offense  in  this  regard  must  be  particularly  obvious  in  order 
to  be  met  with  a  reversal  in  an  upper  court  on  the  ground  of  an  improper 
charge  to  the  jury. 

When  a  verdict  is  returned  contrary  to  the  wishes  of  the  judge,  it  is 
not  unknown  for  the  latter  to  telephone  the  attorney  who  has  won  the 
case  and  ask  him  to  let  the  judgment  drop.  This  cannot,  of  course,  be 
done  in  any  criminal  case.  But  it  can  readily  be  done  in  the  instance 
of  a  judgment  in  a  civil  case.  Two  cases  have  come  to  the  attention 
of  the  writer  within  a  brief  period  of  time  in  which  the  same  judge 
requested  lawyers  to  "forget"  a  judgment  just  rendered  by  the  jury. 
And  it  hardly  need  be  added  that  the  lawyers  took  the  hint  and  urged 
their  clients  to  let  the  judgment  drop.  This  the  clients  had  to  do  because 
they  could  find  no  other  lawyer  who  would  risk  the  wrath  of  the  trial 


LAW  IN  ACTION  401 

judge  by  picking  up  the  case.  This  form  of  tyranny  is  most  usual  in 
smaller  cities  where  only  one  or  two  judges  preside  throughout  the  court 
terms  of  the  year.  Attorneys  are  dependent,  literally,  for  their  bread  and 
butter  upon  keeping  on  good  terms  with  the  judge  before  whom  they  have 
to  appear  constantly. 

We  have  referred  above  only  to  instances  in  which  the  judges  have 
exercised  arbitrary  authority  in  interpreting  the  law,  stretching  the  law, 
or  conducting  court  procedure  in  such  a  fashion  as  to  favor  one  party 
in  the  legal  contest  before  them.  But  it  is  not  uncommon  for  judges  to 
ignore  inconvenient  laws,  to  usurp  undue  power,  and  to  interpret  laws  in 
such  a  fashion  as  to  destroy  the  intent  of  the  makers.  In  their  important 
book,  Lawless  Judges,  Louis  P.  Goldberg  and  Eleanore  Levenson  have 
summarized  some  of  the  more  common  deviations  of  judges  from  the 
high  ideal  set  for  judicial  procedure: 

1.  Judges,  in  the  decision  of  cases,  have  deliberately  applied  their  economic 
principles  and  prejudices,  rather  than  the  existing  laws. 

2.  Not  only  have  judges  failed  to  apply   the  constitutional  provisions   for 
the  protection  of  civil  rights  of  individuals  and  minority  groups  but  they  have 
construed  such  provisions  so  as  to  deprive  large  masses  of  workers  and  non- 
conforming  minorities  of  their  constitutional  privileges. 

3.  Judges  have  changed  existing  law  by  judicial  decision,  thereby  usurping  the 
legislative  function. 

4.  Judges  have  used  their  power  to  interpret  laws  so  as  to  emasculate  statutes 
and  prevent  the  intent  of  the  legislatures  from  being  applied. 

5.  Judges  have  declared  unconstitutional,  laws  intended  to  protect  the  people 
against  econoniic  exploitation. 

6.  The  judiciary  has  to  all  intents  and  purposes  established  itself  as  dictator 
over  the  American  people. 

From  previous  experience  it  is  clearly  inimical  to  the  best  interests  of  tho 
people  to  permit  judges  to  continue  to  exercise  the  powers  they  have  in  the  past 
assumed  to  possess.14 

The  chief  reason  why  the  abuse  of  judicial  powers  has  persisted  is  that 
no  practical  method  exists  whereby  judges  can  be  disciplined  or  controlled. 
Nothing  short  of  the  commission  of  a  gross  crime  can  get  a  judge  removed 
from  the  bench.  No  one  can  effectively  protest  against  judicial  tyranny 
and  impropriety  without  rendering  himself  liable  to  prosecution  on  the 
grounds  of  contempt  of  court.  Judges  enjoy  an  immunity  for  their 
actions  matched  only  by  oriental  potentates  or  major  league  baseball 
umpires.  But  one  can  criticize  the  latter  without  suffering  the  serious 
penalties  which  a  judge  can  impose.  As  Alice  Hamilton  puts  it:  "One 
may  revile  the  President  of  the  United  States  with  impunity,  one  may 
utter  blasphemies  against  the  Most  High  without  even  attracting  atten- 
tion, but  if  one  is  bold  enough  to  protest  against  an  abusive  tirade  by  an 
ill-bred  or  drunken  judge  one  may  have  to  expiate  it  in  prison." 15 

It  is  all  but  impossible  to  bring  charges  against  a  judge  for  incompe- 
tence or  arbitrary  disregard  of  the  law  and  elementary  principles  of 

i*  Rand  School  Press,  1935,  pp.  231-232. 
15  Harper's  Magazine,  October,  1931, 


402  LAW  IN  ACTION 

fairness.  Only  the  lawyers  who  practice  before  the  judge  are  likely  to 
be  familiar  with  his  deficiencies  and  offenses,  and  they  take  their  pro- 
fessional lives  in  their  hands  the  moment  they  incur  the  displeasure  of 
the  judge.  It  is  literally  impossible  to  get  practicing  lawyers  to  band 
together  and  prefer  charges  against  even  the  most  notoriously  incompetent 
or  arbitrary  judge.  The  reasons  for  this  have  been  well  set  forth  by  the 
eminent  jurist,  Dean  John  H.  Wigmore: 

The  public  docs  not  fully  understand  the  position  of  the  judge  in  respect  to  his 
immunity  from  exposure  by  I  he  bar.  His  iniquities  or  incompetence,  if  any,  are 
so  committed  as  to  become  directly  known  only  to  a  few  persons  in  any  given 
instance? ;  and  these  few  persons  are  the  attorneys  in  charge  of  the  case.  To  bear 
open  testimony  against  him  now  is  to  risk  professional  ruin  at  his  hands  in  the 
near  future.  Moreover,  this  ruin  can  be  perpetrated  by  him  without  fear  of  the 
detection  of  his  malice,  because  a  judge  s  decision  can  be  openly  placed  upon 
plausible  grounds,  while  secretly  based  on  the  resolve  to  disfavor  the  attorney  in 
the  case.  Hence  lawyers  dread,  most  of  all  things,  to  give  personal  offense  to 
a  judge.16 

In  the  light  of  the  mode  of  selecting  our  judges,  and  of  their  almost 
complete  immunity  from  the  consequences  of  any  conduct  short  of  the 
grossest  criminality  attended  by  conspicuous  publicity,  the  wonder  is  that 
we  do  not  suffer  more  than  we  do  from  judicial  tyranny  and  oppression. 
It  is  probably  no  exaggeration  to  say  that  the  conduct  of  the  typical 
Fascist  bureaucrat  and  Soviet  commissar  in  Europe  today  is  no  more 
arbitrary  or  thoroughly  removed  from  democratic  control  than  is  the 
behavior  of  the  average  American  judge. 

In  the  Municipal  Courts  of  large  cities  is  found,  perhaps,  the  lowest 
order  of  what  is  somewhat  humorously  termed  the  "administration  of 
justice"  in  this  country.  This  situation  is  due  in  part  to  the  overcrowding 
of  the  courts.  For  example,  in  1930,  there  were  no  less  than  645,451 
proceedings  in  the  Municipal  Court  of  New  York  City.  Not  even  a 
Charles  Evans  Hughes  could  administer  justice  in  adequate  fashion 
amidst  the  congestion  and  confusion  that  prevail.  When  we  find  on  the 
bench  of  these  courts  third-  and  fourth-rate  lawyers,  without  high  ethical 
standards,  and  often  with  the  most  sordid  political  affiliations,  it  is  not 
surprising  that  the  state  of  affairs  in  the  lower  courts  throughout 
the  country  is  a  blot  upon  American  civilization.  It  is  merely  a  lucky 
accident  if  a  case  is  decided  in  a  magistrate's  court  in  harmony  with  fact 
and  justice.  Mr.  Gisnet  thus  describes  the  character  of  our  magistrates' 
courts: 

The  conduct  of  some  of  the  magistrates  who  preside  in  the  police  courts  of  the 
big  cities  the  country  over,  and  particularly  in  those  of  New  York  City,  is  dis- 
graceful. Some  of  them  have  absolutely  no  regard  whatever  for  the  fundamental 
rights  of  the  average  poor  person  who  is  brought  before  them  sometimes  on  the 
flimsiest  charge.  Others  display  woeful  ignorance  and  vile  tempers  fit  for  bar- 
rooms and  sink  so  low  as  to  threaten  defendants  with  physical  violence  in  the 
name  of  real  Americanism.  While  still  others  are  so  much  in  love  with  publicity 
that  they  are  on  the  alert  for  opportunities  to  create  news-items  that  will  get 

16  Cited  in  Goldberg  and  Levenson,  op.  cit.,  pp.  230-231. 


LAW   IN   ACTION  403 

their  names  into  the  press,  like  imposing  on  a  defendant  the  stupid  penalty  of 
kissing  his  mother-in-law  in  open  court  as  a  condition  of  regaining  his  freedom, 
and  similar  stunts. 

The  experienced  observer  can't  help  noticing  very  quickly  that  the  game  of 
"fixing"  and  "wire  pulling"  is  played  in  these  courts  by  low  ward  politicians  and 
shyster  lawyers.  Persons  with  money  and  political  influence  escape  the  rigors 
of  the  law  while  the  poor  and  ihe  friendless  are  made  to  suffer  even  if  innocent.17 

Another  abuse  associated  with  the  magistrates'  courts  is  the  frequency 
with  which  innocent  persons  are  at  least  temporarily  jailed  because  of 
inability  to  furnish  bail.  The  poor  and  friendless  types  wrho  frequently 
appear  in  magistrates'  courts  are  particularly  subject  to  this  handicap 
and  humiliation.  In  the  light  of  the  generally  low  estate  of  justice  in 
magistrates'  courts,  one  may  pay  a  special  tribute  to  the  few  magistrates 
who  exhibit  a  high-minded  devotion  to  justice,  and  display  commendable 
industry  and  a  degree  of  judicial  enlightenment  all  too  frequently  absent 
from  the  bench  on  the  highest  courts  of  the  land.  In  what  is  literally  the 
judicial  and  legal  cellar  are  the  night  courts.  These  courts  frequently 
maintain  an  intellectual  and  moral  level  not  much  above  that  of  the 
brothel,  dive,  saloon,  and  gambling  joints  which  furnish  the  night  courts 
with  most  of  their  cases. 

In  the  preceding  pages,  we  have  been  dealing  mainly  with  judicial 
arbitrariness  and  incompetence.  Much  more  serious  is  overt  judicial  cor- 
ruption.18 Most  judges,  even  those  who  are  appointed,  owe  their  position 
to  political  leaders.  Elective  judges  rarely  receive  the  nomination  unless 
they  are  satisfactory  to  political  leaders.  In  return  they  are  expected  to 
make  many  appointments  as  political  favors  and  even  dispense  "justice" 
in  such  a  manner  as  to  serve  the  political  organization.  At  times,  judges 
hear  cases  involving  companies  in  which  they  are  financially  interested. 
While  most  judges  do  not  descend  to  such  a  level,  there  are  all  too  many 
who  are  linked  with  organized  criminals  and  racketeers.  A  distinguished 
criminologist  has  made  the  statement  that  it  is  rare  to  find  any  powerful 
criminal  ring  without  a  corrupt  judge  at  its  center. 

While  honest  judges  and  lawyers  deplore  judicial  corruption,  it  is  hard 
to  get  them  to  act.  Many  fear  that  they  arc  not  qualified  "to  cast  the 
first  stone."  It  is  significant  that  Federal  Judge  Martin  T.  Manton, 
convicted  of  venality  and  sale  of  "justice,"  was  not  exposed  by  lawyers, 
judges,  or  bar  associations,  but  by  a  newspaper  sleuth.19  The  bar  could 
not  have  been  ignorant  of  Manton's  doings,  for  Nicholas  Murray  Butler, 
in  his  autobiography,  mentions  that  the  leaders  of  the  New  York  bar  were 
all  but  prostrated  with  amazement  and  alarm  when  President  Harding 
proposed  to  appoint  Manton  to  the  Supreme  Court  of  the  United  States. 
Yet,  these  same  leaders  of  the  bar  did  nothing  for  nearly  twenty  years, 
and  stood  by  while  Manton  became  the  ranking  Federal  judge,  next  to 
the  members  of  the  Supreme  Court.  It  may  be  noted  that  the  sentence 


17  Gisnet,  op.  dt.,  pp.  113-114. 

18  For  a  good  discussion  of  this  subject,  see  Jackson,  op.  cit.,  Chap.  X. 

id.,  pp.  289 If.;  and  S.  B.  Heath,  Yankee  Reporter,  Funk,  1940. 


404  LAW   IN  ACTION 

imposed  on  Judge  Manton  was  only  half  as  severe  as  that  given  to  Earl 
Browder  for  a  technical  violation  of  the  law  in  applying  for  a  passport. 
The  poor  man  is  handicapped  in  a  number  of  ways  in  getting  equality 
of  treatment  with  the  rich  in  the  courtroom.  It  is  more  difficult  for  the 
former  to  meet  the  ordinary  costs  of  litigation,  such  as  getting  bail,  ordi- 
nary court  fees,  the  hiring  of  a  competent  lawyer,  and  other  inevitable 
expenses  of  courtroom  procedure/20  These  difficulties  have  been  sum- 
marized by  a  capable  and  experienced  lawyer,  John  MacArthur  McGuire 
of  Massachusetts: 

In  more  than  one  of  the  United  States  such  a  plaintiff  fa  poor  person]  may  be 
cast  out  of  court  and  barred  from  testing  the  merits  of  his  cause  if  he  cannot 
produce  security  or  a  bondsman.  Nor  is  this  by  any  means  the  whole  story, 
roverty,  often  through  the  application  of  some  rule  of  law  which  otherwise  seems 
eminently  reasonable,  blocks  a  civil  litigant's  path  at  every  stage  of  the;  proceed- 
ings. A  penniless  suitor  may  lose  his  day  in  court  because  he  has  no  ready  money 
to  pay  the  fees  for  his  writ,  for  serving  process,  for  entering  suit  and  for  other 
similar  official  acts.  lie  may  get  into  court  but  be  helpless  because  he  cannot 
pay  for  a  lawyer;  or  he  may  become  helpless  in  the  midst  of  a  case  because  he 
lacks  funds  to  bring  his  witnesses,  to  pay  a  stenographer  or  to  pay  a  printer. 
He  must,  in  short,  surmount  four  financial  barriers:  costs,  fees,  expense  of  legal 
service,  and  sundry  miscellaneous  expenses  incidental  to  litigation.21 

It  is  obvious  that  the  poor  are  at  a  definite  disadvantage  in  obtaining 
lawyers  to  serve  them.  A  wealthy  client  can  almost  invariably  procure 
the  ablest  attorneys  and  can  get  the  latter  to  devote  their  best  talents  to 
the  handling  of  the  case.  The  poor  man  has  to  get  the  best  lawyer  he  can 
afford  and  has  to  run  the  chance  that  the  latter  will  give  the  case  only 
the  superficial  attention  which  the  small  fee  is  thought  to  justify.  More- 
over, the  poor  man  stands  at  a  disadvantage  with  respect  to  the  judge. 
Most  judges  arc  naturally  and  inevitably  sympathetic  with  the  well-to-do, 
and  are  much  more  likely  to  be  prejudiced  against,  and  impatient  with, 
the  poor  man. 

As  Chief  Justice  Taft  once  pointed  out,  a  wealthy  person  can  frequently 
either  win  a  case  or  get  a  favorable  compromise  simply  by  arranging  for 
indefinite  postponements : 

It  may  be  asserted  as  a  general  proposition,  to  which  many  legislatures  seem  to 
be  oblivious,  that  everything  which  tends  to  prolong  or  delay  litigation  between 
individuals  or  between  individuals  and  corporations  is  a  great  advantage  for  that 
litigant  who  has  the  longer  purse.  The  man  whose  all  is  involved  in  the  decision 
of  the  lawsuit  is  much  prejudiced  in  a  fight  through  the  courts,  if  his  opponent 
is  able,  by  reason  of  his  means  to  prolong  the  litigation  and  keep  him  for  years 
out  of  what  really  belongs  to  him.  The  wealthy  defendant  can  almost  always 
secure  a  compromise  of  yielding  of  lawful  rights  because  of  the  necessities  of  the 
poor  plaintiff.22 

If  the  poor  man  is  lucky  enough  to  win  his  case  in  court,  he  then  has 
to  face  the  prospect  of  appeal  by  a  wealthy  opponent.  Appeals  involve 


20  For  details,  see  Smith,  Justice  and  the  Poor,  Chaps.  V,  VI. 

21  Gisnet,  op.  cit.t  pp.  95-96.    For  more  details  on  this,  see  Jackson,  op.  cit.,  pp. 
155  ff. 

22  Gisnet,  op.  cit.,  pp.  94-95. 


LAW   IN  ACTION  405 

further  delays  and  expenses.  Often,  the  poor  man's  funds  have  been 
exhausted  in  the  original  trial  and  he  has  no  reserve  for  financing  the  case 
during  the  appeal  period.  It  is,  thus,  obvious  that  a  poor  man  faces 
special  handicaps  if  a  wealthy  opponent  appeals  a  defeat  in  the  trial 
court.  He  is  likely  to  have  to  remain  content  with  licking  his  wounds.23 
A  thoroughgoing  study  of  the  handicaps  of  the  poor  litigant  in  an 
American  court  was  made  a  number  of  years  ago  under  the  auspices  of  the 
Carnegie  Foundation  for  the  Advancement  of  Teaching  by  Reginald 
Heber  Smith  of  the  Boston  bar.  His  comprehensive  and  highly  capable 
report,  entitled  Justice  and  the  Poor,  presented  a  staggering  picture  of  the 
difficulties  a  poor  man  faces  in  getting  justice  in  the  United  States.  But 
it  was  approved  as  a  substantially  accurate  picture  of  the  true  situation 
by  no  less  eminent  lawyers  than  Elihu  Root  and  Charles  Evans  Hughes. 
Mr,  Smith  thus  expresses  some  of  his  major  conclusions: 

The  administration  of  American  justice  is  not  impartial,  the  rich  and  the  poor 
do  not  stand  on  an  equality  before  the  law,  the  traditional  method  of  providing 
justice  has  operated  to  close  the  doors  of  the  courts  to  the  poor,  and  has  caused 
a  gross  denial  of  justice  in  all  parts  of  the  country  to  millions  of  persons.  Sweep- 
ing as  this  indictment  may  appear,  it  is  substantiated  by  ample  authority.  .  .  . 

Because  law  is  all-embracing,  the  denial  of  its  protection  means  the  destruction 
of  homes  through  illegal  foreclosures,  the  loss  through  trick  or  chicanery  of  a 
lifetime's  savings,  the  taking  away  of  children  from  their  parents  by  fraudulent 
guardianship  proceedings.  Hundreds  of  thousands  of  men,  many  of  them  immi* 
grants,  have  been  unable  to  collect  their  wages  honestly  earned. 

Denial  of  justice  is  not  merely  negative  in  effect;  it  actively  encourages  fraud 
and  dishonesty.  Unscrupulous  employers,  seeing  the  inability  of  wage-earners  to 
enforce  payments,  have  deliberately  hired  men  without  the  slightest  intention  of 
paying  them.  Some  of  these  employers  are  themselves  poor  men,  who  strive  in 
this  way  to  gain  an  advantage.  The  evil  is  not  one  of  class  in  the  sense  that  it 
gives  the  poor  over  to  the  mercies  of  only  the  rich.  It  enables  the  poor  to  rob 
one  another;  it  permits  the  shrewd  immigrant  of  a  few  years'  residence  to  defraud 
his  more  recently  arrived  countrymen.  The  line  of  cleavage  which  it  follows  and 
accentuates  is  that  between  the  dishonest  and  the  honest.  Everywhere  it  abets 
the  unscrupulous,  the  crafty,  and  the  vicious  in  their  ceaseless  plans  for  exploiting 
their  less  intelligent  and  less  fortunate  fellows.  The  system  not  only  robs  the 
poor  of  their  only  protection,  but  it  places  in  the  hands  of  their  oppressors  the 
most  powerful  and  ruthless  weapon  ever  invented.  .  ,  . 

The  effects  of  this  denial  of  justice  are  far  reaching.  Nothing  rankles  more  in 
the  human  heart  than  the  feeling  of  injustice.  It  produces  a  sense  of  helplessness, 
then  bitterness.  It  is  brooded  over.  It  leads  directly  to  contempt  for  law,  dis- 
loyalty to  the  government,  and  plants  the  seeds  of  anarchy.  The  conviction 
grows  that  law  is  not  justice  and  challenges  the  belief  that  justice  is  best  secured 
when  administered  according  to  law.  The  poor  come  to  think  of  American  justice 
as  containing  only  laws  that  punish  and  never  laws  that  help.  They  are  against 
the  law  because  they  consider  the  law  against  them.  A  persuasion  spreads  that 
there  is  one  law  for  the  rich  and  another  for  the  poor.24 

The  material  presented  in  this  section  constitutes  only  a  few  of  the 
outstanding  illustrations  of  the  deficiencies  in  American  law,  as  it  is 


23  C/.  Jackson,  op.  cit.,  pp.  237  ff. 

24  Smith,  op.  cit.,  pp.  8-10. 


406  LAW   IN   ACTION 

actually  practiced  before  our  courts,  but  it  is  sufficient  to  illustrate  the 
variety  and  seriousness  of  the  defects  of  American  law  in  operation.  We 
shall  also  touch  upon  these  problems  incidentally  in  later  sections  of  the 
chapter. 

Natural  'Law,  Constitutional   Law,  and  the  Protection 

of  Property 

The  New  Testament  set  up  a  famous  triad  of  virtues — faith,  hope,  and 
charity — arid  Paul  explicitly  stated  that  the  greatest  of  these  is  charity. 
The  theory  of  natural  law,  lying  back  of  our  Declaration  of  Independence 
and  Federal  Constitution,  created  an  equally  historic  triad  in  the  form  of 
the  natural  rights  of  man — life,  liberty,  and  property — and  the  subsequent 
interpretation  of  these  rights  in  our  courts  has  elevated  property  to  as 
preeminent  a  place  as  charity  occupied  in  the  Pauline  scale  of  values. 

in  a  notable  book,  The  Revival  of  Natural  Law  Concepts,  Charles 
Grove  Haines  has  made  it  clear  that  the  conservative  jurisprudence  of  the 
United  States  Supreme  Court,  especially  in  the  twentieth  century,  has 
been  based  primarily  upon  the  concepts  of  seventeenth-century  natural 
law.25  There  is  the  same  tendency  to  seek  a  foundation  for  law  in 
sources  "external  to  man  and  his  law-making  and  law-enforcing  agencies." 
When  the  rule  of  reason  was  introduced  in  1911,  in  dealing  with  anti-trust 
cases,  we  had  a  literal  revival  of  the  very  essence  of  natural  law  theory  in 
interpreting  and  applying  the  laws  of  the  United  States  to  business*  The 
Supreme  Court  has  thus  been  able  to  hold  over  American  lawmakers  the 
extremely  vague  but  highly  potent  club  of  the  rule  of  reason.  As  Pro- 
fessor Haines  says,  "the  United  States  is  practically  alone  in  placing 
super-censors  over  its  legislative  chambers  with  often  nothing  more  than 
the  elusive  rule  of  reason  as  a  standard."  In  fact,  the  older  and  broader 
concept  of  "due  process  of  law"  is  little  more  than  another  name  for 
natural  law  and  the  dominion  of  reason. 

Professor  Haines  well  observes  that  our  judges  have  found  a  "haven 
in  due  process  of  law,  which  is  little  else  than  a  natural  law  given  consti- 
tutional sanction — with  the  same  vagueness  and  uncertainty  inherent  in 
the  standard  phrases."  Using  these  antiquated  but  extremely  convenient 
legal  notions,  the  Supreme  Court  has  wrought  havoc  with  progressive 
legislation  in  the  United  States  and  has  been  very  effective  in  protecting 
private  property  and  corporate  rights  against  effective  social  control. 

Perhaps  as  good  a  statement  as  was  ever  made  of  the  philosophy  of 
property  rights  accepted  by  the  Supreme  Court  was  that  set  forth  by  the 
corporation  lawyer  Joseph  H.  Choate  when  he  argued  in  1895  against  the 
constitutionality  of  the  income-tax  law,  in  the  famous  Pollock  case: 

I  believe  that  there  are  rights  of  property  here  to  be  protected;  that  we  have 
a  right  to  come  to  this  Court  and  ask  for  this  protection,  and  that  this  Court  has 
a  right,  without  asking  leave  of  the  Attorney  General  or  of  any  counsel,  to  hear 
our  plea.  The  Act  of  Congress  [the  income  tax  law]  we  are  impugning  before 

25  See  above,  p.  369. 


LAW   IN   ACTION  407 

you  is  communistic  in  its  purposes  and  tendencies,  and  is  defended  here  upon 
principles  as  communistic,  socialist— what  shall  I  call  them? — populistic  as  ever 
have  been  addressed  to  any  political  assembly  in  the  world.  ...  I  have 
thought  that  one  of  the  fundamental  objects  of  all  civilized  government  was  the 
preservation  of  the  rights  of  private  property.  I  have  thought  that  it  was  the 
very  keystone  of  the  arch  upon  which  all  civilized  government  rests.  ...  If  it 
be  true  .  .  .  that  the  passions  of  the  people  are  aroused  011  this  subject,  if  it  be 
true  that  a  mighty  army  of  60,000,000  citizens  is  likely  to  be  incensed  by  this 
decision,  it  is  the  more  vital  to  the  future  welfare  of  this  country  that  this  Court 
again  resolutely  and  courageously  declare,  as  Marshall  did,  that  it  has  the  power 
to  set  aside  an  Act  of  Congress  violative  of  the  Constitution,  and  that  it  will  not 
hesitate  in  executing  that  power,  no  matter  what  the  threatened  consequences  of 
popular  or  populistic  wrath  may  be.20 


One  scarcely  needs  to  be  reminded  that  the  Court  accepted  Mr.  Choate's 
reasoning  and  set  the  law  aside  as  unconstitutional.  It  required  a  consti- 
tutional amendment,  many  years  later,  to  put  the  income-tax  legislation 
beyond  the  reach  of  the  Supreme  Court.  Whatever  attitude  the  Court 
may  take  on  property  in  the  future,  certainly  it  is  fair  and  accurate  to 
say  that  the  majority  of  its  members  subscribed  to  Mr.  Choate's  philos- 
ophy from  the  close  of  the  Civil  War  to  the  court  reform  proposals  of 
Franklin  D.  Roosevelt  in  1937. 

Far  more  illuminating  than  any  broad  generalizations  or  blanket 
attacks  on  the  Court  is  a  calm  factual  statement  of:  (1)  how  it  has  stood, 
for  the  most  part,  like  a  stone  wall  in  the  path  of  progressive  legislation ; 
(2)  the  processes  it  makes  use  of;  and  (3)  the  decisions  through  which  it 
has  frustrated  liberal  and  humane  legislation. 

The  foundation  of  the  activities  of  the  Court  in  obstructing  progress  is 
its  assertion  of  the  right  to  set  aside  federal  and  state  legislation  as 
unconstitutional.  This  right,  of  dubious  legal  validity,  it  first  claimed  in 
1803,  in  the  case  of  Marbury  vs.  Madison,  and  in  1810,  in  the  case  of 
Fletcher  vs.  Peck.27  For  a  hundred  and  thirty  years  it  has  used  this 
power,  with  ever-increasing  frequency  since  1886.  This  means  that, 
whenever  the  Court  believes  that  a  law  does  not  square  with  the  Consti- 
tution, as  interpreted  at  the  time  by  five  out  of  the  nine  judges  on  the 
bench,  the  law  is  declared  invalid  and  of  no  account.  Until  1886,  how- 
ever, the  Court  was  relatively  cautious  and  restrained  in  declaring  laws 
unconstitutional.  It  had  to  be  shown  that  the  law  in  question  clearly 
violated  some  explicit  provision  of  the  Constitution.  There  were  only 
two  major  cases  of  setting  aside  a  federal  statute  before  the  Civil  War. 
Shortly  after  the  Civil  War,  a  judicial  perversion  of  one  of  the  Reconstruc- 
tion amendments  gave  the  Court  much  greater  leeway. 

In  order  to  protect  the  Negro  against  a  return  to  servility,  the  Four- 
teenth Amendment  had  been  added  to  the  Constitution.  It  directed  that 
no  state  should  deprive  any  person  of  life,  liberty,  or  property  without 


26  Cited  in  Maurice  Finkelstein,  The  Dilemma  of  the  Supreme  Court:   Is  the 
N.RA.  Constitutional?  Day,  1933,  p.  24. 

27  In  Marbury  vs.  Madison,  the  Court  set  aside  federal  legislation ;  in  Fletcher  vs. 
Peck,  it  voided  a  state  statute. 


408  LAW  IN  ACTION 

due  process  of  law.  A  drive  was  made  at  once  to  get  corporations  ad- 
mitted as  "persons,"  under  the  meaning  of  the  Fourteenth  Amendment. 
Success  came  in  1886,  in  the  Santa  Clara  County  case  in  California,  when 
the  Court  unanimously  decided  to  include  corporations  in  its  interpre- 
tation of  the  Fourteenth  Amendment  and  "due  process  of  law."  This 
let  down  the  bars.  As  "due  process  of  law"  is,  quite  literally,  anything 
the  Supreme  Court  decides  it  to  be  at  any  moment,  there  is  no  limit 
whatever  to  its  power  to  invalidate  legislation.  Whatever  runs  counter 
to  the  economic,  social,  or  political  philosophy  of  five  judges  can  be  set 
aside  quite  casually,  no  matter  what  the  popular  demand  for  the  measure 
or  what  its  logical  or  traditional  legality  may  be.  The  eminent  jurist, 
John  Bassett  Moore,  once  cryptically  remarked  that,  while  the  Fourteenth 
Amendment  has  given  little  protection  to  the  Negro,  it  has  been  extremely 
effective  in  aiding  and  sheltering  "the  corporation  nigger-in-the-wood- 
pile."  E.  S.  Corwin  has  observed  that  "  'due  process  of  law'  is  not 
a  regular  concept  at  all,  but  merely  a  roving  commission  of  judges  to  sink 
whatever  legislative  craft  may  appear  to  them,  from  the  standpoint  of 
the  vested  interests,  to  be  of  piratical  tendency."  27a  The  distortion  of 
both  the  Fourteenth  Amendment  and  "due  process"  by  the  Supreme  Court 
since  1886  is  well  summarized  by  Professor  Rodell: 

The  "due  process"  clause  was  originally  intended  to  apply  only  to  criminal 
cases.  The  idea  that  any  statute,  much  less  a  non-criminal  one  like  a  tax  or  a 
regulation  of  business,  after  being  properly  passed  by  a  legislature,  signed  by  a 
governor,  and  enforced  according  to  its  terms  by  judges,  could  amount  to  a 
deprivation  of  anything  without  due  process  of  law  would  once  have  been  laughed 
out  of  court.  Yet  the  Supreme  Court  has  built  the  bulk  of  its  Constitutional 
Law,  as  applied  to  the  states,  on  precisely  that  strange  supposition.  It  has  taken 
a  simple  phrase  of  the  Constitution  which  originally  had  a  plain  and  precise 
meaning,  twisted  that  phrase  out  of  all  recognition,  ringed  it  around  with  vague 
general  principles  found  nowhere  in  the  Constitution,  and  then  pontifically 
mouthed  that  phrase  and  those  principles  as  excuses  for  throwing  out,  or  majes- 
tically upholding,  state  laws.28 

The  fact  that  the  Fourteenth  Amendment  and  "due  process  of  law" 
were,  used  mainly  to  protect  property  from  unfavorable  legislation  gave 
the  courts  remarkable  leeway  and  freedom  in  killing  off  legislation.  Pro- 
fessor Corwin  has  shown  that  "due  process"  means  anything  the  courts 
wish  it  to  mean.  We  have  already  seen  that,  in  recent  years,  the  property 
concept  was  widened  by  the  courts  to  include  anything  the  vested  inter- 
ests desired  to  protect.  Therefore,  when  a  constitutional  or  corporation 
lawyer  appealed  to  the  courts  to  protect  property  by  the  use  of  "due  proc- 
ess," there  was  almost  no  limit  to  the  extent  to  which  the  courts  could  go, 
if  they  wished. 

After  corporations  were  admitted  to  the  category  of  "persons"  under 
the  "due  process"  clause  of  the  Fourteenth  Amendment,  the  Supreme 


2<m  Cited  by  Max  Farrand,  The  Development  of  the  United  States,  Houghton 
Mifflin,  1918,  p.  272. 


LAW  IN  ACTION  409 

Court  became  more  reckless  in  setting  aside  legislation  on  the  ground  that 
it  was  contrary  to  the  Constitution.  Far  more  laws  were  set  aside  be- 
tween 1886  and  1900  than  in  the  previous  history  of  the  Court,  and  more 
than  twice  as  many  have  been  invalidated  by  the  Court  in  the  twentieth 
century  as  in  the  whole  period  from  Marshall  to  the  opening  of  the  present 
century.  So  ruthless  and  arrogant  was  the  attitude  of  the  Court  in  this 
matter  that,  in  1912,  Theodore  Roosevelt  openly  proposed  the  recall  of 
judicial  decisions.  But  the  Court  became  even  more  active  and  light- 
hearted  in  setting  aside  legislation  after  1912.  Others  have  proposed  a 
congressional  veto  upon  the  action  of  the  Court  in  setting  aside  federal 
laws. 

With  the  exception  of  an  occasional  liberal,  such  as  Harlan,  Holmes, 
Brandeis,  Stone,  and  Cardozo,  the  Supreme  Court  justices  down  to  1938 
were  almost  invariably  reactionary  lawyers,  long  in  the  service  of  great 
corporate  interests.  Their  experience,  contacts,  and  outlook  were  those 
of  businessmen  and  financiers.  Their  philosophy  inevitably  colored  their 
view  of  law.29  The  vague  and  broad  character  of  the  "due  process  of  law" 
test  of  constitutionality  gave  them,  as  we  have  seen,  almost  unrestricted 
power  to  quash  any  law  that  conflicted  with  their  conservative  philosophy 
and  their  reverence  for  property  rights. 

The  Supreme  Court  became  a  particularly  aggressive  champion  of 
capitalism  about  the  time  we  reached  the  stage  of  monopoly  capitalism. 
The  liberals,  fearing  the  power  of  great  mergers  and  monopolies  to  control 
prices  at  will,  endeavored  to  check  this  process  by  the  Sherman  Anti- 
Trust  Act  of  1890.  In  the  E.  C.  Knight  Case  (1895) ,  the  Supreme  Court 
declared,  essentially,  that  the  Sherman  Act  applied  only  to  monopolies  in 
restraint  of  commerce  between  states  and  not  to  monopoly  in  manufactur- 
ing. In  1897-98,  the  Court  admitted  that  the  act  covered  both  reasonable 
and  unreasonable  restraint  of  trade.  But,  in  1911,  the  Court,  guided  by 
the  reasoning  of  Justices  White  and  Hughes,  reinterpreted  the  Sherman 
Act  according  to  the  famous  "rule  of  reason,"  derived  from  natural  law. 
It  held  that  the  Sherman  Act  was  violated  only  by  "unreasonable"  re- 
straint of  trade.  As  a  result  some  of  the  greatest  mergers,  such  as  the 
United  States  Steel  Corporation,  got  through  dissolution  suits  safely. 
The  Clayton  Act,  in  Wilson's  administration,  endeavored  still  further  to 
control  monopolies,  but  in  the  case  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  vs. 
Gratz  (1920)  the  Court  emasculated  this  as  it  had  earlier  undermined 
the  Sherman  Act.  Some  might  allege  that  the  "trust-busting"  reformers 
were  mistaken  in  their  policies,  but  at  least  they  had  the  support  of  the 
public,  and  the  Court  thus  frustrated  the  popular  will. 

The  railroads  were,  in  their  early  days,  the  scene  of  much  dubious 
financial  practice.  Some  semblance  of  public  control  was  essential,  and 
the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  was  established  in  1887  to  supply 
this  supervision.  The  Supreme  Court  was  soon  found  operating  deci- 


29  C/.  Zechariah  Chafee,  Jr.,  "The  Economic  Determination  of  Judges,"  The 
Inquiring  Mind,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1928,  pp.  254-265;  and  Gustavus  Myers,  A  History 
of  the  Supreme  Court,  Kerr,  1912. 


410  LAW   IN  ACTION 

sively  on  the  side  of  the  railroads.  Out  of  sixteen  appeals  made  from  the 
rulings  of  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  between  1887  and  1905, 
the  Court  decided  in  favor  of  the  railroads  fifteen  times.  In  1897,  the 
Court  further  undermined  the  power  of  the  commission  by  denying  it 
authority  to  fix  rates.  About  all  that  was  left  was  the  right  to  collect 
railroad  statistics  and  give  them  publicity.  Under  Theodore  Roosevelt's 
influence,  the  commission  was  strengthened,  and,  in  1913,  it  was  author- 
ized to  make  a  physical  valuation  of  railroad  properties  as  the  basis  for 
scientific  determination  of  rates.  Further  power  was  bestowed  in  1920, 
and  liberals  began  to  anticipate  the  day  when  the  Interstate  Commerce 
Commission  would  have  both  the  authority  to  fix  railroad  rates  and  the 
knowledge  requisite  to  do  this  in  accurate  and  just  fashion.  This  hope 
the  Court  upset  in  the  O'Fallon  Case  (1929)  and  in  United  Railways  vs. 
West  (1930).  The  Court  held  that  not  "prudent  investment"  but  "repro- 
duction cost  new"  must  be  taken  into  account  in  determining  rates.  It 
also  held  that  anything  less  than  7.44  per  cent  return  per  year  would  be 
confiscatory.  The  Court  further  permitted  the  deduction  of  a  depreci- 
ation charge  from  net  income.  Much  the  same  principles  favorable  to 
corporate  wealth  were  extended  from  the  railroads  to  the  electric  utilities 
by  the  Court. 

The  Supreme  Court  has  actually  frustrated  efforts  to  enforce  elemen- 
tary honesty  in  business,  affecting  such  basic  matters  as  both  quantity  and 
quality  of  marketed  materials.  It  thus  tacitly  encouraged  the  most  anti- 
social practices  of  marketing  according  to  the  theory  of  business  enter- 
prise, which  we  described  earlier  in  the  book.  For  example,  in  the  case 
of  the  Burns  Baking  Company  vs.  Bryan  (1924),  the  Court  declared 
unconstitutional  a  standard-weights  law  designed  to  protect  buyers  from 
short  weight  in  sales.  During  the  next  year,  in  the  case  of  Weaver  vs. 
Palmer  Bros.,  the  Court  set  aside  a  Pennsylvania  law  enacted  to  prevent 
the  use  of  shoddy  in  making  comfortables. 

Even  more  fundamental  and  sweeping  was  the  Court's  clearly  implied 
declaration,  in  the  case  of  Allgeyer  vs.  Louisiana  (1897),  that  business 
practices  and  callings  are  above  the  law  and  that  the  Fourteenth  Amend- 
ment guarantees  a  man  the  right  to  live,  work,  and  follow  business 
activities  as  he  wishes,  irrespective  of  statutory  law. 

One  of  the  most  elemental  principles  of  economic  and  social  democracy 
is  that,  when  money  has  to  be  raised  for  public  purposes,  taxation  shall  be 
based  upon  the  principle  of  capacity  to  pay.  The  more  a  man  is  allowed 
to  prosper  in  any  society,  the  more  may  be  reasonably  exacted  from  him 
to  support  the  existing  political  and  social  order.  The  wealthy  have 
never  been  willing  to  concede  this  truism  and  have  thus  far  prevented 
taxation  measures  from  even  approximating  a  real  "capacity-to-pay" 
basis.  The  Supreme  Court  has  not  failed  them  in  this  struggle  to  evade 
equitable  taxation. 

First  came  the  notable  decision  in  the  case  of  Pollock  vs.  Farmers'  Loan 
and  Trust  Company  (1895),  in  which  the  Court  declared  an  income-tax 
law  unconstitutional.  As  has  been  noted,  it  took  a  constitutional  amend- 


LAW  IN  ACTION  411 

ment  to  enable  our  government  to  collect  a  tax  on  personal  incomes. 
The  Supreme  Court  then  came  to  the  rescue  in  the  case  of  Eisner  vs. 
Macomber  (1920)  and  declared  that  stock  dividends  were  not  income 
and  hence  not  liable  to  taxation.  This  provided  a  spacious  loophole  for 
the  rich.  The  Court  steadfastly  and  consistently  blocked  any  program  of 
fair  and  adequate  taxation  of  corporations  and  holding  companies. 

If  there  is  any  practice  of  capitalism  that  is  open  to  criticism,  it  is  the 
transmission  of  vast  wealth  from  one  generation  to  the  next.  An  able  and 
energetic  man  may  accumulate  a  fortune,  in  some  cases  to  the  benefit  of 
the  public  as  well  as  himself.  But  under  our  present  system  he  may 
transmit  his  riches  to  a  parasitical  descendant  who  may  never  make  even 
a  gesture  of  industriousness.  The  only  way  to  correct  this  abuse  is 
through  drastic  inheritance  and  estate  taxes.  Some  states  have  tried  to 
introduce  such  taxation.  Wisconsin  was  a  pioneer.  The  Supreme  Court 
stepped  into  the  breach,  and  in  the  case  of  Schlesinger  vs.  Wisconsin 
(1925),  declared  unconstitutional  the  Wisconsin  law  designed  to  end 
evasions  of  the  inheritance  tax  through  spurious  "gifts."  In  1931,  the 
Court  continued  its  obstructive  policies  in  regard  to  taxes  on  inheritances 
in  two  cases,  Farmers'  Loan  and  Trust  Company  vs.  Minnesota,  and 
Coolidge  vs.  Long. 

If  capitalism  is  to  endure,  it  must  make  provision  for  safe  and  decent 
working-conditions,  for  an  income  sufficient  to  make  each  self-supporting 
adult  an  effective  purchaser,  and  for  sufficient  leisure  to  produce  a  broad 
need  for  consumers'  goods.  Progressives  have  sought  to  bring  such  condi- 
tions into  being.  An  Employers'  Liability  Act  was  passed  in  1906,  but 
the  Court  set  it  aside  in  Howard  vs.  Illinois  C.  R.  Co.  (1907).  An 
amended  act  was  upheld  in  Second  Employers'  Liabilities  Cases  (1912) 
and  in  New  York  Central  R.R.  Co.  vs.  White  (1917).  The  State  of  New 
York  tried  to  eliminate  atrocious  working  conditions  in  bakeshops  by 
limiting  the  hours  of  work.  The  Court  invalidated  this  legislation  in  the 
famous  case  of  Lochner  vs.  New  York  (1905),  reversed  in  Bunting  vs. 
Oregon  (1917). 

At  first,  the  Court,  influenced  by  the  masterly  presentation  of  the  case 
by  Louis  D.  Brandeis,  approved  the  Oregon  minimum-wage  law  in  Muller 
vs.  Oregon  (1908).  But,  in  1923,  in  the  case  of  Adkins  vs.  Children's 
Hospital,  it  set  aside  a  District  of  Columbia  minimum-wage  law  of  1918 
as  unconstitutional  because  it  infringed  perfect  "freedom  of  contract." 
That  the  temper  of  the  Court  in  this  matter  did  not  change  for  years  was 
proved  in  the  case  of  Morehead  vs.  Tipaldo  (1936),  in  which  a  con- 
servative majority  of  five  set  aside  as  unconstitutional  the  New  York 
State  minimum-wage  legislation.  Child  labor  was  outlawed  in  Britain 
a  century  ago,  but  the  Supreme  Court  tolerated  the  practice,  lest  interfer- 
ence destroy  the  sacred  right  of  free  contract.  In  the  case  of  Hammer  vs. 
Dagenhart  (1918)  it  declared  the  federal  anti-child-labor  law  of  1916 
unconstitutional.  Congress  tried  again,  in  a  law  of  1919  taxing  the 
employers  of  child  labor.  The  court  set  aside  this  law  in  1922,  in  the  case 
of  Bailey  vs.  Drexel  Furniture  Co. 


412  LAW   IN   ACTION 

If  labor  is  to  be  kept  satisfied  with  the  capitalistic  system,  it  must  be 
accorded  equality  with  capital,  yet  in  the  famous  Danbury  hatters  case, 
Loewe  vs.  Lawlor  (1908),  labor  was  declared  punishable  for  secondary 
boycott,  under  the  Sherman  Act.  In  1911,  the  Court  went  still  further 
(Gompers  vs.  Buck's  Stove  and  Range  Co.)  and  declared  that  officials  of 
the  American  Federation  of  Labor  could  be  punished  for  encouraging 
boycotts  against  non-union  employers.  The  labor  clauses  of  the  Clayton 
Act  were  specifically  designed:  (1)  To  prevent  the  prosecution  of  labor 
under  the  Sherman  Act,  which  was  aimed  at  business  trusts  and  monop- 
olies; and  (2)  to  reduce  the  use  of  the  injunction  against  unions.  But,  in 
the  case  of  the  Duplex  Printing  Company  vs.  Deering  (1921),  the  Court 
asserted  that  the  Clayton  Act  did  not  prevent  the  issuing  of  injunctions 
against  organized  labor.  In  the  same  year,  in  the  case  of  Truax  vs. 
CorrigaUy  the  Court  threw  out  an  Arizona  law  forbidding  the  use  of 
injunctions  against  labor. 

In  the  notorious  case  of  Adair  vs.  United  States  (1908) ,  the  Court  held 
that  neither  a,  federal  statute  nor  a  state  law  could  prevent  an  employer 
from  discharging  one  of  his  workers  for  joining  a  union.  In  the  famous 
case  of  Coppage  vs.  Kansas  (1915),  the  Court  set  aside  a  Kansas  law 
which  made  it  a  misdemeanor  to  discharge  a  man  simply  because  of  his 
union  membership.  Justice  Pitney,  for  the  majority,  ruled  that  a  worker 
"has  no  inherent  right  to  remain  in  the  employ  of  one  who  is  unwilling  to 
employ  a  union  man."  The  case  of  Hitchman  Coal  and  Coke  Company 
vs.  Mitchell  (1917)  was  a  particularly  deadly  blow  to  organized  labor. 
It  upheld  the  notorious  "yellow-dog"  contracts  and  reaffirmed  the  appli- 
cability of  the  Sherman  Act  to  labor  union  activities.  In  the  Coronado 
Case  (1922) ,  the  Court  went  still  further  and  declared  that  a  union  might 
be  sued  for  damages  under  the  antitrust  laws,  even  though  it  was  not 
incorporated.  In  the  Bedford  Cut  Stone  Case  (1927),  the  Court  went  the 
limit  and  upheld  the  use  of  the  injunction  against  union  labor,  even  if  it 
could  be  proved  that  the  strikers  had  in  no  way  acted  in  an  illegal  manner. 
In  short,  Supreme  Court  decisions  no  less  than  paralyzed  organized  labor 
and  collective  bargaining,  while,  at  the  same  time,  sabotaging  the  efforts 
of  tbc  government  to  subject  business  and  finance  to  social  control. 

We  have  now  indicated  a  few  of  the  ways  in  which  the  Supreme  Court 
has  frustrated  or  retarded  the  efforts  of  liberal  leaders  to  establish  a  just 
and  civilized  social  and  economic  order  in  our  country.  It  opposed 
equitable  taxation,  permitted  business  to  engage  in  even  dishonest  prac- 
tices, interfered  with  efforts  to  provide  decent  wages  and  living  conditions, 
and  all  but  ended  the  initiative  of  organized  labor.  In  this  way  it  has  led 
many  of  the  more  hot-headed  to  feel  that  the  only  way  out  is  through 
violence.  While  promoting  revolution  through  its  opposition  to  social 
change,  the  Supreme  Court  has,  however,  naturally  tried  to  outlaw 
revolutionary  movements  in  the  United  States.  In  the  Gitlow  Case 
(1925),  it  outlawed  revolutionary  tactics  and  approved  the  prosecution  of 
the  Communists  and  Syndicalists.  Three  years  later  it  took  the  same 
position  in  the  Whitney  Case,  upholding  the  California  Criminal  Syndi- 
calism law. 


LAW  IN  ACTION  413 

In  our  age,  after  witnessing  the  wastes,  sorrows,  and  imbecilities  of  a 
war  and  a  postwar  period,  most  thoughtful  people  have  come  to  agree 
upon  the  futility  of  war.  More,  they  look  upon  war  as  a  menace  to  the 
race.  But  the  Supreme  Court  still  holds  the  obligation  to  bear  arms 
an  essential  to  citizenship.  Even  a  middle-aged  and  invalid  woman  of 
high  culture  will  not  be  admitted  to  citizenship  unless  she  agrees  to  bear 
arms  in  case  of  war.  In  the  Schwimmer  Case  (1928) ,  the  Supreme  Court, 
as  Justice  Holmes  clearly  implied,  took  a  position  of  disapproval  of  the 
Sermon  on  the  Mount.  The  same  attitude  was  continued  in  the  Mac- 
intosh and  Bland  Cases  three  years  later.  These  cases  involved  applica- 
tions for  citizenship  by  Rosika  Schwimmer,  a  cultivated  Hungarian,  by 
Professor  Douglas  C.  Macintosh  of  the  Yale  Divinity  School,  a  former 
army  chaplain  decorated  for  bravery  under  fire,  and  by  Miss  Marie 
Bland,  a  former  war  nurse.  They  would  not  agree  to  bear  arms  under 
any  and  all  conditions. 

The  attitude  of  the  Supreme  Court  with  respect  to  New  Deal  legisla- 
tion can  be  followed  through  a  series  of  decisions  which  sorely  disap- 
pointed many  liberal-minded  persons  who  hoped  for  a  more  generous  and 
liberal  judgment  of  measures  that,  at  least,  were  rational  efforts  to  cope 
with  profound  social  and  economic  maladjustments.  The  first  important 
New  Deal  cases  to  come  before  the  Court  were  the  Gold  Cases,  which  were 
decided  on  February  18,  1935.  The  Court  found  for  the  government 
in  these  cases  by  a  narrow  majority  and  thus  raised  false  hopes  in  the 
minds  of  many  liberals.  From  this  decision  onward,  all  the  major  New 
Deal  measures  were  set  aside.  The  National  Industrial  Recovery  Act 
was  voided  in  tho  case  of  the  Schechter  Poultry  Corporation  vs.  U.S. 
(May  27,  1935).  The  Court  was  unanimous  in  this  decision.  The 
attempt  to  control  production  in  agriculture  under  the  Agricultural  Adjust- 
ment Act  was  frustrated  when  the  Court  declared  the  AAA  unconstitu- 
tional in  the  case  of  U.S.  vs.  Butler  (January  6,  1936).  An  effort  to~ 
bring  order  into  the  chaotic  bituminous  coal  industry  was  destroyed  when 
the  Court  invalidated  the  Guffey  Coal  Act,  in  the  case  of  Carter  vs.  Carter 
Coal  Co.  (May  18,  1936).  The  opposition  of  the  Court  to  humane  legis- 
lation, when  the  latter  conflicts  with  even  an  extreme  view  of  the  invio- 
lability of  property  rights,  was  illustrated  by  the  voiding  of  the  Railway 
Retirement  Act  granting  pensions  to  railway  employees  in  Railway 
Retirement  Board  vs.  Alton  Ry.  Co.  (1935).  The  Frazier-Lemke  Farm 
Bankruptcy  Act  was  passed  in  1934  to  save  the  most  desperate  class  of 
farmers  from  unnecessarily  hasty  foreclosure  and  eviction.  But  the 
Court  set  it  aside  in  1935.  The  Court  came  to  the  rescue  of  property 
interests,  when  threatened  at  all  by  public  agencies,  by  declaring  the 
Municipal  Bankruptcy  Act  unconstitutional  on  May  25,  1936.  It  also 
invalidated  the  New  York  State  Minimum  Wage  Act  in  the  above-men- 
tioned case  of  Morehead  vs.  Tipaldo  (1936). 

The  defiance  of  democratic  principles  and  of  the  mandate  of  the  people 
by  the  Supreme  Court  in  voiding  most  of  the  important  New  Deal 
measures  produced  great  indignation  on  the  part  of  American  liberals, 


414  LAW  IN  ACTION 

including  President  Roosevelt  himself.  He  accused  the  Court  of  wishing 
to  take  the  country  buck  to  "horse  and  buggy  days."  It  was  expected 
that  he  would  propose  some  plan  for  curbing  the  power  of  the  Court. 
This  he  did,  on  February  5,  1937,  when  he  gave  out  to  the  press  his  plan 
for  the  reform  of  the  federal  judiciary.  He  suggested  facilitating  and 
endowing  the  retirement  of  Supreme  Court  justices  at  the  age  of  70,  giving 
the  President  the  right  to  appoint  new  members  of  the  Court,  up  to  a 
total  of  fifteen,  one  for  each  judge  who  failed  to  resign  at  70,  and  taking 
steps  to  speed  up  the  work  in  the  federal  courts  as  a  whole. 

The  plan  was  an  extremely  clever  one,  though  perhaps  announced  with 
rather  more  than  appropriate  levity.  There  were  a  number  of  liberals 
who  would  have  preferred  to  have  a  constitutional  amendment,  limiting 
the  power  of  the  Court  to  declare  laws  unconstitutional,  but  the  President 
evidently  recognized  that  any  such  amendment  would  require  years  for 
ratification,  if,  indeed,  it  would  ever  be  ratified.  The  President's  great 
mistake  was  his  failure  to  carry  on  an  adequate  program  of  public  edu- 
'cation  on  the  Court  issue  in  the  early  spring  of  1937.  Rather,  he  relied 
upon  Senate  leader  Joseph  T.  Robinson  to  get  the  bill  through  Congress, 
having  apparently  promised  Senator  Robinson  the  first  appointment  to 
the  enlarged  Court.  But  Robinson  died  in  July,  1937,  and  the  Court 
fight  flared  up  with  great  vigor.  Reactionaries,  and  liberals  jealous  of 
the  President,  poured  out  all  their  jealousy  and  venom  upon  the  bill. 
It  was  perfectly  suited  for  their  purposes.  They  could  use  an  ostensible 
effort  to  save  the  Constitution  as  a  cloak  for  highly  partisan  sentiments 
and  motives.  Senator  Burton  K.  Wheeler  of  Montana,  the  leader  of  the 
renegade  liberals,  went  so  far  as  to  suggest  that  God  struck  down  Senator 
Robinson  because  of  his  sponsorship  of  the  Court  bill.  The  bill  was 
defeated,  but  resignations  helped  the  President  to  remake  the  Court.  In 
May,  1937,  Judge  Willis  Van  Devanter  resigned.  The  President  ap- 
pointed in  his  place,  Senator  Hugo  L.  Black  of  Alabama,  a  vigorous  and 
stalwart  liberal.  The  President's  enemies  renewed  their  attacks  because 
of  the  fact  that  Black  had  once  been  a  somewhat  indifferent  member  of 
the  Ku  Klux  Klan  but  had  long  since  resigned.  In  January,  1938,  Justice 
George  Sutherland  resigned  and  President  Roosevelt  appointed  to  the 
vacancy  Solicitor-General  Stanley  Reed.  One  resolute  and  one  moderate 
liberal  thus  replaced  two  of  the  arch  reactionaries  formerly  on  the  Court. 
In  the  next  three  years  the  personnel  of  the  Court  changed.  Justice 
Benjamin  N.  Cardozo  died  in  1938;  Justice  Pierce  B,utler  died  in  1939; 
Justice  Louis  D.  Brandeis  resigned  in  1939;  and  Justice  James  C.  Mc- 
Reynolds  resigned  in  1941.  To  their  posts  President  Roosevelt  appointed 
Felix  Frankfurter  and  William  0.  Douglas  in  1939,  Frank  Murphy  and 
Robert  Jackson  in  1940,  and  James  F.  Byrnes  in  1941.  Mr.  Roosevelt 
had  thus  appointed  no  less  than  seven  liberal  members  of  the  Court  by 
the  end  of  1941. 

Even  before  this  great  shake-up,  however,  the  Court  showed  a  new 
temper.  Chief  Justice  Hughes  was  a  clever  politician  with  a  generation 
of  political  experience  behind  him.  He  realized  that,  if  the  Court  con- 


LAW   IN  ACTION  415 

tinued  to  hand  down  reactionary  decisions  and  invalidated  further  im- 
portant New  Deal  legislation,  the  President's  case  for  his  Court  bill 
would  be  greatly  strengthened.  He  appears  to  have  converted  to  his 
point  of  view  Mr.  Justice  Roberts,  who,  according  to  the  suggestion  of 
Thomas  Reed  Powell,  may  have  realized  that  "a  switch  in  time  saves 
nine."  At  least,  Justice  Roberts  left  the  reactionaries  and  gave  the 
Court  a  liberal  majority  of  five  to  four.  As  a  succinct  summary  of  the 
President's  Court  fight,  lawyers  are  fond  of  quoting  from  Smollett: 
"Whereupon  he  leapt  upon  her  and  would  have  raped  her,  had  she  not 
prevented  him  by  her  timely  acquiescence." 

The  Court  made  the  most  startling  right-about-face  in  its  entire 
history.  On  March  29,  1937,  it  reversed  the  stand  that  it  had  taken 
the  previous  year  on  the  New  York  State  Minimum  Wage  Law,  and 
declared  constitutional  the  legislation  of  the  State  of  Washington  pro- 
viding minimum  wages  for  women.  On  April  12,  1937,  it  upheld  in  four 
cases  the  Wagner  National  Labor  Relations  Act,  the  most  comprehensive 
piece  of  labor  legislation  ever  enacted  in  this  country.  In  the  spring  of 
1937,  the  Court  also  upheld  the  constitutionality  of  the  Social  Security 
Act,  in  the  cases  of  Helvering  vs.  Davis  and  The  Steward  Machine  Co.  vs. 
Davis.  In  the  case  of  Senn  vs.  Tile  Layers'  Protective  Union,  the  Court 
upheld  a  Wisconsin  statute  that  legalized  peaceful  picketing.  Civil 
liberties  were  upheld  in  the  case  of  DeJonge  vs.  Oregon,  in  which  the 
Court  voided  the  Oregon  Criminal  Syndicalism  Act,  and  in  the  case  of 
Herndon  vs.  Lowry,  in  which  the  Court  held  that  Herndon,  a  Negro  Com- 
munist, had  been  deprived  of  freedom  of  speech  and  denied  "due  process 
of  law." 

Most  striking  of  all  were  the  dissenting  decisions  of  Mr.  Justice  Black, 
who  showed  himself  a  more  upstanding  liberal  than  any  other  person 
who  has  been  on  the  Court  within  memory.  Especially  striking  was  his 
dissent  in  the  case  of  the  Connecticut  General  Life  Insurance  Company 
vs.  Johnson.  He  had  the  courage  to  assert  that  the  Court  had  acted 
improperly  since  1886  in  including  corporations  as  persons  under  the 
Fourteenth  Amendment.  This  was  the  first  time  since  1873 80  that  a 
justice  of  the  Supreme  Court  had  possessed  such  candor  and  fortitude. 
As  Max  Lerner  expresses  it,  "he  swept  away  fifty  years  of  Supreme 
Court  history  and  struck  at  one  of  the  props  of  corporate  power."  But 
it  is  doubtful  if  the  Justice  will  be  able  to  convert  even  his  liberal  col- 
leagues to  such  an  advanced,  but  rational,  view.81 

In  the  session  of  1937-38,  the  Court  further  upheld  the  National  Labor 
Relations  Board  and  thus  sustained  the  operation  of  the  Wagner  Act. 
Especially  important  was  the  case  of  Myers  vs.  Bethlehem  Shipbuilding 


30  The  date  of  the  Slaughterhouse  Cases  when  the  court  refused  to  extend  the 
Fourteenth  Amendment  to  corporations. 

31  Alarmed  at  Justice  Black's  audacity,  other  judges  and  lawyers  accused  him  of 
being  woefully  ignorant  of  the  law.    But,  as  Professor  Rodell  correctly  says  of 
Justice  Black:  "He  knows  The  Law  too  well— for  what  it  really  is."  op.  cit.,  p.  196. 
For  an  authoritative  estimate  of  Justice  Black,  see  Walton  H.  Hamilton,  "Mr.  Justice 
Black's  First  Year,"  in  New  Republic,  June  8,  1938. 


416  LAW   IN  ACTION 

Corporation,  in  which  the  Court  forbade  the  granting  of  injunctions 
against  the  Board  until  the  employer  had  exhausted  all  administrative 
remedies  provided  by  law.  Civil  liberties  were  further  protected  in  the 
case  of  Nardone  vs.  United  States,  in  which  the  Court  denied  federal  law 
enforcement  agents  the  right  to  get  evidence  by  wire-tapping.  The  Na- 
tional Labor  Relations  Board  was  again  upheld  in  the  session  of  1938-39. 
Whereas  the  Court  set  aside  the  original  Agricultural  Adjustment  Act  in 
1936,  it  sustained  the  new  AAA,  passed  in  1938,  as  well  as  upholding  the 
Agricultural  Marketing  Agreement  Act  of  1937.  The  most  important 
civil  liberties  case  of  the  session  was  that  of  Hague  vs.  CJ.O.,  in  which 
the  Court  rebuked  Mayor  Hague  of  Jersey  City  for  his  various  abridge- 
ments of  civil  liberties  and  "due  process  of  law."  From  1937,  the  Court 
moved  steadily  ahead  in  limiting  the  immunity  of  official  salaries  from 
intergovernmental  taxation.  In  the  case  of  O'Malley  vs.  Woodrough  in 
1939,  the  Court  even  conceded  the  right  of  the  federal  government  to  tax 
the  salaries  of  judges  in  the  federal  courts. 

In  the  Court  session  of  1939-40,  the  National  Labor  Relations  Board 
was  further  strengthened  in  its  execution  of  the  Wagner  Act.  In  the  case 
of  Apex  Hosiery  vs.  Leader,  labor  unions  were  granted  further  immunity 
from  anti-trust  laws.  In  the  case  of  Anthracite  Coal  Co.  vs.  Adkins  the 
court  upheld  the  Bituminous  Coal  Act,  which  was  much  like  the  Guffey 
Act  of  1936,  that  the  Court  had  declared  unconstitutional.  The  power 
of  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  over  railroad  consolidations  was 
strengthened  in  the  case  of  U.S.  vs.  Lowden.  A  number  of  decisions 
further  protected  civil  liberties.  Weiss  vs.  U.8.  continued  the  ban  on 
wire-tapping.  Schneider  vs.  Irving  ton  upheld  the  right  to  distribute 
handbills  on  the  streets.  Third  degree  methods  were  denounced  in  the 
cases  of  Chambers  vs.  Florida  and  White  vs.  Texas,  in  both  of  which 
Justice  Black  wrote  the  majority  opinion.  In  the  case  of  Avery  vs. 
Alabama,  the  constitutional  right  of  a  defendant  to  counsel  was  upheld. 
But  civil  liberties  suffered  a  severe  set-back  in  the  case  of  Minersville 
School  District  vs.  Gobitis,  involving  the  rights  of  religious  minorities, 
in  this  case,  the  rights  of  Jehovah's  Witnesses.  The  decision  was  written 
by,' of  all  persons,  Justice  Frankfurter.  It  represented  a  symptom  of  the 
reactionary  trend  in  the  face  of  war  hysteria.  As  Robert  E.  Cushman 
observes,  "Mr.  Justice  Stone's  dissenting  opinion  deserves  a  place  in  the 
classic  literature  of  civil  liberty."  It  completely  pulverized  the  reason- 
ing of  Justice  Frankfurter  and  the  majority.  The  reaction  continued  in 
another  Jehovah's  Witnesses  case  in  the  1941-42  session,  when  the  Court 
upheld  the  right  of  cities  to  impose  a  license  fee  for  the  distribution  of 
non-commercial  literature. 

Another  symptom  of  the  reaction  prompted  by  defense  and  war  threats 
came  in  the  session  of  1940-41,  when  Justice  Frankfurter  read  another 
majority  decision  that  limited  the  right  of  unions  to  picket.  But,  in  the 
same  session  the  Court  upheld  the  Wages  and  Hours  Act,  holding  that 
interstate  commerce  is  wholly  within  the  control  of  Congress.  In  this 
(Darby)  case,  the  Court  opened  the  way  for  anti-child  labor  legislation 
by  specifically  overruling  Hammer  vs.  Dagenhart.  When  Justice  Frank- 


LAW   IN  ACTION  417 

furter  wrote  the  majority  decision  in  the  Phelps  Dodge  Case,  declaring 
that  the  NLRB  could  compel  employers  to  hire  men  who  had  been  re- 
fused employment  because  of  union  affiliations,  it  was  a  far  cry  from 
the  Hitchman  case  and  "Yellow  Dog"  days.  A  racial  rights  case  in  this 
session  promoted  civil  liberties.  Late  in  April,  1941,  the  Court  declared 
that  Negroes  are  entitled  to  the  same  first-class  accommodations  in 
Pullman  cars  as  white  passengers.  By  the  end  of  the  1940-41  session, 
the  Court  had  overruled  by  name  ten  important  reactionary  decisions 
and  a  number  of  others  by  implication. 

Therefore,  while  Mr.  Roosevelt  lost  his  Court  plan,  he  at  least  tempo- 
rarily accomplished  his  main  objective,  namely,  the  liberalization  of  the 
Court  and  the  protection  of  progressive  legislation.  But  it  would  have 
been  better  if  he  had  won  his  fight  for  the  Court  bill.  A  change  of  tem- 
per, due  to  current  liberal  ascendency  on  the  bench,  is  not  permanently 
dependable.*13-  Moreover,  it  does  not  touch  the  basic  evil,  namely,  the 
ability  of  the  Court  to  declare  Federal  laws  unconstitutional,  especially 
with  the  levity  invited  by  the  "due  process"  formula  and  the  conception 
of  corporations  as  persons  under  the  Fourteenth  Amendment.  At  any 
rate,  a  new  era  in  Court  history  has  been  opened,  and  its  progress  will  be 
watched  with  interest  by  all  discerning  Americans. 

Corporation  Law  and  Commercialized  Legal  Practice 

The  efficiency  of  the  Supreme  Court  and  corporations  against  legislative 
interference  has  been  made  clear.  But  a  certain  amount  of  inconvenient 
legislation  has  nevertheless  been  placed  on  the  statute  books  and  escaped 
massacre  by  the  Supreme  Court.  We  shall  in  this  section  deal  with  the 
manner  in  which  the  more  eminent  members  of  the  legal  profession  have 
aided  American  big  business  in  evading  or  safely  breaking  such  laws. 

As  Adolph  A.  Berle  has  pointed  out,  there  are  three  main  groups  of 
lawyers  in  the  United  States  today.  At  the  top  arc  the  great  legal 
partnerships  or  legal  factories,  with  their  offices  mainly  in  New  York  City 
and  Chicago.32  In  this  group,  a  firm  may  include  from  30  to  75  partners, 
as  many  as  300  associated  attorneys,  and  do  a  business  of  many  millions 
of  dollars  each  year: 

The  bulk  of  the  really  lucrative  law  business  of  the  United  States  is  probably 
transacted  by  no  more  than  three  hundred  metropolitan  law  firms.  Many  of 
these  firms  are  extremely  large,  although  importance  in  the  field  of  law  does  not 
always  depend  on  the  size  of  the  firm;  some  of  the  most  influential  legal  partner- 
ships consist  of  only  two  men. 

The  big  firms  may  include  as  many  as  fifty  to  seventy-five  partners  and  asso- 
ciates, as  well  as  a  small  army  of  salaried  employees — stenographers,  typists, 
bookkeepers,  clerks,  and  investigators,  and  in  special  instances  certified  account- 
ants, engineers,  tax  experts,  investment  consultants,  lobbyists,  and  general 
research  specialists.  The  big  firms  in  New  York,  Chicago,  Boston,  and  elsewhere 
occupy  as  much  office  space  as  a  good-sized  corporation  does.  .  .  . 

81aC/.  Raymond  Moley,  "The  Boot  Is  On  the  Other  Leg,"  News-Week,  July  29, 
1942. 

82  For  an  excellent  description  of  these  great  legal  concerns,  see  Ferdinand  Lund- 
berg,  "The  Law  Factories,"  Harper's,  July,  1939,  pp.  180  ff.  For  statistics,  see  p.  188. 
See  also  Jackson,  op.  tit.,  p.  275. 


418  LAW   IN   ACTION 

These  big  law  firms  have  sprung  up  like  shadows  alongside  the  great  corpo- 
rations and  banks.  .  .  . 

Until  fairly  recently  one  large  New  York  law  firm  regularly  adhered  to  a 
three-shift  factory  schedule  of  eight  hours  a  shift,  its  offices  never  being  dark 
except  over  week-ends.83 

Much  of  the  actual  work  in  these  big  firms  is  done  for  a  pittance  by 
recent  law-school  graduates.  The  eminent  lawyers  at  the  top  devote 
themselves  primarily  to  exploiting  their  economic,  political,  and  social 
connections  to  attract  business.  Their  social  functions  are  often  more 
important  than  their  legal  activities.  They  gain  repute  and  get  addi- 
tional business  by  attendance  at  all  elaborate  social  functions.  One 
writer  has  said  that  if  many  poor  lawyers  get  business  as  ambulance- 
chasers,  it  is  equally  true  that  top  lawyers  in  great  legal  factories  get 
much  of  their  business  as  "banquet-chasers."  These  big  firms  are  con- 
cerned chiefly  with  corporation  and  commercial  law.  Often  they  do  not 
play  an  important  part  in  actual  courtroom  work,  since  their  function  is 
mainly  to  give  advice  enabling  their  clients  to  operate  in  so  adroit  a 
fashion  as  to  keep  out  of  the  courtroom.  As  Judge  Learned  Hand  once 
said:  "With  the  courts  they  have  no  dealings  whatever,  and  would  hardly 
know  what  to  do  if  they  came  there." 

The  more  prominent  members  of  these  firms  have  tended  to  dominate 
the  bar  associations  of  the  country  and  to  keep  the  legal  philosophy  of 
the  latter  in  harmony  with  the  policies  of  big  business.  Despite  their 
vast  and  lucrative  practice,  these  lawyers  have  done  next  to  nothing 
in  the  way  of  contributing  to  substantial  legal  literature  or  public  leader- 
ship through  legal  channels,  though  some,  like  Paul  D.  Cravath  and 
Robert  T.  Swaine,  have  veritably  converted  the  technique  of  big  business, 
especially  corporate  reorganization,  into  legal  literature.  They  have  been 
the  bulwarks  of  big  business,  using  their  tremendous  influence  in  opposing 
legislation  designed  to  curb  the  freedom  of  big  business  and  corporate 
wealth.  For  example,  these  legal  luminaries  constituted  the  "front"  for 
the  Liberty  League,  organized  in  1935  to  combat  the  New  Deal. 

The  brains  behind  this  type  of  law  firm  is  what  is  known  as  "the 
lawyers'  lawyer."  He  is  a  master  of  the  technicalities  and  the  hidden 
recesses  of  the  law.  If  a  case  can  be  won  by  legal  ledgerdemain  or  suc- 
cessfully argued  on  appeal,  he  knows  how  it  can  be  done.  He  is  not 
usually  so  well-known,  honored,  or  well-paid  as  are  the  "fronts,"  often 
"stuffed  shirts,"  who  get  the  business  for  the  firm  by  hobnobbing  with 
corporate  moguls.  But  he  "delivers  the  goods"  in  putting  the  subtleties 
of  the  law  and  the  fog  of  legal  jargon  at  the  service  of  the  corporate 
interests.  Professor  Rodell  thus  describes  the  "lawyers'  lawyer." 

The  kind  of  lawyer  who  is  never  lost  for  legal  language,  who  would  never  think 
of  countering  a  legal  principle  with  a  practical  argument  but  only  with  another 
legal  principle,  who  would  never  dream  of  questioning  any  of  the  processes  of 
The  Law — that  kind  of  lawyer  is  the  pride  and  joy  of  the  profession.  He  is 
what  almost  every  lawyer  tries  hardest  to  be.  He  is  known  as  the  "lawyers' 
lawyer." 


88  Lundberg,  loc.  cit.,  July,  1939,  pp.  180-181. 


LAW   IN   ACTION  419 

Except  in  a  purely  professional  capacity,  in  which  capacity  they  can  be  both 
useful  and  expensive,  you  will  do  well  to  keep  away  from  lawyers'  lawyers. 
They  are  walking,  talking  exhibits  of  the  lawyers'  belief  in  their  own  nonsense. 
They  are  the  epitome  of  the  intellectual  inbreeding  that  infests  the  whole  legal 
fraternity. 

And  since  lawyers'  lawyers  are  the  idols  of  their  fellows,  it  is  small  wonder 
that  lawyers  take  their  Law  and  their  legal  talk  in  dead  earnest.  It  is  small 
wonder  that  they  think  a  "vested  interest  subject  to  be  divested"  or  a  frankly 
"incorporoeal  hereditament"  is  as  real  and  definite  and  substantial  as  a  brick 
outhouse.  For  the  sad  fact  is  that  almost  every  lawyer,  in  his  heart  and  in  his 
own  small  way,  is  a  lawyers'  lawyer.34 

Below  the  great  moguls  of  the  legal  profession,  and  their  sweated  clerks 
in  the  law  factories,  are  the  firms  of  from  three  to  twenty  lawyers  who 
usually  lead  in  the  actual  courtroom  practice  of  our  larger  cities.  Their 
practice  is  limited  primarily  to  the  civil  law  and  the  more  lucrative  cases 
therein.  They  also  supply  the  top  criminal  lawyers.  They  frequently 
take  a  prominent  part  in  municipal  politics  and  occasionally  make  some 
contribution  to  legal  thought  and  scholarship.84* 

The  general  evolution  of  these  two  groups  of  lawyers  and  tfre  mental 
attitudes  which  dominate  them  has  been  well  stated  by  the  distinguished 
lawyer,  Julius  Henry  Cohen: 

Since  I860  a  great  change  has  come  over  our  land.  The  nation  was  torn  with 
a  battle  over  a  great  moral  principle.  After  the  war,  a  period  of  reconstruction, 
a  period  of  commercial  prosperity  followed,  such  as  had  never  been  seen  before. 
The  brain  and  hand  of  the  lawyer  then  became  devoted  not  to  the  expounding 
of  the  law  and  the  application  of  moral  principles  in  decisions  and  legislation, 
but  to  the  formulation  of  plans,  schemes  and  contrivances  for  the  commercial 
captains  of  the  day.  Not  to  the  service  of  his  country,  but  to  the  service  of 
his  clients'  enterprises  the  lawyer  became  dedicated.  In  and  out  of  the  statutes 
he  crawled,  seeking  to  find  that  which  would  aid  his  lord,  the  great  commercial 
baron,  to  build  up  the  great  aggregations  of  wealth  now  dominant  in  this  country. 
He  was  no  longer  a  student  in  morals,  he  was  no  longer  a  groat  statesman,  a 
great  orator,  a  great  patriot.  He  became  the  servant  of  his  master.35 

It  is  obvious  that  only  the  rich  can  lay  claim  to  the  services  of  these 
two  groups  of  lawyers.  Their  fees  are  often  enormous.  A  fee  of  $1,000 
a  day  is  not  at  all  uncommon  for  court  appearances,  and  it  may  rise  much 
higher.  It  is  stated  that  William  Fox  paid  Samuel  Untermeycr  no  less 
than  a  million  dollars  in  his  fight  with  Wall  Street  moguls  and  other  movie 
companies.  Max  Steuer,  a  famous  criminal  lawyer  and  noted  also  in 
civil  practice,  said  that  he  averaged  half  a  million  dollars  a  year  in  the 
latter  part  of  his  life.  Payment  of  a  million  dollar  fee  is  not  uncommon 
in  important  public  utility  cases.  It  is  believed  that  the  largest  fee  ever 
paid  an  American  lawyer  was  one  of  some  11  million  dollars,  paid  to 
William  Nelson  Cromwell  by  the  New  Panama  Canal  Company  of  France 
for  arranging  the  sale  of  its  rights  to  the  government  of  the  United  States 
and  thus  clearing  the  way  for  the  construction  of  the  Panama  Canal. 


34  Rodell,  op.  cit.,  pp.  196-197.    Reprinted  by  permission. 

34aFor  an  extremely  interesting  and  discerning  account  of  this  type  of  legal  prac- 
tice, see  A.  G.  Hays,  City  Lawyer,  Simon  and  Schuster,  1942. 
85  Cited  in  Gisnet,  op.  cit.,  pp.  36-37. 


420  LAW   IN   ACTION 

At  the  other  extreme,  forming  the  third  group  of  lawyers — the  great 
mass  of  everyday  lawyers  who  practice  either  alone  or  in  partnership 
and  who  are  devoted  chiefly  to  criminal  law  and  to  personal  and  small 
business  affairs — one  out  of  every  ten  in  New  York  City  qualified  for 
relief  on  a  pauper's  oath  in  1935.  Adolf  A.  Berle  thus  describes  the 
range  and  composition  of  the  rank-and-file  lawyers  of  the  country: 

They  run  the  entire  gamut  from  the  lawyer  who  seeks  chiefly  to  be  a  human 
being  to  the  marching  lawyer,  who  finds  it  necessary  to  make  his  living  by  dubious 
means,  chasing  ambulances  or  carrying  on  doubtful  litigation  for  revenue  only. 
While  the  upper  limits  of  this  class  frequently  produce  unexceptionable  indi- 
viduals, the  lower  limits  in  the  great  cities  lie  dangerously  close  to  the  criminal 
class.36 

The  suitability  of  the  law  factory  to  corporate  practice,  and  the  nature 
of  its  clientele,  are  well  stated  by  Lundberg: 

The  law  factory,  a  sort  of  composite  lawyer,  offers  services  to  corporations 
whose  interests  are  far  beyond  the  capacity  of  one  lawyer  or  a  limited  group 
of  lawyers  to  handle.  The  division  of  labor  in  the  lame  law  office  is  absolutely 
necessary  to  the  well-being  of  the  giant  corporation,  which,  served  by  a  big  law 
firm,  knows  that  certain  partners  and  groups  of  partners  are  devoting  all  their 
time  to  particular  phases  of  its  business.  Furthermore,  the  corporation,  touching 
society  at  so  many  points,  is  involved  in  such  a  mass  of  cases  requiring  simul- 
taneous attention  that  a  restricted  group  of  lawyers  could  hardly  begin  to  give 
it  the  attention  it  needs.  .  .  . 

The  big  firm  usually  devotes  itself  to  the  affairs  of  the  major  corporations  in 
certain  fields,  and  may  even  specialize  in  the  type  of  corporation  it  serves.  Thus 
some  law  firms  have  among  their  clients  mainly  public-utility  holding  companies, 
chain-store  systems,  department  stores,  or  theatrical  producers;  manufacturing 
companies,  mining  corporations,  railroads,  or  holding  and  investment  companies 
and  banks.  Ordinarily  the  clientele  is  headed  by  a  bank  or  cluster  of  banks, 
after  which  the  holding  and  operating  companies  in  the  sphere  of  this  banking 
group  follow  in  logical  order.  The  private  business  that  these  firms  handle  for 
individuals  is  chiefly  derived  from  officers  or  leading  stockholders  of  such  a 
segment  of  corporations  and  banks,  or  from  members  of  their  families.87 

It  is  frequently  supposed  that  these  aristocrats  of  the  legal  profession 
never  stoop  to  solicit  business — that  more  comes  to  them  than  they  can 
take  care  of.  Mr.  Jackson  punctures  this  illusion: 

The  big  lawyer  solicits  legal  business  by  participating  in  the  acquisition  of 
business  enterprises,  utilities,  investment  trusts;  by  seeking  directorates  in  banks, 
trust  companies,  title  companies  and  other  business  corporations;  by  employing 
or  engaging  in  partnership  with  influential  lawyers,  public  officials  or  ex-public 
officials,  who  act  solely  as  business-getters.  The  little  lawyer  solicits  negligence 
and  divorce  business,  joins  clubs  and  lodges  and  seeks  publicity,  for  similar  pur- 
poses .  .  .  it  is  as  imperative  for  big  lawyers  to  get  business  to  survive  as  it  is 
for  little  lawyers  to  get  business  to  live.  The  result  is  competition  for  business, 
which  starts  with  solicitation  and  ends  in  yielding  any  barrier  of  restraining  pro- 
fessional standards  to  clients  who  seek  results  only  and  are  not  concerned  with 
methods.88 


36  Berle,  Encyclopedia  of  the  Social  Sciences,  Macmillan,  Vol.  9,  p.  342. 

87  Lundberg,  Harper's,  July,  1939,  p.  183. 

88  Jackson,  op.  tit.,  pp.  274,  275. 


LAW   IN   ACTION  421 

As  former  Chief  Justice  Frederick  E.  Crane  of  the  New  York  State 
Court  of  Appeals  pointed  out,  these  opulent  potentates  of  the  legal  pro- 
fession have  set  the  pace  for  that  commercialization  of  legal  practice 
and  legal  ideals  which  distresses  so  many  candid  students  of  the  law  in 
our  day: 

May  I  not  ask  who  has  commercialized  our  law  ?  Has  it  been  the  humble  and 
lowly  practitioner  or  the  man  at  the  top?  How  much  of  the  practice  today  is 
the  organizing  and  developing  of  business  enterprises  in  which  the  lawyer's  large 
return  is  dependent  upon  the  value  of  stocks  and  bonds,  of  which  he  has  a  part? 
How  many  of  our  lawyers  have  gone  into  business  and  are  carrying  on  business 
as  executives  and  officials  in  connection  with  their  law  offices?  I  ask  you  in  all 
fairness  whether  a  good  example  has  been  held  up  before  the  younger  members 
of  the  profession — young  men  looking  for  ideals — by  many  of  our  leading  lawyers 
who  enter  into  all  kinds  of  commercial  enterprises  to  make  money?39 

Justice  Louis  D.  Brandeis  once  observed  that  "the  leading  lawyers  of 
the  United  States  have  been  engaged  mainly  in  supporting  the  claims 
of  the  corporations:  often  in  endeavoring  to  aid  or  nullify  the  extremely 
crude  laws  by  which  legislators  sought  to  regulate  the  power  or  curb  the 
excesses  of  corporations."  40  Professor  Rodell  points  out  that  their  work 
has  had  little  relation  to  real  justice:  "The  corporations  know  and  the 
lawyers  know  that  a  master  manipulator  of  legal  mumbo- jumbo  is  a  far 
more  useful  thing  to  have  on  your  side  than  all  the  certain  and  impartial 
justice  in  the  world."  41 

Most  notable  has  been  the  work  of  these  big  legal  firms  in  making 
clear  how  the  anti-trust  laws  might  be  escaped  and  economic  control 
concentrated  in  the  hands  of  a  few  individuals.  They  are  responsible 
for  the  invention  of  the  holding  company  and  subsidiary  corporations, 
whereby  the  Sherman  Anti-trust  Law  and  the  Clayton  Act  have  been 
successfully  circumvented.  By  such  clever  devices  as  the  issuance  of 
non-voting  stock,  the  utilization  of  proxies,  voting  trusts,  and  other  legal 
hocus-pocus,  a  small  group  of  insiders  have  been  able  to  get  control  of 
our  vast  corporations  and  holding  companies,  thus  separating  ownership 
from  control  and  leading  to  all  the  numerous  abuses  of  finance  capitalism, 
which  lie  at  the  heart  of  the  evils  of  American  capitalism.42 

There  is  much  talk,  and  rightly  so,  about  the  great  burden  imposed 
upon  the  people  of  the  United  States  by  our  ordinary  crime  bill  and  the 
levies  of  racketeers.  But  little  attempt  has  been  made  to  estimate  care- 
fully just  what  the  skulduggery  of  our  great  corporate  potentates  has 
cost  the  rank  and  file  of  American  investors.  Under  the  advice  of  crafty 
lawyers,  businessmen  and  other  individuals  and  corporations,  whose  lia- 
bilities have  reached  a  somewhat  alarming  or  distressing  level,  took 
advantage  of  our  liberal  bankruptcy  laws  to  prevent  the  creditors  from 
realizing  anything  like  their  legitimate  claims  on  the  estate  and  property 


89  Cited  in  Gisnet,  op.  cit.,  p.  88. 

40  Cited  by  Ferdinand  Lundberg,  Harper's,  December,  1938,  p.  1. 

41  Op.  cit.,  p.  230. 

42  See  above,  pp.  127  ff. 


422  LAW   IN  ACTION 

of  the  bankrupt.  It  has  been  estimated  by  careful  students  of  the 
problem  that  creditors  have  been  cheated  out  of  from  500  to  800  million 
dollars  annually.  As  Ferdinand  Lundberg  puts  it: 

There  has  been  one  common  denominator  in  all  the  scandals  uncovered  in 
Washington  and  in  the  bankruptcy  courts  in  recent  years:  it  was  lawyers  who 
gave  the  advice  that  landed  their  clients  in  the  dock  before  the  country,  although 
the  lawyers  have  not  been  blamed,  have  not  even  been  regarded  as  a  social  factor, 
by  the  lawyer-legislators  and  judges  conducting  the  inquiries.  Instill,  Krueger, 
the  Van  Sweringen  brothers,  and  others  with  their  complicated  schemes,  all 
worked  through  the  medium  of  high-priced  attorneys,  but  although  the  average 
newspaper  reader  could  tell  much  about  the  principals,  it  is  doubtful  if  they  could 
mention  one  attorney  who  worked  out  the  plans  that  carne  to  grief  at  great  cost 
to  thousands  of  investors.43 

Nothing  could  be  in  worse  taste  than  the  frequent  spectacle  of  a  sleek 
and  socially  prominent  corporation  lawyer  denouncing  with  vehemence 
one  of  his  lesser  brothers  who  is  suspected  of  giving  aid  and  counsel  to 
the  leaders  of  one  of  the  conventional  American  rackets  or  of  being  in- 
volved in  ambulance-chasing.  The  difference  lies  mainly  in  the  classes 
with  which  they  work,  rather  than  in  the  ethics  of  their  acts.  The 
corporation  lawyer  advises  what  Professor  E.  H.  Sutherland  calls  "the 
white  collar  criminal/7  while  the  ambulance-chaser  gets  his  "cut"  out  of 
human  misfortunes,  and  the  lawyer-criminal  gives  advice  to  the  racketeer. 

The  bankruptcy  law  and  practice  have  been  amended  under  the  New 
Deal,  and  it  is  becoming  less  easy  to  cheat  creditors.  Strong  credit  asso- 
ciations have  sprung  up  in  most  trades,  and  the  remedies  given  by  the  new 
bankruptcy  law  are  such  that  it  is  mainly  the  fault  of  a  lawyer  if  his 
client  allows  the  bankrupt  to  "get  away"  with  anything.  But  the  un- 
represented or  incompetently  represented  creditor  can  still  be  fleeced. 

Closely  associated  with  the  bankruptcy  racket  is  the  receivership  racket. 
We  have  already  pointed  out  that  a  receivership  is  the  natural  finish  of 
the  life  history  of  one  of  our  corporations,  under  the  control  of  finance 
capitalism.  After  exploitation  has  run  its  complete  course,  the  tottering 
concern  is  thrown  into  a  receivership  and  the  exploiters,  aided  by  cor- 
poration lawyers  and  friendly  judges,  make  off  with  the  corpse.44 

Ah  extremely  remunerative  quasi-racket  associated  with  bankruptcies, 
foreclosures,  and  receiverships  is  the  fee  system.  It  is  used  by  corpora- 
tion lawyers  and  judicial  officers  alike.  The  evils  were  once  thoroughly 
exposed  by  Mitchell  Dawson  of  the  Illinois  bar  in  an  article  on  "The 
Fee  Feed-Bag"  in  The  American  Mercury.45 

The  fee  system  had  its  origin  in  the  institution  of  the  Justice  of  the 
Peace,  which  we  took  hook,  line,  and  sinker  from  Britain.  As  one  wag 
has  remarked,  this  meant  quite  literally  "paying  for  justice  by  the  piece," 
like  any  other  commodity.  The  justice  usually  gets  no  salary  and  must 
secure  his  income  from  fees.  The  justices  are  on  the  fee  system  in  most 


43  Lundberg,  Harper's,  December,  1938,  p.  5. 

44  C/.  Jackson,  op.  cit.,  pp.  225  ff.    See  above,  pp.  128-129. 

45  Loc.  cit.,  June,  1932. 


LAW   IN  ACTION  423 

of  our  states.  The  fee  system  puts  a  premium  on  conviction  and  favor- 
itism. If  the  justice  convicts  a  man  in  a  criminal  case  he  gets  his  fee 
directly  and  promptly.  If  he  acquits,  he  must  get  it  through  appeal  to  the 
county,  accompanied  by  delay  and  red  tape.  In  civil  cases,  the  justice 
will  not  get  much  work  unless  he  has  developed  a  reputation  for  de- 
pendability with  a  large  clientele  who  can  refer  cases  to  him  with  assur- 
ance. As  a  result,  it  is  a  popular  saying  in  civil  cases  that  "J.P."  stands, 
not  for  justice  of  the  peace  but  for  judgment  for  the  plaintiff. 

Far  more  serious,  however,  is  the  fee  system  as  it  operates  with  re- 
ceivers, their  attorneys,  rnasters-in-chancery  and  the  like — all  more 
powerful,  glamorous,  and  expensive  than  the  humble  justices.  There  is 
here  an  impressive  record  of  political  favoritism  in  appointments  and  of 
high  fees  rendered  for  services.  Take  bank  receiverships.  They  are 
probably  the  most  efficient  of  the  lot,  the  best  supervised,  and  the  freest 
from  political  venality.  In  the  case  of  receivers  for  closed  federal  banks 
the  Comptroller  of  the  Currency  makes  the  selections.  Yet  there  is 
plenty  of  evidence  that  even  bank  receiverships  are  often  political  plums: 

In  one  urban  district,  for  instance,  a  casual  inspection  discloses  that  bank 
receiverships  have  been  handed  out  to  a  party  leader  in  the  State  Legislature, 
a  former  public  administrator,  the  son  of  a  county  commissioner,  the  husband 
of  a  former  collector  of  internal  revenue,  a  former  treasurer  of  a  park  board,  a 
former  assistant  to  a  probate  judge.  The  political  hook-up  is  even  more  striking 
when  we  examine  a  list  of  those  appointed  as  attorneys  for  bank  receivers.46 

Even  in  the  case  of  federal  receiverships,  where  the  fees  are  supervised 
by  the  federal  courts,  vast  sums  are  eaten  up  in  fees  and  administrative 
costs:  "The  report  of  the  Attorney  General  of  the  United  States  shows 
that  the  fees  allowed  to  receivers,  trustees,  masters,  marshals  and 
attorneys  in  bankruptcy  cases  alone,  for  the  year  ending  June  30,  1931, 
amounted  to  $9,711,605,  and  that  other  expenses  of  administration  brought 
the  total  cost  to  $19,777,068  for  collecting  and  distributing  assets  valued 
at  $89,535,070.  ...  A  motley  congregation  of  parasites  swarms  through 
every  bankrupt  estate,  demanding  fees,  knowing  they  will  be  paid." 47 

Fees  in  state  bank  receiverships  are  less  controlled  than  those  in  na- 
tional bank  cases.  In  one  case,  a  bank  had  resources  of  $975,161  and 
deposits  of  $1,228,704.  Over  a  period  of  18  months  the  receiver  got 
$20,340,  his  attorney  $19,378,  and  clerical  help  $24,130.  But  not  a  cent 
in  dividends  was  paid  to  the  creditors.  Masters-in-chancery  are  espe- 
cially notorious  for  their  charges.  One  asked  $118,000  for  282  days  of 
service  of  five  hours  each.  The  court  finally  cut  it  to  $49,250. 

When  it  comes  to  such  lucrative  and  very  loosely  supervised  plums  as 
receiverships  for  business  blocks,  apartment  houses,  and  the  like,  the 
situation  has,  quite  literally,  attained  the  proportions  of  a  racket.  In 
the  case  of  one  apartment  hotel,  the  receiver  reported  a  gross  income  of 
$459,017  but  a  net  income,  before  interest,  depreciation,  and  amortization, 


^Ibid. 


424  LAW  IN  ACTION 

of  only  $4,392.  The  lax  laws  permitting  the  continuance  of  the  scandal- 
ous bankruptcy  racket  gave  rise  to  the  fact  that  an  average  of  about  ten 
cents  on  the  dollar  was  all  that  was  collected  for  creditors.  Mr.  Dawson's 
conclusions  seem  warranted  by  the  facts  he  brings  forward: 

No  reasonable  person  can  doubt  that  the  system  of  paying  public  officials 
directly  by  fees  is  wasteful  and  demoralizing,  .  ,  .  The  remedy  for  the  fee 
system,  like  that  for  any  parasitic  growth,  is  complete  excision.  .  .  .  The  public 
would  do  well  to  devote  its  energies  towards  removing  the  feed-bag  beyond  the 
hungry  reach  of  officialdom,  rather  than  to  waste  time  over  fees  that  have  already 
been  apportioned  and  consumed.48 

The  fees  received  in  corporate  reorganizations  are  even  more  out- 
rageous, and  until  recently  they  were  unrestrained.  In  the  reorganization 
of  the  Paramount-Publix  Corporation,  a  federal  judge  approved  fees  of 
over  a  million  dollars.  This  was  less  than  half  the  fees  originally  de- 
manded. In  the  reorganization  of  the  Chicago,  Milwaukee  &  St.  Paul 
Railroad,  the  lawyers'  fees  ran  between  $500,000  and  $750,000.  Over  a 
million  dollars  was  paid  the  lawyers  for  reorganizing  the  American  Bond 
and  Mortgage  Company. 

Under  the  New  Deal,  the  worst  aspects  of  the  receivership  racket  and 
cxhorbitant  fees  have  been  corrected,  in  part.  The  Securities  and  Ex- 
change Commission  now  takes  over  supervision  of  receiverships  and  reor- 
ganizations and  demands  the  disclosure  of  all  relevant  information  con- 
cerning the  acts  of  committees  and  the  like.  Railroad  receiverships  and 
reorganizations  are  supervised  by  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission. 
Both  this  body  and  the  SEC,  as  well  as  the  courts,  now  pass  on  the  fees 
charged. 

A  lucrative  racket  connected  with  the  more  elegant  phases  of  law 
practice  is  the  trust  fund  business.  Lawyers  frequently  advise  persons 
with  considerable  estates  to  hand  them  over  to  trust  companies.  This 
advice  is  given  with  apparent  disinterestedness  for  the  good  of  the  client. 
But,  all  too  often,  the  lawyer  is  acting  in  collusion  with  a  trust  company 
and  gets  a  fee  for  his  persuasive  efforts.  As  Fred  C.  Kelly  points  out 
in  his  interesting  book  on  trust  companies  and  trust  funds,  How  to  Lose 
Your  Money  Prudently:  "Another  shady  practice  which  appears  to  have 
gained  headway  is  that  of  collusion  between  lawyers  drawing  wills  and 
trust  companies  which  are  appointed  trustees  upon  their  supposedly 
disinterested  advice." 40  Mr,  Kelly  quotes  sharp  criticism  of  this  prac- 
tice by  Surrogate  Judge  George  A.  Slater  of  Westchester  County,  New 
York,  and  Henry  W.  Jessup  of  the  New  York  City  bar.50 

Mr.  Kelly's  book  affords  ample  .evidence  that  even  the  best  trust 
companies  are  all  too  often  lacking  in  sagacity  in  handling  the  portfolios 
of  securities  left  in  the  estate,  and  that  many  of  them  are  guilty  of  quasi- 
criminal  lethargy  and  indifference  to  all  responsibilities  save  for  collect- 


48  Dawson,  loc.  cit . 

49  Op.  cit.,  Swain,  1933,  p.  74. 
«°/btc*.,  pp.  74-83. 


LAW  IN  ACTION  425 

ing  their  fees  and  commissions.  Even  worse  is  the  frequent  practice  of 
unloading  on  estates  questionable  bonds,  which  are  transferred  to  trust 
accounts  through  dealings  with  a  subordinate  bond  house  affiliated  with 
the  trust  company.  Mr.  Kelly  recommends  the  following  precautions 
to  be  followed  by  those  who  insist  on  putting  estates  in  the  hands  of  trust 
companies : 

Until  such  time  as  law  courts  begin  to  show  greater  concern  for  protection  of 
the  customer  as  opposed  to  the  trust  company,  the  person  who  is  nevertheless 
willing  to  risk  his  money  in  a  trust  fund  may  at  least  protect  himself  by  observing 
the  following  half  dozen  rules: 

1.  Have  the  will  or  trust  indenture  drawn  by  an  independent  lawyer  whom 
you  have  reason  to  trust. 

2.  Never  place  a  trust  fund  in  any  bank  or  trust  company  which  has  a  bond 
department  or  is  affiliated  with  any  bond  house,  or  which  has  anything  to  sell  you. 

3.  Before  permitting  a  trust  company  to  handle  your  funds,  investigate  the 
laws  of  your  own  state  regulating  trust  companies  and  do  not  take  for  granted 
protection  not  specifically  guaranteed. 

4.  Never  make  a  will  naming  a  trust  company  your  executor  without  knowing 
in  advance  exactly  what  their  charges  are  going  to  be. 

5.  Always  remember,  in  dealing  with  a  trust  company,  that  impressive  stone 
pillars  in  front  of  a  bank  Imve  no  intelligence,  but  your  funds  will  be  handled 
by  bank  employees.    Look  into  the  experience  and  ability  of  those  men  with 
whom  you  deal. 

6.  Rid  yourself  of  the  idea,  promoted  by  trust  company  advertising,  that  a 
trust  fund  is  completely  safe,  and  be  on  your  guard,  just  as  you  would  in  any 
other  business  transaction.51 

The  leaders  of  the  first  and  second  groups  of  lawyers  whom  we  de- 
scribed at  the  outset  of  this  section  render  another  definite  service  to 
organized  corporate  wealth  in  this  country,  namely,  the  role  they  assume 
in  preparing  and  arguing  cases  involving  the  constitutionality  of  legisla- 
tion designed  to  curb  the  freedom  of  predatory  wealth  and  to  bring 
corporations  under  proper  social  control  through  legislation.  These  men 
not  only  employ  their  own  legal  acumen  and  that  of  their  underlings,  but 
also  capitalize  upon  their  public  eminence  and  their  previous  relations 
with  members  of  the  bench  of  the  federal  and  other  courts  to  influence 
the  judges  before  whom  their  argument  is  delivered.  Not  a  few  victories 
have  been  won  primarily  as  a  result  of  the  personal  prestige  and  influence 
of  the  attorney  who  appeared  before  the  court.  His  personality  is  usually 
more  potent  than  his  argument. 

While  the  great  legal  partnerships  are  still  the  most  powerful  element 
in  the  legal  profession,  they  do  not  have  the  income,  strength,  or  prestige 
that  they  did  before  1933,  and  especially  before  the  crash  of  1929.  The 
holding  companies  themselves,  which  were  the  main  source  of  their  power, 
are  disintegrating  or  have  already  been  broken  up  as  a  result  of  the 
Investment  Trust  Act,  The  Securities  Act,  the  Securities  and  Exchange 
Act,  the  Public  Utility  Holding  Company  Act,  and  the  like.  Their  in- 
vestment clients,  the  bankers,  who  were  mainly  responsible  for  the  power 


Op.  cit.,  pp.  102-103 


426  LAW   IN  ACTION 

of  the  corporation  lawyers,  have  also  lost  out  in  the  process.  Competitive 
bidding,  registration  rules,  supervision  of  underwriting  and  legal  fees, 
restrictions  on  corporate  acts,  and  adverse  judgments  of  courts  in  stock- 
holders' suits  have  broken  the  spell  and  shattered  the  power  of  both  the 
holding  companies  and  the  investment  banks. 

Having  surveyed  briefly  the  activities  and  interests  of  the  two  classes  of 
lawyers  at  the  top  of  the  legal  profession,  we  may  now  turn  to  the  doings 
of  the  third  main  group  of  lawyers,  the  great  majority  who  make  up  the 
rank-and-file  practitioners  of  law. 

Activities  and  Methods  of  Rank-and-File  Lawyers 

Ironically,  the  current  decline  in  legal  ethics  and  the  mounting  evils  of 
legal  practice  have  come  about  at  a  time  when  lawyers  are  far  better 
educated  and  have  a  vastly  superior  professional  training  than  at  any 
previous  time  in  American  history.  Only  a  generation  ago  lawyers  were 
not  required  to  attend  a  law  school.  They  were  permitted  to  "read  law" 
in  the  office  of  some  practicing  attorney  and  then  take  a  not  too  exacting 
bar  examination.  Today,  all  lawyers  must  have  professional  training, 
and  the  better  law  schools  are  graduate  schools,  admitting  only  students 
who  have  a  bachelor's  degree.  And  the  bar  examinations  are  becoming 
ever  more  stringent.  In  spite  of  this,  there  are  far  more  lawyers  prac- 
ticing today  than  ever  before.  Their  numbers  have  grown  at  a  rate  even 
faster  than  the  growth  of  American  population  or  the  evolution  of 
American  business.  There  are,  at  the  present  time,  nearly  200,000  prac- 
ticing lawyers  in  the  United  States.  There  are  around  12,000  students 
in  the  law  schools  of  New  York  City  alone  as  compared  with  some  2,700 
in  1916.  The  New  York  Law  Journal  thus  described  the  situation  back 
in  1928,  when  there  were  fewer  lawyers  and  law  students  than' today: 

The  law  schools  are  turning  out  the  young  lawyers  more  rapidly  even  than 
Henry  Ford  turned  out  the  old  model  of  the  Tin  Lizzie.  Lawyers  shoot  forth 
as  speedily  as  meteors  across  the  heaven  on  a  clear  July  night.52 

In  the  same  way  that  the  growth  of  corporate  wealth,  power,  venality, 
and  avarice  have  been  the  chief  causes  of  the  corruption  of  legal  practice 
among  the  rich  leaders  of  the  profession,  so  the  large  increase  in  the 
rank-and-file  of  practicing  attorneys  has  been  an  outstanding  cause  of 
the  evils  which  prevail  in  the  activities  of  the  great  majority  of  practicing 
lawyers  today.  The  condition  has  been  aggravated  by  the  fact  that,  at 
the  very  moment  when  lawyers  became  much  more  numerous  than  pre- 
viously, the  possible  forms  of  employment  for  the  average  lawyer  have 
been  greatly  curtailed  by  the  development  of  new  trends. 

Title,  guaranty,  and  trust  companies  are  taking  over  more  and  more 
work  in  the  real  estate  business,  such  as  the  searching  of  titles,  convey- 
ancing of  properties,  and  the  drawing  up  of  mortgages.  The  handling 


52  Cited  in  Gisnet,  op.  cit.f  p.  45 


LAW  IN  ACTION  427 

of  the  estates  of  deceased  persons  is  being  handed  over  ever  more  fre- 
quently to  trust  companies.  Credit  and  collection  agencies  are  getting 
more  and  more  of  the  business  involved  in  the  collection  of  delinquent 
accounts.  Casualty  companies  are  constantly  appropriating  an  ever 
larger  section  of  the  business  involved  in  negligence  cases.  While  trust 
companies  and  the  like  have  to  employ  trained  lawyers  to  $o  their  work, 
efficient  methods  and  the  handing  over  of  a  good  deal  qf  the  work  to 
accountants,  and  others  not  technically  lawyers,  greatly  reduces  the 
number  of  attorneys  necessary.  Moreover,  the  abuses  and  delays  in 
courtroom  practice  are  leading  more  and  more  lawyers  to  recommend  to 
their  clients  that  they  settle  cases  out  of  court,  often  a  commendable 
procedure  but  one  which  cuts  in  seriously  on  the  trial  work  hitherto  open 
to  lawyers.  A  less  serious  invasion  of  previous  legal  activities  is  to  be 
seen  in  the  juvenile  court,  which  is  becoming  ever  less  of  a  criminal  court, 
and  where  the  lawyer  is  being  superseded  by  the  psychiatrist  and  the 
social  worker. 

The  desperate  economic  situation  of  the  lesser  lawyers  in  the  country 
which  has  grown  jointly  out  of  the  increase  in  the  number  of  lawyers  and 
the  curtailment  of  the  scope  of  legal  employment  has  been  well  described 
by  I.  Maurice  Wormser: 

To  a  large  degree  the  troubles  among  the  Metropolitan  lawyers  arise  from 
economic  causes.  The  lawyer  has  seen  himself  slowly  stripped  of  a  vast  amount 
of  legal  practice.  The  practice  of  law  in  many  fields  is  no  longer  a  matter  for 
attorneys.  Powerful  and  wealthy  corporations  boldly  trespass  upon  the  licit 
domains  of  lawyers.  The  title  companies,  the  insurance  companies,  the  trust 
companies,  the  powerful  corporations,  are  spreading  their  tentacles  around  an 
apparently  helpless  profession.  The  defense  of  negligence  suits  has  been  taken 
over  almost  entirely  by  corporations.  The  handling  of  wills  and  estates  is  no 
longer  the  province  of  the  lawyer.  Great  corporations  do  sixty  per  cent  of 
corporate  law  work.  We  can  remember  when  title  searching  was  the  forte  of 
the  attorney.  Today,  except  in  the  rural  districts,  title  searching  has  passed 
out  of  lawyers'  hands.  The  prosecution  of  claims  now  provided  for  by  the 
Workmen's  Compensation  Law  has  closed  another  field  of  practice  formerly  open. 
Arbitration  and  conciliation  have  made  vast  strides.  In  some  important  in- 
dustries, as  for  example,  the  silk  trade,  litigation  is  becoming  unknown.  The 
illegal  practice  of  law  among  foreigners,  particularly  notaries  public  and  com- 
missioners of  deeds,  is  another  encroachment.  Last,  but  not  least,  attorneys  are 
faced  with  an  ever  growing  influx  of  Portias,  some  of  whom  are  remarkably 
efficient  and  all  of  them  are  willing  to  work  for  excessively  low  wages.  In  the 
light  of  all  this,  can  it  be  doubted  there  is  ground  for  economic  discontent?  Is 
there  any  room  for  question  that  the  lawyers'  domain  is  being  lessened?  Can 
any  fair-minded  person  question  that  the  conditions  arising  from  this  cause  are 
serious?  53 

As  only  a  fortunate  few  can  gain  access  to  the  charmed  circle  of  lawyers 
who  control  the  lucrative  practice  of  corporation  and  commercial  law, 
the  ever-increasing  number  of  lawyers  have  to  get  out  and  hustle  simply 
to  make  a  living.  The  lawyers  are  handicapped  by  the  fact  that,  like 
doctors,  they  are  prevented  by  the  ethics  of  the  legal  profession  from 


68  Cited  in  Gisnet,  op.  cit.,  pp.  52-54. 


428  LAW  IN  ACTION 

overt  advertising.  This  is  a  strange  restriction,  in  the  light  of  the  highly 
elastic  character  of  legal  ethics.  Nevertheless,  it  is  a  taboo  respected  by 
the  majority  of  lawyers.  While  there  are  a  certain  number  of  petty  real 
estate  and  other  business  cases  which  may  be  picked  up  by  these  lesser 
lawyers,  their  main  field  is  what  we  know  as  negligence  cases,  chiefly 
accidents  of  one  sort  or  another.  Prior  to  1920,  most  of  these  accidents 
were  industrial  accidents.  When  automobile  accidents  began  to  out- 
number all  others  of  a  serious  character,  they  dominated  negligence  prac- 
tices, which  now  closely  approximates  the  proportions  and  methods  of  a 
legal  racket. 

The  methods  employed  to  drum  up  negligence  cases  have  been  as 
diversified  and  obvious  as  the  desperation  of  the  lawyer's  economic  con- 
dition implies.  Most  notorious  is  "ambulance-chasing."  Lawyers  hire 
"runners"  whose  job  is  to  be  on  the  scene  of  the  accident  first,  to  contact 
the  injured  party  and  possible  witnesses.  The  runner  turns  over  the 
information  to  the  lawyer,  who  then  makes  a  proposal  to  the  injured 
person  on  the  basis  of  what  is  known  as  the  contingent  fee  principle.  He 
agrees  to  bring  action  for  damages  for  a  fixed  proportion  of  the  sum 
awarded,  usually  half  of  the  damages. 

The  essential  elements  of  success  in  ambulance-chasing  are  closely 
knit  organization  and  great  speed  in  operation.  The  core  of  the  operating 
force  are  the  runners,  who  are  most  effective  in  conjunction  with  "fixed" 
policemen  who  tip  off  the  runners  often  before  reporting  the  accident  to 
headquarters.  Usually  the  lawyer  employs  at  least  two  runners,  and  if 
they  are  alert,  they  will  bring  in  30  good  hospital  cases  a  year,  represent- 
ing a  gross  business,  on  the  average,  of  $300,000. 

Many  of  the  luminaries  of  corporation  law  develop  a  fine  sense  of 
indignation  against  the  so-called  ambulance-chasers.  But  the  latter  have 
often  rendered  a  real  service  to  the  poor,  who  would  not  be  able  to  get  any 
legal  assistance  otherwise.  Half  the  damages  is  better  than  nothing  at 
all.  This  was  particularly  true  before  workmen's  compensation  laws 
were  put  on  the  statute  books.  But  in  most  states  injured  persons  still 
need  a  lawyer  to  represent  them  even  since  compensation  laws  have  been 
passed.  The  employers  or  the  insurance  company  are  represented  by 
clever  attorneys  and  the  claimant  is  at  a  great  disadvantage  unless  he 
has  good  legal  advice. 

The  ambulance-chasing  lawyers,  operating  on  a  contingent  fee  basis, 
are  a  nuisance  mainly  when  they  abuse  the  system.  All  too  often  a 
veritable  racket  develops.  Doctors  and  hospital  employees  are  corrupted 
and  given  their  "cut-in."  There  is  no  regard  for  fact  or  reality.  One 
dancer  hurt  her  head  in  a  taxi  accident,  but  the  racketeer-lawyer  sued 
for  damages  due  to  fallen  arches,  since  the  dancer's  feet  were  more 
valuable  than  her  head. 

Lawyers  will  freely  take  the  cases  of  guilty  persons  in  automobile  acci- 
dents and  urge  them  to  bring  suit  for  damages.  In  one  not  unusual  case, 
known  to  the  writer,  an  irresponsible  and  drunken  individual  pulled  out 
of  the  line  of  traffic  and  smashed  into  a  careful  driver  who  was  proceeding 


LAW   IN  ACTION  429 

on  his  side  of  the  road.  It  was  a  plain  case  of  criminal  negligence  and 
there  were  witnesses  to  the  accident  to  testify  thereunto.  The  guilty 
party  should  certainly  have  received  a  jail  sentence.  But  the  person  he 
injured  had  insurance.  A  shyster  lawyer  took  the  case,  sued  for  damages, 
and  the  jury,  believe  it  or  not,  awarded  damages  to  a  man  who  should 
have  been  imprisoned  for  recklessness.  There  are  thousands  of  such 
cases  annually  in  the  United  States.  It  is  in  instances  of  this  sort,  which 
bring  about  a  gross  miscarriage  of  justice,  that  ambulance-chasing  is  a 
nuisance  which  should  be  suppressed. 

By  and  large,  however,  casualty  companies  and  insurance  adjusters  are 
guilty  of  just  as  reprehensible  practices.  This  fact  was  well  brought  out 
by  Judge  Wasservogel: 

The  evidence  before  me  shows  that  casualty  companies,  transportation  com- 
panies and  corporate  defendants  have  engaged  in  practices  eaually  reprehensible. 
Frequently  the  insurance  adjuster  races  with  the  ambulance  chaser  to  the  bedside 
of  the  injured  person  to  obtain  a  release  from  him  while  he  is  overwrought  and 
in  pressing  need  of  money.  If  a  release  cannot  be  obtained,  the  injured  person 
is  asked  to  sign  a  statement  of  the  circumstances  of  the  accident  or  is  plied  with 
questions.  The  oral  or  written  statements  extracted  do  not  present  a  fair  or 
complete  picture.  Nevertheless  they  are  used  against  the  plaintiff  at  the  trial 
with  exaggerated  and  harmful  effect.  Furthermore,  the  representatives  of  some 
corporate  defendants  have  not  hesitated  to  effect  settlements  directly  with 
claimants  whom  they  knew  to  be  represented  by  attorneys.  This  practice  is 
unfair  to  such  attorneys  and  deprives  the  clients  of  the  benefit  of  their  advice.54 

A  new  development  which  takes  millions  from  innocent  people  yearly 
is  the  so-called  "faked-claims  racket,"  in  which  there  has  either  been  no 
accident  at  ,all  or  the  accident  has  been  staged  for  the  purpose  of  launch- 
ing a  damage  suit.  Its  victims  are  found  chiefly  among  the  relatively 
ignorant,  poor,  and  helpless,  for  a  rich  man  usually  turns  such  matters 
over  to  his  lawyer  for  investigation.  But  even  in  such  cases  the  crooks 
often  clean  up,  for  juries  are  prone  to  be  sympathetic  with  the  fakery 
artists  whose  tricks  they  do  not  understand.  The  general  pattern  of  the 
racket  is  made  clear  by  Robert  Monaghan: 

If  youVe  got  a  job  or  a  small  business,  if  you  are  a  professional  man  or  if  you 
demonstrate  solvency  in  any  other  way,  you're  an  easy  target  for  these  little 
squeeze  plays. 

Once  the  claim  artist  has  the  facts  on  your  ability  to  pay  he  can  slip  behind 
your  automobile  and  swear  you  struck  him  down.  He  can  trip  on  your  sidewalk, 
stumble  over  your  doorsill,  declare  your  dog  chewed  a  piece  out  of  his  thieving 
hide  or  work  any  of  a  dozen  other  dodges.55 

Some  of  this  fake-claims  racket  is  carried  on  by  lone  wolves,  and  often 
they  "make  a  killing."  But  most  of  the  extortion  is  carried  on  by  a  well- 
organized  syndicate,  usually  headed  by  a  lawyer  in  good  standing  as  a 
member  of  the  bar.  He  has  a  whole  staff  at  his  call — other  lawyers, 
runners,  doctors,  hospital  attendants,  X-ray  technicians,  and  professional 


54  Gisnet,  op.  cit.,  p.  77. 

ss  "The  Fake  Claims  Racket,"  Forum,  February,  1940,  pp.  87-91. 


430  LAW  IN  ACTION 

perjurers.  Some  of  these  syndicates  have  regular  accident-faking  head- 
quarters. Such  was  the  "House  of  Pain"  maintained  by  a  Pittsburgh 
syndicate,  which  cleaned  up  millions  of  dollars  before  it  was  closed  up. 

The  most  extreme  examples  of  this  racket,  but  not  uncommon  ones, 
represent  complete  fakery.  A  man,  upon  going  to  his  parked  car,  for 
example,  may  find  himself  accosted  by  men  with  a  damaged  car.  The 
innocent  party  will  be  accused  of  having  caused  the  damage.  He 
protests  the  fraud,  but  to  no  avail.  A  suit  is  threatened  and,  unless  the 
man  has  an  impregnable  alibi,  his  lawyer  will  usually  advise  him  to  settle 
the  case  out  of  court  for  a  hundred  dollars  or  so.  Submitting  to  this 
extortion  is  cheaper  than  defending  the  case  in  court,  for  nobody  can 
guess  how  erratic  a  jury  may  be,  even  though  the  fraud  is  palpable. 

The  fake-claims  racket  meets  little  opposition  from  "the  strong  arm 
of  the  law/'  since  its  minions  are  often  in  on  the  "cut."  The  greatest 
progress  in  breaking  up  the  racket  has  been  made  by  a  private  organiza- 
tion— the  Association  of  Casualty  and  Surety  Executives,  whose  fraud- 
fighting  department  is  known  as  the  Claims  Bureau.  This  has  succeeded 
in  putting  the  fear  of  God  into  the  racketeers  in  some  cities,  notably 
Boston. 

In  order  to  rake  up  criminal  cases,  lawyers  frequently  have  rustlers  who 
circulate  in  the  magistrates'  courts,  snooping  for  cases  which  they  report 
to  the  attorney.  Bondsmen,  court  attendants,  and  policemen  also  call 
criminal  cases  to  the  attention  of  such  lawyers.  Frequently  the  lawyer 
himself  hangs  around  courtrooms  when  he  is  not  busy  and  looks  for 
cases.  Raymond  Moley  describes  such  procedure: 

The  lawyer  himself  is  active  in  the  scramble  for  cases.  He  sometimes  comes 
to  the  court  daily,  deposits  his  coat  and  hat  immediately  upon  arrival,  and 
participates  in  the  activities  exactly  as  though  he  were  a  paid  attache.  He  chats 
with  policemen,  bondsmen,  attendants,  even  the  magistrate.  He  mingles  freely 
with  the  unfortunates  who  are  waiting  in  the  court,  and  so  gets  business  first- 
hand. He  has,  with  two  or  three  others  who  monopolize  most  of  the  cases  in 
that  particular  court,  a  permanent  status  there.  He  is  a  "regular."  He  is  as 
definitely  a  part  of  the  court  machinery  as  the  clerk,  the  prosecutor  and  the 
judge.68 

The  worst  abuses  in  connection  with  rustling  criminal  cases  take  place 
when  victims  are  actually  framed  and  then  ruthlessly  exploited  by 
shyster  lawyers.  Professor  Moley  recounts  a  characteristic  case: 

According  to  the  testimony  of  one  witness  who  was  "framed,"  her  lawyer 
answered  her  protests  over  the  huge  fee  demanded  by  saying,  "Now  don't  worry, 
my  child,  I'm  not  one  of  those  who  just  plunder  people/' 

Reassured,  she  paid  him  $150  on  account.  Before  the  trial,  however,  he 
continued  to  remind  her  that  though  he  had  influence  in  court  she  must  give  him 
more  money  or  he  could  do  nothing  for  her.  She  paid  him  $100  more.  Half 
an  hour  before  her  trial  he  called  her  to  his  office  and  said,  "If  -you  do  not  give 
me  $100  more  immediately,  something  will  happen." 

The  terrified  woman  promised  to  scrape  together  half  that  amount.    This  she 


se  The  New  York  Times,  May  3,  1931. 


LAW   IN  ACTION  431 

gave  him  after  she  had  been  tried  and  discharged.  But  the  lawyer  insisted  that 
she  owed  him  "the  rest  of  the  $100."  This,  too,  was  handed  over  and  the  woman 
finally  got  a  receipt  for  payment  in  full.  The  matter  did  not  end  there,  however. 
She  continued  to  receive,  by  letter  and  telephone,  regular  demands  for  more 
money.  When  the  lawyer  was  questioned  he  declared  that  he  did  not  recall 
how  much  this  client  had  paid  him.  He  thought,  however,  that  "there  was  a 
little  balance  still  due."  57 

In  the  old  days,  the  criminal  lawyer  who  defended  anybody,  whether 
guilty  or  not,  was  looked  upon  as  being  at  the  bottom  of  the  legal  ladder, 
from  the  standpoint  of  legal  ethics.  But  he  has  since  been  nosed  out  of 
the  legal  cellar  by  what  is  now  known  as  the  lawyer-criminal,  namely, 
the  lawyer  who  gives  advice  to  organized  criminals  and  racketeers.  In 
the  olden  times,  the  smart  criminal  was  one  who  got  an  able  lawyer  to 
defend  him  after  he  committed  a  crime.  But  today,  taking  a  leaf  out  of 
the  book  of  the  corporate  mogul,  the  bright  racketeer  gets  a  lawyer  before 
he  commits  a  crime.  Most  organized  crime  today  is  committed  on 
advice  of  counsel.  The  broad  similarity  between  this  procedure  and 
corporation  law  practice  has  been  pointed  out  by  Mr.  Jackson: 

Nor  does  the  public  mind  any  longer  distinguish  between  the  gangster-lawyer 
and  the  banker-lawyer  in  this  respect.  It  knows  that  in  these  instances  the 
racketeer  and  his  lawyer  have  merely  adopted  the  methods  and  practices  of  our 
best  people  for  their  own.  The  racketeer  who  asks  a  lawyer  to  set  up  an  alibi 
for  him  before  he  goes  out  "to  knock  off  a  rival  gangster"  is  emulating  the 
financiers  who  retain  counsel  to  advise  them  how  they  can  sell  watered  securities 
or  gilded  bonds  of  an  insolvent  and  defaulting  South  American  republic  to  a 
gullible  public,  without  liability  to  themselves.  The  gangsters  are  merely  stealing 
the  methods  of  respected,  church-going  leaders  of  industry  who  brag  that  they 
hire  lawyers  to  tell  them  what  laws  they  need  not  respect.  What  difference  is 
there,  asks  John  Q.  Public,  between  the  lawyer  who  advises  the  banker  how  he 
can  avoid  the  penalties  of  a  Securities  Act,  and  the  lawyer  who  tells  a  gangster 
how  he  can  avoid  the  provisions  of  an  extortion  statute  ? 58 

The  bar  expresses  little  indignation  over  legal  services  rendered  to  the 
moguls  of  gangland.  As  Mr.  Lundberg  says:  "Al  Capone  and  other 
eminent  gangsters  had  the  same  set  of  skilled  lawyers  over  a  long  period 
6f  years,  and  the  courts  have  yet  to  express  astonishment  at  counsellors 
appearing  time  and  again  in  court  for  the  same  thugs."  59  Indeed,  as 
Jackson  and  Lundberg  point  out,  the  lawyer  is  all  but  immune  from 
punishment  for  giving  advice  that  lands  his  client  in  jail.60  Professor 
Rodell  insists  that  a  lawyer  can  get  away  with  almost  anything,  provided 
he  observes  the  correct  legal  etiquette — that  is,  plays  the  game  according 
to  legal  rules: 

What  the  lawyers  care  about  in  a  judge  or  a  fellow  lawyer  is  that  he  play  the 
legal  game  with  the  rest  of  them — that  he  talk  their  talk  and  respect  their  rules 
and  not  go  around  sticking  pins  in  their  pretty  principles.  He  can  be  a  New 


57 Ibid.;  cf.  Jackson,  op.  cit.,  pp.  155 ff. 

58  Jackson,  op.  cit.,  p.  261. 

69  Harper's,  April,  1939,  p.  521. 

60  Jackson,  op,  cit.,  p.  263;  and  Lundberg,  Harper's,  December,  1938,  pp.  3,  5. 


432  LAW   IN  ACTION 

Dealer  or  a  Ku  Kluxer  or  a  Single  Taxer  or  an  advocate  of  free  love,  just  so 
long  as  he  stays  within  the  familiar  framework  of  legal  phraseology  in  expressing 
his  ideas  and  prejudices  wherever  they  happen  to  impinge  on  The  Law.61 

While  pointing  out  these  offenses  against  both  justice  and  common 
decency,  we  should  not  fail  to  call  attention  to  the  numerous  public- 
spirited  lawyers  of  high  ability  who  have  generously  given  their  time 
and  talents  in  behalf  of  the  poor  and  downtrodden.  Clarence  Darrow 
was  the  most  conspicuous  example,  but  he  did  not  by  any  means  stand 
alone.  But  such  a  public-spirited  lawyer  risks  his  reputation  and  prac- 
tice. The  distinguished  Chicago  lawyer,  W.  P.  Black,  who  defended  the 
Chicago  anarchists  back  in  1886,  was  all  but  ruined  professionally.  And 
the  equally  distinguished  Boston  attorney,  William  G.  Thompson,  who 
defended  Sacco  and  Vanzetti,  saw  his  practice  cut  in  half.62 

In  spite  of  the  large  and  increasing  number  of  lawyers  and  their 
desperate  scramble  to  make  a  living,  Mr.  Lundberg  usefully  emphasizes 
the  fact  that  we  would  probably  need  twice  as  many  lawyers  as  we  have 
today,  if  the  masses  were  as  well  served  by  the  bar  as  are  the  classes. 
The  reason  that  the  mass  of  the  lawyers  now  find  it  hard  to  make  a  living 
is  that  the  bulk  of  the  people  who  need  lawyers  do  not  have  enough 
income  to  pay  them.  As  Mr,  Lundberg  puts  it: 

In  relation  to  the  inability  of  most  people  to  pay  for  legal  services  under  the 
present  dispensation,  it  is  true  that  there  are  too  many  lawyers.  But  in  relation 
to  the  social  need  for  the  services  of  lawyers  the  country  could  probably  use  a 
bar  with  twice  the  present  number.63 

Probably  this  is  all  academic,  however,  since  only  in  a  just  and  efficient 
economic  system  could  the  masses  afford  to  pay  for  needed  legal  aid; 
but  in  such  a  system  they  would  require  little  legal  advice.  Russia 
virtually  gets  along  without  any  lawyers. 

Some  Outstanding  Defects  in  the  Criminal   Law 

Grave  as  may  be  the  defects  in  our  civil  law,  from  the  large  scale 
dignified  corruption  of  corporation  law  practice  to  the  petty  venality  of 
ambulance-chasing,  students  of  law  and  sociology  alike  agree  that  the 
practice  of  criminal  law  represents  the  most  debased  and  vulgar  area  of 
legal  practice  and  courtroom  procedure.  The  subject  has  been  handled 
in  admirable  and  comprehensive  fashion  by  Professor  Raymond  Moley  in 
his  book  on  Our  Criminal  Courts. 

The  whole  philosophy  of  criminal  law,  namely,  the  attempt  to  find  a 
punishment  to  fit  the  crime,  rather  than  the  right  treatment  to  fit  a 
particular  criminal,  is  archaic,  wrong-headed,  and  brutal.  Some  head- 
way has  been  made  in  the  way  of  getting  indeterminate  sentence  laws, 
but  such  success  as  has  been  achieved  here  has  been  mainly  in  the  case  of 
juvenile  delinquents.  For  the  most  part,  the  judges  still  impose  a  time 


61  Rodell,  op.  cit.,  p.  196.    Reprinted  by  permission. 

62  Lundberg,  "The  Priesthood  of  the  Law/'  Harper's,  April,  1939,  p.  524. 

63  "Thp    Lpornl    Prnfo«rairm  "    f? rimer's     Dpppmhpr     1Q2fl     n.    14. 


LAW   IN  ACTION  433 

sentence,  though  it  is  becoming  more  common  to  impose  a  maximum  and 
minimum  sentence,  the  time  actually  served  to  depend  upon  the  conduct 
of  the  convict. 

The  first  stage  of  criminal  procedure  in  this  country  is  characterized 
by  gross  lawlessness  and  brutality.  We  refer  to  the  Third  Degree,  which 
the  police  apply  to  suspects  after  arrest  in  order  to  obtain  a  confession  of 
guilt.  The  Third  Degree  has  been  the  subject  of  more  heated  interchange 
of  invective  than  any  other  phase  of  contemporary  criminal  jurispru- 
dence in  the  United  States.  Reformers  have  charged  that  it  is  universal 
in  police  practice,  while  the  police  have  hotly  contended  that  it  is  the 
exception.  There  had  been  no  comprehensive  study  of  the  actual  facts, 
over  the  country  as  a  whole,  until  Ernest  Jerome  Hopkins  reported  the 
situation  for  the  Wickersham  Commission.  Emanuel  Lavine's  excellent 
volume  The  Third  Degree  is  a  vivid  book,  but  it  was  based  too  much 
upon  local  New  York  evidence  to  constitute  a  decisive  indictment  of  the 
system  through  the  nation  as  a  whole.  The  same  was  true  of  the  ex- 
cellent report  submitted  by  the  Bar  Association  of  New  York,  some  time 
back.  Mr.  Hopkins,  however,  made  a  thorough  sampling  of  the  situation 
throughout  the  country  and  his  report  certainly  proved  that  the  brutal 
application  of  third  degree  methods  is  so  wide-spread  that  it  may  be 
declared  a  general  characteristic  of  American  police  procedure.04  Mr. 
Hopkins  found  that  about  five  out  of  every  six  cases  of  arrested  suspects 
are  settled  in  outlaw  police  tribunals,  either  by  forced  confessions,  which 
the  trial  court  simply  ratifies,  or  by  release  by  the  police.  As  Mr.  Hop- 
kins puts  it:  "The  outlaw  pre-trial  inquisition  by  police  is  by  all  odds 
our  predominating  trial  court  in  point  of  fact."  In  other  words,  the 
majority  of  our  criminal  jurisprudence  is  quite  literally  official  vigilante 
justice. 

The  Hopkins  report  was  in  no  way  surprising  to  close  students  of 
criminal  justice.  It  only  furnished  authoritative  confirmation  of  what 
such  students  knew  to  be  the  case.  The  police  employ  diverse  methods 
of  torture  to  secure  confessions:  beating;  whipping;  deprivation  of  sleep, 
food,  and  water;  electric  carpets,  rods  and  chairs;  and  various  types  of 
psychic  deception  and  intimidation.  Many  fatalities  have  resulted.  The 
Supreme  Court  of  Virginia  was  restrained  when  it  said  of  typical  third 
degree  practices:  "The  evidence  of  the  police  officers  as  to  the  manner  in 
which  the  alleged  confession  of  the  accused  was  obtained  reads  like  a 
chapter  from  the  history  of  the  Inquisition  of  the  Middle  Ages." 

The  lawlessness  of  the  police  inquisition  and  the  Third  Degree  may  be 
seen  from  the  comparison  of  the  actual  police  procedure  with  the  formal 
law  in  the  circumstances.  The  law  states  that:  (1)  the  police  shall 
secure  adequate  evidence  before  arrest;  (2)  they  shall  promptly  produce 
the  accused  before  a  magistrate  to  be  arraigned  and  committed  or  re- 
leased; (3)  the  police  may  not,  under  the  ban  of  the  Fifth  and  Fourteenth 
Amendments,  even  subject  the  accused  to  questioning  as  to  his  guilt; 


64  This  report  was  amplified  and  published  as  Our  Lawless  Police,  Viking  Press, 
1931. 


434  LAW   IN   ACTION 

and  (4)  all  matters  pertaining  to  the  decision  as  to  the  innocence  or  guilt 
of  the  accused  shall  be  left  to  a  jury  of  his  peers,  presided  over  by  an 
impartial  jurist. 

This  raises  the  vital  question  of  the  justification  of  the  Third  Degree. 
Is  it  essential  to  the  ascertainment  of  guilt?  The  answer  may  be  given 
in  the  form  of  a  categorical  negative.  Mr.  Hopkins,  for  example,  found 
that  the  English  court  records  do  not  yield  one  reference  to  third  degree 
methods  in  the  last  twenty  years.  We  need  not  assume  that  there  have 
been  no  instances  of  its  use  in  Britain,  but  it  surely  is  not  characteristic 
of  English  criminal  justice,  yet  England  has  a  far  better  record  as  to 
crime  repression  than  we  have.  If  the  Third  Degree  can  be  justified  at 
all,  it  is  only  under  the  same  conditions  that  vindicated  the  Vigilantes  of 
frontier  days;  namely,  its  use  in  areas  and  periods  where  orderly  legal 
justice  cannot  be  obtained.  It  is  conceivable  that,  in  certain  American 
cities  today,  a  decay  of  lawful  justice  exists  which  approaches  the 
anarchy  of  the  frontier.  It  is  possible  that  effective  repression  of  crim- 
inals, especially  lesser  henchmen  of  racketeers,  can  be  accomplished  in 
such  localities  only  through  resort  to  third  degree  practices.  If  so,  then 
each  police  commissioner  who  tolerates  such  methods  should  publicly 
announce  what  he  is  doing  and  why.  This  would  accomplish  a  quadruple 
good:  (1)  It  would  direct  public  attention  to  the  demoralization  of  our 
judges  and  courts;  (2)  it  would  compel  the  commissioner  to  prove  his 
case  or  reform  his  ways;  (3)  it  would  let  the  crooks  know  just  what  to 
expect  if  seized  by  a  policeman;  and  (4)  it  would  let  the  people  know 
what  they  must  insist  upon  if  they  desire  civilized  justice. 

Certainly  any  permanent  or  habitual  use  of  the  Third  Degree  is  incom- 
patible with  either  science  or  humanity.  The  case  was  well  stated  by 
the  late  Judge  Cuthbert  Pound,  formerly  chief  justice  of  the  New  York 
State  Court  of  Appeals,  one  of  the  ablest  of  American  jurists.  In  re- 
versing the  conviction  of  John  Barbato,  he  wrote: 

Lawless  methods  of  law  enforcement  should  not  be  countenanced  by  our  courts, 
even  though  they  may  seem  expedient  to  the  authorities  in  order  to  apprehend 
the  guilty.  Whether  a  guilty  man  goes  free  or  not  is  a  small  matter  compared 
with  the  maintenance  of  principles  which  still  safeguard  a  person  accused  of 
crime. 

Nowhere  is  there  a  greater  departure  from  the  formal  theory  of  the 
dignity  and  earnestness  of  the  law  and  its  administration  than  in  the 
antics  of  lawyers  in  criminal  courtrooms.  There  is  every  type  of  horse- 
play, cunning,  ingenuity,  and  the  like,  designed  to  win  the  case.  There 
is  little  regard  for  the  facts  and  slight  interest  in  seeing  that  justice  is 
done.  The  rules  governing  the  admission  and  exposition  of  evidence  are 
better  suited  to  obscuring  the  facts  than  they  are  to  revealing  and  em- 
phasizing them.  We  shall  have  more  to  say  about  this  later  in  the  section 
on  the  jury  trial.  Further,  the  wealthy  defendant  has  the  same  ad- 
vantage in  the  criminal  courtroom  that  he  has  in  the  field  of  civil  litiga- 
tion. He  has  the  money  to  hire  not  only  a  very  clever,  but  also  a  very 
influential,  lawyer  whose  extra-courtroom  connections  may  be  even  more 


LAW   IN  ACTION  435 

important  than  his  adroitness  and  eloquence  within  the  courtroom.  The 
poor  man  must  be  content  either  with  the  best  lawyer  he  can  afford  to 
hire  or  with  the  perfunctory  defense  put  up  by  the  lawyer  assigned  by 
the  court  to  defend  him. 

The  prevalence  of  what  has  been  called  "bargain-counter  justice"  was 
brought  out  in  the  Report  of  the  New  York  State  Crime  Commission  on 
the  crimes  and  sentences  of  prisoners,  of  which  Sam  A.  Lewisohn  was  the 
chairman.  In  the  year  1931,  at  least  70  per  cent  of  the  convicts  received 
in  state  penal  institutions  in  New  York  had  not  been  convicted  in  a  jury 
trial.  They  had  made  pleas  of  guilty  to  lesser  offenses  than  those  for 
which  they  had  been  indicted,  and  their  pleas  had  been  accepted.  There 
is  often  little  exact  relationship,  at  present,  between  the  crimes  for  which 
persons  are  arrested  in  New  York  State  and  those  for  which  they  are 
convicted.  The  reason  for  this  is  the  absurd  and  savage  system  of  severe 
mandatory  sentences  produced  by  our  hysteria  about  the  crime  wave. 
Judges  with  some  spark  of  decency  and  humanity  hesitate  to  impose  the 
atrocious  sentences  made  mandatory  for  a  particular  crime.  Hence,  as 
the  New  York  Report  puts  it,  they  are  prone  to  accept  a  plea  of  guilty 
for  a  lesser  crime: 

It  is  as  if  the  courts  themselves,  realizing  almost  instinctively  the  essential 
injustice  inherent  in  these  mandatory  sentences  turned  with  relief  to  any  methods, 
however  clumsy,  to  avoid  imposing  such  long  inflexible  terms  of  punishment. 
In  so  doing  they  unconsciously  often  rendered  the  whole  system  of  prison 
sentences  absurd  and  gave  to  the  prisoners  and  their  families  a  sense  of  being 
able  to  frustrate  or  evade  any  of  the  laws  of  punishment  and  correction. 

This  system  is  particularly  vicious,  in  that  it  gives  a  special  advantage 
to  the  clever  and  experienced  criminal  who  has  already  had  contact  with 
our  criminal  law  and  knows  enough  to  get  an  astute  lawyer  who  will 
help  him  to  make  the  best  possible  bargain  with  the  judge  and  district 
attorney.  The  Report  gives  a  number  of  representative  cases  indicating 
the  unfairness  of  the  system  as  it  operates  today.  One  man  who  had 
fired  shots  to  kill  in  the  robbery  for  which  he  was  indicted,  admitted  that 
he  already  had  participated  in  48  other  robberies.  A  plea  of  guilty  of 
robbery,  third  degree,  was  accepted  and  the  man  was  given  an  inde- 
terminate sentence  of  from  three  to  six  years  in  a  state  prison.  Another 
man,  with  no  previous  criminal  record,  held  up  a  store  and  got  away  with 
some  $600  in  cash  and  jewelry.  No  shots  were  fired.  He  entered  a 
plea  of  guilty  of  robbery,  first  degree,  and  was  sentenced  to  state's  prison 
for  from  15  to  30  years  with  an  additional  sentence  of  from  5  to  10 
years  for  the  use  of  a  gun.  In  another  case,  a  man  with  accomplices 
entered  a  man's  home,  beat  him  up  so  severely  that  he  required  major 
medical  attention  for  six  weeks,  and  robbed  him  of  his  money.  The 
assailant  was  indicted  for  robbery,  first  degree,  assault,  first  degree,  petty 
larceny,  and  receiving  stolen  goods.  A  plea  of  robbery,  third  degree, 
was  accepted  and  he  was  sentenced  to  the  Elmira  Reformatory.  In  two 
years,  he  would  be  eligible  for  release  on  parole.  Another  mah  with  an 
armed  accomplice  held  up  a  leather  shop  clerk  and  stole  some  $200. 


436  LAW  IN  ACTION 

He  stood  trial  for  robbery  in  the  first  degree,  was  convicted,  and  sen- 
tenced to  state  prison  to  from  15  to  30  years. 

Absurd  discrepancies  like  these  could  be  multiplied  indefinitely.  The 
Report  wisely  suggests  the  logical  remedy,  namely,  that  the  judge  shall 
impose  automatically  the  maximum  sentence  provided  by  law  for  the 
crime.  Then  the  power  of  release  should  be  transferred  to  the  Board  of 
Parole,  with  authority  to  act  at  any  time  after  the  convicted  person  has 
served  one  year  in  a  penal  or  reformatory  institution.  The  Report  em- 
phasizes the  utter  illogicality  which  prevails  today  in  our  system,  where 
the  sentencing  judge  is  allowed  to  consider  only  the  crime,  ignoring  the 
offender,  while  the  parole  board  is  expected  to  consider  the  offender 
rather  than  the  crime.  This  logical  contradiction  brings  confusion  and 
inefficiency  into  our  system  of  criminal  jurisprudence,  from  the  moment 
of  arrest  until  the  final  discharge  of  the  convict. 

The  way  our  conventional  criminal  jurisprudence  deals  with  insanity 
and  the  mental  capacity  of  the  accused  is  literally  a  travesty.  In  most 
states  it  is  almost  impossible  for  an  expert  in  medical  psychology  to 
present  straightforward  and  relevant  evidence  in  the  courtroom.  He 
can  only  answer  the  questions  put  to  him,  and  they  are  adroitly  framed 
to  bring  out  the  points  desired  by  the  examining  lawyers.  He  can  never 
present  the  well-organized  and  unified  report  that  he  would  set  forth  in 
dealing  with  a  case  in  private  practice.  The  legal  test  of  insanity — that 
is,  the  question  whether  or  not  a  person  can  distinguish  between  right  and 
wrong  and  recognize  the  consequences  of  his  acts — bears  no  important 
relationship  to  the  scientific  medical  notions  of  mental  disease.  Plenty 
of  psychopathic  people  have  no  serious  impairment  of  mental  powers  but 
are  quite  incapable  of  normal  social  conduct  in  the  face  of  inciting  cir- 
cumstances. This  is  especially  true  of  paranoids  and  those  suffering  from 
compulsion  psychoses  and  neuroses. 

Massachusetts  was  the  first  commonwealth  to  eliminate  the  worst 
obstacles  to  the  introduction  of  medical  science  in  the  courtroom.  Here 
the  burlesque  and  horseplay  involved  in  the  legal  examination  and  cross- 
Sxamination  of  psychiatrists  have  been  done  away  with.  The  accused 
man  is  thoroughly  examined  by  an  accredited  psychiatrist  from  the  State 
Department  of  Mental  Diseases,  and  a  careful  report  is  drawn  up  and 
available  when  the  trial  opens.  The  doctor  functions  in  the  courtroom 
as  he  might  when  dealing  with  a  private  patient.  His  only  incentive  is 
the  ascertainment  of  truth  and  he  suffers  no  significant  handicap  in  setting 
it  forth  for  the  benefit  of  the  court. 

In  sentencing  prisoners,  judges  follow  the  wrong-headed  principle  of 
trying  to  make  a  punishment  fit  a  crime,  and  they  indulge  in  the  most 
irresponsible  arbitrariness  in  imposing  sentences  for  a  -given  crime.  The 
writer  once  made  a  special  study  of  variations  in  sentencing  for  similar 
crimes  in  the  same  state  and  in  the  same  era.  The  grossest  discrepancies 
were  found — among  sentences  imposed  by  different  judges  for  the  same 
crime  as  well  as  among  sentences  imposed  by  the  same  judge  for  identical 
crimes.  Sound  criminal  science  shows  the  desirability  of  varying  the 


LAW   IN  ACTION  437 

sentence  for  a  given  crime,  according  to  the  personality  of  the  convict 
and  the  conditions  surrounding  the  crime.  There  is  little  evidence,  how- 
ever, that  these  considerations  weigh  at  all  heavily  with  sentencing  judges. 
Far  more  potent  are  the  reactions  they  develop  toward  the  defendant 
during  the  trial  and  the  general  state  of  their  digestive  tract  at  the 
moment  of  sentencing.  Judges  also  differ  widely  in  the  extent  to  which 
they  use  their  opportunity  to  prescribe  punishments  other  than  imprison- 
ment. F.  J.  Gaudet,  G.  S.  Harris,  and  Charles  W.  St.  John  once  studied 
the  sentences  imposed  during  a  nine-year  period  by  six  judges  in  one 
New  Jersey  county.  The  following  table  shows  the  results  of  their 
study: 65 

PERCENTAGE  OF  EACH  KIND  OF  SENTENCE  GIVEN  BY  EACH  JUDGE 

Judge  1  Judged  Judge 8     Judged  Judged  Judged 

Imprisonment    .35.6%        33.6%        53.3%        57.7%      45.0%      50.0% 

Probation    28.5  30.4  20.2  19.5         28.1         32.4 

Fined     2.5  2.2  1.6  3.1  1.9  1.9 

Suspended    33.4  33.8  24.3  19.7         25.0         15.7 

No.  of  cases 1235  1693  1869  1489          480          676 

The  Travesty  of  the  Jury  Trial 

There  is  hardly  a  more  respected  institution  in  American  life,  except 
for  the  Christian  Church  and  the  Supreme  Court,  than  our  customary 
jury  trial.  And  probably  there  is  not  a  greater  obstacle  to  the  scientific 
determination  of  fact  in  legal  disputes  and  criminal  cases.  Few,  if  any, 
of  our  legal  practices  contribute  more  to  the  prevalence  of  miscarriages 
of  justice.  . 

In  the  selection  of  the  panel,  a  definite  number  of  names  are  drawn  at 
random  from  a  collection  of  slips  or  cards  bearing  the  names  of  all  the 
qualified  citizens  of  the  county.  In  some  cases  the  theory  of  a  choice  by 
lot  has  become  a  legal  fiction,  and  accommodating  commissioners  of 
juries  have  been  known,  for  a  reasonable  consideration,  to  draw  the  names 
of  the  men  desired  by  either  district  attorneys  or  lawyers  for  the  defense. 
When  a  "fixed"  panel  supplies  a  jury,  the  outcome  of  the  trial  may  be  all 
but  settled  before  a  single  witness  has  been  summoned.  But  even  when  a 
panel  is  honestly  selected,  it  conforms  precisely  to  the  dubious  doctrine 
that  special  training  is  in  no  way  essential  to  competence  in  the  handling 
of  public  affairs.  It  is  drawn  from  the  very  classes  from  which  a  mob 
might  be  raised  by  the  Ku  Klux  Klan. 

In  the  choice  of  the  actual  jury  from  the  panel,  we  can  observe  a  process 
that  may  be  called  counter-selection.  The  obviously  more  intelligent  and 
abler  members  of  the  panel,  drawn  from  the  business  and  professional 
classes,  are,  for  the  most  part,  automatically  excused  from  service,  leaving 
only  the  farmers,  cobblers,  barbers,  clerks,  hodcarriers,  and  day-laborers. 


65  Gaudet,  Harris,  and  St.  John,  "Individual  Differences  in  the  Sentencing  Tend- 
encies of  Judges,"  Journal  of  Criminal  Law  and  Criminology,  January-February, 
1933,  p.  816. 


438  LAW   IN  ACTION 

These  men  are  then  questioned  forthwith  as  to  whether  they  have  read 
about  or  formed  any  opinion  concerning  the  case.  Those  who  answer  in 
the  affirmative  are  likewise  automatically  disqualified.  Any  honest  man 
with  a  modicum  of  literacy  is,  in  significant  cases,  compelled  to  give  an 
affirmative  answer.  Thus  the  choice  of  jurymen  in  important  trials  is 
actually  limited,  for  the  most  part,  to  the  illiterates  and  the  liars. 

Naturally,  the  attorneys  for  both  sides  want  a  jury  which  will  be, 
a  priori,  as  favorable  as  possible  to  their  side.  Therefore,  they  challenge 
all  jurymen  who,  because  of  party  affiliation,  religious  belief,  class  mem- 
bership, or  nationality,  may  possibly  be  against  them.  If  the  defendant 
is  a  prominent  Democrat,  the  district  attorney  naturally  desires  a  Re- 
publican jury;  likewise  a  Catholic  defendant  calls  for  a  heavy  represen- 
tation of  Methodists  and  Baptists.  With  a  "Red"  on  trial,  the  district 
attorney  tries  to  get  a  jury  of  bank  clerks  and  stock  brokers,  while  the 
counsel  for  the  defense  labors  to  secure  venircmen  who  admire  W.  Z.  Foster 
and  Earl  Browder.  The  liberal  legal  arrangements  for  challenging  with- 
out cause,  and  the  practically  unlimited  right  of  challenging  for  cause, 
make  this  maneuvering  easy.  Only  an  exactly  equal  balancing  of  oppor- 
tunity, favoritism,  knowledge,  and  wits  on  the  part  of  the  opposing 
barristers  can  prevent  it.  The  jury  is  thus  often  "fixed,"  "hand-picked," 
or  composed  of  the  most  colorless  and  feeble-minded  of  the  illiterates  and 
liars. 

The  jury,  after  a  few  days  of  excitement  or  bewilderment  in  the  new 
atmosphere,  settles  down  into  a  state  of  mental  paralysis  which  makes  it 
practically  impossible  for  the  majority  of  its  members  to  concentrate 
upon  the  testimony  and  rulings  of  the  court.  The  farmer  wonders 
whether  his  hens  are  being  fed;  the  drummer  bemoans  his  lost  sales  and 
"dates."  Awakened  from  time  to  time  from  this  state  of  distraction  by 
the  unusual  beauty,  volubility,  resonance,  or  obscenity  of  the  witnesses 
and  testimony,  the  jurymen  pounce  upon  some  irrelevant  bit  of  testimony 
and  forget  or  overlook  the  most  significant  facts  divulged  by  the  witnesses. 
Thus  we  have,  in  a  typical  jury  trial,  the  testimony  of  the  witnesses  and 
the  rulings  of  the  judge  presented  to  a  group  of  colorless  men  drawn  from 
the  least  intelligent  elements  in  the  population  who  have  lapsed  into  a 
mental  state  which  all  but  paralyzes  the  operation  of  their  normally 
feeble  intellects.  As  Ferdinand  Lundberg  observes: 

The  underlying  aim  of  the  lawyer  in  a  great  majority  of  cases  seems  to  be  to 
fill  the  jury  box  with  a  well-balanced  aggregation  of  the  feebleminded.  Only  a 
reasonable  limitation  upon  his  peremptory  challenges  keep  him  short  of  complete 
success.66 


66  Harper's,  December,  1938,  p.  13.  For  a  more  favorable  view  of  juries,  see  the 
article  "Just  How  Stupid  Are  Juries?"  ibid.,  pp.  84  ff.  For  an  able  lawyer's  account 
of  his  experiences  on  a  jury,  see  William  Seagle,  "Confessions  of  a  Juror,"  Coronet, 
March,  1941,  pp.  136-138.  Probably  the  most  complete  and  authoritative  critique 
of  the  jury  trial  is  Judge  Irvin  Stalmaster's  What  Price  Jury  Trials?  Stratford,  1931. 
See  also,  Jerome  Frank,  Law  and  the  Modern  Mind,  Brentano,  1930,  pp.  170-185, 
302-09;  and  Leon  Green,  Judge  and  Jury,  Vernon  Law  Book  Co.,  Kansas  City,  Mo., 
1930. 


LAW   IN   ACTION  439 

The  situation  as  regards  the  testimony  itself  is  scarcely  more  satis- 
factory. Psychologists,  following  the  pioneer  work  of  Hugo  Munsterberg, 
have  proved  time  and  again  that  the  most  honest  and  intelligent  eye- 
witnesses, having  observed  an  act  in  question  leisurely  and  directly,  are 
unable  to  testify  about  it  with  exactitude  or  unanimity. 

The  testimony  normally  produced  in  a  courtroom  is  much  inferior  to 
that  brought  forth  in  carefully  controlled  psychological  tests.  Usually 
eye-witnesses  are  scarce,  and  they  are  rarely  persons  of  intelligence.  As 
likely  as  not,  they  are  among  the  "undesirable  citizens"  of  the  community, 
who  would  not  be  believed  under  oath  if  they  were  disgorging  from  any 
other  vantage-point  than  the  witness  chair.  But  even  these  inferior 
persons,  with  their  inadequate  information,  are  rarely  allowed  to  testify 
in  a  straightforward  fashion.  The  technical  rules  of  evidence  often  pre- 
vent their  being  permitted  to  tell  the  most  pertinent  things  they  know. 
On  the  other  hand,  counsel  may  seduce  them  into  making  all  sorts  of 
vague  insinuations — or  even  precise  statements — about  things  of  which 
they  know  practically  nothing. 

But  even  this  is  not  the  worst  of  it.  Witnesses  are  usually  as  carefully 
coached  by  counsel  as  prize  speakers  in  a  rhetorical  contest.  Often  the 
"best"  type  of  witness  is  one  who  knows  nothing  about  the  case  and  so 
may  be  coached  from  the  beginning  to  tell  a  coherent  story.  Convictions 
or  confessions  of  perjury  in  all  sorts  of  cases,  from  the  celebrated  Mooney 
case  to  the  equally  notorious  one  of  Sacco  and  Vanzetti,  have  demon- 
strated the  frequency  of  this  building  up  of  "impressive"  testimony  by 
counsel  and  witness  without  the  slightest  factual  basis.  One  of  the  in- 
justices of  our  criminal  procedure  is  that,  in  a  conviction  for  perjury,  the 
witness  alone,  instead  of  the  witness  and  counsel  together,  is  punished. 
But  even  accurate  testimony  by  witnesses  of  highest  intelligence  and 
undisputed  veracity  would  be  wasted  upon  the  illiterate,  inattentive,  dis- 
tracted jury. 

Hence  the  outcome  is  essentially  this:  a  number  of  individuals  of 
average  or  less  than  average  ability,  who  could  not  tell  the  truth  if  they 
wanted  to,  who  usually  have  little  of  the  truth  to  tell,  who  are  not  allowed 
to  tell  even  all  of  that,  and  who  are  frequently  instructed  to  fabricate 
voluminously  and  unblushingly,  present  this  largely  worthless,  wholly 
worthless,  or  worse  than  worthless  information  to  twelve  men,  who  are 
for  the  most  part  unconscious  of  what  is  being  divulged  to  them,  and  would 
be  incapable  of  an  intelligent  interpretation  of  the  information  if  they 
had  actually  heard  it. 

In  case  there  is  intelligent,  pertinent,  and  damaging  testimony  and  a 
few  competent  jurymen  who  have  slipped  by  the  lawyers  unchallenged, 
the  lawyer  whose  side  seems  likely  to  lose  tries  to  obscure  the  significance 
of  the  testimony  and  divert  the  attention  of  the  jurymen  from  it.  Every 
form  of  inflammatory  oratorical  appeal  is  permitted  by  the  rules,  and  so 
is  every  type  of  effort  to  stir  the  prejudices  of  the  jurymen.  The  jury 
may  even  be  covertly  threatened  with  mob  reprisal  if  it  does  not  render 
a  certain  type  of  verdict.  Particularly  in  closing  appeals  is  this  rhetorical 


440  LAW  IN  ACTION 

gaudiness  utilized.  If  the  evidence  as  a  whole  is  strongly  unfavorable,  the 
lawyer  is  likely  to  ignore  the  testimony  altogether  and  appeal  solely  to 
the  emotions  of  the  jury.  And  to  the  average  jury,  an  emotional  appeal 
is  far  more  potent  than  a  factual  demonstration.  F.  L.  Wellman  thus 
described  the  contribution  to  juridical  objectivity  and  scientific  crimi- 
nological  accuracy  made  by  one  J.  J.  Parker,  a  venerable  and  learned 
barrister  of  Mobile,  Ala.: 

Once,  while  he  was  defending  a  case  in  the  criminal  court  in  Mobile,  and  during 
the?  argument  of  the  prosecuting  attorney,  who  was  a  rather  prosy  man,  Parker 
moved  his  chair  around  so  as  to  be  under  the  judge's  desk  and  behind  the 
speaker,  so  that  neither  could  see  him.  But  he  was  in  full  sight  of  the  jury. 
After  a  short  time  he  began  to  nod  his  head  as  though  very  drowsy,  and  to  tilt 
his  chair  back  until  it  looked  as  if  he  would  fall  backwards.  He  would  then  make 
a  little  start  and  right  his  chair,  and  then  pretend  to  go  to  sleep  again,  much  to 
the  amusement  of  the  jury.  The  prosecutor  realized  that  something  was  going 
on  to  distract  the  attention  of  the  jury,  because  their  faces  were  covered  with 
broad  grins  in  spile  of  his  solemn  argument.  Finally,  Parker  lost  his  balance 
and  fell  over  backwards,  making  a  good  deal  of  commotion.  The  bystanders, 
who  had  been  enjoying  the  scene  as  much  as  the  jurors,  broke  into  uncontrollable 
laughter,  which  was  joined  in  by  the  jury,  and  the  prosecutor's  argument  was 
completely  destroyed.07 

Perhaps  the  most  instructive  thing  about  the  modern  jury  trial  is  that 
neither  the  district  attorney  nor  the  counsel  for  the  defense  is  vitally 
interested  in  the  hard  facts.  The  district  attorney  wants  to  convict, 
whether  the  defendant  is  guilty  or  not;  the  counsel  for  defense  wants  an 
acquittal,  whether  his  client  is  innocent  or  not.  Moreover,  it  is  the  jury 
which  invites  the  lavish  use  of  money  in  hiring  expensive  counsel  to  ob- 
scure facts  and  create  fiction — that  transition  in  trials  which  Hobhouse 
describes  as  the  substitution  of  battle  by  purse  for  the  ancient  battle  by 
person.  Before  a  group  of  trained  experts,  the  dramatics  of  high-priced 
counsel  would  have  about  as  much  standing  as  the  pulpit  gymnastics 
of  Billy  Sunday. 

The  technical  rulings  on  law  are  often  as  ineffective  before  the  jury  as 
is^the  testimony.  The  average  juryman  knows  little  of  the  law,  and 
almost  invariably  misses  the  significance  of  the  judge's  interpretation  of 
it.  Sometimes  even  when  the  rulings  are  simple,  explicit,  and  direct,  the 
jury  brazenly  ignores  them.  In  one  interesting  case,  a  judge  instructed 
the  jury  to  bring  in  a  verdict  in  a  certain  manner,  unless  they  felt  that 
they  knew  more  about  the  law  than  he  did.  Astonished  when  they  dis- 
regarded his  advice,  he  reminded  them  of  his  charge.  Whereupon  the 
foreman  responded,  "Well,  Jedge,  I  reckon  we  considered  that  point,  too." 
Especially  futile  are  the  rulings  with  respect  to  the  rejection  of  evidence 
that  has  actually  been  presented.  If  a  juryman  has  really  been  impressed 
with  the  testimony,  in  not  one  case  out  of  ten  will  he  be  influenced  by  a 
subsequent  ruling  of  the  judge  that  it  is  irrelevant  and  must  be  excluded 
from  consideration.  At  the  other  extreme,  as  we  have  seen,  the  prejudices 


67  F.  L.  Wellman,  Gentlemen  of  the  Jury,  Macmillan,  1924,  p.  153. 


LAW   IN   ACTION  441 

of  the  judge  may  be  so  determined  and  persistent  as  to  override  the  im- 
port of  the  evidence.  If  the  judge  is  both  adroit  and  impressive,  he  may 
exert  a  greater  influence  over  the  jury  than  all  the  testimony  submitted 
during  the  trial. 

The  burlesque  upon  science  and  justice  which  trial  by  jury  thus  presents 
is  carried  from  the  courtroom  to  the  room  where  the  jury  deliberates. 
Here  it  can  and  often  does  ignore  the  instructions  of  the  judge  and  all  the 
testimony  presented,  and  its  decision  is  based  on  the  prejudices  of  the 
members.  In  a  notorious  murder  trial  in  New  Jersey  the  jury  frankly 
disregarded  all  the  testimony,  knelt  in  prayer,  and  then  found  a  unani- 
mous verdict  for  the  defendant.  The  case  was  unique  only  in  regard  to 
the  frankness  of  the  jury's  confession  of  the  method  it  pursued  and  the 
publicity  which  that  confession  received  in  the  press.  Even  when  a  jury 
is  reasonably  alert  in  following  the  testimony,  the  desirable  results  of 
such  an  unusual  phenomenon  may  be  destroyed  by  the  presence  upon  the 
panel  of  a  powerful  and  impressive  personality  or  an  unusually  stubborn 
moron.  Innumerable  miscarriages  of  justice  have  been  due  to  the  con- 
version of  the  jury  to  the  point  of  view  of  a  prejudiced  but  convincing 
orator,  or  to  the  presence  of  a  juror  who,  through  bias,  bribery,  or  stupid- 
ity has  held  out  against  the  judgment  of  his  eleven  colleagues.  The  most 
elementary  psychology  makes  it  clear  that  even  if  twelve  able  men  were 
on  the  jury,  they  could  rarely  come  to  a  concise,  definite,  well-reasoned 
agreement  based  upon  a  study  of  the  same  body  of  facts. 

William  Seagle  suggests  that  the  presence  of  a  dominant  personality 
on  a  jury  may  often  aid  the  cause  of  justice.  He  holds  that:  "The  whole 
jury  system  rests  upon  the  theory  that  in  every  group  of  twelve  men  there 
will  be  at  least  one  who  is  not  a  moron."  Mr.  Seagle's  thesis  is  doubtless 
sound  when  the  able  juror  is  a  trained  lawyer  and  a  good  psychologist, 
such  as  Mr.  Seagle,  but  the  vigorous  figure  who  sways  his  fellow  jurors  is 
more  likely  to  be  a  strong-willed  amateur,  often  bigoted  and  prejudiced. 
In  such  cases,  his  influence  is  likely  to  be  even  more  mischievous  and 
prejudicial  to  justice  than  the  "deliberations"  of  the  eleven  "morons." 

We  have  thus  the  spectacle  of  a  "fixed"  or  "selected"  jury,  or  one  of 
colorless  liars  and  illiterates  deciding  the  matter  of  the  corporeal  existence, 
public  reputation,  property  rights,  or  personal  freedom  of  a  fellowman 
upon  the  basis  of  prayer,  lottery,  rhetoric,  debate,  stubbornness,  or  intimi- 
dation, in  ignorance  or  defiance  of  legal  rulings  which  they  do  not  under- 
stand and  of  testimony,  perhaps  dishonest,  which  they  have  only  imper- 
fectly followed,  and  from  an  intelligent  comprehension  of  which  they 
have  been  diverted  by  the  emotional  appeals  of  counsel. 

If  one  protests  against  the  accuracy  of  this  picture  by  the  allegation 
that  most  verdicts  are,  nevertheless,  sound  and  that  such  a  result  could 
scarcely  be  expected  from  so  grotesque  a  procedure  as  we  have  described, 
the  first  answer  would  be  the  query  as  to  how  one  knows  a  particular 
verdict  is  a  correct  one.  The  majority  of  our  convicted  murderers  go  to 
the  chair  bawling  protestations  of  innocence,  while  many  obviously  guilty 
ones  are  freed.  There  being  under  our  system  an  opportunity  only  for 


442  LAW  IN  ACTION 

a  verdict  of  guilty  or  not  guilty,  by  the  mathematical  laws  of  chance 
verdicts  should  be  right  in  50  per  cent  of  all  cases.  There  is  no  proof 
whatsoever  that  more  than  half  of  our  jury  verdicts  are  accurate,  or  that 
the  majority  of  those  which  are  sound  are  such  for  any  other  reason  than 
pure  chancfe.  An  equally  satisfactory  result  might  be  obtained  far  less 
expensively,  and  in  a  more  expeditious  and  dignified  manner,  simply  by 
resort  to  dice  or  the  roulette  wheel.  The  writer  would  be  quite  willing 
to  defend  the  thesis  that,  insofar  as  accuracy  and  justice  are  concerned, 
the  modern  jury  trial  is  scarcely  superior  to  the  ordeal  or  trial  by  battle. 
Those  who  feel  convinced  of  the  relatively  high  accuracy  of  jury  ver- 
dicts and  believe  that  the  jury  trial  promotes  justice  will  do  well  to  read 
the  careful  book  of  Edwin  M.  Borchard  Convicting  the  Innocent,™  which 
presents  representative  examples  in  which  jury  verdicts  were  completely 
overthrown  by  the  facts  as  later  demonstrated.  Among  these  cases  are 
several  in  which  persons  had  been  convicted  of  murder  only  to  have  the 
supposed  victim  turn  up  hale  and  hearty.  Professor  Borchard  has  been 
a  leader  among  those  who  believe  that  the  state  should  make  restitution 
to  those  wrongfully  convicted  of  crime. 

Suggested  Reforms  in  Legal   Practice  and 
Courtroom   Procedure 

It  is  obvious  that  legal  reform  is  mandatory,  if  we  hope  to  provide 
justice  for  the  mass  of  Americans.  The  lawyers  have  already  done  much 
to  wreck  American  democracy  and  economic  solvency.  If  they  persist 
in  their  policies  and  methods  and  these  destroy  our  present  system  of 
society,  they  will  bring  ruin  on  themselves.  In  totalitarian  societies  the 
legal  profession  is  either  abolished  or  thoroughly  subordinated  to  the 
political  system.  This  warning  to  lawyers  to  repent  and  put  their  house 
in  order  is  thus  phrased  by  Mr.  Lundberg : 

A  poetic  penalty  awaits  the  legal  profession  in  the  event  that  its  clients  of  the 
past  combine  to  abolish  the  democratic  state,  either  by  force  or  by  stealth.  For 
upon  the  abolition  of  the  democratic  state  will  surely  follow  the  abolition  of  the 
legal  profession,  as  in  Russia,69  or  its  reduction  in  status  to  a  very  mean  level, 
as  in  Germany  and  Italy. 

Essentially  the  same  warning  is  given  by  Mr.  Jackson: 

The  law  dominates  or  the  sword  rules.  That  is  the  choice,  and  examples  are 
on  our  doorstep.  Weaken  the  law,  temper  its  honesty  of  administration,  and 
the  tramp  of  marching  feet  grows  louder.  Strengthen  it,  make  its  application 
just  and  curative,  and  visions  of  marching  hosts  grow  dim.70 

Mr.  Jackson  suggests  a  number  of  sensible  reforms,  among  which 
are  the  following:  (1)  inform  and  educate  the  public  on  legal  problems, 
so  that  they  will  demand  improvement;  (2)  simplify  the  law  and  reduce 


68  Yale  University  Press,  1932. 
«•  Harpers,  April,  1939,  p.  526. 
70  Jackson,  op.  cit.,  p.  347. 


LAW  IN  ACTION  443 

its  technicalities;  (3)  insist  upon  civil  service  qualifications  for  legis- 
lators; (4)  work  out  a  proper  division  of  labor  between  courts  and 
administrative  commissions  and  tribunals;  (5)  secure  better  legal  talent 
not  only  to  assist  clients  but  also  to  come  to  the  aid  of  judges;  (6)  remove 
the  judiciary  from  politics,  so  far  as  is  possible;  and  (7)  improve  the 
content  and  standards  of  legal  education. 

Professor  Rodell  does  not  believe  that  any  such  ameliorative  reform 
will  turn  the  trick.  He  contends  that  we  must  get  rid  of  The  Law  and 
lawyers,  bag  and  baggage,  and  adopt  common-sense  and  direct  methods 
of  handling  social  relations  in  our  urban-industrial  age : 

What  is  to  be  done  about  the  fact  that  we  are  all  slaves  to  the  hocus-pocus  of 
The  Law — and  to  those  who  practice  the  hocus-pocus,  the  lawyers? 

There  is  only  one  answer.  The  answer  is  to  get  rid  of  the  lawyers  and  throw 
the  Law  with  a  capital  L  out  of  pur  system  of  laws.  It  is  to  do  away  entirely 
with  both  the  magicians  and  their  magic  and  run  our  civilization  according  to 
practical  and  comprehensible  rules,  dedicated  to  non-legal  justice,  to  common-or- 
garden  fairness  that  the  ordinary  man  can  understand,  in  the  regulation  of  human 
affairs. 

It  is  not  an  easy  nor  a  quick  solution.  It  would  take  time  and  foresight  and 
planning.  But  neither  can  it  have  been  easy  to  get  rid  of  the  medicine  men  in 
tribal  days.  Nor  to  break  the  strangle-hold  of  the  priests  in  the  Middle  Ages. 
Nor  to  overthrow  feudalism  when  feudalism  was  the  universal  form  of  govern- 
ment. .  .  . 

A  mining  engineer  could  handle  a  dispute  centering  about  the  value  of  a  coal 
mine  much  more  intelligently  and  therefore  more  fairly  than  any  judge,  untrained 
in  engineering,  can  handle  it.  A  doctor  could  handle  a  dispute  involving  a  physi- 
cal injury  much  more  intelligently  and  therefore  more  fairly  than  any  judge, 
untrained  in  medicine,  can  handle  it.  A  retail  merchant  could  handle  a  business 
dispute  between  two  other  retail  merchants  much  more  intelligently  and  there- 
fore more  fairly  than  any  judge  can  handle  it.  A  man  trained  in  tax  adminis- 
tration could  have  handled  Senior  v.  Braden  much  more  intelligently  and  there- 
fore more  fairly  than  the  Supreme  Court  handled  it.  In  short,  even  discounting 
for  the  moment  the  encumbrances  of  legal  doctrine  that  obstruct  the  straight- 
thinking  processes  of  every  judge,  the  average  judge  is  sadly  unequipped  to  deal 
intelligently  with  most  of  the  problems  that  come  before  him.  .  .  .  Why  should 
we  keep  on  sacrificing  both  justice  and  common  sense  on  the  altar  of  legal  prin- 
ciples? Why  not  get  rid  of  the  lawyers  and  their  Law?  .  .  .  Why  not  let  the 
people  really  involved  in  any  squabble  tell,  and  try  to  prove  to  the  satisfaction 
of  the  decision-makers,  their  own  lies?  Commissions  have  often  found  it  far 
easier  to  discover  the  true  facts  behind  any  dispute  by  dispensing  with  the 
lawyers'  rules;  arbitrators  have  found  it  easier  still  by  dispensing  with  the 
lawyers.  .  .  . 

If  only  the  average  man  could  be  led  to  see  and  know  the  cold  truth  about 
the  lawyers  and  their  Law.  With  the  ignorance  would  ^go  the  fear.  With  the 
fear  would  go  the  respect.  Then  indeed — and  doubtless  in  orderly  fashion  too — 
it  would  be: — Woe  unto  you,  lawyers! 71 

Even  if  Professor  Rodell  be  right  in  his  drastic  proposal,  it  is  obvious 
that,  short  of  revolution,  it  will  be  a  long  time  before  his  plan  can  be 
realized. 

The  most  drastic  proposal  for  immediate  reform  calls  for  a  socialization 


71  Rodell,  op.  cit.y  pp.  249,  253-255,  269-270,  274.    Reprinted  by  permission 


444  LAW  IN  ACTION 

of  legal  practice.  The  lawyers  representing  both  the  prosecution  and  the 
defendant  would  be  paid  by  the  state.  It  is  held  that  the  state  provides 
hospitals,  even  if  it  does  not  make  the  diseases.  But  the  state  makes  the 
laws,  and  hence  it  should  assume  responsibility  for  their  adjudication. 
This  reform  is  recommended  by  Mr.  Gisnet: 

Bearing  in  mind  that  it  is  the  poor  alone  who  suffer  most  grievously  from  the 
denial  of  justice  which  prevails  in  our  system ;  that  such  denial  of  justice  to  the 
poor  is  caused  by  long  and  undue  delay  in  court  proceedings,  by  costs  and  dis- 
bursements and  by  the  expensiveness  of  counsel  which  the  poor  can't  afford;  and 
also  that  the  cry  is  often  raised  that  the  poor  are  despoiled  by  unscrupulous 
lawyers,  the  obvious  remedy  seems  to  be  socialization  of  the  practice  of  law,  so 
as  to  bring  the  processes  of  the  administration  of  justice  within  easy  reach  of 
every  citizen,  no  matter  how  poor  arid  humble. 

This  could  be  accomplished  by  the  adoption  of  the  following  measures: 

First:  By  the  abolition  of  all  legal  costs  and  disbursements  in  all  courts  and 
in  all  classes  of  cases  or  actions  for  all  parties,  including  expenses  of  appeals  to 
higher  courts. 

Second:  By  the  creation  of  the  office  of  a  Public  Defender  as  a  part  of  the 
administration  of  justice  in  the  criminal  courts  for  the  free  defense  by  the  state 
of  all  persons  charged  with  misdemeanors  or  crimes,  except  such  persons  who 
would  be  able  and  might  want  to  employ  private  counsel. 

Third:  By  the  creation  of  Legal  Aid  Offices  as  a  part  of  the  administration  of 
justice  in  the  Civil  Courts  to  be  attached  to  the  various  courts  and  to  furnish 
counsel  free  of  charge  to  represent  parties,  plaintiff  or  defendant,  in  all  litigated 
actions.72 

The  notion  of  providing  a  public  defender  is  highly  recommended  by 
many  interested  in  the  reform  of  our  legal  procedure.73  The  idea  under- 
lying is  summarized  by  Charles  Mishkin  in  an  article  in  the  Journal  of 
Criminal  Law  and  Criminology: 

It  is  axiomatic  that  one  of  the  primary  duties  of  the  government  is  to  admin- 
ister justice.  Rich  and  poor  should  be  on  an  equal  plane  when  before  the  bar 
of  justice;  but  in  practice  are  they  equal?  The  rich  man  has  his  corps  of  brilliant 
attorneys  and  sufficient  funds  to  employ  investigators  to  discover  witnesses, 
gather  evidence,  and  prepare  an  adequate  defense  on  his  behalf.  The  poor  man, 
on  the  other  hand,  is  helpless,  without  funds,  often  not  understanding  what  the 
proceedings  are  all  about,  and  is  forced  to  rely  for  his  protection  upon  an  attorney 
wlio  has  been  assigned  to  represent  him  without  "compensation.  Honest  and  well 
meaning  though  the  attorney  may  be,  he  is  handicapped  by  lack  of  funds  to  con- 
duct an  investigation  to  ascertain  the  facts,  and  often  without  experience  in 
criminal  matters.  Thus  handicapped,  he  is  forced  to  contend  against  the  un- 
limited power  and  resources  and  prestige  possessed  by  the  public  prosecutor's 
office.  Truly  this  is  a  spectacle  of  the  state  bringing  all  its  power  and  wealth 
to  bear  against  a  weak  and  powerless  accused  [person],  who  may  in  fact  be 
innocent  of  the  charge  brought  against  him.  .  .  . 

The  state  should  be  just  as  diligent  in  attempting  to  prove  the  man  innocent 
as  it  is  in  attempting  to  prove  him  guilty.  Still  it  maintains  the  powerful  offices 
of  public  prosecutor  to  represent  the  prosecution,  and  leaves  the  indigent  accused 
to  present  his  defense  as  best  he  may.  .  .  .  The  truth  is  obvious  that  if  it  is  the 
primary  function  of  the  State  to  seek  the  truth  in  a  criminal  prosecution,  then 
that  function  is  not  fully  performed  unless,  side  by  side  with  the  office  of  public 

72  Gisnet,  op.  cit.,  pp.  145-146. 

73  Cf.  Smith,  Justice  and  the  Poor,  Chap.  XV. 


LAW   IN  ACTION  445 

prosecutor  to  prosecute  the  charges,  there  exists  also,  as  an  arm  of  the  state,  the 
office  of  public  defender  to  defend  against  the  charges.  This,  in  brief,  is  the 
basis  for  the  public  defender  idea.74 

The  present  system  of  assigning  counsel  is  highly  defective:  Assigned 
attorneys  are  often  young,  inexperienced;  and  incompetent.  A  class  of 
undesirable  lawyers  hover  about  the  courtrooms,  eager  for  assignment, 
with  the  sole  purpose  of  getting  as  much  as  they  can  from  the  accused 
and  his  relatives,  and  then  lying  down  on  the  job.75  Such  conditions  lead 
the  more  competent,  and  ethical  attorneys,  who  might  otherwise  accept 
defense  assignments,  to  avoid  the  responsibility. 

The  institution  of  the  public  defender,  suggested  as  a  remedy  for  this 
situation,  is  not  new.76  The  office  was  created  in  Spain  five  centuries  ago. 
Other  countries  which  adopted  it  included  Hungary,  Norway,  and  Argen- 
tina. The  latter  country  has  developed  the  idea  and  practice  to  a  high 
degree.  There  is  a  strong  movement  in  England  working  for  the  institu- 
tion of  this  office.  The  plan  has  been  established  in  a  preliminary  way  in 
California,  Connecticut,  Minnesota,  and  Nebraska  and  in  several  cities 
— Portland  (Oregon) ,  Columbus,  Cincinnati,  Dayton  and  Indianapolis. 
The  advantages  from  the  standpoint  of  both  justice  and  economy  are  the 
following:  (1)  clearly  guilty  offenders  are  urged  to  plead  guilty,  thus 
saving  unnecessary  trials;  (2)  adequate  defense  is  provided  for  all  good 
cases;  (3)  jury  trial  is  often  waived;  (4)  cases  are  tried  promptly  when 
reached  on  the  calendar;  (5)  cases  are  tried  more  expertly  and  expedi- 
tiously;  (6)  great  economies  result  from  the  foregoing;  (7)  trial  judges 
may  trust  the  public  defender  in  advice  as  to  sentencing;  (8)  the  usual 
chicanery  of  criminal  trials  has  no  logical  basis  for  existence;  and  (9) 
there  is  a  great  reduction  in  the  probability  that  a  poor  and  innocent 
defendant  will  be  "railroaded."  77 

While  keenly  alert  to  the  evils  of  courtroom  procedure  in  legal  practice, 
Adolph  A.  Berle  has  some  doubts  about  the  practicability  of  the  socializa- 
tion of  the  legal  profession.  He  says  that  it  is  almost  a  contradiction  in 
terms:  "If  property  is  not  socialized,  it  is  difficult  to  demand  that  legal 
services  for  the  settlement  of  questions  concerned  with  property  be  social- 
ized." 78  But  he  is  extremely  appreciative  of  the  work  done  by  volunteer 
lawyers  in  the  effort  to  improve  justice  for  the  poor.  He  says  that  this 
has  probably  contributed  more  than  any  other  single  force  to  the  mainte- 
nance of  the  integrity  and  stability  of  the  bar. 

The  legal  aid  societies  which  have  sprung  up  in  many  of  our  cities  have 
also  made  a  very  important  contribution  to  the  improvement  of  legal  prac- 
tice. The  legal  aid  movement  has  given  poor  defendants  competent  and 
free  advice.  Most  important  of  all,  it  has  saved  them  from  expensive 

74Loc.  cit.,  November,  1931,  pp.  495-496.  See  also  Samuel  Rubin,  "The  Public 
Defender  as  an  Aid  to  Criminal  Justice,"  Journal  of  Criminal  Law  and  Criminology , 
November,  1927. 

75  See  above,  pp.  430-431. 

76  Of.  Smith,  op.  cit.,  pp.  115  ff. 

77  Cf.  Mishkin,  loc.  cit.,  pp.  504-505. 

78  For  contrary  opinions,  see  Gisnet,  op.  cit.;  and  Rodell;  op.  cit. 


446  LAW   IN  ACTION 

and  often  fruitless  litigation.  The  New  York  City  Legal  Aid  Society 
obtains  pacific  settlements  in  9  out  of  10  cases  it  handles.  The  move- 
ment now  has  a  definite  national  basis  in  the  National  Association  of 
Legal  Aid  Organizations,  which  came  into  being  in  1923.  John  Mac- 
Arthur  Maguire  of  Harvard  University  thus  summarizes  the  important 
contributions  which  we  may  expect  from  the  legal  aid  movement: 

The  significance  of  the  wide  legal  aid  development  in  modern  civilization  is 
very  great.  It  has  progressively  bettered  the  condition  of  the  poor,  increased 
their  understanding  of  law  and  willingness  to  conduct  themselves  lawfully  and 
corrected  unwise  revolutionary  inclinations.  Fair  minded  legal  aid  lawyers  have 
again  and  again  changed  for  the  better  the  attitude  of  employers  to  employees. 
Efficient  legal  aid  unquestionably  increases  the  public  prestige  of  bar  and  bench 
alike.  The  movement  gives  considerable  opportunity  for  training  young  lawyers, 
sometimes  even  during  the  course  of  their  studies.  It  will  combat  more  and  more 
effectively  such  abuses  as  extortionate  contingent  fee  arrangements.  Finally, 
one  of  its  most  important  possibilities,  already  amply  manifested  in  the  United 
States,  is  furtherance  of  wise  law  reform  by  recommendations  based  upon  exceed- 
ingly broad  observation  of  the  practical  results  of  existing  substantive  and 
procedural  rules.  Legal  aid  may  well  be  one  of  the  decisive  factors  in  successful 
social  adjustment.79 

It  is  especially  desirable  that  the  third  degree  evil  should  be  curbed. 
Some  sane  observations  on  this  subject  are  contained  in  an  article 
"Remedies  for  the  Third  Degree/'  in  the  Atlantic  Monthly  by  Zechariah 
Chafee,  Jr.80  Professor  Chafee  makes  it  clear  at  the  start  that  these  law- 
less practices  are  not  necessary  to  convict  criminals.  The  experience  of 
England,  where  police  inquisition  is  strictly  forbidden,  and  of  Boston, 
Philadelphia  and  Cincinnati,  which  do  not  employ  the  third  degree  fre- 
quently, prove  definitely  that  satisfactory  results  can  be  obtained  without 
any  brutal  and  illegal  methods.  The  brutality  of  the  police  comes  chiefly 
between  arrest  and  the  arraignment  of  the  accused.  After  the  magistrate 
commits  the  man  to  jail  or  admits  him  to  bail,  the  police  have  little  oppor- 
tunity to  get  in  any  "rough  stuff."  Therefore,  attention  must  be  concen- 
trated on  cutting  down  the  time  between  arrest  and  arraignment  and  on 
giving  proper  publicity  to  what  goes  on  in  this  interval. 

•Professor  Chafee  does  not  believe  we  need  any  more  laws.  The  ac- 
cused has  plenty  of  formal  legal  protection  already.  He  is  constitution- 
ally protected  in  the  matter  of  testifying  against  himself.  Confessions 
obtained  by  coercion  are  declared  void  by  law.  Policemen  may  be  pun- 
ished as  criminals  if  found  guilty  of  violent  third  degree  methods. 
Illinois,  California,  and  Washington  have  especially  stringent  laws  against 
police  brutality,  but  the  third  degree  was  found  to  be  flourishing  in  Chi- 
cago, Los  Angeles,  and  Seattle.  The  difficulty  arises  from  the  fact  that 
it  is  hard  to  enforce  these  laws.  The  district  attorney  is  frequently  "in 
cahoots"  with  the  police  and  is  not  likely  to  be  enthusiastic  about  prose- 


70  Encyclopedia  of  the  Social  Sciences,  Macmillan,  Vol.  9,  p.  324.    For  the  best 
discussion  of  the  origins  of  legal  aid  societies,  see  Smith,  op.  cit.,  Part  III. 
so  November,  1931,  pp.  621-630. 


LAW   IN  ACTION  447 

cuting  his  own  collaborators.  In  the  courtroom,  the  judge  and  jury  are 
more  likely  to  believe  the  policeman  than  the  defendant. 

Reform,  says  Professor  Chafee,  must  be  gradual.  Changes  so  drastic 
as  to  disrupt  our  present  police  system  would  be  temporarily  disastrous. 
Professor  Chafee  suggests  the  following  specific  reforms:  (1)  measures 
should  be  taken  to  promote  more  prompt  production  of  the  accused 
person  before  a  magistrate  after  arrest.  (2)  Compulsory  records  of  the 
time  of  arrest  and  of  arraignment  before  the  magistrate  should  be  kept. 
(3)  Improvement  should  be  made  in  the  quality  of  the  police.  If  the 
public  understands  that  prevalence  of  third  degree  methods  is  proof  of 
inferior  police  service,  the  police  will  not  be  long  in  abandoning  this 
stigmatized  practice.  (4)  A  public  authority  should  be  created,  inde- 
pendent and  fearless,  which  can  hear  complaints  of  the  third  degree  and 
make  prompt  and  effective  investigation  of  the  facts.  The  proposed 
public  defender  might  exercise  this  function.  (5)  Relentless  publicity 
should  be  given  to  revealed  abuses:  "The  third  degree  cannot  thrive 
under  publicity.  The  police  need  and  desire  the  approval  of  their  com- 
munity; and  few  communities  can  be  proud  of  men  who  habitually  use 
the  rubber  hose." 

The  evils  connected  with  jury  trial  should  be  ended  by  the  creation  of 
commissions  of  experts,  trained  in  psychology,  criminalistics,  criminal 
law,  and  sociology,  who  would  examine  the  evidence  and  decide  upon 
guilt.  Until  jury  trial  can  be  abolished,  a  step  in  the  right  direction 
would  be  the  elimination  of  the  power  of  the  judge  to  impose  a  definite 
time  sentence. 

Effective  action  must  be  taken  against  the  judicial  oligarchies  in  the 
country.  Such  measures  would  involve  the  checking  of  the  judicial  usur- 
pation of  legislative  functions  and  the  termination  of  arbitrariness  and 
favoritism  in  the  every  day  conduct  of  the  judge  in  the  courtroom.  Gold- 
berg and  Levenson  have  made  certain  suggestions  along  this  line: 

1.  The  recall  of  judges  and  judicial  decisions  should  be  established  throughout 
the  country.  .  .  . 

2.  Until  the  recall  of  judges  and  judicial  decisions  shall  become  effective,  we 
advocate  the  impeachment  of  any  judge  who  deliberately  misinterprets  a  statute 
or  law,  and  that  the  process  of  impeachment  be  made  simpler. 

3.  A  constitutional  amendment  depriving  the  courts  of  the  power  to  declare 
laws  unconstitutional  should  be  adopted. 

4.  The  establishment  of  legislative  commissions  to  hear  complaints  against 
judges  for  the  purpose  of  promptly  bringing  to  the  attention  of  the  impeaching 
authorities  all  meritorious  charges. 

The  difficulty  of  bringing  and  prosecuting  charges  against  judges  is  well  known. 
Lawyers,  no  matter  how  prominent  they  may  be,  hesitate  to  proceed  against 
judges  before  whom  they  must  appear.  This  condition  has  made  it  practically 
impossible  for  the  ordinary  citizen  to  obtain  a  fair  and  impartial  hearing  against 
a  judge  who  has  acted  lawlessly.  A  legislative  commission  composed  of  laymen 
would  be  the  proper  body  with  whom  such  charges  should  be  lodged.  The  mere 
establishment  of  such  a  governmental  organ  would  tend  to  deter  judges  from 
acting  lawlessly. 

We  know  that  it  is  difficult  to  strip  the  ermine  from  judicial  shoulders,  but 
the  worshipful  attitude  of  the  people  towards  the  courts  must  be  changed  through 


448  LAW  IN  ACTION 

education.    A  sign  of  hope  is  the  vague  feeling  of  unrest — the  general  awakening 
to  the  dangers  of  an  unrestrained  judicial  oligarchy  .81 

Less  drastic  and  more  immediately  practicable  suggestions  revolve 
around  taking  the  sentencing  power  away  from  judges.  After  an  accused 
person  is  found  guilty  the  judge  would  remand  him  to  the  proper  authori- 
ties for  study  and  treatment.  This  would  not  necessarily  eliminate  judi- 
cial savagery  and  arbitrariness  in  the  courtroom  but  it  would  lessen  the 
consequences  of  such  behavior.  Moreover,  it  would  also  terminate  the 
abuses  connected  with  both  undue  severity  and  grotesque  variations  in 
the  use  of  the  sentencing  power.  Such  proposals  as  these  have  the  sup- 
port of  many  respectable  and  relatively  conservative  persons.  Alfred  E. 
Smith  once  made  such  a  suggestion  while  governor  of  the  State  of  New 
York. 

Above  all,  we  need  a  broader  and  more  humane  view  of  the  law.  This 
point  has  been  well  emphasized  by  Raymond  Moley: 

What  is  wanted,  really,  is  a  doctor  of  human  relations,  a  new  kind  of  lawyer. 
As  Judge  Seabury  has  recently  pointed  out,  we  need  in  the  criminal  courts  some- 
thing closely  akin  to  what  has  been  developed  in  the  medical  profession  in  pro- 
visions for  public  clinics  where  science  and  public  service  develop  side  by  side; 
where  able  young  lawyers  may  learn  and  apply  a  wider  range  of  wisdom  than 
they  find  in  their  law  books,  and  where  the  victims  of  a  complex  and  exacting 
social  order  may  find  enlisted  in  their  service  genuinely  interested  and  adequately 
endowed  friends  in  court.82 

The  evils  of  corporation  law  practice  can  best  be  handled  by  legislation 
curbing  criminality  and  borderline  criminality  in  corporate  practice.  If 
the  law  is  broad  and  clear  enough  on  such  matters,  it  will  be  difficult  for 
the  most  astute  corporation  lawyers  to  evade  it.  A  step  in  the  right 
direction  was  taken  when  the  Federal  Securities  Act  was  passed  in  1933, 
and  when  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission  was  created.  Other 
important  reform  legislation  in  this  field  has  followed,  such  as  the  Securi- 
ties and  Exchange  Act  of  1934,  the  Public  Utility  Holding  Company  Act 
of  1935,  the  Chandler  Corporate  Reorganization  Act  of  1938,  the  Rail- 
noad  Reorganization  Act  of  1940,  and  the  like. 

Corporate  practice  could  further  be  improved,  in  part,  by  a  constitu- 
tional amendment  specifying  that  no  corporation  can  qualify  as  a  "per- 
son" under  the  wording  and  intent  of  the  Fifth  and  Fourteenth  Amend- 
ments. This  would  do  away  with  the  "due  process"  nuisance  in  protect- 
ing lawless  and  anti-social  corporations  and  in  affording  the  Supreme 
Court  almost  unlimited  freedom  in  setting  aside  legislation  which  conflicts 
with  the  prejudices  of  a  majority  on  the  bench.  It  would  also  be  desirable 
to  deprive  the  Court  of  its  right  to  set  aside  federal  laws,  but  its  right  to 
void  state  laws  should  be  continued,  in  the  case  of  state  legislation  which 
clearly  violates  the  federal  Constitution.  But  it  should  not  have  the 


81  Goldberg  and  Levenson,  op.  cit.,  pp.  240-242. 

82  The  New  York  Times,  May  3,  1931. 


LAW   IN   ACTION  449 

right  to  invalidate  state  statutes,  on  the  ground  that  they  interfere  with 
corporations  as  "persons." 

During  the  last  decade  there  has  been  considerable  progress,  some  of 
which  has  already  been  noted,  both  in  the  way  of  improving  the  law  and 
in  correcting  the  social  and  economic  conditions  which  encouraged  abuses 
of  the  law.  Certain  trends  reveal  progress  in  legal  concepts  and  prac- 
tices. The  new  Federal  Practice  Act  incorporates  the  fruits  of  many 
years  of  professorial  research  and  legal  experience.  The  American  Law 
Institute  is  promulgating  a  modern  code  of  evidence,  drawn  up  by  the 
two  outstanding  American  authorities  on  the  subject.  An  office  under  the 
supervision  of  the  Supreme  Court  is  charged  with  the  duty  of  making  a 
constant  survey  of  the  practical  operations  of  the  courts  and  recommend- 
ing needed  changes  in  procedure.  Certain  progressive  states,  like  New 
York,  have  law  revision  commissions  which  make  yearly  reports  to  the 
legislatures  recommending  the  revision  of  both  substantive  and  statutory 
law  which  has  become  archaic  or  otherwise  unjust  and  unworkable. 

The  social  and  economic  reforms  of  the  New  Deal  have  eliminated  or 
curbed  many  of  the  abuses  of  corporation  law.  The  Supreme  Court 
battle  ultimately  resulted  in  a  liberal  court.  The  Sutherlands  and  Mc- 
Reynolds  have  been  replaced  by  the  Blacks  and  Douglases.  This  has 
made  it  more  difficult  to  use  the  Constitution  as  an  instrument  of  oppres- 
sion and  exploitation  and  as  an  agency  to  slaughter  progressive  legislation. 
Liberal  lawyers,  like  Charles  E.  Clark,  Jerome  Frank,  and  Leon  Green, 
are  coming  to  share  in  the  legal  prestige  once  monopolized  by  the  Cra- 
vaths  and  the  Strawns.  What  our  entry  into  the  second  World  War 
may  do  to  reverse  these  laudable  trends  is,  of  course,  another  matter. 

That  the  danger  of  reaction  and  intolerance  is  very  great  was  made 
evident  by  the  American  Civil  Liberties  Union  in  their  brochure  "The 
Bill  of  Rights  in  War,"  issued  on  June  27,  1942,  reviewing  the  status  of 
civil  liberties  during  the  previous  year.  It  was  pointed  out  how  even 
liberal  judges  had  lost  their  former  regard  for  the  right  of  minorities 
and  how  the  Supreme  Court  had  refused  to  review  cases  in  which  obvious 
injustices  had  been  done  and  constitutional  rights  had  been  violated. 
Especially  menacing  was  a  decision  by  the  Court  upholding  the  right  of 
cities  to  require  licenses  for  the  distribution  of  non-commercial  literature. 
Professor  Raymond  Moley  warned  of  the  menace  in  an  able  editorial 
in  News-Week,  June  29,  1942. 

Great  as  is  the  need  for  legal  reform,  we  cannot  reasonably  hope  for 
very  speedy  action.  The  evils  of  "The  Law"  are  nothing  new.  Consid- 
erably over  a  hundred  years  ago,  Thomas  Jefferson  wrote  to  his  lawyer 
friend,  Joseph  Cabell,  completely  in  the  spirit  of  Fred  Rodell: 

I  should  apologize,  perhaps,  for  the  style  of  this  bill.  I  dislike  the  verbose  and 
intricate  style  of  the  English  statutes.  .  .  .  You,  however,  can  easily  correct 
this  bill  to  the  taste  of  my  brother  lawyers,  by  making  ever>  other  word  a  "said" 
or  "aforesaid,"  and  saying  everything  over  three  or  four  times,  so  that  nobody 
but  we  of  the  craft  can  untwist  the  diction,  and  find  out  what  it  means;  and  that, 
too,  not  so  plainly  but  that  we  may  conscientiously  divide  one-half  on  each  side.83 

83  Cited  in  S.  K.  Padover,  Jefferson,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1942,  p.  24. 


PART  IV 

Communication  and  the  Formation  of 
Public  Opinion 


CHAPTER  XIII 
Communication  in  Contemporary  Society 

Language  as  the   Fundamental   Medium  of 
Communication 

The  Origins  of  Language.  One  of  the  greatest  differences  between 
man  and  his  fellow  primates  is  man's  ability  to  use  language  and  symbols. 
Apes  can  use  tools;  they  can  even  invent  simple  ones.  But  man  through 
language  can  make  tool-using  continuous  and  hence  cumulative  in  nature. 
Human  culture  may  be  regarded  as  derived,  in  the  last  analysis,  from  the 
use  of  tools  and  symbols.  Therefore  we  may  fairly  say  that  the  essence 
of  human  culture  is  the  spoken  word  and  symbolic  communication. 

Our  culture  has  developed  beyond  that  of  other  primates  largely  because 
of  our  mastery  of  speech.  This  implies  that  evolution  into  a  human  state 
was  intimately  connected  with  the  function  of  formal  communication. 
The  late  G.  Elliot  Smith  says  that: 

It  seems  a  legitimate  inference  from  the  facts  to  assume  that  the  acquisition 
of  the  power  of  communicating  ideas  and  the  fruits  of  experience  from  one  indi- 
vidual to  another  by  means  of  articulate  speech  may  have  been  one  of  the  factors, 
if  not  the  fundamental  factor,  in  converting  an  ape  into  a  human  being.1 

But  speech,  like  intelligence,  is  not  a  human  monopoly.  Animals  have 
means  of  communicating  with  each  other.  The  dog  barks,  the  cow  moos, 
monkeys  chatter,  the  cat  has  a  diapason  of  sounds.  Animals  can  thus 
express  well-defined  emotions,  but  as  C.  K.  Ogden  says,  we  must  not 
assume  that  animals  have  the  ability  to  name  anything  specific.  An 
animal  makes  a  sound  to  express  a  need  or  desire,  or  merely  to  spend 
surplus  energy.  A  naming  cry  is  an  interpretive  sound.  "Plainly  nam- 
ing cannot  arise  until  the  animal  can  respond  to  situations  not  merely  as 
eliciting  this  or  that  activity,  but  as  possessing  this  or  that  character."  2 

Let  us  pursue  the  distinction  a  little  farther.  All  speech,  whether  ani- 
mal or  human,  involves  expression.  Man's  speech  involves  more  than 
that — it  embraces  what  Ogden  calls  "objective  reference"  (interpreta- 
tion). This  objective  reference  is  man's  peculiar  achievement.  How  did 
such  an  all-important  achievement  come  about? 

Man's  higher  or  differentiated  use  of  speech  developed  out  of  the  ani- 
mal's lower  or  undifferentiated  vocal  expressions.  Even  among  animal 
cries  there  is  some  sort  of  objective  reference.  Before  infants  can  speak, 


1  Quoted  by  C.  K.  Ogden,  The  Meaning  of  Psychology,  Harper,  1926,  p.  149. 

2  Ibid.,  p.  150. 

450 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      451 

they  have  a  wide  variety  of  vocal  expressions,  such  as  a  call  for  food,  or 
a  cry  of  discomfort.  An  infant  can  communicate  long  before  he  utters 
a  definable  word.  Animals  can  do  much  the  same.  Their  cry  is  a  call 
to  action.  It  expresses  an  emotion  "long  before  any  explicit  reflection 
upon,  or  recognition  of,  the  situation  can  have  arisen.  We  must  remem- 
ber in  considering  any  stage  of  language,  that  its  use  in  reflection,  as  an 
instrument  of  thought,  is  a  kind  of  diversion  of  it  from  its  original  uses." 3 
The  danger  cries  and  other  social  utterances  of  animals  may  be  regarded 
as  crude  names.  What  they  name  is  not  any  specific  feature  of  a  situa- 
tion but  the  whole  situation.  A  similar  phenomenon  meets  us  in  human 
speech  if  we  go  back  as  far  as  we  can  into  the  origin  of  any  given 
language. 

When  man  had  arrived  at  the  stage  of  forming  sentences,  he  too  prob- 
ably first  expressed  a  situation  as  a  whole  rather  than  in  its  component 
parts.  He  probably  expressed  himself  as  the  Eskimo  does  in  saying 
"sinikatachpok,"  rather  than  the  English  way  of  putting  it:  "He  is  ill 
from  having  slept  too  much."  In  the  beginning,  language  probably  cre- 
ated some  of  its  "ideas"  or  "words"  by  imitating  natural  sounds,  such  as 
"cuckoo,"  "pee-wit,"  "bang,"  "crash,"  "plop,"  "zip."  This  practice  of 
imitating  natural  sounds  is  called  "onomatopoeia." 

A  rival  to  the  onomatopoeic  theory  of  the  origin  of  language  holds  that 
movements  of  hands  and  feet  were  associated  with  cries  which,  within  the 
family  or  community,  became  standardized  in  time.  In  other  words,  as 
Sir  J,  G.  Frazer  points  out,  all  members  of  a  community  agreed  to  make 
the  same  sounds  when,  for  instance,  looking  at  the  sun,  peering  into  a  dark 
place,  or  kicking  an  object.  After  a  while  the  sound  alone  would  suggest 
the  various  actions.  This  is  called  the  "gesture  theory."  Probably, 
language  actually  arose  both  from  imitation  of  natural  sounds  and  from 
gesticular  meanings  put  into  words. 

Some  recent  and  scientific  philologists  have  abandoned  any  search  for 
the  actual  origin  of  language.  The  late  Edward  Sapir,  the  ablest  student 
of  language  that  this  country  has  produced,  summarizes  the  contempo- 
rary point  of  view: 

About  all  that  can  be  said  at  present  is  that  while  speech  as  a  finished  organiza- 
tion is  a  distinctly  human  achievement,  its  roots  probably  lie  in  the  power  of  the 
higher  apes  to  solve  specific  problems  by  abstracting  general,  forms  or  schemata 
from  the  details  of  given  situations ;  that  the  habit  of  interpreting  certain  selected 
elements  in  a  situation  as  signs  of  a  desired  total  one  gradually  led  in  early  man 
to  a  dim  feeling  for  symbolism;  and  that  in  the  long  run  and  for  reasons  which 
can  hardly  be  guessed  at  the  elements  of  experience  which  were  most  often 
interpreted  in  a  symbolic  sense  came  to  be  the  largely  useless  or  supplementary 
vocal  behavior  that  must  have  often  attended  significant  action.  According  to 
this  point  of  view  language  is  not  so  much  directly  developed  out  of  vocal  expres- 
sion as  it  is  an  actualization  in  terms  of  vocal  expression  of  the  tendency  to  master 
reality,  not  by  direct  and  ad  hoc  handling  of  its  elements  but  by  the  reduction 
of  experience  to  familiar  forms.4 


s  Ibid.,  p.  152. 

4  Article,  "Language,"  Encyclopaedia  of  the  Social  Sciences,  Vol.  IX,  p.  159. 


452      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

It  is  not  difficult  to  see  how  concrete  things  and  events  got  their  names. 
It  is  much  more  difficult  to  imagine  how  abstractions — good,  bad,  true, 
for  instance — arose.  Probably  abstractions  began  as  concrete  words  and 
eventually  lost  their  concreteness.  Latin  anima  (soul)  is  connected  with 
Sanskrit  aniti  (breathes)  and  with  Sanskrit  anilas  (wind).  The  Latin 
word  itself  must  originally  have  meant  breath.  Once  the  conception  of  a 
"spirit"  appeared,  its  presence  was  located  in  the  body,  and  it  was  asso- 
ciated with  breathing.  In  time  the  word  lost  its  connection  with  the  act 
of  breathing  and  referred  merely  to  the  spirit  that  was  supposed  to  control 
the  breathing. 

Probably  language  originated  in  many  places  at  different  times.  Our 
earliest  record  of  language  comes  from  the  valleys  of  the  Nile  and 
Euphrates.  But  these  examples  date  from — comparatively — yesterday, 
when  we  remember  that  man  has — crudely  in  the  beginning — conversed 
for  probably  a  half-million  years.  Sumerian,  spoken  about  5,000  years 
ago  in  southern  Mesopotamia,  is  one  of  the  earliest  languages  we  know. 
Nothing,  however,  would  justify  our  calling  the  Sumerian  dialect  a  primi- 
tive language,  in  the  sense  that  it  resembled  the  language  spoken  by  pre- 
historic types  like  Heidelberg  man,  the  Neanderthal  man,  or  even  the 
Cro-Magnon  peoples. 

Little  light  is  thrown  on  the  problem  by  the  languages  of  existing 
aborigines.  From  them  we  mainly  learn  that  primitive  culture  is  often 
accompanied  by  extremely  complicated  languages.  For  instance,  the 
language  of  the  Eskimo  is,  to  a  person  acquainted  with  Germanic  or 
Romance  languages,  one  of  almost  insurmountable  difficulties.  This  will 
suffice  to  upset  a  common  notion  that  primitive  man  has  a  very  limited 
vocabulary  and  a  language  of  simple  structure.  Such  may  have  been 
true  of  the  Neanderthal  man,  but  it  is  not  true  of  existing  savages.  What- 
ever the  origin  of  language,  there  can  be  no  doubt  of  the  vast  importance 
of  its  appearance  and  development  for  the  human  race: 

Language  became  the  chief  vehicle  for  the  transmission  and  preservation  of 
culture,  as  well  as  the  most  characteristic  aspect  of  culture.  Long  before  written 
language  was  invented,  oral  tradition  preserved  and  handed  down  from  generation 
to  generation  the  discoveries,  the  inventions,  and  the  social  heritage  of  the  past. 
Language  provided  man  with  a  boon  without  price,  the  means  of  storing  ex- 
ternally to  any  particular  nervous  system,  records  of  experience  having  social 
values  to  the  group.  External  storage  of  individual  experience  in  language  sym- 
bols is  a  process  entirely  unknown  to  any  form  of  life  other  than  man.  The 
importance  of  this  process  seems  beyond  calculation.  It  reaches  its  highest 
development  in  the  alphabet.5 

Civilization  is  a  verbal  complex.  This  fact,  more  than  any  other, 
separates  our  culture  from  the  lower  forms  of  primate  life.  If  our  lan- 
guage and  its  literary  products  were  suddenly  to  be  taken  away,  we  would 
sink  to  the  cultural  level  of  savages  of  the  cave-dwelling  period.  We 
would  have  no  greater  cultural  or  institutional  equipment  than  Homo 


5  F.  S.  Chapin,  Cultural  Change,  Appleton-Century,  1928,  p.  40. 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      453 

sapiens  possessed  when  he  first  appeared  in  Europe  some  thirty  thousand 
years  or  more  ago. 

The  question  arises:  Do  all  our  languages  go  back  to  a  common  ances- 
tor? The  case  for  such  linguistic  monogenesis  has  been  argued  by  a 
brilliant  Italian  scholar,  Trombetti,  but  has  received  little  support  from 
others.  This  question,  like  many  others  involving  the  origins  of  man, 
cannot  yet  be  answered  decisively. 

The  Origins  of  the  Alphabet  and  a  Written  Language.  The  origins  of 
writing  can  be  linked  with  the  pictograms  on  the  implements  and  cave 
walls  of  the  Paleolithic  era.  However,  before  the  picture  signs  could  be 
regarded  as  a  written  language,  they  had  to  pass  through  three  well- 
defined  stages. 

First,  the  pictures  had  to  become  "conventionalized,"  so  that  they 
always  had  the  same  appearance  and  represented  the  same  object.  Next, 
they  had  to  become  the  symbols  of  abstract  conceptions.  Finally,  the 
conventionalized  symbols  had  to  pass  into  a  stage  where  they  described  an 
abstract  concept  and  the  sound  of  the  human  voice  representing  that 
concept. 

The  last  stage,  as  may  be  expected,  is  the  most  difficult  to  attain.  It  is 
called  "sound  writing,"  and  in  its  most  elementary  form  each  symbol 
represents  ah  entire  word.  Some  languages,  like  the  Chinese,  have  gone 
little  beyond  this  stage.  Normally,  a  written  language  goes  farther  than 
the  Chinese,  each  symbol  representing  not  the  object  but  the  sound  of  the 
word  referring  to  the  object.  Then  the  various  sounds  of  the  human 
voice  are  analyzed  and  each  is  represented  by  a  separate  symbol  or  letter; 
this  constitutes  an  alphabet. 

Around  3000  B.C.  the  Egyptians  had  taken  an  important  step  in  devel- 
oping an  alphabet  by  using  24  hieroglyphic  signs  to  indicate  24  con- 
sonantal sounds.  But  they  continued  to  use  many  additional  symbols 
for  words  and  syllables,  and  therefore  failed  to  develop  a  strictly  phonetic 
alphabet.  A  certain  Semite  of  the  nineteenth  century  B.C.,  perhaps  a 
Phoenician  from  Byblos,  seems  to  have  invented  a  true  alphabet  based 
on  Egyptian  antecedents.  His  alphabet  is  used  in  inscriptions  recently 
found  in  southern  Palestine.  Other  inscriptions  recently  discovered  at 
Rasesh  Shamra  near  Latakihey  in  ancient  Ugarit  (in  Syria)  are  written 
in  an  alphabetic  cuneiform  script  of  a  northern  Semitic  dialect.  Our 
earliest  inscription  in  a  fully  developed  Phoenician  alphabet  is  the  epitaph 
of  Ahiram,  king  of  Byblos,  who  lived  about  1250  B.C.  It  contains  21 
letters,  all  consonants.  The  Greeks  improved  the  Phoenician  alphabet 
by  using  some  of  its  signs  to  indicate  vowels.  This  Greek  alphabet,  with 
some  modifications,  was  spread  by  the  Romans  to  western  Europe  and  by 
the  Byzantines  to  eastern  Europe. 

Writing  was  probably  invented  in  many  other  places — Anatolia,  Crete, 
Egypt,  Babylonia,  India,  China,  and  Central  America.  There  were,  how- 
ever, only  three  great  systems  of  ideographs  or  picture-forms:  (1)  the 
Sumerian  or  Babylonian  cuneiform,  which  died  out  about  the  beginning 
of  the  Christian  Era;  (2)  the  Chinese,  with  its  branches  in  Korea  and 


454      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

Japan;  and  (3)  the  Egyptian,  from  which  our  alphabet  was  originally 
derived. 

When  man  learned  to  write  he  also  made  writing  materials.  The 
Babylonians  wrote  on  clay  tablets  and  stone  walls,  which,  although 
durable,  were  awkward  to  handle.  The  Egyptians  solved  the  problem 
by  using  the  membrane  of  the  papyrus  reed,  thin  strips  which  they  pasted 
together  at  right  angles.  On  papyrus  (whence  our  word  "paper")  they 
wrote  with  an  ink  made  of  water,  vegetable  gum,  and  soot. 

Papyrus  was  so  widely  known  that  it  probably  suggested  to  the 
Chinese,  around  200  B.C.,  the  idea  of  making,  at  less  cost,  a  form  of 
paper  from  the  pulp  of  the  mulberry  tree.  Peoples  who  had  no  papyrus 
wrote  on  parchment  made  from  animal  skins.  The  Arabs,  about  A.D. 
750,  brought  to  Spain  a  paper  made  from  cotton  fiber.  Five  centuries 
later  flax  was  substituted  for  cotton  and  modern  linen  paper  came  into 
use.  Rag  paper  was  fairly  common  in  western  Europe  by  the  middle 
of  the  fourteenth  century. 

The  first  pens  were  pieces  of  reed  sharpened  and  pointed  by  hand. 
They  were  superseded  by  the  quill,  and  later  by  the  modern  steel  pen. 
The  first  ink  was  made  by  thickening  water  with  vegetable  gums  and 
then  mixing  this  with  soot  obtained  from  blackened  pots.  Later,  it  was 
made  from  various  dyes. 

The  invention  of  writing  and  a  system  of  keeping  records  have  had  a 
greater  influence  on  man's  intellectual  development  than  any  other 
achievement,  with  the  exception  of  speech.  Writing  made  it  possible 
permanently  to  transmit  man's  ideas,  traditions,  and  mythology.  Profes- 
sor Breasted  has  stated  the  importance  of  this  step  in  the  evolution  of 
civilization,  which  we  may  credit  to  the  Egyptians:  "The  invention  of 
writing  and  of  a  convenient  system  of  records  on  paper  has  had  a  greater 
influence  in  uplifting  the  human  race  than  any  other  intellectual  achieve- 
ment in  the  career  of  man.  It  was  more  important  than  all  the  battles 
ever  fought  and  all  the  constitutions  ever  devised." 

The  great  contributions  of  writing  have  been  accompanied  by  certain 
evils.  Although  it  has  enabled  us  to  transmit  culture  from  age  to  age, 
it  has  at  the  same  time  kept  alive  outworn  notions  and  reprehensible  be- 
liefs, whose  pernicious  influences  might  otherwise  never  have  reached  suc- 
ceeding generations  with  any  such  completeness  and  force. 

Social  and  Intellectual  Problems  of  Language.  In  the  western  world, 
the  accidents  of  history  have  given  unusual  importance  to  Semitic  lan- 
guages, especially  Arabic,  and  to  Latin,  French,  and  English.  The 
Muslims  of  the  Middle  Ages  were  the  great  pioneers  and  civilizers  of  the 
medieval  period,  and  they  spread  the  Arabic  language  from  India  to 
Spain.  Medieval  Latin  was  the  language  of  culture  in  western  Christen- 
dom during  the  Middle  Ages.  French  has  been  the  language  of  diplomacy 
and  polite  society  in  Europe  in  modern  times.  With  the  growth  of  the 
British  Empire  and  its  expansion  in  the  Old  and  New  Worlds,  the  English 
language  has  been  widely  disseminated  over  the  face  of  the  earth. 

One  of  the  greatest  conceivable  additions  to  better  communication  and 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      455 

understanding,  especially  in  this  era,  would  be  a  universal  language  which 
could  be  understood  by  all  literate  persons.  Medieval  Latin  might  have 
grown  into  such  a  language  had  it  not  been  suppressed  by  the  Humanists 
of  early  modern  times  in  favor  of  the  florid  and  rhetorical  classical  Latin. 
The  late  Louis  J.  Pactow  labored  strenuously  in  favor  of  reviving 
medieval  Latin  as  a  world  language.  This  would  hardly  be  feasible  be- 
cause many  of  the  objects  and  most  of  the  experiences  of  our  day  were 
little  known,  or  unknown,  in  the  Middle  Ages.  There  has,  however,  been 
some  success  in  promulgating  Esperanto  as  a  world  language.  A  univer- 
sal language  would  not  only  be  a  great  convenience,  but  it  might  also 
contribute  much  to  a  growth  of  international  understanding  and  goodwill. 

Many  illusions  have  developed  with  respect  to  the  relation  of  language 
and  race.  It  has  been  widely  held  that  language  is  a  test  of  race  and  that 
there  is  a  definite  identity  between  a  given  race  and  a  given  language  or 
a  type  of  language.  It  was  this  illusion  that  gave  rise  to  the  Aryan 
Myth.  According  to  this,  there  was  a  primordial  Aryan  race  which 
fathered  the  family  of  Aryan  languages.  We  now  know  that  there  was 
never  an  Aryan  race  and  the  so-called  Aryan  languages  were  brought 
into  Europe  by  peoples  unrelated  racially  to  the  blond  Nordics,  who  are 
customarily  regarded  as  the  typical  Aryans  in  a  racial  sense.  There  was 
some  definite  connection  between  race  and  language  in  very  early  days, 
before  race  mixture  had  advanced  very  far.  But  during  historic  times 
the  same  language  has  been  spoken  by  many  races,  while  a  single  race 
in  a  physical  sense  may  speak  many  languages  and  even  more  dialects. 
There  is  no  direct  relationship  whatever  between  the  physical  fact  of  race 
and  the  cultural  phenomenon  of  language. 

Language  has  been  held  by  some  philosophers  to  be  a  sign  of  cultural 
superiority.  For  example,  Johann  Gottlieb  Fichte  held  that  the  German 
language  proves  the  Prussians  a  superior  people.  While  a  high  culture 
could  hardly  express  itself  through  a  rudimentary  primitive  language, 
there  is  no  necessary  relationship  between  cultural  superiority  and  lan- 
guage, on  roughly  the  same  level  of  development.  Certain  languages  lend 
themselves  better  than  others  to  a  more  facile  and  melodious  expression  in 
one  type  or  another  of  literary  effort;  but  a  high  culture  may  find  expres- 
sion in  a  relatively  rudimentary  form  of  language.  For  instance,  there 
have  never  been  any  higher  expressions  of  human  sentiment  than  the 
sayings  of  Confucius,  which  had  to  be  set  down  in  the  relatively  elemen- 
tary monosyllabic  Chinese  language. 

For  a  long  time  the  absence  of  a  universal  language  has  been  deplored. 
But  recently  it  has  been  pointed  out  that  most  persons  who  speak  a  given 
language  do  not  know  the  real  meaning  of  many  of  its  words.  The  mean- 
ing of  many  words  may  literally  be  quite  different  to  one  person  from 
what  it  may  be  to  another,  according  to  his  upbringing  and  experience. 
This  does  not  refer  primarily  to  the  vocabulary  limitations  of  the  masses, 
which  are  very  striking,  but  to  the  ignorance  of  the  meaning  of  words 
which  are  known  in  a  formal  sense  to  the  user.  It  also  has  reference  to 
pure  fictions  which  are  created  through  the  unmeaningful  use  of  words. 


456      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

In  short,  persons  using  the  same  language  all  too  often  talk  and  write 
without  actually  communicating. 

While  this  important  consideration  has  been  popularized  only  in 
recent  years,  the  whole  notion  was  clearly  understood  by  Francis  Bacon 
at  the  beginning  of  the  seventeenth  century.  The  obstructions  to  thought 
growing  out  of  linguistic  difficulties  and  inadequacies  constituted  what 
Bacon  called  "The  Idol  of  the  Marketplace."  As  Bacon  pointed  out, 
language,  particularly  rhetorical  language,  leads  to  the  weakness  of  sub- 
stituting the  well-said  for  the  well-thought,  encumbers  the  mind  with  con- 
centration on  verbal  problems,  and  creates  the  illusion  that  words  always 
correspond  to  things.  Words  are  very  imperfect  vehicles  for  the  expres- 
sion of  ideas.  Even  if  one  is  well  informed  and  exact  in  his  own  expres- 
sion of  ideas,  it  is  always  difficult  to  transmit  the  same  meaning  to  others. 
Again,  many  people,  particularly  orators,  are  so  entranced  by  the  music 
of  their  words  that  they  become  relatively  indifferent  to  the  thought 
content.  As  Bacon  summarizes  the  matter: 

There  are  also  idols  formed  by  the  reciprocal  intercourse  and  society  of  man 
with  man,  which  we  call  idols  of  the  market,  from  the  commerce  and  association 
of  men  with  each  other;  for  men  converse  by  means  of  language,  but  words  are 
formed  at  the  will  of  the  generality,  and  there  arises  from  a  bad  and  unapt 
formation  of  words  a  wonderful  obstruction  to  the  mind.  Nor  can  the  definitions 
and  explanations  with  which  learned  men  are  wont  to  guard  and  protect  them- 
selves in  some  instances  afford  a  complete  remedy — words  still  manifestly  force 
the  understanding,  throw  everything  into  confusion,  and  lead  mankind  into  vain 
and  innumerable  controversies  and  fallacies. 

Fred  C.  Kelly,  commenting  on  a  recent  book  of  Professor  S.  I.  Kaya- 
kawa  on  Language  in  Action,  amplifies  this  same  important  point  in 
contemporary  setting: 

Spoken  words  are  merely  noises  people  make  and  written  words  only  symbols 
for  those  noises.  At  best,  such  noises  and  symbols  do  not  tell  all.  A  man  may 
look  at  a  sunset  and  make  the  noise  "wonderful"  or  "glorious,"  but  the  noise  or 
word  he  uses  cannot  tell  all  he  feels.  It  would  take  a  long  time  and  millions 
of  words  to  tell  all  about  even  so  simple  an  article  as  an  ordinary  pencil.  For  all 
dbout  it  would  have  to  include  a  microscopic  and  sub-microscopic  description. 
And  a  word  never  means  the  same  thing  twice,  for  the  meaning  varies  according 
to  context.  An  orange  is  not  this  orange;  nor  is  the  orange  you  saw  yesterday 
quite  the  same  orange  today.  We  think  we  know  the  meaning  of  the  word 
"love,"  but  the  love  of  a  man  for  this  girl  cannot  be  the  same  as  the  love  of 
another  man  for  that  girl. 

Much  more  than  a  word  is  needed  to  tell  all.  Yet  we  often  permit  ourselves 
to  be  directed  into  forming  an  opinion  on  a  highly  complicated  situation  without 
examination  of  facts,  with  nothing  more  than  a  word  or  two  to  guide  us.  When 
a  piece  of  proposed  legislation  for  reorganizing  government  departments  wtis 
pending  in  Congress,  a  Chicago  newspaper  invariably  referred  to  it  as  the  "dic- 
tator bill."  Whether  the  legislation  would  have  worked  for  good  or  evil  is  beside 
the  point.  "Dictator  bill"  was  not  a  complete,  unbiased  description  of  the  pro- 
posal. The  word  "dictator"  is  not  a  dictator.  But  many  readers  behaved  as  if 
the  word  and  the  thing  were  identical.6 


6  "Do  Words  Scare  Us?"    Saturday  Review  of  Literature,  November  22,  1941,  p.  11. 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      457 

The  need  for  an  understanding  use  of  language  has  given  rise  in  recent 
years  to  what  is  known  as  semantics,  or  a  real  science  of  communication. 
Such  books  as  Count  Alfred  Korzybski's  Science  and  Sanity,  C.  K.  Ogden 
and  I.  A.  Richard's  The  Meaning  of  Meaning,  and  S.  I.  Kayakawa's 
Language  in  Action  are  representative  works  in  this  field.  But  it  re- 
mained for  Stuart  Chase  to  popularize  the  matter  in  his  article  on  "The 
Tyranny  of  Words"  in  Harper's,7  and,  soon  afterwards,  in  a  book  of  the 
same  title. 

Few  words  have  any  universal  and  precise  meaning.  Even  when  a 
person  uses  a  word  in  an  accurate  and  meaningful  way  to  himself,  it 
rarely  means  the  same  thing  to  another  person  and  never  will  mean  the 
same  thing  to  all  persons.  We  recognize  our  blank  ignorance  or  confusion 
when  we  do  not  understand  a  foreign  language,  but  most  of  us  delude 
ourselves  into  imagining  we  can  all  understand  our  own  language.  As 
Chase  puts  it: 

When  a  Russian  speaks  to  an  Englishman  unacquainted  with  Slavic,  nothing 
comes  through.  But  the  Britisher  shrugs  his  shoulders  and  both  comprehend 
that  communication  is  nil.  When  an  Englishman  speaks  to  an  Englishman  about 
ideas — political,  economic,  social — the  communication  is  often  equally  blank,  but 
the  hearer  thinks  he  understands,  and  sometimes  proceeds  to  riotous  action.  .  .  . 

Failure  of  mental  communication  is  painfully  in  evidence  nearly  everywhere 
we  choose  to  look.  Pick  up  any  magazine  or  newspaper,  and  you  will  find  many 
of  the  articles  devoted  to  sound  and  fury  from  politicians,  editors,  leaders  of 
industry,  and  diplomats.  You  will  find  the  text  of  the  advertising  sections  de- 
voted almost  solidly  to  a  skillful  attempt  to  make  words  mean  something  different 
to  the  reader  from  what  the  facts  warrant.  Most  of  us  are  aware  of  tne  chronic 
inability  of  school  children  to  understand  what  is  taught  them;  their  examination 
papers  are  familiar  exhibits  in  communication  failure.  Let  me  put  a  question 
to  my  fellow-authors  in  the  fields  of  economics,  politics,  and  sociology:  How  many 
book  reviewers  show  by  their  reviews  that  they  know  what  you  are  talking 
about?  One  in  ten?  That  is  about  my  ratio.  Yet  most  of  them  assert  that 
I  am  relatively  lucid,  if  ignorant.  How  many  arguments  arrive  anywhere?8 

Chase  gives  us  some  interesting  examples  of  the  obstructive  social 
illusions  that  we  create  through  the  misuse  and  misunderstanding  of 
words,  especially  when  we  get  into  abstractions: 

Judges  and  lawyers  have  granted  to  a  legal  abstraction  the  rights,  privileges, 
and  protection  vouchsafed  to  a  living,  breathing  human  being.  It  is  thus  that 
corporations,  as  well  as  you  or  I,  are  entitled  to  life,  liberty,  and  the  pursuit  of 
happiness.  It  would  surely  be  a  rollicking  sight  to  see  the  Standard  Oil  Company 
of  New  Jersey  in  pursuit  of  happiness  at  a  dance  hall.  It  would  be  a  sight  to  see 
United  States  Smelting,  Refining  and  Mining  being  brought  back  to  consciousness 
by  a  squad  of  coast  guardsmen  armed  with  a  respirator,  to  see  the  Atlas  Corpora- 
tion enjoying  its  constitutional  freedom  at  a  nudist  camp.  .  .  . 

Corporations  fill  but  one  cage  in  a  large  menagerie.  Let  us  glance  at  some  of 
the  otner  queer  creatures  created  by  personifying  abstractions  in  America.  Here 
in  the  center  is  a  vast  figure  called  the  Nation — majestic,  and  wrapped  in  the 


7  November,  1937. 

8  From  The  Tyranny  of  Words,  copyright  1938,  by  Stuart  Chase,  pp.  14r-19.    Re- 
printed by  permission  of  Harcourt,  Brace  and  Company,  Inc. 


458      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

flag.  When  it  sternly  raises  its  arm  we  are  ready  to  die  for  it.  Close  behind 
rears  a  sinister  shape,  the  Government.  Following  it  is  one  even  more  sinister, 
Bureaucracy.  Both  are  festooned  with  the  writhing  serpents  of  Red  Tape.  High 
in  the  heavens  is  the  Constitution,  a  kind  of  chalice  like  the  Holy  Grail,  suffused 
with  ethereal  light.  It  must  never  be  joggled.  Below  floats  the  Supreme  Court, 
a  black-robed  priesthood  tending  the  eternal  fire.  The  Supreme  Court  must  be 
addressed  with  respect  or  it  will  neglect  the  fire  and  the  Constitution  will  go  out. 
This  is  synonymous  with  the  end  of  the  world.  Somewhere  above  the  Rocky 
Mountains  are  lodged  the  vast  stone  tablets  of  The  Law.  We  are  governed  not 
by  men  but  by  these  tablets.  Near  them,  in  satin  breeches  and  silver  buckles, 
pose  the  stern  figures  of  our  Forefathers,  contemplating  glumly  the  Nation  they 
brought  to  birth.  The  onion-shaped  demon  cowering  behind  the  Constitution  is 
Private  Property.  Higher  than  Court,  Flag,  or  The  Law,  close  to  the  sun  itself 
and  almost  as  bright,  is  Progress,  the  ultimate  God  of  America.9 

The  misuse  and  misunderstanding  of  words  brings  about  similar  illu- 
sions and  misconceptions  about  personality.  Chase  illustrates  this  by 
the  popular  notions  of  Tugwell  and  Landon  during  the  presidential  cam- 
paign of  1936: 

Another  sad  performance,  closer  to  home,  is  the  fabric  of  bad  language  which 
entangled  the  names  of  Rexford  Guy  Tugwell  and  Alfred  M.  Landon  in  the 
presidential  campaign  of  1936.  The  objective  of  the  spinners,  the  publishers  of 
the  majority  of  American  newspapers — was  to  create  a  devil  of  the  first  and  a  god 
of  the  second.  With  vast  enthusiasm  they  plunged  to  the  task.  Round  the  word 
"Tugwell"  were  woven  emotive  abstractions  of  the  general  order  of:  long-haired 
professor,  impractical  visionary,  public  spendthrift  and  presently,  agent  of  Mos- 
cow, red,  home  destroyer,  Constitution  wrecker.  Round  the  word  "Landon" 
were  woven  abstractions  of  the  opposite  emotional  order — practical,  honest  busi- 
ness man,  meeter  of  payrolls,  home  lover,  early  riser,  good  neighbor,  budget 
balancer,  Constitution  defender;  good,  homely,  folksy  stuff.  The  real  character- 
istics of  both  men  were  swept  away  in  this  hail  of  verbiage,  and  citizens  were 
asked  in  effect  to  choose  between  Lucifer  and  the  Angel  Gabriel.10 

What  semantics,  or  the  scientific  and  understanding  use  of  words,  really 
does  to  the  so-called  prevailing  knowledge,  even  the  eternal  verities  of 
philosophy,  is  graphically  described  by  Chase : 

Another  matter  which  distressed  me  was  that  I  found  it  almost  impossible  to 
read  philosophy.  The  great  words  went  round  and  round  in  my  head  until  I 
became  dizzy.  Sometimes  they  made  pleasant  music,  but  I  could  rarely  effect 
passage  between  them  and  the  real  world  of  experience.  William  James  I  could 
usually  translate,  but  the  great  classics  had  almost  literally  no  meaning  to  me — 
just  a  haughty  parade  of  Truth,  Substance,  Infinite,  Absolute,  Over-soul,  the 
Universal,  the  Nominal,  the  Eternal.  As  these  works  had  been  acclaimed  for 
centuries  as  part  of  the  priceless  cultural  heritage  of  mankind,  it  seemed  obvious 
that  something  in  my  intellectual  equipment  was  seriously  deficient.  I  strove 
to  understand  Plato,  Aristotle,  Spinoza,  Kant,  Hegel,  Herbert  Spencer,  Schopen- 
hauer. The  harder  I  wrestled  the  more  the  solemn  procession  of  verbal  ghosts 
circled  through  my  brain,  mocking  my  ignorance.  Why  was  this?  Was  I  alone 
at  fault  or  was  there  something  in  the  structure  of  language  itself  which  checked 
communication?  .  .  . 


»Ibid.,  pp.  22-23. 

10  Harper's,  November,  1937,  p.  567. 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      459 

With  the  tools  of  semantic  analysis,  the  authors  laid  in  ruin  the  towering  edifice 
of  classical  philosophy  from  Aristotle  to  HegeL  Psychology  (pre-Freudian) 
emerged  in  little  better  repair.  Large  sections  of  sociology,  economics,  the  law, 
politics,  even  medicine,  were  as  cities  after  an  earthquake.  .  .  . 

For  the  individual,  as  I  can  testify,  a  brief  grounding  in  semantics,  besides 
making  philosophy  unreadable,  makes  unreadable  most  political  speeches,  classi- 
cal economic  theory,  after-dinner  oratory,  diplomatic  notes,  newspaper  editorials, 
treatises  on  pedagogics  and  education,  expert  financial  comment,  dissertations  on 
money  and  credit,  accounts  of  debates,  and  Great  Thoughts  from  Great  Thinkers 
in  general.  You  would  be  surprised  at  the  amount  of  time  this  saves.11 

How  devastating  semantics  is  to  modern  propaganda  is  illustrated  by 
a  reference  to  a  sentence  from  one  of  Hitler's  speeches,  which  reads  as 
follows : 

The  Aryan  Fatherland,  which  has  nursed  the  souls  of  heroes,  calls  upon  you  for 
the  supreme  sacrifice  which  you,  in  whom  flows  heroic  blood,  will  not  fail,  and 
which  will  echo  forever  down  the  corridors  of  history.13 

When  submitted  to  the  acid  test  of  semantics,  the  speech  comes  out  as 
follows: 

The  blab  blab  which  has  nursed  the  blabs  of  blabs,  calls  upon  you  for  the 
blab  blab  which,  in  whom  flows  blab  blab,  will  not  fail,  and  which  will  echo  blab 
down  the  blabs  of  blab.12a 

These  inadequacies  in  language  are  especially  dangerous  in  our  machine 
age.  In  the  simple  life  of  the  old  handicraft  era,  society  was  local  and 
men  lived  in  face-to-face  contact.  Words  applied  mainly  to  objects  and 
to  the  realities  of  life.  There  was  little  reading  or  writing  except  on  the 
part  of  a  small  literate  minority.  In  our  day  of  power  and  machines, 
culture  transcends  personal  and  community  experience,  and  misunder- 
standing is  more  frequent  and  more  menacing: 

Power-age  communities  have  grown  far  beyond  the  check  of  individual  experi- 
ence. They  rely  increasingly  on  printed  matter,  radio,  communication  at  a  dis- 
tance. This  has  operated  to  enlarge  the  field  for  words,  absolutely  and  relatively, 
and  has  created  a  paradise  for  fakers.  A  community  of  semantic  illiterates,  of 
persons  unable  to  perceive  the  meaning  of  what  they  read  and  hear,  is  one  of 
perilous  equilibrium.13 

It  is  difficult  enough  to  solve  our  social  problems  if  we  have  a  full 
comprehension  of  what  they  are.  The  outlook  is  hopeless  unless  we  can 
have  some  general  understanding  of  our  civilization.  This  is  especially 
true  in  a  democratic  society,  the  successful  operation  of  which  presupposes 
an  acquaintance  on  the  part  of  the  majority  with  the  problems  society 
faces. 


11  From  The  Tyranny  of  Words,  op.  cit.,  pp.  5,  8,  15.    Reprinted  by  permission  of 
Harcourt,  Brace  and  Company,  Inc. 
.,  p.  21. 


is  Ibid.,  p.  26. 


460      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

The  Invention  of  Printing  and  the  Rise  of  Communication  Through 
Books  and  the  Printed  Page.  While  the  art  of  writing  began  in  the  an- 
cient Orient  with  the  invention  of  the  alphabet,  books  and  printed  com- 
munication were  a  by-product  of  Humanistic  scholarship  in  early  modern 
times.  The  recovery  and  editing  of  many  Latin  texts,  the  desire  for 
greater  permanence  and  uniformity  in  both  Greek  and  Latin,  and  the 
growing  volume  of  contemporary  literature,  all  made  imperative  a  more 
facile  mode  of  putting  words  on  paper  than  the  laborious  copying  which 
existed  from  Oriental  times  to  the  close  of  the  Middle  Ages. 

It  is  a  common  practice  to  refer  to  the  "invention  of  printing"  in  the 
fifteenth  century.  However,  the  elements  which  entered  into  the  achieve- 
ments of  Coster  and  Gutenberg  rested  upon  a  complex  of  inventions  run- 
ning back  over  thousands  of  years. 

The  Egyptians  suggested  an  alphabet  before  there  was  anything  to 
write  upon  except  stone  and  clay  bricks.  The  Syrian  Semites,  the 
Phoenicians,  and  the  Greeks  perfected  the  Egyptian  alphabet,  and  the 
Romans  invented  the  particular  form  of  letters  we  now  use.  But  in 
classical  times  formal  literature  was  written  entirely  in  capitals,  smaller 
or  lower-case  letters  being  employed  only  in  commercial  and  epistolary 
documents.  Small  letters  were  first  commonly  used  by  Alcuin  and  his 
monks  in  the  days  of  Charlemagne,  and  are  known  as  Carolingian  minus- 
cule. 

The  first  writing  material  was  stone.  Then  came  the  clay  bricks  of 
Mesopotamia.  The  Egyptians  used  papyrus,  brittle  fabric  made  from 
the  fiber  of  a  reed.  The  later  Mesopotamians,  the  Greeks,  and  the 
Romans  used  parchment,  chiefly  sheepskin,  and  papyrus.  Papyrus 
gradually  went  out  of  use  in  the  early  medieval  period.  It  has  been 
humorously  said  that  the  prolific  church  fathers  exhausted  the  supply, 
but  the  Muslim  occupation  of  Egypt  had  something  to  do  with  the  dis- 
appearance of  papyrus  in  the  West.  Further,  the  codex,  or  first  paged 
book,  then  became  popular,  and  papyrus  was  not  so  well  adapted  for  this 
as  for  the  scroll  book — papyrus  or  other  material  rolled  on  a  rod.  Hence, 
parchment  became  the  most  common  writing  material  from  the  sixth 
•century  to  the  thirteenth.  Paper,  after  its  migrations  from  China  to 
Egypt  and  Spain,  was  widely  used  in  the  West  by  the  thirteenth  and 
fourteenth  centuries. 

The  first  modern  type  of  book — the  codex — was  found  in  the  later 
Roman  Empire.  It  was  a  volume  made  up  into  rectangular  pages,  but 
much  larger  than  our  books*  Because  of  their  form  we  refer  to  early 
texts  of  the  Bible,  around  the  fourth  century  A.D.,  as  the  Codex  Vaticanus, 
the  Codus  Alexandrinus,  and  so  on.  Most  of  the  beautiful  books  of  the 
medieval  period  had  a  larger  format  than  is  common  today. 

Early  medieval  bookmaking  was  done  chiefly  by  monks.  The  closest 
analogue  to  our  publishing  house  was  the  monastic  scriptorium,  where 
manuscripts  were  copied  for  secular  as  well  as  ecclesiastical  purposes. 
With  the  rise  of  universities,  a  moderately  flourishing  book  trade  de- 
veloped. University  authorities  controlled  the  trade  and  supervised  the 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      461 

copying  of  textbooks.  Lay  scribes  now  entered  the  profession,  although 
the  monks  still  dominated  it.  The  copyists  could  meet  the  demand  for 
books  because  there  was  no  such  book  market  as  there  is  today.  Few 
people  could  read  and  fewer  could  write.  Of  the  literate  minority,  only  a 
small  fraction  needed  books.  Indeed,  many  an  American  artisan  today 
owns  more  books  than  were  known  even  to  the  greatest  scholars  of  the  thir- 
teenth century.  The  schools  and  universities  used  only  a  few  textbooks, 
and  these  sometimes  remained  unchanged  for  centuries.  There  was  none 
of  our  present  high -pressure  book  salesmanship  which  leads  to  frequent 
changes  of  texts.  Aristotle's  Logic  was  the  same  basic  text  in  the  seven- 
teenth century  as  in  the  thirteenth.  Until  the  Protestant  revolt,  few  lay 
communicants  owned  or  read  the  Bible.  A  flourishing  second-hand  trade 
existed,  and  students  frequently  rented  books. 

In  the  late  fourteenth  century  and  the  early  fifteenth,  the  practice  of 
printing  from  whole  pages  carved  word  for  word  on  wooden  blocks  began 
in  western  Europe.  This  device  had  been  known  in  China  many  cen- 
turies. It  was  a  slow  and  expensive  process.  Only  pages  on  which  there 
was  more  pictorial  matter  than  text,  or  fragments  of  books  in  great 
demand,  like  Donatus'  Latin  grammar,  were  printed  in  this  way.  These 
block  books  were  not  widely  produced  and  did  not  materially  affect  the 
common  practice  of  hand-copying. 

The  increasing  intellectual  ferment  of  the  later  Middle  Ages,  reports 
of  travelers,  the  rise  of  universities,  the  development  of  science,  and,  above 
all,  the  Humanists'  recovery  of  ancient  texts  were  a  combination  of  forces 
which  led  to  the  printing  of  books  on  paper  by  means  of  movable  type. 

The  modern  art  of  printing  began  in  western  Europe  with  the  invention 
of  separate,  movable  types  for  each  letter  of  the  alphabet.  Words  could 
be  assembled  by  hand  and  arranged  to  make  up  a  page,  which  was  then 
printed  on  paper  by  means  of  a  wooden  hand  press.  When  a  page  had 
been  printed  a  sufficient  number  of  times,  the  type  was  removed  from  the 
"form"  and  re-distributed  alphabetically,  and  composition  of  the  next 
page  was  begun.  This  type,  at  first  carved  out  of  wood,  was  eventually 
cast  from  metal.  Once  the  die  or  pattern  for  a  letter  had  been  made, 
countless  letters  could  be  cast  from  the  same  die.  Printing  was  a  slow 
and  tedious  process  until  the  invention  of  modern  typesetting  machines 
— notably  the  linotype  and  monotype — in  the  latter  part  of  the  nine- 
teenth century.  These  made  it  possible  for  the  typesetter,  or  compositor 
as  he  is  usually  called,  by  means  of  a  few  levers  and  a  keyboard  much 
like  that  of  a  typewriter,  to  cast  whole  lines  of  type  ready  to  be  placed 
in  a  press  for  printing.  Though  today  large  display  type,  newspaper 
headlines,  notices,  printed  cards,  and  so  on,  are  set  by  hand,  the  bulk  of 
all  reading  matter  is  machine-set.  The  early  printer,  says  Preserved 
Smith: 

.  .  .  first  had  a  letter  cut  in  hard  metal,  this  was  called  the  punch ;  with  it  he 
stamped  a  mould,  known  as  the  matrix,  in  which  he  was  able  to  found  a  large 
number  of  exactly  identical  types  of  metal,  usually  of  lead.  These,  set  side  by 
side  in  a  case,  for  the  first  time  made  it  possible  satisfactorily  to  print  at  reason- 


462      TRANSPORTAtlON  AND  COMMUNICATION 

able  cost  a  large  number  of  copies  of  the  same  text,  and,  when  that  was  done,  the 
types  could  be  taken  apart  and  used  for  another  work.14 

Type  forms  (styles)  were  at  first  an  imitation  of  the  "black  letter," 
made  with  a  flat-pointed  pen,  which  had  been  used  in  the  handwritten 
manuscripts  of  the  Middle  Ages.  Later  on  stylized  versions  of  the  letter- 
ing on  Roman  stone  monuments  and  tablets  were  cast.  Both  forms  have 
survived.  We  see  the  medieval  script  today  in  German  books,  news- 
papers, and  magazines,  as  well  as  in  the  "Old  English"  and  similar  type 
faces  used  for  emphasis  or  display  in  legal  and  church  documents,  and  in 
newspaper  titles — that  of  The  New  York  Times,  for  example.  The  com- 
mon "book"  or  "body"  types  such  as  the  one  used  here  arc  derived  from 
the  old  Roman  alphabet  and  the  Carolingian  minuscule  of  the  Prankish 
monks,  and  are  commonly  referred  to  as  "roman"  or  "old  style." 

Half  a  century  of  careful  research  by  scholars  has  failed  to  establish 
with  absolute  certainty  who  actually  invented  printing  by  movable  type.15 
It  is  known,  however,  that  the  invention  took  place  in  the  middle  of  the 
fifteenth  century.  The  two  men  for  whom  primacy  is  usually  claimed  are 
Lourens  Coster  of  Haarlem,  in  Holland,  and  Johann  Gutenberg  of  Mainz, 
in  Germany.  Coster  died  in  1440,  and  our  only  authority  for  his  alleged 
invention  of  printing  is  the  statement  of  an  individual  who  lived  a  century 
later.  Whether  or  not  Gutenberg  actually  "invented"  printing,  he  was 
certainly  the  first  to  convert  it  into  a  practical  art  and  a  productive  indus- 
try. Yet,  curiously  enough,  "nothing  printed  during  his  lifetime  bears  his 
name  as  printer  or  gives  any  information  about  him  in  that  capacity." 
He  was  born  in  Strassburg  in  1398  and  died  in  Mainz  in  1468.  Some 
authorities  believe  that  he  was  engaged  in  printing  as  early  as  1438,  but 
the  first  work  definitely  attributable  to  him  is  an  indulgence  printed  in 
1454.  It  is  also  believed  that  he  printed  Donatus'  Latin  grammar  and 
made  a  particularly  beautiful  edition  of  the  Bible  with  forty-two  lines  to 
a  page.  Whoever  may  have  been  the  inventor  of  printing,  it  is  certain 
that  by  1455  the  practical  and  revolutionary  character  of  the  art  had  been 
thoroughly  demonstrated,  and  that  it  was  no  longer  in  the  experimental 
stage. 

After  the  middle  of  the  fifteenth  century  the  printing  industry  de- 
veloped rapidly.  In  1455  Johann  Fust,  a  former  partner  of  Gutenberg, 
and  Peter  Schoeffer  formed  the  first  great  printing  company.  Schoeffer 
introduced  many  inventions.  He  originated  the  use  of  lead  spacing 
between  the  lines,  also  printing  in  colors,  and  improved  the  art  of  type 
founding.  Strassburg,  Augusburg,  Cologne,  and  Nuremberg  followed 
Mainz  as  important  German  printing  centers.  The  most  famous  German 
printer  of  the  early  sixteenth  century  was  Antony  Koberger  of  Nurem- 
berg, who  made  printing  an  international  industry  by  sending  his  agents 
throughout  Europe  to  find  manuscripts  suitable  for  publication. 


14  The  Age  of  the  Reformation,  Holt,  1920,  pp.  g-9. 

15  Pierce  Butler,  The  Origin  of  Printing  in  Europe,  University  of  Chicago  Press, 
1040. 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      463 

The  craft  spread  to  other  parts  of  Europe.  It  reached  Italy  by  1465, 
Paris  by  1470,  England  by  1480,  Sweden  by  1482,  Portugal  by  1490,  and 
Spain  by  1499.  The  recovery  of  classical  manuscripts  stimulated  the 
printing  trade  in  Italy,  especially  in  Venice.  The  freedom  of  the  press 
in  Holland  encouraged  the  printing  industry  there.  It  is  estimated  that 
by  1500  there  were  in  existence  between  eight  and  nine  million  printed 
books  of  various  kinds  and  sizes. 

The  invention  of  printing  had  incalculable  consequences  in  the  cultural 
history  of  mankind.  As  W.  T.  Waugh  asserts: 

It  may  be  an  exaggeration  to  say  that  it  is  the  most  momentous  invention  in 
the  history  of  the  world,  but  it  is  certainly  the  most  momentous  since  that  of 
writing,  and  of  more  fundamental  consequence  than  any  of  the  countless  inven- 
tions of  the  last  two  centuries,  however  much  they  may  have  transformed  the 
conditions  of  life.16 

Or  as  Professor  Smith  declares: 

The  importance  of  printing  cannot  be  overestimated.  There  are  few  events 
like  it  in  the  history  of  the  world.  The  whole  gigantic  swing  of  modern  democ- 
racy and  of  the  scientific  spirit  was  released  by  it.  The  veil  of  the  temple  of 
religion  and  of  knowledge  was  rent  in  twain,  and  the  arcana  of  the  priest  and 
clerk  exposed  to  the  gaze  of  the  people.  The  reading  public  became  the  supreme 
court  before  whom,  from  this  time,  all  cases  must  be  argued.  The  conflict  of 
opinion  and  parties,  of  privilege  and  freedom,  of  science  and  obscurantism,  was 
transferred  from  the  secret  chamber  of  a  small,  privileged,  professional,  and 
sacerdotal  coterie  to  the  arena  of  the  reading  public.17 

Almost  every  social  institution  and  most  phases  of  our  culture  are  in 
one  way  or  another  instruments  of  communication. "  For  many  thousands 
of  years  the  family  was  the  chief  center  of  communication.  With  the  rise 
of  formal  education,  the  school  came  to  exercise  a  large  part  in  the  com- 
munication function  of  society.  The  church  and  religion  have  done  much 
to  promote  communication.  Libraries  aid  the  process  of  communication 
by  gathering  and  storing  the  accumulated  words  and  language  of  the 
past  and  making  them  available  for  the  present.  Nearly  every  functional 
group,  from  chambers  of  commerce  to  trade  unions,  exercises  the  respon- 
sibility of  communication  in  a  greater  or  less  degree. 

In  the  remainder  of  this  chapter,  however,  we  shall  be  mainly  concerned 
with  the  new  agencies  of  communication  and  transportation  which  domi- 
nate our  machine  and  power  age.  The  activities  of  many  of  the  afore- 
mentioned instruments  of  communication  are  treated  in  other  chapters 
of  the  book. 

The  Revolutionary  Character  of  Modern 
Communication 

The  most  notable  aspect  of  contemporary  technology  has  been  the 
improvement  in  the  transportation  of  persons  and  objects  and  in  com- 


™  History  of  Europe  from  1878  to  1494,  Putnam,  1932,  p.  517, 
"Smith,  op.  cit.,  p.  10. 


464      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

munication  of  information.  It  has  broken  down  the  isolation  of  previous 
days  and  lessened  the  intellectual  import  of  geographical  distance ;  it  has 
created  new  mental  attitudes  and  modified  the  operation  of  older  ones; 
and  it  has  produced  a  whole  new  series  of  social  and  cultural  problems. 

At  the  opening  of  the  nineteenth  century  it  took  from  four  days  to  a 
week  to  carry  news  on  horseback  from  New  York  to  Boston.  The  War 
of  1812  began  because  there  was  no  Atlantic  cable  to  bring  us  the  news 
that  the  British  had  abolished  their  Orders  in  Council,  which  were  the 
immediate  cause  of  our  entering  the  war.  Likewise,  the  bloody  battle  of 
New  Orleans  was  fought  after  peace  had  been  signed  by  the  British  and 
American  delegates  at  Ghent.  In  the  'forties  of  the  last  century  it 
required  five  months  of  heroic  effort  by  Marcus  Whitman  to  make  the 
trip  from  the  State  of  Washington  to  the  City  of  Washington.  Even  as 
late  as  1909,  when  Admiral  Robert  E.  Peary  discovered  the  North  Pole, 
months  elapsed  before  he  could  emerge  from  the  polar  region  and  make 
his  discovery  known.  When  Admiral  Richard  Byrd  discovered  the  South 
Pole  in  1926,  however,  The  New  York  Times  radio  station  picked  up 
the  news  of  the  crossing  of  the  Pole  as  it  was  being  radioed  back  by 
Byrd  to  his  base  camp.  From  the  standpoint  of  the  communication  of 
information,  then,  distance  has  been  almost  eliminated. 

A  Brief  Survey  of  the  Development  of  the 
Agencies  of  Communication 

We  have  already  pointed  out  that  human  civilization  differs  from  the 
life  of  lower  animals  mainly  in  being  a  symbolic  culture  made  possible 
by  the  mastery  of  language.  The  more  rapid  and  facile  communication 
within  and  between  groups  has  played  a  vital  role  in  the  course  of  history. 

Groups  which  cannot  communicate  with  others  are  almost  sure  to  have 
a  backward,  stagnant,  and  unprogressive  culture.  The  greater  the  con- 
tact between  groups,  the  greater  the  possibility  of  spreading  novel  and 
valuable  information  and  of  creating  a  progressive  culture. 

Communication  created  an  inter-group  and  later  an  international  eco- 
nomic specialization  and  division  of  labor.  The  rice  of  commerce  has 
had  a  great  influence  upon  social  classes  and  political  institutions. 

In  the  social  field,  communication  has  brought  about  knowledge  of  new 
folkways  and  customs,  helped  to  create  scepticism  about  older  institu- 
tions, promoted  social  flexibility  and  progress,  and  increased  toleration. 
The  institutions  of  an  isolated  group  are  almost  invariably  backward  and 
stagnant.  The  character  and  social  significance  of  the  growth  of  com- 
munication have  been  admirably  stated  by  T.  A.  M.  Craven: 

If  not  the  most  important,  probably  one  of  the  most  important  reasons  for  the 
progressive  widening  of  the  individual  human  being's  perception  of  the  world 
around  him  has  been  the  tremendous  growth  in  communications  during  the  last 
half  century.  This  led  to  a  concomitant  shrinkage  in  the  size  of  the  earth  as  a 
whole  viewed  from  a  relative  standpoint,  and  today  there  is  hardly  a  place  on 
the  surface  of  the  globe  which  is  not  within  almost  immediate  hailing  distance, 


TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION      465 

when  we  consider  the  hailing  to  be  done  by  one  of  our  many  modern  communica- 
tion methods. 

As  man  has  learned  to  wrest  from  nature  the  various  tools  by  which  he  enriches 
human  experience,  communication  has  always  been  one  of  his  immediate  con- 
siderations. In  the  days  when  social  units  consisted  first  of  farlfclies  and  then  of 
clans,  beginning  with  the  Stone  Age,  man  hewed  his  messages  onto  rough  slabs 
of  rock  broken  from  the  walls  of  his  dwelling  place  in  the  caves.  Through  the 
times  of  the  nomadic  forest  dwellers  who  signaled  to  one  another  by  means  of 
crude  marks  chopped  on  the  sides  of  trees  and  by  smoke  signals,  down  to  the 
present  when  two  important  business  houses,  one  in  London  and  the  other  in 
New  York,  can  carry  on  a  highly  technical  arbitrage  business  with  16-second 
delivery  from  sender  to  addressee,  the  need  for  communications  has  been  one 
of  the  first  thoughts  in  the  mind  of  man  after  his  primary  requirements  of  food, 
shelter,  and  clothing  were  satisfied.18 

The  course  of  history  well  illustrates  the  importance  of  communica- 
tion. Many  isolated  cultures  have  existed  for  thousands  of  years  with- 
out making  any  notable  progress.  Factors  which  promoted  contacts, 
travel,  and  the  growth  of  trade  helped  to  bring  about  the  birth  of  civiliza- 
tion in  the  ancient  Near  Orient.  The  progress  of  transportation  to  the 
point  of  horseback  travel  and  the  building  of  passable  roads  made  the 
great  Persian  Empire  possible.  The  civilization  of  the  Greeks  rested 
largely  upon  the  seafaring  life  of  cities  like  Athens  and  their  contacts 
with  most  of  the  cultures  of  the  Mediterranean  basin.  The  Roman  Em- 
pire rested  upon  the  most  elaborate  development  of  communication  known 
in  the  ancient  world.  But  Roman  imperial  ambitions  outran  the  trans- 
portation and  communication  facilities  of  that  era,  and  the  inadequacies 
thereof  were  a  chief  cause  of  the  decline  of  the  Roman  Empire. 

One  of  the  main  reasons  for  the  backward  character  of  medieval  civi- 
lizations was  the  destruction  or  decline  of  earlier  methods  of  communica- 
tion and  the  relapse  into  local  and  isolated  cultures.  Towards  the  later 
Middle  Ages,  inventions  such  as  the  compass  and  other  marine  aids  made 
possible  the  conquest  of  the  ocean,  the  discovery  of  America,  the  Com- 
mercial Revolution,  and  the  rise  of  modern  civilization.  The  Commercial 
Revolution  led  directly  to  the  Industrial  Revolution  and  the  rise  of  our 
modern  methods  of  transportation  and  communication.  Modern  civi- 
lization is,  in  large  part,  the  product  of  ever  improved  methods  of  com- 
munication and  transportation.  The  world-wide  aspect  of  our  contem- 
porary civilization  is  almost  wholly  an  outgrowth  of  the  present-day 
agencies  of  transportation  and  communication. 

Land  transportation  began  on  primitive  footpaths.  It  later  developed 
into  roads  traversed  on  horseback  and  in  carts  and  wagons.  The  Persians 
were  the  first  to  develop  a  fair  system  of  roads  over  great  areas.  The 
Greek  roads  were  notoriously  poor,  and  this  accounts  for  the  backward 
character  of  Greek  culture  in  the  states  that  did  not  have  access  to  the 
sea.  The  Romans  were  the  greatest  road  builders  of  antiquity,  but  foot 
and  horse  travel  on  the  best  of  roads  was  not  adequate  to  the  needs  and 


18  Technological  Trends  and  National  Policy,  Government  Printing  Office,  1937, 
pp.  211-212. 


466      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      . 

perplexities  of  the  vast  Roman  Empire.  Medieval  roads  were  poor 
except  where  they  could  follow  along  the  old  Roman  highways.  Not 
until  Telford  and  Macadam  introduced  scientific  road-building  at  the 
beginning  of  tte  nineteenth  century  were  adequate  highways  provided 
for  modern  life.  These  men  made  good  roads  possible;  the  invention 
of  the  automobile  made  them  mandatory.  In  the  last  half  of  the  nine- 
teenth century,  railroads  revolutionized  land  transport,  and  in  the  twen- 
tieth century  the  automobile  carried  the  conquest  of  land  transport  still 
further.  The  airplane  has  revolutionized  transport  over  both  land  and 
water. 

Water  transport  began  with  small  rafts  and  rowboats  on  rivers.  The 
ancient  world  conquered  the  seas  and  modern  civilization  triumphed  over 
the  oceans.  The  motive  power  for  water  transportation  began  with  the 
natural  current  of  rivers.  Then,  in  succession,  boats  were  propelled  by 
oars  and  by  sails;  finally  by  steam  engines,  internal  combustion  engines, 
and  electricity. 

Communication  began  among  primitive  peoples  by  signaling  with 
fires  and  smoke  on  hilltops.  The  Greeks  signaled  from  towers  on  moun- 
tains. Then,  messages  were  carried  by  foot  messengers  and  runners. 
After  the  Kassites  introduced  the  use  of  the  horse  about  2000  B.C., 
mounted  couriers  supplied  the  most  rapid  method  of  communication 
known  until  the  invention  of  railroads,  except  for  the  limited  use  of  carrier 
pigeons.  In  the  last  decade  of  the  eighteenth  century,  the  Chappee 
brothers  in  France  invented  a  method  of  signaling  by  semaphores  which 
was  utilized  to  some  degree  by  Napoleon.  But  the  railroad  provided  the 
most  speedy  means  of  communication  prior  to  the  invention  of  various 
electrical  devices  after  1840,  such  as  the  telegraph,  the  telephone,  and  the 
radio. 

The  steam  engine  and  railroads  made  a  dependable  postal  system 
possible.  In  the  twentieth  century  came  the  most  rapid  and  spectacular 
of  all  transportation  triumphs,  the  airplane  and  air  mail  service.  The 
invention  of  printing  facilitated  the  use  of  all  these  mechanical  agents  of 
transportation  and  communication  in  transmitting  information  over  wide 
afeas.  Especially  important  was  the  growth  of  the  contemporary  news- 
paper as  a  medium  of  information  which  can  be  shipped  rapidly  over 
great  distances.  But  the  newspaper  depended  not  only  upon  the  mechan- 
ical art  of  printing  and  the  rise  of  the  railroad  to  transport  printed  papers 
but  also  upon  the  new  electrical  devices  which  made  possible  the  rapid 
accumulation  and  transmission  of  news. 

While  newspapers  date  from  the  latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  century, 
the  large  modern  daily  newspaper  could  not  have  existed  before  the 
American  Civil  War.  It  depends  upon  the  linotype  machine,  which  was 
first  introduced  in  1876,  and  the  rotary  printing  press,  which  was  in- 
vented a  half  century  earlier  but  was  not  generally  introduced  into  news- 
paper offices  until  about  the  same  time  as  the  linotype  machines. 

Aside  from  the  telegraph  and  Atlantic  cable,  the  electrical  equipment 
upon  which  newsgathering  depends  likewise  dates  from  the  same  period 


TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION      467 

or  much  later.  The  telephone  was  invented  in  1876;  radio  messages  and 
pictures  are  a  relatively  recent  achievement,  coming  since  the  first  World 
War. 

The  earliest  successful  demonstrations  of  the  telegraph  took  place 
between  1837  and  1844.  The  first  successful  Atlantic  cable  was  laid  in 
1866.  Alexander  Graham  Bell  invented  the  telephone  in  1876.  Marconi 
sent  the  first  wireless  message  across  the  Atlantic  in  1901.  Edison  and 
Armat  laid  the  basis  for  the  moving  picture  in  1895,  but  the  first  real 
story  movie  was  not  turned  out  until  1905.  It  took  10  years  more  to 
create  large-scale  movie  production,  which  was  first  notably  successful  in 
the  "Birth  of  a  Nation,"  presented  in  1915.  In  1927,  the  first  crude  sound 
pictures  were  presented.  The  radio  slowly  progressed  from  1909  until 
1920,  by  which  time  its  basic  technical  foundations,  prior  to  frequency 
modulation,  had  been  worked  out.  But  it  took  nearly  10  years  more  to 
give  us  a  first-class  radio  set.  Today  we  seem  on  the  eve  of  the  radio 
newspaper,  which  will  automatically  print  the  major  news  events  of  the 
world.  Television  was  steadily  improved  during  the  'thirties  and  is  now 
being  launched  for  commercial  distribution.  It  combines  the  radio  and 
moving  picture  in  reproducing  current  events. 

Outstanding   Improvements  in  Travel  and 
Transportation   Facilities 

Among  the  outstanding  changes  in  communication  agencies  in  the 
present  century  has  been  the  improvement  and  diversification  of  passenger 
transportation  due  to  better  railroad  transportation,  the  advent  of  the 
automobile  and  motorbus,  advances  in  the  quality  and  mileage  of  good 
highways,  and  the  rise  of  airplane  traffic. 

The  major  aspects  of  railroad  engineering,  both  with  respect  to  rolling 
stock  and  trackage,  as  well  as  the  financial  system  associated  with  the 
railroads,  is  a  heritage  from  the  last  century.  In  1940,  there  were 
approximately  235,000  miles  of  railroads  in  the  United  States,  with  a  total 
operated  trackage  of  408,000  miles.  This  marked  a  slight  decline  from 
the  first  World  War  period;  in  1916  the  mileage  was  254,000  and  the  track- 
age, 397,000.  The  high  point  was  reached  in  1929,  with  a  mileage  of 
249,000  and  a  trackage  of  429,000. 

The  outstanding  items  in  American  railroad  history  in  the  twentieth 
-century  have  been  the  improvement  in  train  construction  and  service  and 
competition  by  private  automobiles,  motorbuses,  trucks,  and  airplanes. 
In  1920,  the  railroad  passenger-miles  per  capita  amounted  to  444.6. 
There  had  been  a  definite  gain  since  1900,  when  the  figure  stood  at  212.5. 
The  extent  and  sharpness  of  automobile  competition  in  the  'twenties  are 
shown  by  the  fact  that,  in  1930,  the  railroad  passenger  miles  per  capita 
had  dropped  to  218.3,  thus  almost  wiping  out  the  gains  of  30  years.  The 
figure  continued  to  drop  and  stood  at  179.2  in  1940,  though  this  was  an 
advance  over  the  depression  years.  Tables  I,  II,  and  III  indicate  the 
recent  history  of  railroad  mileage  and  railroad  traffic. 


468      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

MILES  OF  RAILWAY  LINE 


The  total  mileage  of  railway  lines  in  the  continental  United  States  is 
shown  in  the  following  table:  10 

TABLE  I 

TOTAL  RAILWAY  MILEAGE 

1916                           254,037      1932 247,595 

1921 ::: 251,176  1933 245,703 

1926 249,138      1934 243,857 

1927 249^31      1935 241,822 

1928     249,309      1936 240,104 

929 ::.' 249433      1937 238,539 

1930 249,052      1938 236,842 

1931  .'.'..'.'.'.'.'.'.'.'.'.'.' 248,829      1940 233,670 

Figures  follow  showing  the  number  of  revenue  passengers  carried  by 
the  Class  I  lines. 


TABLE  II 
REVENUE  PASSENGERS  CARRIED 

1916          1,005,954,777      1932    478,800,122 

1921     '  ....     1,035,496,329      1933    432,979,887 

1926 . . ' 862,361,333      1934    449,775,279 

1927  " "       829,917,845      1935    445,872,300 

1928  "  .  .       790,327,447      1936    490,091,317 

1929 780,468,302      1937    497,288,356 

1930  .' 703,598,121      1938    452,731,040 

1931  "..'!    596,390,924      1941    486,582,138 


i9  Figures  in  Tables,  I,  II,  and  III  are  taken  from  A  Yearbook  of  Railroad  Informs 
tion,  Association  of  American  Railroads,  Washington,  1940,  with  additions  for  1941 , 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      469 

The  following  figures  show  the  passenger  traffic  of  the  Class  I  railways 
in  terms  of  revenue  passenger-miles. 

TABLE  III 
TOTAL  PASSENGER-MILES 

1916 34,585,952,026  1932 16,971,044,205 

1921  37,312,585,966  1933 16,340,509,724 

1926 35,477,524,581  1934 18,033,309,043 

1927 33,649,706,115  1935 18,475,571,667 

1928 31,601,341,798  1936 22,421,009,033 

1929 31,074,134,542  1937 24,655,414,121 

1930 26,814,824,535  1938 21,628,718,038 

1931  21,894,420,536  1941  29,359,895,428 

In  the  1920's  the  American  railroads  began  to  encounter  serious  com- 
petition from  automobiles,  motorbuses,  and  trucks.  Private  automobiles 
carried  many  on  business  and  pleasure  trips  that  had  previously  been 
made  by  railroad  travel.  Even  transcontinental  trips  began  to  be  made 
by  motorbus.  For  shipments  of  perishable  or  relatively  light  commodi- 
ties, especially  on  trips  of  500  miles  or  less,  automotive  trucking  proved  a 
serious  competitor  with  the  express  and  freight  service  of  railroads.  In 
the  1930's  air  travel  was  added  as  another  form  of  competition  with  rail- 
road service. 

After  1930  the  railroads  woke  up  and  took  belated  steps  to  make  train 
travel  more  attractive  and  efficient.  Some  of  the  railroads  reduced  the 
abnormally  high  passenger  rates  of  1914-1930,  thus  offering  the  induce- 
ment of  economy.  The  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  compelled 
many  other  railroads  to  reduce  fares  and  thus  increase  revenue  from 
passenger  traffic.  The  passenger  fare  was  reduced  throughout  the  coun- 
try to  two  cents  a  mile  in  coaches,  with  some  of  the  Southern  railroads 
dropping  their  rate  as  low  as  one  cent  a  mile  in  coaches  on  all  but  the 
crack  trains.  Since  1939  some  railroads  have  facilitated  travel,  especially 
summer  travel,  by  making  it  possible  to  pay  for  long  trips  on  the  install- 
ment plan.  Railroad  travel  increased,  though  nothing  like  the  traffic 
before  1915  was  ever  recaptured. 

There  has  been  a  marked  improvement  in  the  speed  and  equipment  of 
railroad  trains.  The  conventional  steam  locomotives  have  been  built  to 
travel  faster  and  to  draw  more  coaches,  and  many  have  been  streamlined. 
A  number  of  railroad  lines  have  been  electrified,  particularly  on  the 
Atlantic  Seaboard  and  in  the  Northwest.  But  the  most  remarkable  in- 
novation has  been  the  development  of  Diesel-driven  motor  trains.  One 
of  the  pioneers,  the  Zephyr  of  the  Chicago,  Burlington  &  Quincy  Railroad, 
covered  the  1,015  miles  from  Denver  to  Chicago  in  785  minutes,  at  an 
average  speed  of  77.6  miles  per  hour,  making  a  top  speed  of  112.5  miles. 
Diesel-motored  streamlined  trains  have  now  been  rather  widely  intro- 
duced, especially  for  traffic  between  Chicago  and  St.  Louis,  in  the  Mid- 
West,  and  the  Pacific  Coast.  They  represent  the  most  direct  answer  of 
the  railroads  to  both  bus  and  airplane  competition.  Travel  upon  them 
is  clean,  smooth,  and  swift. 


470      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

Telephones  and  stock  tickers  have  been  placed  in  trains  at  terminals. 
Radios  have  been  installed.  The  better  trains  frequently  have  shower 
baths,  barber  shops,  beauty  parlors,  and  luxurious  lounging  quarters. 
Coach  equipment  has  also  been  greatly  improved,  particularly  on  the 
railroads  of  the  Middle  and  Far  West.  One-  or  two-car  trains,  often 
drawn  by  gasoline  engines,  have  been  installed  for  branch-line  service. 
The  comfort  of  summer  travel  has  been  improved  by  the  introduction  of 
air  conditioning. 

In  a  day  in  which  automobile  accidents  are  becoming  ever  more  fre- 
quent and  deadly,  the  greater  safety  of  railroad  transportation  cannot 
be  overlooked.  The  days  of  frequent  and  bloody  accidents  are  past. 
Steel  coaches,  automatic  block  signal  systems,  and  the  like,  have  reduced 
passenger  mortality.  In  the  year  1935,  not  a  single  passenger  was  killed 
while  en  route  on  a  railroad  in  the  United  States.  This  is  especially 
impressive,  when  one  reflects  that  the  total  passenger  miles  in  this  year 
were  over  18  billion,  and  approximately  450  million  passengers  were 
carried.  A  serious  railroad  wreck  is  a  rarity  today  and,  almost  without 
exception,  wrecks  are  due  to  a  washout  or  some  other  "act  of  God,"  to 
sabotage  or  criminal  acts,  or  to  gross  disobedience  of  orders  by  train 
crews.  It  would  be  difficult  to  reduce  train  wrecks  below  the  current 
minimum. 

A  final  and  more  drastic  method  of  dealing  with  motorbus  competition 
has  been  the  growing  trend  of  railroads  to  buy  up  motorbus  lines. 

The  railroads  could  stand  up  under  the  new  forms  of  competition  more 
successfully,  were  it  not  for  the  tremendous  burden  of  overcapitalization 
which  they  have  inherited  from  the  days  of  high  finance  in  railroad  con- 
trol and  operation  back  in  the  last  century,  when  railroads  were  as  much 
gambling  devices  as  transportation  systems.  Railroad  financing  and 
business  methods  have  greatly  improved  since  1900. 

Most  persons,  when  they  think  of  railroads,  limit  their  ideas  to  pas- 
senger service,  but  the  freight  service  is  even  more  important  in  the 
work  of  the  nation.  The  competition  of  trucks  after  1920  stimulated  the 
railroads  to  improve  their  freight  facilities.  Some  of  the  more  notable 
gains  in  freight  service  have  been  summarized  by  M.  J.  Gormley,  in  an 
article  on  "Railway  Problems  of  1941": 

BAIL  IMPROVEMENTS  SINCE  WORLD  WAR 

$9,500,000,000  spent  since  1923  for  improvements — divided  45  per  cent  for  equip- 
ment; 55  per  cent  for  other  facilities  of  all  kinds. 

Result  of  Expenditures 

1,146,000  cars  and 

17,000  locomotives  installed  new  since  1923 
1,800,000  cars  and 

40,000  locomotives  retired. 
17%  increase  in  capacity  of  cars 
36%  increase  in  capacity  of  locomotives 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      471 


Efficiency  in  Operation 

60%  increase  in  train  speed 
100%  increase  in  tons  per  train  hour 
62,000  cars  per  week  can  be  loaded  now  for  each  100,000  cars  owned,  compared 

with  a  loading  of 

42,000  cars  per  week  for  each  100,000  serviceable  cars  owned  in  1918. 
8,000,000  more  carloads  loaded  in  1929  than  in  1918,  with  a  considerable  de- 
crease in  the  ownership  of  cars  and  locomotives. 

$30,000,000  less  demurrage  collected  in  1939  than  was  collected  in  1918,  a  decrease  of 
83%,  with  a  decrease  of  only  30%  in  the  number  of  loaded  cars;  a 
further  indication  of  more  prompt  unloading  by  receivers.-0 

The  total  number  of  freight  cars  in  the  United  States  reached  their 
high  in  1926,  with  2,348,679 ;  they  had  dropped  to  1,650,031  in  1939.  This 
was  offset  in  some  degree  by  the  greater  carrying  capacity  of  the  newer 
cars,  but  it  reflected  mainly  the  loss  of  traffic  to  motor  trucks.  There 
were  2,764,222  of  these  registered  in  1926,  and  4,413,692  in  1939.  The 
average  speed  of  freight  trains  increased  from  11.9  miles  per  hour  in 
1926  to  16.7  in  1939.  The  efficiency  of  freight  service  per  hour  increased 
from  an  average  of  9,201  tons  in  1926  to  13,449  in  1939. 

The  most  important  innovation  in  travel  since  the  development  of  the 
railroad  has  been  the  rise  of  the  automobile.  The  essential  mechanical 
inventions  upon  which  the  automobile  is  based  were  made  in  the  nine- 
teenth century,  but  their  application  to  the  mass  production  of  efficient 
and  attractive  cars  at  a  low  price  has  been  an  achievement  of  the 
twentieth  century.  Automobiles  were  becoming  common  on  the  eve  of 
the  first  World  War,  but  their  mass  popularity  really  dates  from  the  post- 
war period.  The  mass  production  of  cheap  cars  by  Henry  Ford  first 
became  significant  about  1913.  But  the  Model  T  Ford  was  an  un- 
attractive vehicle.  Ford  finally  gave  up  his  Model  T  because  General 
Motors  cut  deeply  into  his  market  by  producing  a  low-priced  and  more 
beautiful  car.  It  was  not  until  1928,  however,  that  Ford  produced  a 
car  that  was  at  once  cheap,  dependable,  and  attractive.  Even  more 
advanced  was  his  first  eight-cylinder  car  produced  in  1932.  By  this 
time  other  motorcar  companies,  especially  General  Motors  and  the 
Chrysler  Corporation,  had  fallen  in  line  with  Ford's  mass-production 
methods  and  a  new  era  of  fast,  beautiful,  and  dependable  cars  at  a  low 
price  came  into  being. 

The  peak  of  automobile  production  came  in  1929,  when  a  total  of 
5,621,715  cars  and  trucks  were  turned  out  in  the  United  States  and  Can- 
ada. There  was  a  bad  slump  during  the  depression,  but  in  1936  and  1937 
there  was  an  approximation  to  the  1929  high,  with  a  figure  of  5,016,437  for 
1937.  Automobile  registrations  increased  after  1929,  reaching  31,468,887 
in  1940.  The  automobile  registration  in  the  United  States  alone  amounted 
to  over  70  per  cent  of  the  world's  total,  which  was  45,422,411  in  1940. 
Of  these,  27,300,000  were  passenger  cars.  The  automobile  has  revolu- 


20  Loc.  cit.,  pp.  4-5.    (Pamphlet  published  by  the  Association  of  American  Rail- 
roads.) 


472      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

tionizcd  the  travel  habits  of  America.     As  Malcolm  M.  Willey  and  Stuart 
A.  Rice  have  observed: 

The  American  people  have  become  remarkably  mobile.  The  automobile  has 
fostered  a  widespread  travel  psychology.  Spontaneity  and  universality  dis- 
tinguish contemporary  from  earlier  travel.  The  popular  expression  "hop  in"  has 
more  than  surface  meaning;  it  typifies  a  state  of  mind.  Travel  for  necessity 
and  travel  for  the  sake  of  travel  (pleasure  travel)  alike  are  involved  in  the 
enhanced  mobility.  The  trip  of  a  few  hours'  duration  (the  drive)  and  the  longer 
pleasure  trip  (touring)  have  become  accepted  parts  of  modern  life.  It  is  the 
general  extension  of  the  touring  habit  that  is  particularly  impressive.21 

The  extent  of  automobile  traffic  is  almost  incredible.  Willey  and  Rice 
estimate  that  in  1930  some  404,000,000,000  passenger  miles  were  traveled 
by  the  occupants  of  passenger  cars  alone.  This  extensive  automobile 
travel  has  brought  about  many  new  economic  problems  and  social  habits. 
Hotels  have  in  many  cases  been  thrown  out  of  business,  because  people 
preferred  to  keep  on  the  move  rather  than  to  settle  down  in  some  tradi- 
tional resort.  The  hotels  that  have  survived  have  been  compelled  to 
transform  their  facilities  to  deal  with  a  transient  automobile  clientele 
rather  than  with  permanent  seasonal  guests.  A  large  business  has  been 
built  up  in  the  form  of  tourist  lodgings  in  private  dwellings.  Then  there 
are  many  tourist  camps.  There  is  a  growing  tendency  to  license  and 
inspect  such  roadside  camps. 

A  recent  development  has  been  the  growth  of  the  passenger  trailer.  It 
is  estimated  that  in  1936  about  50,000  tourist-type  trailers  were  manu- 
factured, &nd  even  this  production  could  not  keep  up  with  the  demand. 
The  trailers  range  in  price  from  $200  to  $4,000,  the  average  being  around 
$650.  Instead  of  merely  putting  Americans  on  wheels,  trailers  put  the 
American  home  on  wheels.  Roger  Babson  predicted  that  within  twenty 
years  half  the  population  of  the  United  States  would  be  living  in  trailers. 
Any  such  spectacular  development  is  unlikely,  but  no  doubt  the  trailer 
will  contribute  markedly  to  the  mobility  of  the  American  population. 
A  most  unfortunate  development  has  been  the  increase  of  automobile 
accidents.  The  fatalities  therefrom  in  the  United  States  ran  to  over 
35',000  in  1940. 

The  effect  of  the  automobile  upon  American  morals  is  warmly  debated. 
It  has  served  to  undermine  many  of  the  old  folkways  and  customs ;  it  has 
somewhat  lessened  church-going;  and  it  has  probably  led  to  greater  laxity 
in  sex  habits. 

Motorbuses  are  somewhat  inconvenient  for  long  trips,  but  their  cheap- 
ness appeals  to  the  mass  of  travelers.  While  much  more  safe  than  a 
decade  ago,  they  are  still  far  behind  the  railroads  from  the  standpoint  of 
safety  and  dependability  in  travel.  The  motorbus  was  fairly  common 
in  urban  transportation  in  large  cities  before  the  first  World  War,  but  its 
use  for  interurban  transportation  has  been  chiefly  a  post-war  develop- 
ment. By  1930,  motorbuses  were  carrying  annually  1,778,000,000  rev- 
enue passengers.  By  1936,  the  figure  had  jumped  to  2,869,000,000.  In 


21  Recent  Social  Trends  in  the  United  States,  McGraw-Hill,  1933,  Vol.  I,  p.  186. 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      473 

1940,  the  number  was  4,238,000,000.  There  is  an  elaborate  network  of 
motorbus  lines  covering  the  entire  country,  many  of  them  operating  swift 
express  buses  in  interstate  traffic.22  In  1940  interurban  buses  carried 
slightly  over  350,000,000  revenue  passengers.  In  the  last  decade,  urban 
motorbuses  have  all  but  supplanted  the  electric  trolley  lines.  Motorbuses 
have  made  possible  the  centralization  of  schools,  which  in  turn  has  pro- 
vided better  plant  equipment,  a  more  adequate  teaching  force,  and  a  more 
diversified  curriculum.  At  the  beginning  of  1941,  school  buses  were 
carrying  approximately  4  million  school  children  daily.  The  following 
graph  will  give  a  comprehensive  idea  of  the  motorbus  industry  and  service 
at  the  present  time: 

How  the  Bus  Industry 
Serves  America 


Provides  54,000  Buses 

A  A  A  A  A  A  A 

Serves  4,000,000,000  Revenue  Passengers 

06  *  6  6  6  * 

Operates  1,954,702,000  Revenue  Bus  Miles 


Covers  343,300  Miles  of  Highway 

I  I   II  I   I   I   I 

Employs  125,000  Persons 


Maintains  12,000  Garages  and  Shops 


Provides  10,000  Terminals  and  Rest  Stops 


Courtesy  National  Association  of 
Motorbus  Operators,   Washington. 

The  private  automobile  and  the  motorbus  have  brought  about  a  real 
revolution  in  highway  construction.  Back  in  1904,  there  were  only  about 
150,000  miles  of  surfaced  roads,  with  only  150  miles  of  high-type  surface. 
By  1930,  the  mileage  of  surfaced  roads  had  increased  to  approximately 
700,000,  with  some  125,000  miles  of  high-type  surfaced  roads.  Highways 
ceased  to  be  primarily  a  local  affair  and  were  taken  more  and  more  under 


22  For  a  graphic  account  of  transcontinental  travel  by  motorbus,  see  R.  S.  Tompkins, 
"Ordeal  by  Bus,"  in  The  American  Mercury,  November,  1930.  Motorbus  travel 
facilities  have  improved  since  1930. 


474      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 


state  control  and  supervision.  On  January  1,  1940,  there  were  in  the 
United  States  some  540,000  miles  of  state  highways,  of  which  410,000 
miles  were  surfaced  and  130,000  miles  were  of  high-type  surface.  Most 
of  the  improved  highways  of  our  day  are  state  highways.  The  funds 
for  their  constructing  are  made  possible  by  revenues  derived  from  motor 
vehicle  registration  fees,  gasoline  taxes,  bridge  tolls,  and  fines.  Federal 
aid  in  building  highways  was  notably  extended  under  the  New  Deal. 

The  most  spectacular  innovation  in  transportation  in  the  twentieth 
century  came  with  the  conquest  of  the  air.  The  first  successful  flight  in 
a  heavier-than-air  motor-driven  plane  was  made  at  Kitty  Hawk,  North 
Carolina,  by  the  Wright  brothers  in  1903.  In  1906  they  made  a  non-stop 
flight  of  40  miles.  Three  years  later  Louis  Bleriot  flew  across  the  English 
Channel.  The  first  World  War  brought  about  a  number  of  technical  im- 
provements in  airplane  manufacture.  Commercial  airplane  travel  did 
not,  however,  become  notable  in  the  United  States  until  about  1926. 
Since  that  time  there  has  been  a  remarkable  expansion.  During  1940  the 
major  airlines  of  the  United  States  carried  2,939,647  passengers,  a  new 
record  for  commercial  aviation  in  this  country.  Adding  to  this  the 
passengers  carried  on  trips  in  Canada  and  Latin  America,  the  grand  total 
was  3,162,817.  This  may  be  compared  with  5,782  passengers  in  1926, 
and  1,020,931  in  1936.  The  number  of  passenger-miles  flown  were 
1,261,003,818,  and  some  12,282,560  pounds  of  express  matter  was  carried. 
The  pound-miles  of  air  mail  increased  from  8,265,000,000  in  1936  to 
20,147,000,000  in  1940.  The  graphs  below  and  on  page  476  present  the 
main  facts  about  the  development  of  airplane  traffic  and  the  progress  in 
the  safety  of  air  travel  since  1926. 


TOTAL  ROUTE  MILES 


Source-  Civil  Aeronautics  Journal 


60  SO 

THOUSANDS  OF  MILES 


Note:  Figures  for  the  year  1939  and  1940  do  not 
include  the  operations  of  the  following  affil- 
iated companies  of  Pan  American  Airways 
System:  Cia  Mexicana  de  Aviacion,  S.  A.,  Cia 
Nacional  Cubana  de  Aviacion,  and  Panair 
do  Brasil,  which  prior  to  the  year  1939 
were  included  with  International  figures. 


DOMESTIC    AND   INTERNATIONAL 

1926 
1927 
1928 
1929 
1930 
1931 
1932 
1933 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1938 
1939 
1940 

20     tO     0  •     0     10 
CALENDAR  YEARS 


40     90     60 
THOUSANDS  OF  MILES 


From  Little  Known  Facts,  Air  Transport  Association  of  America. 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      475 

The  speed  of  these  commercial  airplanes  makes  air  travel  especially 
alluring  to  those  who  must,  or  believe  they  must,  make  fast  time.  It  is 
possible  to  leave  New  York  late  one  afternoon  and  have  breakfast  the 
next  morning  in  Los  Angeles.  One  can  fly  from  Cleveland  to  New  York, 
transact  a  day's  business,  and  be  back  in  Cleveland  that  night  for  dinner. 

The  main  drawback  to  air  transportation  is  the  relatively  precarious 
nature  of  air  travel,  which  has  not  yet  been  made  as  safe  as  land  trans- 
portation. Very  few  accidents  today  are  due  to  defects  in  planes  or  to 
the  incompetence  of  pilots.  As  Marquis  W.  Childs  has  pointed  out: 

It  is  true  that  for  ordinary  purposes  of  flight  under  ordinary  circumstances 
the  modern  airplane  is  a  thoroughly  reliable  machine.  .  .  .  The  machine  itself 
can  be  counted  upon  for  an  almost  perfect  performance.  The  pilots  are  of  an 
equally  high  order.  Out  of  a  great  surplus  of  pilots  "the  airlines  choose  by  an 
almost  superhuman  set  of  requirements  and  rigorous  examinations  the  best 
men."  23 

Most  airplane  accidents  happen  during  what  is  known  as  "blind  fly- 
ing," namely,  flying  through  fog  or  bad  weather  which  makes  it  impossible 
to  see  the  ground  and  observe  the  ordinary  signals  that  can  keep  an 
airplane  on  its  course.  Blind  flying  with  passengers  is  not  permitted  in 
most  European  countries,  and  this  restriction  accounts  for  the  low  mor- 
tality rate  of  European  air  travel,  in  spite  of  the  fact  that  Europeans 
admit  that  the  United  States  leads  the  world  in  airplane  engineering  and 
navigation. 

The  dangerous  tendency  to  indulge  in  blind  flying  as  a  general  practice 
in  American  air  travel  is  due  in  part  to  the  unwillingness  of  air  lines  to 
admit  that  their  mode  of  navigation  is  more  at  the  mercy  of  the  elements 
than  railroad  and  bus  traffic,  and  other  competitive  modes  of  travel.  But 
more  than  this  it  is  due  to  the  mania  of  Americans  for  speed  in  travel  and 
the  saving  of  time  for  something  or  other.  Passengers  often  urge  air 
transport  companies  to  make  trips  against  the  latters'  better  judgment 
and  resent  those  cancellations  which  the  air  companies  feel  are  warranted 
by  adverse  flying  conditions. 

Next  to  the  speed  mania  of  the  passengers  comes  the  competitive  spirit 
in  air  travel.  This  induces  certain  air  lines  to  undertake  travel  in  bad 
weather  and  thus  demonstrate  superiority  over  their  competitors.  Then 
we  have  the  competition  of  air  lines  in  trying  to  beat  their  rivals  to  the 
airports,  resulting  in  rash  navigation  and  congestion  at  landing  fields. 

We  may  well  regret  any  black  eye  given  to  air  travel,  for  the  latter  is 
a  substantial  and  permanent  addition  to  human  transportation.  But  it 
is  well  to  know  where  the  reforms  must  be  achieved.  The  sensible  thing 
is  to  follow  the  European  practice  in  tabooing  blind  flying.  As  one 
realistic  commentator  has  observed,  "it  is  better  to  be  ten  hours  late  in 
New  York  or  Los  Angeles  than  thirty  years  early  in  Hell." 

It  is  well,  however,  to  bear  in  mind  that  air  accidents  are  few  and 
trivial  compared  to  our  banner  method  of  killing  off  Americans,  namely, 


23  Harper's,  October,  1936. 


476     TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 


TOTAL  PASSENGER  MILES  FLOWN 

REVENUE  AND  NON-REVENUE 

1 

t 

)OME 

STIC 

AND 

INTE 

RNA 

TION 

At 

Source;  Cvil  Aeronautics  Joumtl 

vxj  Urr/eis  Monthly  Keporu 

1927 

1927 

1926     NotAyoiloUe 

1928 

M 

H 

1928 

1927       " 

•• 

1929 
1930 
1931 
1932 

84,014,572 
106,442,375 
127,038798 
173,492,119 

1 

•1 

1929 
1930 
1931 

Note:  Figures  for  the  yeer  1939  and  1940  do  not 
include  the  operations  of  the  following  affil- 
|           lated  companies  of  Pan  American  Airway* 
i            System.  Cia  Mexicana  de  Avtacion,  S.  A,,  Cia 
1            National  Cubana  de  Aviacion,  and  Panair 

1928       " 
1929       ' 
1930 
1931 
1932 

19732,677 
14,680,402 
21,147,539 

1934 
1935 
1936 

167,858,629 
313,905,508 
435740,253 

1 

• 

•LI 
•• 

1932 
1933 

I           do  Brasil,  which  prior  to  the  year  1939 
•           were  Included  with  International  figures. 

1933 
1934 
1935 

26,283,915 
38792,228 
48,465,412 

1937 
1931 
1939 
194Q. 

476,603,165 
557719,26* 
749787,096 
1.144  163J18* 

I 

•1 

•I 

•1 

1934 
1935 

£ 

1937 
1938 

1939 

58443,618 
76,045,474 
77436,916 
85,03,146 

940        1 

16j840,C 

= 

= 

= 

••J1937 

5 

DH.S* 

IOC* 

)      X 

10       1C 

10       7<X 

60 

0        » 

X>       40 

0        30 

0        20 

0       10 

0           0              C 

•i 

10 

1 

0        20 

0        » 

0        4( 

0        SO 

0       60 

0 

700       1C 

O      X 

10-      1A 

M 

MILLIONS  OF  MILK 

CALENDAR  YtARS 

MILLIONS  OF  MILES 

MILES  FLOWN  PER  FATAL  ACCIDENT 

'DOMESTIC  AIR  CARRIERS)  So™.  C™t  AWM*  A,AM, 


1936 
1937 
1938 
1939 
1940 


EACH  SYMBOL  IS  THE  EQUIVALENT 
OF  80  TIMES  AROUND  THE  WORLD. 
OR  2  MILLION  MILES  OF  FLYING 


41.28S.76? 
"i  tt.266,812 


From  Little  Known  Facts,  Air  Transport  Association  of  America. 

automobile  travel.  While  following  the  headlines  with  respect  to  color- 
ful air  accidents,  we  too  often  forget  that,  in  1937,  nearly  800  Americans 
lost  their  lives  in  automobile  accidents  over  the  Christmas  week-end 
alone.  The  increased  safety  of  air  travel  may  be  seen  from  the  fact  that, 
in  the  eighteen  months  prior  to  August,  1940,  there  was  not  a  single 
fatality  in  civilian  air  travel  within  the  boundaries  of  the  United  States. 
But  it  was  evident,  from  the  fact  that  there  were  five  bad  accidents  be- 
tween August,  1940,  and  March,  1941,  that  Utopia  had  not  been  realized. 
Nevertheless,  air  travel  is  becoming  ever  safer.  The  striking  progress  in 
safety  is  shown  by  the  fact  that  in  1936  the  miles  flown  per  fatal  accident 
were  7,972,153,  while  in  1940  they  were  36,266,812. 

Progress  in  the  Means  of  Communication 

The  TekgrapL    Of  all  the  innovations  in  contemporary  civilization, 
probably  no  other  group  of  changes  has  been  quite  as  spectacular  and 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      477 

significant  as  the  development  of  the  contemporary  means  of  communi- 
cation.   As  Willey  and  Rice  point  out: 

An  interconnected  system  of  communication  has  come  into  existence  whereby 
the  individual  is  enabled  at  scarcely  a  moment's  notice  to  place  himself  in  contact 
with  almost  any  other  person  in  the  nation.  Speed  and  distance  concepts,  again, 
have  been  totally  recast.  No  longer  do  men  in  any  part  of  the  world  live  to 
themselves  alone.  For  an  increasing  majority  in  the  United  States  and  for  a 
substantial  fraction  in  the  whole  western  world,  the  telephone  bell  is  always 
potentially  within  ear  shot,  the  postman  and  telegraph  messenger  are  just  around 
.the  corner  and  the  cable  and  wireless  may  bring  messages  which  are  dated  the 
day  after  they  are  received.24 

Of  the  methods  of  communication  which  depend  on  electricity,  the 
telegraph  came  first.  It  rested  upon  certain  advances  in  electro-magnetic 
science  in  the  late  eighteenth  and  early  nineteenth  centuries.  The  idea 
of  sending  messages  by  electricity  was  first  set  forth  by  an  anonymous 
writer  in  Scott's  Magazine  in  England  in  1753.  The  first  transmissions 
of  messages  were  made  by  a  German,  Karl  A.  Steinheil,  in  Munich,  in 
1837,  and  by  Sir  Charles  Wheatstone  in  England  in  the  same  year.  But 
the  practical  beginnings  of  the  electric  telegraph  date  from  the  message 
transmitted  from  Baltimore  to  Washington  by  Samuel  F.  B.  Morse  in 
1844.  After  Morse's  time,  telegraph  facilities  on  land  developed  speedily. 
Wires  were  strung  on  poles  between  cities,  and  in  due  time  underground 
cables  in  conduits  were  provided  to  put  the  city  wires  under  the  streets. 
The  transmitting  capacity  of  a  given  mileage  of  wire  was  increased  by 
mechanical  devices  for  sending  and  receiving  the  Morse  code  at  high 
speed.  The  multiplex  system  of  transmission,  invented  by  Edison  and 
Baudot  in  1874,  and  improved  in  1915,  made  it  possible  for  a  single  wire 
to  carry  eight  messages  simultaneously.  The  sheer  speed  of  transmission 
has  been  increased  threefold.  A  message  can  be  sent  from  New  York  to 
London  in  16  seconds.  By  1927,25  there  were  2,145,897  miles  of  single 
wire  and  257,000  miles  of  telegraph  pole  lines  in  the  United  States,  and 
their  efficiency  for  the  transmission  of  messages  was  three  or  four  times 
as  great  as  the  same  number  of  miles  would  have  been  at  the  opening  of 
the  century. 

The  most  remarkable  advance  since  the  first  World  War  has  been  the 
development  of  the  automatic  teletypewriter  or  printer's  telegraph.  This 
has  all  but  superseded  the  Morse  code.  The  operator  no  longer  has  to 
master  the  complicated  Morse  code;  he  needs  only  to  be  a  competent 
touch  typist.  The  operator  writes  on  his  teletypewriter,  and  all  instru- 
ments connected  with  it  can  type  the  same  message  anywhere  in  the 
country.  This  device  simplifies  and  increases  the  speed  of  transmission 
at  least  twofold.  In  the  transmission  of  news,  where  one  operator  sends 
messages  to  a  number  of  receivers,  it  is  estimated  that  the  teletypewriter 
increases  the  efficiency  of  telegraph  service  by  the  ratio  of  fifteen  to  one. 


24  Recent  Social  Trends,  McGraw-Hill,  Vol.  I,  p.  216. 

25  The  figures  are  approximately  the  same  today. 


478      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

From  1930  to  1940,  the  Morse  code  operators  were  very  generally  sup- 
planted by  teletypists.  This  even  took  place  among  railroad  telegraphers. 
In  1910,  some  90  per  cent  of  the  telegrams  were  sent  by  Morse  code;  to- 
day over  95  per  cent  are  transmitted  by  the  automatic  telegraph  type- 
writer. It  has  also  meant  a  shift  in  the  sex  of  operators,  since  most 
teletype  operators  are  women.  An  automatic  self-service  telegraph  which 
the  public  can  operate  is  now  in  the  process  of  perfection  and  will  prob- 
ably soon  be  put  into  active  use.  It  will  be  an  advance  comparable  to 
the  automatic  switchboard  and  the  dialing  system  in  telephony. 

The  increased  use  of  the  telegraph  is  evident  by  the  fact  that,  in  1917," 
the  number  of  messages  sent  was  158,176,000,  whereas  the  number  of 
messages  transmitted  in  1937  was  218,115,000.  This  greater  use  of  the 
telegraph  has  been  brought  about  in  part  by  the  encouragement  of  the 
social  use  of  the  telegraph  for  cut-rate  holiday  and  greeting  messages,  and 
the  like.  Over  twelve  million  are  sent  annually.  Reduced  rates  are  in 
operation  for  so-called  tourist  telegrams,  for  which  ten  words  relating  to 
travel  can  be  sent  anywhere  in  the  United  States  for  thirty-five  cents. 
There  has  also  been  a  drastic  cut  in  the  rates  for  overnight  letters.  Skill- 
ful advertising,  suggested  by  E.  L.  Bernays  26  and  others,  has  popularized 
the  use  of  the  telegraph.  The  great  advantage  of  telegraph  service  today 
lies  in  its  rapid  transmission  of  long-distance  messages  at  a  rate  far  under 
that  charged  for  telephone  messages. 

The  general  expansion  of  the  telegraph  business  and  facilities  since  the 
first  World  War  may  be  seen  from  the  fact  that  between  1917  and  1937 
the  investment  in  plant  and  equipment  increased  by  108  per  cent;. the 
number  of  messages  sent,  by  38  per  cent;  the  number  of  employees,  by 
13  per  cent;  and  the  operating  revenue,  by  27  per  cent. 

The  telegram  still  remains  psychologically  the  most  important  com- 
munication which  the  average  man  can  receive.  The  fact  that  a  telegram 
comes  less  frequently  than  letters  or  telephone  conversations  accounts  in 
part  for  its  importance.  As  Willey  and  Rice  put  it,  "A  crisis  psychology 
has  been  involved  in  its  use  and  its  receipt."  Wider  use  of  the  telegraph 
for  rather  trivial  social  messages  and  greetings  may  in  time  modify  this 
traditional  attitude. 

A  generation  after  Morse  first  demonstrated  the  practicality  of  the 
telegraph,  Morse  and  F.  N.  Gisborne  interested  Cyrus  W.  Field  in  laying 
an  Atlantic  cable.  After  a  series  of  failures,  success  crowned  their  efforts 
in  1866.  Field  was  aided  by  the  great  English  physicist  Lord  Kelvin. 
By  1931,  there  were  21  cable  lines  connecting  North  America  with  Europe. 
The  first  Pacific  cable  was  laid  in  1902.  Greatly  increased  efficiency  has 
been  achieved  in  laying  cables.  Especially  important  is  the  recently 
invented  device  for  plowing  cables  into  the  bottom  of  the  ocean.  This 
eliminates  damage  to  cables  by  fishermen,  which  formerly  involved  an 
annual  repair  bill  of  around  $500,000.  The  efficiency  of  cable  systems 
has  paralleled  that  of  land  telegraph  systems.  Better  relaying  equipment 


26  Bernays  invented  the  slogan,  "Don't  write,  telegraph." 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      479 

has  reduced  the  personnel  required  by  25  per  cent.  The  Permalloy 
cable,  introduced  in  1924,  increased  the  transmission  capacity  from  60 
words  a  minute  to  500  words  a  minute.  The  competition  of  wireless 
telegraphy,  which  was  probably  the  most  dramatic  development  of  the 
twentieth  century,  forced  a  considerable  reduction  of  rates,  thus  in- 
creasing the  use  of  the  cable. 

The  idea  of  a  wireless  telegraph  was  suggested  by  Steinheil  in  1838. 
The  Italian  physicist  Guglielmo  Marconi  (1874-  )  who  began  to  work 
on  his  invention  of  wireless  telegraphy  about  1890,  made  use  of  the  dis- 
coveries of  Heinrich  Hertz  with  respect  to  the  transmission  of  electro- 
magnetic waves  through  the  ether.  In  1899,  he  sent  a  message  across  the 
English  Channel,  and  in  1901  across  the  Atlantic  Ocean.  The  first  com- 
mercial trans-Atlantic  wireless  telegraphy  service  was  launched  in  1908. 
Regular  trans-Atlantic  service  began  in  1910.  In  1914,  wireless  service 
between  San  Francisco  and  Honolulu  was  established,  and  the  next  year 
between  Honolulu  and  Japan.  After  the  first  World  War,  the  United 
States  took  the  lead  in  promoting  wireless  communication  with  all  the 
major  states  of  the  world.  The  number  of  commercial  wireless  messages 
transmitted  increased  from  154,000  in  1907  to  3,777,000  in  1927.  While 
most 'trans-oceanic  communication  is  still  carried  on  by  cable,  wireless 
telegraphy  is  constantly  gaining  in  importance.  It  made  the  countries 
of  the  world  partially  independent  of  cables,  in  case  the  use  of  the  latter 
should  for  any  reason  be  temporarily  suspended.  Wireless  telegraphy 
has  been  especially  important  in  connection  with  the  more  scientific 
control  and  guidance  of  ocean  navigation  and,  along  with  wireless 
telephony,  is  even  more  necessary  to  commercial  aviation. 

Probably  the  wireless  system  will  ultimately  supplant  cable  telegraphy. 
But  the  latter  represented  the  first  important  stroke  in  shrinking  the  size 
of  the  planet,  so  far  as  the  transmission  of  information  is  concerned. 

In  Europe,  the  telegraph  lines  have  been  usually  owned  and  operated 
by  the  governments.  A  similar  development  would  once  have  been  easy 
in  this  country,  for  in  1845  Congress  was  offered  the  opportunity  to  buy 
Morse's  rights  to  the  telegraph  patents  for  $100,000.  Partially  as  the 
result  of  the  opposition  of  the  Postmaster  General,  Congress  turned  down 
this  offer,  thus  taking  a  critical  step  in  the  history  of  American  communi- 
cations. What  is  usually  regarded  as  a  natural  public  function  was 
turned  over  to  private  agencies. 

A  number  of  companies  tried  to  make  money  out  of  the  new  telegraph 
business,  but  the  Western  Union  Telegraph  Company  soon  assumed 
leadership.  It  has  its  origins  in  the  New  York  &  Mississippi  Valley 
Telegraph  Company,  organized  in  1851  by  Hiram  Sibley,  Ezra  Cornell, 
and  Samuel  L.  and  Henry  R.  Selden  of  Rochester,  N.  Y.  In  1854-1856, 
the  Rochester  company  bought  up  most  of  the  existing  small  lines  and 
formed  Western  Union  in  April,  1856.  Cornell,  founder  of  Cornell 
University,  gave  the  new  company  its  name.  It  built  the  first  trans- 
continental telegraph  line,  which  was  opened  in  1861.  In  1866,  it 
absorbed  its  leading  competitors,  the  American  Telegraph  Company  and 


480      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

the  United  States  Telegraph  Company,  and  moved  its  headquarters  from 
Rochester  to  New  York  City.  By  this  time  it  had  2,250  offices  and  75,000 
miles  of  wire.  In  1870,  it  inaugurated  the  practice  of  sending  money  by 
telegraph.  Today  about  275  million  dollars  is  transferred  each  year  by 
telegraph. 

In  the  latter  part  of  the  century  the  rapid  growth  of  the  daily  news- 
papers, with  their  telegraph  services,  helped  on  the  growth  of  the  tele- 
graph. In  the  present  century,  the  telegraph  stock-ticker  systems  also 
became  a  stimulus  to  telegraph  activity.  In  1911,  Western  Union  entered 
extensively  into  the  cable  service  and  now  has  over  30,000  nautical  miles 
of  submarine  cable.  The  new  Permalloy  cables  can  handle  2,400  letters 
per  minute.  In  spite  of  the  ingenuity  and  competition  of  the  Postal 
Telegraph  Company,  Western  Union  controls  today  about  80  per  cent 
of  the  telegraph  business  of  the  country.  The  following  statistical  facts 
will  show  the  extent  of  the  activities  of  Western  Union: 

1,876,867  miles  of  wire 
211,530  miles  of  pole  line 
30,324  nautical  miles  of  ocean  cable  and 
4,070  miles  of  land  line  cable 
19,543  telegraph  offices 
16,208  telegraph  agency  stations 
31,000  employes 
12,000  messengers 
3,400  stock  quotation  tickers 
120,000  time  service  units 
3,000  baseball  tickers 
28,933  stockholders 

11,000  observations  for  daily  weather  reports 
$99,704,000  gross  operating  revenue  (1940) 
$3,621,000  earned  net  income  (1940) 

The  company  prints  each  year  an  average  of  one  billion  telegram  blanks. 

An  average  of  from  150,000,000  to  200,000,000  telegrams  are  handled  a  year,  and 
the  company  transmits  as  much  as  275  million  dollars  in  telegraphic  money  orders 
annually.27 

The  Postal  Telegraph  Company  grew  out  of  the  activities  of  James 
Gordon  Bennett  of  the  New  York  Herald,  and  John  W.  Mackay.  They 
formed  the  Commercial  Cable  Company  in  1883  and  cut  cable  rates  to 
Europe  from  40  cents  to  25  cents  a  word.  Then  they  turned  their  atten- 
tion to  land  telegraphy  and  formed  the  Postal  Telegraph-Cable  Company 
in  1886.  The  company  prospered  under  the  direction  of  Clarence  H. 
Mackay,  son  of  the  founder.  It  transmitted  about  39  million  messages 
in  1940,  and  had  a  total  revenue  of  about  22  million  dollars. 

The  Telephone.  The  telephone  represents  an  even  more  popular  appli- 
cation of  the  services  of  electricity  in  the  field  of  communication  than  the 
telegraph.  The  first  successful  transmission  of  a  telephonic  message  took 
place  on  March  10,  1876.  It  was  sent  by  Alexander  Graham  Bell,  who, 
along  with  his  associate,  Thomas  A.  Watson,  is  generally  credited  with 
the  invention  of  the  telephone,  in  June,  1875,  though  Elisha  Gray  long 


27  Statistics  furnished  by  the  Western  Union  Company. 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      481 


DISTRIBUTION    OF  THE  WORLD'S  TELEPHONES 
January  1. 1940 

ALL  OTHER  EUROPEAN  ^rm***^**— FRANCE 

COUNTRIES  ^    ..-.»'-.'.'. l-v.-.-.-.-.^-.^ 

.^.  n'l'' ' ".'  r^T'*'"  r^  ,        •  GREAT 

ALL   OTHER  •..,-.......,,.•..,.,.•.•/..•  ..:...-......%...:»* 

COUNTRIES 


CANADA 


GERMANY 


OWNERSHIP  OF  THE  WORLD'S  TELEPHONES 
January  1,  1940 


'GOVERNMENT 
40°/o 


PRIVATE 
60°/o 


Courtesy  American  Telephone  &   Telegraph  Co. 

contested  his  claim.  A  large  number  of  technical  improvements  followed 
Bell's  original  telephone,  among  which  we  may  note  the  provision  of  a 
more  efficient  transmitter,  the  development  of  signaling  devices,  the  con- 
struction of  ever  better  and  multiple  switchboards,  the  increase  in  the 
number  of  wires  carried  on  the  same  line,  with  the  ultimate  development 
of  the  underground  telephone  cable,  the  elimination  of  cross-talk  by  the 
two-line  system,  the  phantom  circuit  and  the  development  of  the  carrier 
system,  automatic  repeaters  and  current  amplifiers,  and  toll  switching 
plans,  which  made  possible  the  ever  more  efficient  handling  of  long- 
distance calls.  Perhaps  the  most  striking  innovation  has  been  the  dialing 
system  and  the  automatic  switchboard.  This  has  reduced  the  number 
of  operators  required  to  handle  calls.  It  is  comparable  to  the  teletype- 
writer and  automatic  telegraph  in  the  telegraph  field.  Overseas  tele- 


482      TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION 

phone  service  was  instituted  with  Europe  in  1927  and  with  South  America 
in  1930.    In  1935  the  first  telephone  call  was  sent  around  the  world. 

The  mass  popularity  and  enormous  growth  of  telephone  service  are 
shown  by  the  fact  that,  in  1900,  there  were  only  1,355,000  telephones  in 
the  country,  while  in  1940  the  number  had  increased  to  21,928,000,  about 
half  of  the  telephones  in  the  world.  The  estimated  week-day  telephone 
communications  grew  from  7,882,000  in  1900  to  98,300,000  in  1940— an 
estimated  30  billion  for  the  whole  year.  As  with  the  telegraph,  so  with 
the  telephone,  there  has  been  an  attempt  to  increase  its  use  by  special 
rates,  particularly  for  long-distance  calls.  Evening  and  Sunday  rates 
are  much  lower  than  those  during  business  hours  on  week-days.  The 
graphs  on  page  481  present  the  distribution  of  the  world's  telephones  and 
the  mode  of  ownership. 

The  ever  greater  accessibility  of  the  telephone  has  developed  what  has 
been  called  the  "telephone  habit,"  and  we  become  ever  more  dependent 
upon  this  instrument.28  The  telephone  industry  is  the  third  largest  public 
utility  industry  in  the  United  States.  It  is  exceeded  only  by  steam  and 
electric  traction  and  by  the  electric,  gas,  power  and  light  industries.  In 
1940,  approximately  $5,380,000,000  was  invested  in  plant  and  equipment, 
and  the  gross  operating  revenue  was  $1,310,000,000.  Approximately 
335,000  persons  are  employed  in  the  industry.  The  monthly  payroll  is 
over  60  million  dollars.  There  are  almost  exactly  100  million  miles  of 
telephone  wires  in  the  United  States  and  some  15  million  telephone  poles. 

There  are  several  companies  engaged  in  promoting  international  tele- 
phonic connections,  of  which  the  most  important  is  the  International 
Telephone  &  Telegraph  Corporation,  in  which  the  Mackay  interests  are 
dominant.  In  1932  they  operated  some  803,000  telephones. 

As  in  the  case  of  the  telegraph,  the  history  of  the  telephone  industry  is 
one  of  progressive  coordination  and  consolidation  under  private  control.29 
The  idea  of  government  ownership  was  anathema  in  the  laissez-faire, 
plutocratic  politics  of  the  last  quarter  of  the  nineteenth  century.  The 
first  telephone  company  to  be  formed  was  the  New  England  Telephone 
Company,  set  up  in  February,  1878,  as  a  trusteeship  of  the  Bell  interests 
under  the  leadership  of  Gardiner  G.  Hubbard  and  Thomas  Sanders.  It 
was  widened  to  a  national  business  when  the  Bell  Telephone  Company 
was  organized  in  July  of  the  same  year  under  the  same  interests.  The 
two  parent  companies  were  merged  as  the  National  Bell  Telephone  Com- 
pany in  1879.  During  this  year  the  Western  Union  Telegraph  Company 
carried  on  a  bitter  fight  with  the  Bell  Company  in  an  effort  to  corner 
the  telephone  business.  The  outcome  was  a  compromise,  in  which  all 
telephone  business  was  assigned  to  the  National  Bell  Telephone  Com- 
pany and  all  telegraph  business  to  the  Western  Union  Telegraph  Com- 
pany. The  Bell  system  has  been  even  more  successful  than  Western 
Union  in  well-nigh  monopolizing  the  business  in  its  line  of  communica- 

2*  On  the  social,  economic,  and  cultural  influence  of  the  telephone,  see  M.  M. 
Dilts,  The  Telephone  in  a  Changing  World.    Longmans,  Green,  1941. 
29  See  Horace  Coon,  American  Tel.  and  Tel,  Longmans,  Green,  1939. 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      483 


tions,  though  it  took  a  number  of  years  to  accomplish  this  result.  In 
1880,  the  American  Bell  Telephone  Company  was  created  to  control  and 
direct  the  Bell  interests,  with  Theodore  N.  Vail  and  William  H.  Forbes 
as  the  leading  executive  figures.  In  1885,  the  American  Telephone  and 
Telegraph  Company  was  formed,  for  the  special  purpose  of  perfecting 
long-distance  service  and  connecting  city  exchanges.  Vail  was  named 
president,  with  Edward  J.  Hall  as  general  manager  and  Angus  J.  Hibbard 
as  general  superintendent.  In  1900,  the  American  Telephone  and  Tele- 
graph Company  was  changed  from  a  subsidiary  to  the  controlling  element 
in  the  Bell  system,  which  is  today  made  up  of  A.T.&T.  and  some  24 
associated  companies.  At  that  time,  the  Bell  Company  conveyed  its 
assets  to  the  American  Telephone  and  Telegraph  Company,  which  is  the 
coordinating  and  consolidating  organization  in  the  American  telephone 
industry  of  today.  The  following  table  indicates  the  development  of  the 
Bell  System  since  1920: 


BELL  SYSTEM  STATISTICS 


Number  of  Telephones  (a)  

Number  of  Central  Offices 

Miles  of  Pole  Lines  

Miles  of  Wire : 

In  Underground  Cable 

In  Aerial  Cable  

Open  Wire  

Total 

Average  Daily  Telephone  Conversations: 

Total  Plant  

Number  of  Employees  (c)  

Number  of  A.T.&T.  Co.  Stockholders  .... 


(b) 


Dec.  31. 1920 
8,133,759 
5,767 
362,481 

14,207,000 

6,945,000 

3,711,000 

24,863,000 

33,125,000 

$1,373,802,000 

228,943 

139,448 


Dec.  31 1939 
16,535,804 
7,001 
397,202 

52,041,000 

28,910,000 

4,586,000 

85,537,000 

73,802,000 

$4,590,510,000 

259,930 

636,771 


(a)  Excludes  private  line  telephones  numbering  77,495  on  December  31,  1939.    Includ- 
ing telephones  of  about  6,500  connecting  companies  and   more  than  40,000  directly   and 
indirectly   connecting   rural   lines,   the   total   number   of   telephones  in   the  United    States 
which  can  be  interconnected  is  approximately  20,750,000. 

(b)  For  the  year  1939  there  were   approximately  71,200,000  average   daily   local   con- 
versations and  2,602,000  toll  and  long  distance  conversations,  an  increase  of  5.6%  and 
6.5%,  respectively,  over  the  year  1938. 

(c)  In  addition,  the  Western-Electric  Company,  Inc.,  and  the  Bell   Telephone  Labo- 
ratories, Inc.,  had  37,197  employees  on  December  31,  1939. 

The  following  table  presents  a  general  picture  of  the  whole  telephone 
industry  of  the  United  States,  at  the  end  of  the  year  1941 : 

STATISTICS  OF  TELEPHONE  INDUSTRY  IN  THE  UNITED  STATES 
DECEMBER  31,  1941 


Number  of  Companies  

Number  of  Central  Offices   

Number  of  Telephones  

Miles  of  Wire     

Investment  in  Plant  and  Equipment  . . 
Total  Operating  Revenues — Year  1941  . . 
Average  Daily  Telephone  Conversations 

during  1941    

Number  of  Employees  


Bell  System 
Companies 
25 
7,128 
18,841,000 
95,127,000 
$5,048,000,000 
$1,299,000,000 

84,690,000 
313,600 

All  Other 
Companies* 
6,436 
11,621 
4,680,000 
10,423,000 
$652,000,000 
$146,000,000 

19,510,000 
63,400 

Total 
United  States 
6,461 
18,749 
23,521,000 
105,550,000 
$5,700,000,000 
$1,445,000,000 

104,200,000 
377,000 

*  Partly  estimated. 


484      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

The  telephone  has  extended  the  range  of  human  conversational  powers 
to  an  incredible  degree.  It  is  now  possible  to  speak  by  word  of  mouth 
to  any  part  of  the  civilized  world  with  relative  expedition.  The  tele- 
phone is  also  invaluable  and  indispensable  in  the  transaction  of  modern 
business  activities.  It  is  no  longer  necessary  to  have  a  plant  located 
close  to  the  executive  offices.  This  will  permit  the  break-up  of  our  great 
urban  communities,  if  and  when  this  is  found  desirable  for  various  social 
and  cultural  reasons.  The  telephone  has  conquered  distance  and  busi- 
nessmen no  longer  need  to  be  close  together  to  carry  on  speedy  and  per- 
sonal conversations  or  conferences. 


( 

UNITED  STATES 
SWEDEN 
NEW  ZEALAND 
CANADA 
DENMARK 

TELEPHONES  PER   100  POPULATION 
January  1,1940 
D                2                4                 6                 8                10               12               14 

SWITZERLAND 
AUSTRALIA 
HAWAII 
NORWAY 

GREAT  BRITAIN 
GERMANY 
NETHERLANDS 
BELGIUM 
FINLAND 
LATVIA 
FRANCE 
ARGENTINA 
URUGUAY 
JAPAN 
CHILE 
HUNGARY 
ITALY 
CUBA 
LITHUANIA 
MEXICO 
RUSSIA 
BRAZIL 

1 

= 

r 

[TOTAL  WORLDl 

0                 2                 4                 6                  8                 10                12                14 

Telephones  per  100  Population 

Courtesy  American  Telephone  &  Telegraph  Co. 

The  necessity  of  safeguarding  the  privacy  of  so  tremendously  important 
an  enterprise  in  contemporary  civilization  led  the  courts  for  a  long  time 
to  forbid  the  admission  of  evidence  obtained  by  wire-tapping.  During 
the  hysteria  connected  with  Prohibition  enforcement,  the  Supreme  Court 
decided  that  evidence  obtained  by  wire-tapping  could  be  admitted  in 
court.  But  in  December,  1937,  a  more  liberal  Court  reversed  this  decision 
and  outlawed  wire-tapping.  There  has  been  a  revived  effort  to  restore 


TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION      485 

the  practice  in  wartime,  and  partial  success  in  so  doing  was  accomplished 
by  a  Supreme  Court  decision  in  April,  1942. 

Railroads,  vessels  at  sea,  airplanes,  and  the  like,  are,  in  differing  de- 
grees, dependent  upon  telephonic  and  telegraphic  communication.  Our 
railroad  system  would  be  paralyzed  were  it  not  for  the  electrical  trans- 
mission now  used  for  block-signaling  devices  and  the  sending  of  messages 
relating  to  traffic  control.  The  airplane  is  particularly  dependent  upon 
radio  connections.  It  is  obvious  that  the  gathering  and  transmitting  of 
news,  which  has  made  possible  the  modern  daily  paper,  is  absolutely 
dependent  upon  electrical  communication. 

Even  a  brief  survey  of  American  communication  agencies  would  be 
incomplete  without  at  least  a  reference  to  the  work  of  Theodore  Newton 
Vail  (1845-1920).  He  was  the  outstanding  figure  in  the  development 
of  American  communications.  Starting  out  as  a  telegraph  operator,  he 
became  a  mail  clerk  and,  in  time,  was  made  General  Superintendent  of 
Railway  Mails  in  1876.  While  in  the  mail  service  he  revolutionized  the 
rapid  delivery  of  mail  over  wide  areas.  He  promoted  civil  service  in 
the  railway  mail  department  and  created  the  first  fast  mail  deliveries 
in  the  country.  In  1878,  he  became  General  Manager  of  the  Bell  Tele- 
phone Company.  It  was  he  who  organized  the  American  Telephone  and 
Telegraph  Company,  which  secured  control  of  the  Bell  System.  In 
1887  he  retired  from  the  telephone  business  and  devoted  himself  to  the 
electrification  of  South  American  railroads.  In  1907,  he  returned  as 
President  of  the  American  Telephone  and  Telegraph  Company,  reorgan- 
ized the  system,  and  created  its  contemporary  efficiency.  He  attempted 
to  absorb  the  Western  Union  Telegraph  Company,  but,  as  we  have  seen, 
was  prevented  by  the  government  from  carrying  out  this  program  in  open 
fashion.  But  for  a  time,  Western  Union  was  dominated  by  the  A.T.&T., 
and  it  was  during  this  period  that  Vail  introduced  such  notable  innova- 
tions as  night  and  day  letters,  cable  letters,  and  week-end  cables.  In  the 
last  years  of  his  life  Vail  was  primarily  interested  in  wireless  telephony, 
and  the  development  of  the  radio  owed  much  to  the  active  support  which 
he  gave  to  the  experimentation.  Communication  requires  consolidation 
for  the  most  efficient  service.  Consolidation  and  efficiency  were  the  main 
ideals  of  Vail's  career. 

Improved  Postal  Service.  While  the  telephone  and  telegraph  are  fre- 
quently thought  of  as  the  more  spectacular  triumphs  in  the  field  of  com- 
munication, the  role  of  the  post  office  should  not  be  overlooked.  Postal 
service  began  in  the  courier  service  initiated  by  King  Cyrus  in  ancient 
Persia  and  by  Julius  Caesar  in  the  Roman  Empire.  About  300  A.D.,  the 
Emperor  Diocletian  set  up  a  limited  postal  system  for  private  persons, 
probably  the  first  of  its  kind  in  history.  The  Roman  Catholic  Church 
maintained  a  remarkable  system  of  couriers  in  the  Middle  Ages.  The 
first  private  postal  system  was  introduced  by  the  University  of  Paris 
about  1300  to  handle  the  correspondence  of  that  great  University,  which 
drew  students  from  all  parts  of  Europe.  In  1464,  Louis  XI  established 


486      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

a  royal  postal  system  for  France  and  a  century  later  this  was  used  by 
private  persons.  The  first  postal  system  in  Germany  was  opened  in  the 
Tyrol  in  the  latter  part  of  the  15th  century.  Early  in  the  next  century 
Charles  V  greatly  extended  the  imperial  postal  service  to  keep  in  touch 
with  all  of  his  far-flung  realms.  Private  postal  routes  of  limited  length 
were  created  in  England  under  Edward  III.  In  1635,  a  postal  service 
was  launched  from  London  to  Edinburgh.  In  1644,  a  weekly  postal 
service  was  provided  for  all  the  main  cities  of  the  country.  A  postal 
service  was  created  in  the  American  colonies  in  1691,  when  Andrew 
Hamilton  was  appointed  postmaster-general  for  the  colonies.  It  covered 
the  chief  settlements  from  Maine  to  Virginia.  But  the  systematic  postal 
service  of  the  world  began  with  Rowland  Hill's  reforms  in  England,  fol- 
lowing 1837.  By  this  time  the  railroad  could  be  exploited  for  more  rapid 
and  efficient  postal  service. 

Rowland  Hill  worked  out  a  scheme  for  the  cheapening  of  mail  distribu- 
tion which  has  been  widely  imitated,  with  many  variations.  Hill  recom- 
mended the  use  of  postage  stamps  at  uniform  cost  for  letters  to  all  parts 
of  England.  Since  Hill's  time  the  standardization  of  the  rates  for  the 
transmission  of  letters,  irrespective  of  distance,  within  any  national 
boundary  has  become  ever  more  prevalent.  In  international  agreements 
such  as  those  which  formerly  prevailed  between  England  and  the  United 
States  the  same  postage  rates  were  applied  to  a  letter  sent  from  Chicago 
to  London  or  New  Zealand  as  applied  to  a  letter  sent  from  Chicago  to 
Springfield,  Illinois. 

Of  enormous  importance  in  the  improvement  of  the  postal  system  in 
the  United  States  has  been  the  extension  of  rural  free  delivery  beginning 
in  1899.  This  puts  at  the  disposal  of  the  agricultural  population  most 
postal  advantages  hitherto  restricted  to  city  populations.  Here,  the 
automobile  has  recently  proved  of  great  utility  in  mail  delivery. 

A  leading  social  feature  of  the  cheapening  of  postal  service  and  the 
standardization  of  rates  was  the  fact  that  it  democratized  postal  service. 
Hitherto,  only  the  wealthy  had  been  able  to  dispatch  letters  frequently, 
and  even  then  the  service  was  none  too  rapid  or  dependable. 

,  The  increase  in  the  extent  of  the  mail  service  in  the  United  States  can 
be  seen  from  the  following  statistics.  In  1890,  about  4  billion  pieces  of 
mail  were  handled;  in  1900,  this  had  increased  to  over  7  billion;  in  1910, 
the  figure  stood  at  nearly  15  billion;  in  1930,  it  had  grown  to  about  28 
billion;  and  in  1939  some  26,445,000,000  pieces  of  mail  were  handled. 
The  development  of  rural  free  delivery  in  the  present  century  has  greatly 
increased  the  volume  of  mail  sent  by  rural  areas  and  received  therein. 
The  length  of  rural  free  delivery  routes  totaled  about  1,500,000  miles 
in  1941. 

The  speed  and  dependability  in  the  handling  of  first-class  mail  have 
improved  within  the  present  century  and  the  per  capita  contacts  effected 
thereby  are  greater.  Our  modern  business  system  would  be  nearly  para- 
lyzed if  it  were  compelled  to  return  to  the  system  of  mail  distribution 
of  the  world  as  it  was  in  1830,  when  national  postal  systems  were  usually 


TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION      487 

unknown  or  privately  owned,  and  letters  had  to  be  transmitted  by  coach 
or  courier,  traveling  slowly  and  on  no  regular  schedule. 

There  has  been  a  great  technical  improvement  in  the  methods  of  trans- 
porting mail,  particularly  through  closer  cooperation  with  the  railroad 
service.  The  mail  service  has  improved  with  every  advance  in  the  tech- 
nical efficiency  of  the  railroad.  Various  devices  have  contributed  to  the 
more  rapid  handling  of  first-class  mail,  such  as  pre-sorting  of  mail  in 
railway  mail  cars,  the  use  of  motor  vehicles  in  gathering  and  delivering 
mail,  postal  tubes,  and  mechanical  canceling  devices.  The  public  in- 
sistence upon  speed  in  communication  is  exemplified  by  the  fact  that 
special  delivery  mail  has  increased  twentyfold  since  1900.  .  But  the  most 
remarkable  contribution  of  the  century  to  the  hastening  of  first-class 
mail  service  has  been  the  institution  of  air-mail  transportation.  At  only 
double  the  cost  of  ordinary  first-class  postage,  letters  may  be  sent  by  air 
across  the  continent  in  a  few  hours.  We  have  already  noted  the  enor- 
mous increase  in  the  volume  of  air  mail. 

The  Daily  Newspaper  as  a  Medium  of 
Communication 

The  daily  newspaper  is  one  of  our  more  important  media  for  the  com- 
munication of  information  to  tens  of  millions  of  readers.  It  gathers  up 
news  from  all  over  the  world  and  makes  it  speedily  available  to  the  read- 
ing public.  It  also  presents  the  opinions  of  special  writers  on  various 
topics  of  the  day.  Some  provision  is  made  even  for  pcrson-to-person 
communication  through  the  correspondence  columns  which  most  daily 
papers  maintain.  Through  various  forms  of  organization,  making  use 
of  the  instruments  of  communication  which  we  have  described  above,  the 
newspaper  does  for  the  nation  or  region  what  the  hangers-on  in  the 
country  grocery  store  and  the  gossips  in  the  rural  town  used  to  do  for 
the  rural  neighborhood  a  century  or  so  ago.  It  gathers  and  prints  the 
news  and  gossip  of  the  world  in  formal  and  systematic  fashion,  whereas 
these  earlier  disseminators  of  news  and  gossip  informally  picked  up 
mainly  local  materials  and  transmitted  them  by  word  of  mouth. 

Newspapers  were  essentially  a  gift  of  the  printing  press.  They  began 
to  appear  a  century  or  so  after  the  invention  of  printing  in  the  middle 
of  the  fifteenth  century.  We  find  references  to  newspapers  in  the  Nether- 
lands at  the  close  of  the  sixteenth  century.  In  the  first  quarter  of  the 
seventeenth  the  Gazette  of  Antwerp  was  being  illustrated  with  wood- 
cuts. A  century  later,  Daniel  Defoe's  classic,  Robinson  Crusoe,  was  run 
in  a  serial  fashion  in  a  London  newspaper.  The  first  newspaper  in 
America  was  established  in  the  English  colonies  at  the  close  of  the  seven- 
teenth century.  The  first  important  free  press  battle  in  the  colonies  was 
the  famous  Zenger  case,  fought  out  in  New  York  City  in  1734.  Zenger 
was  prosecuted  for  alleged  libel  of  the  government,  but  the  jury  freed 
him  on  the  ground  that  his  charges  were  true.  After  the  Revolutionary 
War,  papers  became  more  numerous.  The  development  of  political  par- 
ties and  factions  helped  to  increase  the  prevalence  and  popularity  of  the 


488      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

newspaper.  The  contemporary  newspaper  has  reached  its  highest  devel- 
mcnt  in  the  United  States,  though  England  follows  closely.  On  the  Euro- 
pean continent  there  is  nothing  approaching  the  American  newspaper  for 
size  or  variety  of  content,  though  some  Continental  journals,  such  as  the 
Frankfurter  Zeitung,  before  the  rise  of  Fascism  and  Nazism,  ranked  ahead 
of  most  American  and  English  papers  for  intelligent  editorial  interpreta- 
tion of  current  events  and  world  trends. 

Nothing  in  American  life  has  more  closely  followed  the  trends  in  cul- 
ture and  economic  development  than  the  newspaper.80  At  first,  the 
American  newspapers  were  slight  personal  organs,  usually  founded  to 
advance  some  individual  or  partisan  project  or  to  vent  personal  spite. 
They  rarely  appeared  at  uniform  intervals.  The  "editorial"  attitude 
dominated  entirely  and  there  was  little  news  printed. 

In  the  second  third  of  the  nineteenth  century,  newspapers  improved  in 
quality,  size,  and  influence,  though  the  editorial  interest  and  function  still 
prevailed  over  the  news  element.  News  was  published,  but  it  was  far 
more  scanty  than  today,  and  the  publisher  all  too  often  even  "editorial- 
ized" the  news  so  as  to  make  it  seem  to  vindicate  editorial  opinion.  The 
papers  were  read  chiefly  by  partisans  to  enjoy  the  editorial  judgment  and 
flavor  of  the  paper.  Both  editors  and  readers  were  usually  bitterly  par- 
tisan. Among  the  more  representative  papers  of  this  era  were  the  New 
York  Tribune,  edited  by  Horace  Greeley;  the  Chicago  Tribune,  edited 
by  Joseph  Medill ;  the  New  York  Times,  edited  by  Henry  Raymond ;  the 
New  York  Evening  Post,  edited  by  William  Cullen  Bryant;  the  New 
York  Sun,  edited  by  Charles  A.  Dana;  the  Springfield  Republican,  edited 
by  Samuel  Bowles;  and  the  Albany  Evening  Journal,  edited  by  Thurlow 
Weed. 

The  improvements  in  the  mechanics  of  printing,  the  provision  of  inter- 
national newsgathering  agencies,  the  expansion  of  American  industry 
and  business,  the  concentration  of  large  populations  in  our  cities,  and  the 
like,  encouraged  the  rise  and  triumph  of  the  commercial  newspaper,  in 
the  period  between  1870  and  the  first  World  War.  A  very  important 
aspect  of  this  change  in  journalism  lay  in  the  fact  that  the  former  zeal 
to  express  strong  editorial  judgments  was  slowly  but  surely  subordinated 
to  the  publisher's  aspiration  to  make  a  personal  fortune  out  of  his  news- 
paper or  newspapers.  The  papers,  for  the  first  time,  became  newspapers, 
properly  so  called.  Nevertheless,  even  the  news  interest  was  mainly 
important  as  the  means  of  enriching  newspaper  publishers.  William 
Allen  White  succinctly  put  the  essence  of  this  phase  of  the  revolution  in 
journalism  when  he  observed  that,  in  the  process  of  this  transition, 
journalism  ceased  to  be  a  profession  and  became  an  investment. 

The  formula  for  a  successful  newspaper  was  slowly  but  precisely 
worked  out.  Readers  and  mass  circulation  are  to  be  attained  through 


s°For  a  history  of  American  journalism,  see  F.  L.  Mott,  American  Journalism, 
Macmillan,  1941;  and  for  contemporary  American  journalism,  see  A.  M.  Lee,  The 
Daily  Newspaper  in  America,  Macmillan,  1937;  and  M.  M.  Willey  and  R.  D.  Casey 
(Eds.),  "The  Press  in  the  Contemporary  Scene,"  The  Annals,  1942. 


TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION      489 

publishing  attractive  and  often  sensational  news.  Many  interested  read- 
ers insure  wide  circulation  for  the  paper,  and  a  newspaper  with  an  exten- 
sive circulation  presents  a  favorable  medium  for  commercial  advertising. 
It  is  primarily  from  advertising  that  newspapers  make  their  profits. 
Even  a  vast  circulation  does  not  pay  expenses  through  subscriptions  and 
newsstand  sales.  Wide  circulation  creates  a  profit  only  indirectly 
through  the  resulting  gains  from  extensive  and  well-paid  advertising. 

The  newspaper  thus  became  an  agency  for  selling  lively  news  to  attract 
a  multitude  of  readers,  before  whom  advertising  could  be  placed,  with 
direct  profits  for  the  newspapers  and  indirect  profits  for  the  advertisers. 

The  major  figures  in  this  revolutionary  transition  from  the  editorial 
sheet  to  the  true  newspaper,  with  commercial  aims,  were  James  Gordon 
Bennett  of  the  New  York  Herald,  Charles  A.  Dana  of  the  New  York  Sun, 
Joseph  Pulitzer  of  the  New  York  World,  William  Randolph  Hearst  of  the 
New  York  American  (and  Journal) ,  and  E.  W.  Scripps  of  the  Cleveland 
Press.  Lord  Northcliffe  (Alfred  Harmsworth)  followed  the  procession 
with  his  London  Daily  Mail.  Contrary  to  general  impression,  however, 
the  most  blatant  attempt  to  gain  circulation  by  sensational  and  scandalous 
news  has  not  been  made  by  an  American  paper,  but  by  the  London  News 
of  the  World,  owned  by  Lord  Riddell,  who  died  at  the  close  of  1934. 

The  quest  for  circulation  through  mass  appeal  has  given  rise  to  the 
"tabloid"  newspapers,  with  their  small  and  convenient  format,  their 
visual  appeal,  and  their  ultra-sensational  news.31  The  experiment  has 
in  general  proved  successful,  and  the  New  York  Daily  News  has  the  larg- 
est circulation  of  any  newspaper  in  the  world.  The  tabloid  need  not 
necessarily  be  sensational.  The  first  tabloid,  E.  W.  Scripps'  Chicago 
Day-Book,  was  highly  serious,  severely  editorial,  and  carried  no  adver- 
tising. One  of  the  most  dignified  and  reliable  of  modern  newspapers, 
the  Washington  Daily  News — a  Scripps-Howard  paper — is  published  in 
tabloid  format.  The  New  York  Post,  the  oldest  and  long  the  most  dis- 
tinguished of  New  York  dailies,  turned  tabloid  in  the  spring  of  1942. 
An  interesting  addition  to  tabloid  journalism  has  been  the  New  York 
newspaper,  PM,  launched  in  1940.  Its  policy  called  for  the  printing  of 
news  interpretations  rather  than  news  accounts,  and  for  operating  with- 
out advertising,  with  the  view  of  keeping  editors  free  from  business 
pressure  in  their  selection  and  interpretation  of  news.31a 

One  of  the  most  important  recent  developments  in  newspapers  is  the 
growth  of  newspaper  chains.  These  have  come  about  as  a  result  of  per- 
sonal ambition,  the  desire  for  centralized  control,  and  the  economies  of 
management,  talent,  and  administration.  The  chains  represent  the  prin- 
ciple of  business  consolidation  applied  to  the  commercial  newspaper. 

By  1930,  about  one  sixth  of  the  morning  and  evening  newspapers  were 
organized  in  chains,  which  controlled  about  one  third  of  the  total  daily 


81  See  Emile  Gauvreau,  My  Last  Million  Readers,  Dutton,  1941. 

81aFor  an  interesting  and  authoritative  description  of  the  history  and  policies 
of  PM,  see  the  articles  on  Ralph  Ingersoll  by  Wolcott  Gibbs  in  The  New  Yorker, 
May  2,  9,  1942. 


490      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

newspaper  circulation  and  about  one  half  of  the  Sunday  circulation. 
The  most  important  chains  were  those  of  Hearst  and  Scripps-Howard. 
Since  1930,  there  has  been  some  decline  in  the  number  of  chains  and  the 
papers  controlled  by  them.  This  has  been  especially  true  of  the  Hearst 
group.  The  Scripps-Howard  chain,  established  by  E.  W.  Scripps  for  the 
championship  of  labor  and  the  underdog,  long  retained  a  liberal  and  in- 
dependent outlook.  In  the  last  few  years,  however,  it  has  turned  to 
"Red-baiting"  and  a  generally  critical  attitude  towards  organized  labor, 
a  change  attributed  by  some  to  the  rise  of  the  Newspaper  Guild.32 

The  number  of  daily  papers  reached  its  peak  in  1917,  with  some  2,514 
dailies.  Consolidations,  mergers,  and  discontinuations  brought  the  num- 
ber down  to  1,877  in  1940.  Weekly  newspapers,  mainly  country  publica- 
tions, fell  off  from  15,681  in  1900  to  12,636  in  1931,  the  decline  being 
generally  attributed  to  the  fact  that  rural  free  delivery  brought  the  city 
daily  to  the  farmer's  door  and  that  the  local  dailies  in  the  near-by  cities 
published  personal  news  and  gossip  concerning  the  rural  areas  in  which 
their  papers  might  circulate.  Evening  newspapers  have  become  more 
popular  than  morning  papers,  probably  due  to  the  greater  amount  of 
leisure  time  for  reading  in  the  evening.  In  1940,  there  were  380  morning 
papers  and  1,497  evening  papers,  with  524  Sunday  papers.  The  morning 
circulation  was  16,114,018,  the  evening  circulation  24,895,240,  and  the 
Sunday  circulation  32,245,444,  this  last  a  gain  of  nearly  6  million  over 
1930.  The  second  World  War  stimulated  reader  interest,  and  in  1941 
newspaper  circulation  reached  an  all-time  high,  with  a  total  of  41,131,611 
newspapers  sold. 

The  fact  that  advertising  is  the  chief  source  of  newspaper  income  can 
be  seen  from  the  fact  that  the  revenue  therefrom  amounted  to  well  over 
800  million  dollars  in  1929,  while  only  325  million  was  derived  from  news- 
paper sales.  The  depression  and  the  increased  appropriations  for  radio 
advertising  cut  down  the  newspaper  advertising  revenue  to  a  little  less 
than  525  million  dollars  in  1935.  The  second  World  War  is  likely  to  have 
a  disastrous  effect  on  the  economics  of  newspapers.  Priorities  and  other 
sales  restrictions  are  bringing  a  marked  reduction  in  advertising,  while 
excitement  over  the  war  is  producing  greater  circulation.  Without  added 
advertising  revenue,  however,  increased  circulation  is  a  financial  liability 
to  newspapers.  Probably  most  war-mongering  newspapers  did  not  fore- 
see this  situation,  since  the  period  of  the  first  World  War  was  one  of 
marked  newspaper  prosperity.  Then,  however,  there  was  far  less  re- 
striction of  the  advertising  and  sale  of  consumers'  goods. 

In  former  days  most  newspapers  were  definitely  partisan,  but  in  the 


32  On  the  downfall  of  Scripps-Howard  liberalism  and  related  topics,  see  the  articles 
on  Roy  W.  Howard  by  A.  J.  Liebling,  in  The  New  Yorker,  August  2,  9,  16  and  23, 
1941.  The  author  errs,  however,  in  attributing  chief  responsibility  to  Mr.  Howard. 
It  lies,  rather,  with  W.  W.  Hawkins,  chairman  of  the  board  of  directors,  G.  B.  Parker, 
editor-in-chief,  and  John  H.  Sorrells,  executive  editor.  Of  course,  in  a  negative  way. 
the  responsibility  is  Mr.  Howard's,  for  he  has  always  had  the  power  to  assert  himsejf 
and  overrule  these  nien, 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      491 

twentieth  century  there  has  been  a  growth  of  political  independence.  In 
1930,  505  papers  listed  themselves  as  Republican,  434  as  Democratic,  and 
792  as  independent  in  politics.  But  the  overwhelming  majority  are 
economically  partisan,  namely,  conservative.  The  number  of  genuinely 
liberal  papers  in  the  country  has  declined  alarmingly  since  1933. 

The  development  of  the  daily  newspaper  of  today  has  been  made  pos- 
sible by  a  number  of  important  technological  advances,  such  as  better 
facilities  for  rapid  printing,  and  the  utilization  of  electrical  communica- 
tion for  the  gathering  and  transmission  of  news. 

The  mechanical  processes  for  the  printing  of  the  first  newspapers  in 
^he  seventeenth  century  were  crude.  Pages  were  printed  by  pressing 
i  flat  frame  of  type  on  the  sheet  of  paper,  and  all  type  had  to  be  set  by 
i&nd.  The  first  important  improvement  was  the  cylindrical  press,  which 
fvas  adapted  from  a  device  used  for  printing  calicoes.  It  was  successfully 
ised  in  the  office  of  the  London  Times  in  1812,  and  in  America  by  the 
Philadelphia  Ledger  in  1846.  The  cylindrical  press  was  not  generally 
ntroduced  in  pressrooms,  however,  until  about  1880.  It  was  a  great 
improvement  over  the  old  frame  press  with  respect  to  both  speed  and 
efficiency. 

Since  1880,  the  evolution  of  printing  presses  has  been  a  remarkable 
lemonstration  of  modern  mechanical  ingenuity.  One  of  the  latest  print- 
ing presses  can  print,  fold,  cut,  and  count  no  less  than  1,000  thirty -two- 
sage  newspapers  per  minute.  The  use  of  these  improved  printing  presses 
would  not  be  possible,  were  it  not  for  an  equally  remarkable  development 
3f  typesetting  machinery  already  described  above.  With  the  new  lino- 
type machinery,  typesetters  can  keep  pace  with  the  speed  of  the  printing 
oress.  The  combination  of  the  telegraph,  the  telephone,  radio,  the  rotary 
press,  and  the  linotype  machine  enables  us  to  read  the  news  about  events 
in  a  remote  area  that  may  have  taken  place  only  an  hour  or  so  before 
the  newspaper  is  on  the  street. 

A  remarkable  new  invention,  the  "teletypesetting"  machine,  has  been 
tvorked  out  in  recent  years.  A  master  copy  is  cut  in  a  perforated  tape. 
When  this  copy  is  corrected  and  put  in  a  properly  equipped  teletype- 
setting  machine,  it  can  be  set  simultaneously  and  automatically  by  elec- 
trical control  on  scores  or  hundreds  of  other  typesetting  machines  many 
miles  apart,  if  necessary,  with  no  human  aid  and  without  the  slightest 
oossibility  of  a  typographical  error.  This  invention  seems  bound  to 
revolutionize  mechanical  production  in  certain  newspaper  plants,  espe- 
cially those  under  chain  management. 

One  of  the  major  phases  of  mass  appeal  in  modern  newspaper  publica- 
tion is  the  appeal  of  pictures.  The  tabloid  specializes  in  these,  but  even 
the  most  dignified  newspapers  make  wide  use  of  pictures,  particularly 
those  portraying  various  crises,  such  as  floods,  earthquakes,  and  battles. 
Between  1924  and  1933  a  series  of  electrical  inventions  brought  about 
the  telephoto  device,  which  sends  satisfactory  pictures  instantaneously 
through  wire  transmission.  Beginning  about  1935,  the  American  news- 
papers began  to  install  telephoto  equipment,  and  pictures  from  all  over 


492      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

the  world  were  sent  over  the  wire  as  rapidly  and  almost  as  satisfactorily 
as  news  dispatches. 

Without  a  cheap  and  serviceable  paper  on  which  to  print  material,  all 
the  other  marvelous  accessories  of  newspaper  production  would  be  essen- 
tially worthless.  Rag  paper  could  not  be  provided  in  sufficient  quantity 
or  with  sufficient  economy.  Wood  pulp  has  supplied  the  only  material 
capable  of  making  practicable  newsprint  (paper)  at  a  sufficiently  low  cost. 
The  manufacture  of  wood-pulp  paper,  based  on  Rene  Reamur's  studies  of 
nest-building  by  wasps,  began  about  the  time  of  the  Civil  War.  Paper 
production  had  increased  in  volume  in  this  country  from  127,000  tons 
in  1867  to  11,000,000  tons  by  1929.  The  total  world  production  in  1929 
was  23,400,000  tons.  The  world  production  of  newsprint  (paper  for 
newspapers)  in  1929  was  7,319,000  tons,  about  one  third  of  the  total  pulp 
paper  production.  The  amount  of  forest  reserves  needed  to  furnish 
wood  pulp  for  newsprint  is  incredible  to  those  unfamiliar  with  the  facts. 
It  requires  about  300  acres  of  forest  to  furnish  enough  pulp  to  get  the 
paper  to  print  one  Sunday  issue  of  The  New  York  Times.  Owing  to  the 
short  life  of  wood-pulp  paper,  some  newspapers  publish  a  special  edition 
on  rag  paper  for  preservation  in  libraries. 

The  development  of  modern  printing  machinery  would  have  been  of 
little  value  without  the  corresponding  development  of  elaborate  organ- 
izations for  gathering  news.  If  every  newspaper  were  compelled  to  sup- 
port its  own  correspondents  in  all  parts  of  the  world  and  to  maintain  its 
own  telegraphic  and  cable  connections,  only  a  few  great  newspapers  could 
meet  the  expense.  But  through  the  extensive  machinery  of  newsgather- 
ing  agencies  such  as  the  Associated  Press,  the  more  significant  or  sensa- 
tional information  from  all  parts  of  the  world  is  put  at  the  disposal  of 
newspapers  for  a  relatively  small  expenditure.  These  agencies  are  elabo- 
rate organizations  of  correspondents  gathering  news,  and  of  cables,  tele- 
graphic communications,  and  radio  stations  essential  to  the  rapid  trans- 
mission of  the  information  thus  gathered.  While,  from  the  standpoint  of 
technical  efficiency,  the  newsgathering  agencies  have  achieved  remarkable 
progress,  the  adequacy  and  accuracy  of  their  service  have  been  criticized. 
The  type  of  news  that  will  be  gathered  inevitably  depends  to  a  great  ex- 
tent upon  the  economic,  social,  and  intellectual  attitudes  of  the  subscribing 
newspapers  or  their  advertisers.  Only  "acceptable"  news  will  be  gathered 
and  transmitted.  Then  the  already  selected  news  gathered  by  corre- 
spondents tends  to  be  further  sorted  out  by  editors  for  its  mass  appeal 
and  emotional  content,  not  for  its  educational  value.  In  short,  the  news- 
gathering  agencies  naturally  gather,  and  the  editors  print,  the  news  that 
will  "take"  or  sell.  The  newspapers  using  the  service  .often  distort  the 
facts  by  still  further  editing  and  rewriting  the  information  secured.  In 
this  way,  much  really  significant  news  is  lost  to  the  public  and  much  that 
is  actually  printed  is  highly  unreliable. 

The  extensive  suppression  and  deliberate  distortion  of  foreign  news, 
according  to  social  bias,  by  even  the  best  newspapers,  was  well  brought 
out  by  Walter  Lippmann  and  Charles  Merz  in  their  study  of  the  news  on 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      493 

Soviet  Russia,  printed  over  a  considerable  period  of  time  in  The  New  York 
Times.  Their  findings,  printed  in  their  book  Liberty  and  the  News,™ 
had  a  notable  effect  on  the  Times,  leading,  among  other  things,  to  the 
appointment  of  Walter  Duranty,  probably  the  most  objective  foreign  cor- 
respondent of  our  era,  as  Times  correspondent  in  Russia.84  The  exposure 
also  exerted  a  salutary  influence  on  many  other  American  papers. 

Especially  in  war  time  is  news  distorted  and  suppressed.  We  usually 
find  that  the  zeal,  indeed,  necessity,  to  get  news  in  the  exciting  days  of  war 
time  leads  to  the  demand  that  correspondents  invent  news  if  they  cannot 
get  it.  In  such  cases  they  usually  invent  news  which  they  think  will  be 
favorably  received  at  home.  An  outstanding  example  of  such  creative 
imagination,  even  by  high-grade  correspondents,  were  the  sensational 
stories  on  the  war  in  Norway  in  the  spring  of  1940,  especially  the  widely 
read  tale  that  Norway  fell  primarily  because  of  elaborate  Fifth  Column 
activities  by  Germany  in  Norway  prior  to  the  war.  Any  such  interpre- 
tation was  later  repudiated,  even  by  intensely  anti-Nazi  but  honest  Nor- 
wegian refugees.80  Much  of  the  news  on  the  Russo-Finnish  War  was 
sheer  invention,  because  the  correspondents  were  denied  access  to  the 
front.  In  spite  of  these  defects,  however,  it  is  certain  that  we  have 
profited  through  securing  more  rapidly  gathered  and  unprecedentedly 
varied  information  from  all  over  the  face  of  the  earth. 

The  oldest  of  the  American  agencies  is  the  Associated  Press,  founded 
in  1848  and  reorganized  in  1900  under  the  leadership  of  Melville  Stone. 
It  is  a  cooperative  newsgathering  agency,  the  annual  costs  of  around 
10  million  dollars  being  distributed  among  the  member  papers,  roughly 
according  to  the  importance  of  the  territory  and  the  size  of  the  paper. 
It  is  not  a  profit-making  institution  and  its  services  are  available  only  to 
its  members,  namely,  those  who  hold  an  Associated  Press  franchise.  It 
had  about  1400  members  in  1940.  The  Associated  Press  maintains  an 
elaborate  corps  of  foreign  correspondents  and  reporters,  but  most  Ameri- 
can news  is  gathered  by  the  staff  of  member  papers  in  each  locality. 
They  put  on  the  A.P.  wires  all  local  news  which  they  consider  significant. 
Papers  which  have  an  Associated  Press  franchise  cannot  furnish  news  to 
any  other  newsgathering  agency.  The  fact  that  most  of  the  American 
papers  in  the  A.P.  group  are  relatively  conservative  means  that  the 
majority  of  the  news  gathered  by  A.P.  papers  and  transmitted  over  the 
A,P.  wires  has  a  conservative  flavor.  Special  representatives  of  the  Asso- 
ciated Press  are  provided  to  covers  news  in  the  more  important  centers, 
such  as  Washington  and  state  capitals,  and  a  flock  of  them  are  immedi- 
ately dispatched  to  any  locality  visited  by  disaster  or  any  other  event 
requiring  special  news  coverage. 

The  United  Press  agency  was  founded  by  E.  W.  Scripps  in  1907,  because 
he  feared  the  results  of  a  newsgathering  monopoly,  particularly  under 


33  New  Republic  Press,  1920. 

34  Interestingly  enough,  Mr.  Merz  is  now  editor  of  the  Times. 

35  See  "The  Fifth  Column,"  Bulletin  of  Institute  for  Propaganda  Analysis,  July  8, 
1940. 


494      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

conservative  auspices.  It  was  really  put  on  the  newspaper  map  by  Roy 
W.  Howard  between  1912  and  1920.  Howard  made  the  best  possible  use 
of  the  special  advantages  created  by  the  first  World  War  period.  For 
example,  it  was  Howard  who  got  the  famous  "knock-out  victory"  inter- 
view with  Lloyd  George  on  September  29,  1916,  but  his  alertness  and 
energy  got  a  little  out  of  hand  when  he  sent  the  false  Armistice  cable  on 
November  7,  1918.  The  United  Press  is  a  strictly  commercial  news- 
gathering  organization.  Through  its  paid  staff  it  gathers  news  from 
all  parts  of  the  world  and  sells  its  services  to  such  papers  as  desire  to 
avail  themselves  of  the  opportunity.  It  works  on  a  profit  basis.  Down 
to  1919  it  served  mainly  the  evening  papers,  but  since  that  time  it  has 
adapted  its  service  to  both  morning  and  evening  papers.  It  has  over 
1200  clients  among  the  American  newspapers.  Most  of  the  better  papers 
avail  themselves  of  both  the  A.P.  and  U.P.  services.  Due  to  its  origin 
under  E.  W.  Scripps'  auspices,  the  U.P.  was  for  some  years  more  aggres- 
sive and  liberal  than  the  A.P,  and  more  interested  in  gathering  and  trans- 
mitting news  relative  to  the  doings  of  labor.  This  difference  hardly  exists 
today. 

It  was  natural  that  Mr.  Hearst  should  form  his  own  newsgathering  serv- 
ice. He  was  often  denied  direct  access  to  A.P.  facilities  and  he  did  not 
care  to  increase  the  revenues  of  the  United  Press,  which  was  owned  by 
the  Scripps-Howard  organization,  his  chief  journalistic  rival  in  the  chain 
realm.  So  he  developed  the  Hearst  International  News  Service,  which 
serves  around  700  papers  at  the  present  time,  including  the  Hearst  chain. 
Following  the  well-known  Hearst  formula,  the  International  News  Serv- 
ice has  provided  more  sensational  material  than  either  the  A.P.  or  the  U.P. 

As  newspapers  have  become  more  extensive  and  diversified,  it  has 
proved  profitable  to  develop  organizations  which  furnish  newspapers  with 
special  features,  such  as  columns  by  distinguished  or  popular  writers 
and  cartoon  and  picture  service.  The  most  extensive  and  profitable  of 
these  services  is  King  Features,  owned  and  operated  by  the  Hearst  inter- 
ests, but  utilized  by  many  other  papers.  Next  to  this  comes  the  News- 
paper Enterprise  Association,  which  is  owned  by  the  Scripps-Howard 
organization.  The  latter  organization,  incidentally,  had  the  ingenuity 
to  "gobble"  what  was  for  some  years  the  most  important  feature  property 
in  the  history  of  American  journalism,  the  exclusive  rights  to  news  about 
the  Dionne  quintuplets.  For  a  number  of  years  they  attracted  more 
readers  than  an  international  crisis  or  the  most  shocking  murder.  The 
Scripps-Howard  concern  has  another  feature  service,  known  as  United 
Features,  a  subsidiary  of  the  United  Press.  This  service  created  a  great 
flurry  a  few  years  ago  by  obtaining  the  rights  to  Dickens'  unpublished 
Life  of  Christ  for  Children,  which  proved  one  of  the  most  profitable  tem- 
porary feature  items  in  American  journalistic  history.  The  Associated 
Press  also  has  attempted  several  ventures  in  the  feature  field,  but  its 
accomplishments  here  have  been  far  less  impressive  than  those  of  the 
Hearst  and  Scripps-Howard  organizations. 

It  might  be  worth  while  to  say  a  little  more  at  this  point  about  the 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      495 

nature  and  operation  of  newspaper  chains.  There  are  a  number  of 
advantages  in  chain  newspaper  operation.  It  can  provide  far  greater 
talent  in  every  phase  of  newspaper  work  than  the  individual  paper.  The 
Scripps-Howard  organization  could,  for  example,  hire  the  highest-priced 
editorial  writer  in  the  United  States,  at  a  cost  per  paper  little  greater 
than  the  amount  paid  to  a  cub  reporter  in  any  locality.  And  this  one 
editorial  writer  could  provide  national  and  international  editorials  suffi- 
cient for  the  needs  of  all  the  papers  in  the  chain.  The  same  considera- 
tions apply  to  all  phases  of  newspaper  material  suitable  to  be  printed 
throughout  the  country.  Moreover,  a  chain  can  present  a  united  front, 
thus  giving  it  great  power  in  various  political  crusades.  If  a  chain  stands 
behind  a  particular  member  paper  which  is  being  fought  by  advertisers, 
the  paper  cannot  be  ruined  through  the  temporary  withdrawal  of  local 
advertising  support.  Chain  organization  thus  makes  newspapers  a 
greater  force  for  good,  if  they  see  fit  to  make  use  of  their  power  in  this 
manner.  It  is  obvious  that  chain  newspapers  can  provide  far  higher 
talent  in  every  phase  of  newspaper  work  than  the  individual  paper  if  they 
wish  to  do  so.  But  this  advantage  has  been  offset  to  some  degree  by  the 
fact  that  individual  papers  can  also  often  buy  the  same  type  of  material 
from  the  feature  services  at  a  low  cost. 

Unfortunately  the  chain  newspapers  can  also  be  a  powerful  force  for 
evil.  Since  there  is  centralized  control,  a  wrong-headed  editorial  policy 
can  be  spread  all  over  the  country.  By  and  large,  however,  the  manage- 
ment of  a  powerful  chain  is  likely  to  represent  newspaper  talent  superior 
to  the  staff  of  a  local  journal.  Therefore,  the  errors  and  biases  of  a 
chain  management  are  not  likely  to  be  any  worse  than  the  errors  and 
biases  of  local  publishers  and  editors.  The  ukases  of  Mr.  Hearst  are 
rarely  worse  than  the  stupidities  of  local  publishers  and  editors.  It  has 
been  shown  that  big  business  in  the  United  States  is  more  open-minded 
and  far-sighted  than  little  business.  This  situation  also  applies  to  the 
managers  of  newspaper  chains,  as  over  against  the  majority  of  local 
publishers  and  editors. 

The  degree  to  which  local  editors  are  given  freedom  and  initiative  in 
chains,  depends  both  upon  the  chain  involved  and  the  circumstances  at 
any  given  time.  Hearst  editors  have  had  very  little  personal  leeway. 
Scripps-Howard  editors  have  been  given  a  greater  degree  of  freedom, 
particularly  in  dealing  with  local  matters.  But  chain  management  means 
essentially  newspaper  despotism.  When  it  is  a  benevolent  despotism  it 
produces  the  best  in  American  journalism,  but  when  it  is  a  benighted 
and  absolute  despotism,  it  can  create  the  worst  features  of  contemporary 
newspaperdom. 

Since  our  contemporary  newspapers  rely  upon  news  and  features  to  gain 
the  circulation  necessary  to  obtain  advertising  revenue,  we  should  look 
briefly  into  what  newspapers  consider  the  most  suitable  material  for 
mass  appeal.  Karl  W.  Bickel,  long  president  of  the  United  Press,  said 
that  newspapers  want  material  in  both  news  and  features  which  will  pro- 
voke strong  human  emotions.  Another  able  journalist  stated  that  the 


496      TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION 

best  newspaper  material  will  provoke  in  the  reader  what  he  described  as 
the  "Gee  Whiz"  sentiment.  This  will  serve  to  explain  the  unparalleled 
popularity  of  the  Dionne  quintuplets. 

Boiled  down  to  its  essence,  the  newspapers  want  hot  news.  And  this 
"hotness"  is  of  a  twofold  character.  News  should  be  "hot"  from  the 
standpoint  of  its  emotion-provoking  content,  and  it  should  be  "hot"  in  the 
sense  of  being  up-to-the-minute.  It  should  be  as  personal  as  possible 
and  concentrated  on  emotional  situations  such  as  love,  romance,  sin, 
murder,  death,  and  war. 

Upon  no  matter  do  newspapers  concentrate  their  energy  more  com- 
pletely than  upon  the  effort  to  have  news  as  up-to-the-minute  as  possible, 
one  of  the  great  feats  of  newspaperdom  being  to  "scoop"  a  rival.  The 
haste  of  newspapers  often  approaches  the  ludicrous.  There  is  a  frantic 
effort  to  get  into  headlines  material  which  the  world  would  be  just  as  well 
off  for  knowing  a  week  later,  and  in  too  many  cases  would  be  better  off 
for  not  knowing  at  all.  This  fantastic  straining  for  "spot  news"  has  be- 
come a  fundamental  journalistic  habit  and  one  which  is  not  likely  to  be 
uprooted.  However,  since  the  radio  has  ousted  the  newspaper  from 
supremacy  in  first  divulging  news  material,  newspapers  may  emphasize 
interpretative  news  to  a  greater  extent  in  the  future. 

The  fact  that  news  is  here  today  and  gone  tomorrow — or  sometimes 
gone  in  the  next  edition  on  the  same  day — greatly  lessens  the  value  of  the 
newspaper  as  an  agency  for  information  and  education.  The  trivial 
character  of  too  much  of  the  news,  together  with  the  highly  transient 
character  of  the  majority  of  the  news,  makes  it  impossible  for  the  average 
reader  to  understand  the  nature  and  import  of  what  he  reads  in  the  news- 
papers. The  latter  provide  constant  distraction  instead  of  encouraging 
concentrated  interest  and  intelligent  interpretation. 

The  technique  and  ethics  of  the  gathering  and  printing  of  news  today 
have,  however,  produced  one  notable  advantage.  Except  in  war  time, 
such  news  as  is  printed  is  usually  set  forth  without  editorial  distortion. 
True,  editors  usually  select  from  the  vast  mass  of  material  the  news  which 
most  appeals  to  their  biases  and  prejudices.  But  they  do  not  normally 
maltreat  what  they  do  put  in  print.  The  character  of  modern  news- 
gathering  has  been  mainly  responsible  for  this.  Sirice  all  newspapers 
get  essentially  the  same  news  through  the  A.P.,  the  U.P.,  and  other  agen- 
cies, each  editor  knows  what  other  papers  receive  in  the  way  of  news 
dispatches.  Hence  it  is  easy  to  detect  a  competing  editor's  distortions, 
or,  as  it  is  usually  described,  the  "editing"  of  his  news  columns.  Readers 
can  also  detect  editorial  distortion  of  the  news  through  the  fact  that  they 
have  accessible  several  newspapers  which  present  news  accounts  of  the 
same  daily  events.  In  this  way,  an  unprecedented  degree  of  accuracy  has 
been  produced  in  the  publication  of  conventional  news.  The  editorially 
far  more  aggressive  newspapers  of  the  days  of  Horace  Greeley  never  even 
approximated  such  a  straightforward  presentation.  Of  course,  by  his 
personal  selection  of  the  news  to  be  printed  from  the  vast  amount  of  copy 
supplied,  an  editor  can  present  to  the  readers  of  his  paper  a  highly  dis- 
torted view  of  what  is  going  on.  There  is,  moreover,  a  wide  leeway  for 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      497 

distortion  of  the  news  on  the  part  of  special  correspondents.  Not  in- 
frequently the  same  paper  publishes  on  the  same  day  two  versions  of 
the  same  events  which  differ  diametrically  upon  many  important  aspects 
of  the  events  recounted. 

Despite  the  triviality  of  too  much  of  our  news,  which  is  little  more  than 
glorified  gossip,  there  is  no  denying  the  fact  that  far  more  high-grade 
material  is  carried  today  than  ever  before  in  American  newspapers. 
More  and  more  attention  is  paid  to  cultural,  scientific,  and  religious  ma- 
terial. More  space  is  devoted  to  such  items  in  one  of  our  better  news- 
papers in  a  week  than  was  given  over  in  three  months  a  generation  back. 
Especially  marked  has  been  the  improvement  in  the  treatment  of  inter- 
national news  and  the  space  alloted  to  it.  Certain  areas  have  been 
almost  literally  rescued  from  oblivion.  More  news  on  South  America, 
for  example,  is  now  carried  in  one  day  than  was  carried  in  a  month  two 
decades  back. 

The  desire  to  attract  wide  interest  on  the  part  of  a  reading  public  that 
is  often  neither  too  well  educated  nor  too  intelligent  has  given  rise  to  a 
characteristic  newspaper  style — racy,  pungent,  staccato,  and  often  not 
too  solicitious  of  the  facts.  But  certain  great  newspaper  stylists  have 
been  produced,  of  whom  the  best-known  contemporary  examples  have 
been  Heywood  Broun,  regarded  by  many  as  the  outstanding  journalistic 
writer  in  the  history  of  American  newspapers,  and  Walter  Lippmann, 
once  a  valiant  liberal,  but  now  the  chief  ornament  of  the  reactionary 
press.  Other  columnists  have  introduced  even  more  original  styles. 
Westbrook  Pegler  has  enlivened  journalism  by  carrying  over  the  manner 
of  the  prizefight  reporter  and  bar-room  controversialist  into  comment  on 
public  affairs  and  world  politics.  Walter  Winchell  has  captivated  thou- 
sands of  readers  by  his  racy  banter  and  his  projection  of  "gent's  room" 
witticisms  into  a  highly  popular  daily  column.  Dorothy  Thompson,  in 
her  earnest  and  assured  appraisal  of  current  events,  has  provided  us  with 
a  rich  and  warm  emotionalism,  hitherto  known  only  in  "personal  advice" 
columns  conducted  by  Beatrice  Fairfax  and  Dorothy  Dix. 

One  of  the  penalties  paid  for  mass  circulation  and  the  distraction  of 
readers  by  trivial  news  of  high  emotional  content  has  been  the  marked 
decline  of  the  influence  and  prestige  of  the  editorial  page.  Despite  the 
great  technological  improvements,  the  newspapers  are  declining  in  their 
influence  upon  American  opinion.  This  was  strikingly  illustrated  by  the 
presidential  campaign  of  1936,  when  the  editorial  opinion  of  the  country 
was  lined  up  against  Mr.  Roosevelt  by  a  ratio  of  far  more  than  two  to 
one.  But  the  people  read  the  news,  listened  to  the  campaign  speeches 
over  the  radio,  and,  in  spite  of  all  editorial  frenzy,  put  Mr.  Roosevelt  back 
into  the  White  House  by  an  unprecedented  majority.  The  same  situation 
was  duplicated  in  1940,  when  most  of  the  newspapers  heartily  supported 
Wendell  Willkie,  but  Mr.  Roosevelt  was  reflected  by  a  large  majority. 

This  mass  scepticism  and  indifference  with  respect  to  American  news- 
paper editorials  is  probably  the  most  promising  sign  to  appear  in  Ameri- 
can democracy  in  some  decades.  It  indicates  the  weakening  of  the  influ- 


498      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

ence  of  one  of  the  most  vicious  forms  of  propaganda,  which  has  been  the 
more  dangerous  because  it  has  also  been  so  eminently  respectable.  It  is 
not  out  of  reason  to  predict  the  disappearance  of  the  editorial  page  from 
most  of  our  newspapers.  Indeed,  it  is  already  apparent  that  the  editorial 
page  of  some  of  our  very  best  newspapers  is  a  marked  liability  to  each 
of  the  newspapers  in  question.  Despite  its  waning  influence,  the  style  of 
editorial  writing  has  improved  since  Greeley's  day;  there  is  more  fact  and 
argument  and  less  pure  ranting. 

The  newspaper  columnists  have  taken  over  much  of  the  prestige  for- 
merly enjoyed  by  the  editorial  in  wielding  reader  opinion.30  Distributed 
by  powerful  newspaper  syndicates,  the  interpretations  of  the  columnists 
on  public  affairs  reach  millions  of  readers.  Among  the  more  popular 
are  Walter  Lippmann,  Frank  Kent,  Raymond  Clapper,  Drew  Pearson  and 
Robert  Allen,  David  Lawrence,  Jay  Franklin,  Dorothy  Thompson,  Hugh 
S.  Johnson/™'1  Westbrook  Pegler,  Walter  Winchell,  and  Samuel  Grafton. 
Since  the  columnists  inject  their  personalities  into  their  writings,  they 
naturally  attract  more  attention  than  the  anonymous  editorials.  Fur- 
ther, their  columns  are  usually  more  vividly  written. 

The  columnists  reflect  mainly  Eastern  Seaboard  opinion,  which  is  gen- 
erally internationalist,  and  conservative  economic  and  financial  opinion. 
The  East  thus  possesses  a  disproportionate  influence  in  shaping  national 
opinion.  For  example,  these  columnists,  with  exceptions,  exerted  power- 
ful pressure  in  creating  war  sentiment  before  Pearl  Harbor,  and  took  the 
lead  in  labor-baiting  after  we  entered  the  war. 

The  editorial  influence  of  newspapers  is  both  lessened  and  confused  as 
a  result  of  the  fact  that  most  papers  use  columnists  who  often  present  a 
point  of  view  at  direct  variance  with  the  editorial  opinion  of  the  paper 
or  with  each  other.  While  it  is  excellent  for  newspaper  readers  to 
broaden  their  outlook  by  getting  diverse  points  of  view  on  public  affairs, 
the  editorial  attitude  of  the  paper  is  blurred,  and  the  likelihood  of  definite 
editorial  direction  of  reader  thinking  is  removed.  Probably  the  most 
effective  means  by  which  a  newspaper  can  propagandize  its  views  lies  in 
the  selection  of  news  and  columnists,  in  the  placing  of  unfavorable  in- 
formation in  an  obscure  position  on  an  inside  page  or  giving  a  prominent 
place  to  favorable  information,  and  in  the  emphasis  given  in  the  writing 
of  headlines. 

It  is  impossible  to  understand  the  contemporary  newspaper  unless  one 
realizes  that  journalism  has  become  primarily  a  big  business  enterprise. 
Interest  is  centered  mainly  upon  making  money  rather  than  upon  illumi- 
nating the  public,  or  providing  intelligent  guidance  for  public  opinion. 
What  was  once  primarily  an  intellectual  enterprise,  however  biased  and 
mendacious,  has  now  become  almost  wholly  a  business  venture.  Honest 
newspaper  publishers  freely  admit  this  in  private.  The  formula  of 


36  On  these  columnists,  see  Margaret  Mitchell,  "Columnists  on  Parade,"  in  The 
Nation,  February  26-June  25,  1938;  and  Quincy  Howe,  The  News  and  How  to 
Understand  It,  Simon  and  Schuster,  1940. 

sea   General  Johnson  died  in  April,  1942. 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      499 

modern  journalism  is  simple  and  direct.  "Hot"  news  possessing  great 
mass  appeal  is  published  to  secure  a  large  circulation.  A  large  circulation 
commands  high  advertising  rates.  And  from  advertising  revenue,  which 
reached  its  all  time  high  in  1929  at  over  $800,000,000,000,  the  newspapers 
make  most  of  their  profits.  The  most  successful  newspaper  in  existence 
would  lose  a  large  sum  of  money  each  year  if  it  had  to  depend  on  circula- 
tion revenue  alone.  We  have  already  seen  that,  for  example,  in  1929, 
newspapers  derived  about  three  times  as  much  from  advertising  as  from 
circulation. 

This  overwhelming  importance  of  advertising  has  led  to  the  argument 
that  newspapers  are  the  unwilling  slaves  of  their  advertising  clientele. 
Their  publishers  are  portrayed  as  men  who  would  dearly  like  to  be  liberal 
and  aggressive,  but  are  afraid  to  incur  the  displeasure  of  the  advertisers. 
However,  most  of  them  are  as  liberal  in  their  journalism  as  they  wish  to 
be.  They  are  restrained  much  more  by  their  own  state  of  mind  than  by 
the  intimidation  of  advertisers.  A  clothing  manufacturer,  for  example, 
is  not  expected  to  jeopardize  his  business  in  the  interest  of  elevating 
humanity,  and  there  is  no  more  reason  to  expect  a  newspaper  publisher 
to  do  so. 

A  powerful  newspaper  would,  in  most  cases,  be  able  to  defy  advertisers 
within  the  bounds  of  reason.  It  could  appeal  to  readers  and  even  bring 
about  a  boycott  of  stores  or  of  the  products  of  advertisers  which  could 
be  proved  to  be  opposed  to  the  dissemination  of  truth.  Even  in  smaller 
cities,  newspapers  are  generally  as  indispensable  to  the  advertisers  as  the 
advertisers  are  to  the  newspapers,  and  could  exercise  a  great  deal  of  free- 
dom and  independence.  Above  all,  chain  newspapers  can  be  independent 
of  advertisers  in  any  given  locality.  A  local  newspaper  in  a  chain  can 
be  run  at  a  loss,  if  necessary,  until  the  advertisers  break  down  and  return 
to  the  use  of  its  space. 

In  short,  newspaper  publishers  are  not  afraid  of  businessmen  or  in- 
timidated by  them.  They  are  businessmen  themselves  and  naturally 
sympathize  with  the  economic  biases  and  social  prejudices  of  other 
businessmen,  among  them  those  who  advertise  in  newspapers. 

With  the  growing  tension  of  the  economic  and  social  situation  in  the 
ever  more  evident  crisis  of  capitalism,  liberalism  is  becoming  much  more 
rare  in  American  journalism.  There  are  very  few  literally  liberal  news- 
papers in  the  United  States  today — not  a  half-dozen  leading  dailies.  And 
many  of  the  pseudo-liberal  papers  are  such  only  because  it  is  expedient, 
in  the  light  of  the  journalistic  set-up  in  any  given  city,  for  them  to  be  so. 
Owners  of  several  newspapers  not  infrequently  conduct  a  liberal  paper  in 
one  city,  where  it  pays  them  to  be  liberal,  and  maintain  a  conservative 
paper  in  another  and  more  reactionary  municipality.  The  few  genuinely 
liberal  newspapers  have  taken  their  stand  because  their  publishers  believe 
that  capitalism  can  be  most  certainly  and  effectively  perpetuated  by 
bringing  about  necessary  reforms  in  the  capitalistic  system.  There  is 
scarcely  a  newspaper  in  the  United  States,  save  for  the  Communist  Daily 
Worker,  which  attacks  the  capitalistic  system  as  a  basic  social  institution. 


500      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

There  is  not  a  powerful  labor  daily  in  the  United  States.  The  Daily 
Worker,  a  Communist  organ,  is  just  as  biased  as  the  average  capitalistic 
journal.  Labor  dailies  would  find  it  difficult  to  secure  remunerative 
advertising.  They  would  have  to  rely  primarily  upon  circulation  rev- 
enue, and  the  limited  income  from  this  source  would  make  it  impossible 
for  a  labor  paper  to  duplicate  the  rich  and  varied  offerings  of  our  conven- 
tional newspapers.  Moreover,  it  is  doubtful  if  laborers  would  even  supr 
ply  any  mass  circulation  of  a  strictly  labor  journal.  The  majority  of 
them  would  prefer  to  remain  entertained  by  the  traditional  newspaper 
which  may,  in  policy,  be  vehemently  opposed  to  the  point  of  view  and 
interests  of  organized  labor.  In  spite  of  the  contrary  dogmas  of  Karl 
Marx,  the  American  worker,  like  most  other  Americans,  is  more  sus- 
ceptible to  entertainment  and  a  play  upon  his  emotions  than  to  an  appeal 
to  his  economic  interests. 

It  would  be  interesting  to  watch  the  experiment  of  an  intelligent  and 
liberal  editor  who  decided  to  cast  conventions  to  the  wind  and  run  a 
truly  crusading  newspaper.  There  are  those  who  believe  that  such  an 
experiment  could  be  financially  successful.  It  is  held  that  such  liberal 
papers  as  we  have  today  merely  go  far  enough  with  their  liberalism 
to  annoy  conservative  advertisers,  but  do  not  take  a  sufficiently  advanced 
stand  to  arouse  an  enthusiastic  support  on  the  part  of  liberals  and  labor- 
ites.  It  is  believed  that,  if  there  is  going  to  be  any  flirtation  with  liberal- 
ism, it  is  better  to  go  the  whole  way.  There  may  be  logic  and  truth  in 
this  point  of  view,  but  we  are  not  likely  to  find  a  liberal  newspaper  pub- 
lisher or  editor  who  possesses  both  the  nerve  and  the  resources  to  try 
such  an  experiment  in  a  thorough-going  fashion.  The  New  York  tabloid, 
PM,  started  out  as  a  valiant  left-wing  liberal  paper,  but  a  financial  crisis 
quickly  forced  it  to  alter  its  policy  and  to  dismiss  most  of  its  liberal  staff. 

In  discussing  the  freedom  of  the  press  in  our  day,  one  must  remember 
the  general  character  of  our  era.  It  is  one  in  which  the  struggle  is  nar- 
rowing down  to  a  conflict  between  those  who  wish  to  overthrow  the  pres- 
ent economic  system  and  those  who  wish  to  preserve  it.  The  majority  of 
the  newspapers  in  the  United  States  are  lined  up  with  the  latter  policy. 
As  the  capitalistic  system  weakens,  and  comes  into  greater  jeopardy,  the 
newspapers  are  likely  to  defend  it  more  resolutely  and  to  be  less  con- 
genial to  any  expression  of  radical  criticism. 

When  we  talk  about  the  freedom  of  the  press  in  this  country  we  mean 
the  freedom  of  the  capitalistic  press.    Papers  which  openly  advocate 
revolution,  in  the  spirit  of  the  Declaration  of  Independence,  have  been , 
banned  from  the  mails  and  the  federal  courts  have  upheld  their  suppres- 
sion. 

Americans  make  too  much  of  our  freedom  of  the  press,  as  compared 
with  government  censorship  abroad.  While  it  is  true,  as  Secretary  Ickes 
has  said,  that  the  servitude  of  the  American  press  is  "voluntary  servi- 
tude," yet  there  is  an  enormous  amount  of  this  voluntary  suppression  of 
news.  It  is  probable  that  as  great  a  proportion  of  the  total  news  is  ex- 
cluded in  the  United  States  by  voluntary  newspaper  action  as  is  sup- 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      501 

pressed  by  government  orders  in  totalitarian  countries.  In  this  country, 
the  news  which  is  suppressed  is  that  which  lacks  mass  appeal  or  is  repug- 
nant to  the  publishers,  editors,  and  advertisers.  Abroad,  what  is  sup- 
pressed is  mainly  material  disapproved  by  the  government.  The  cour- 
ageous journalist,  George  Seldes,  has  built  up  an  important  weekly 
publication,  In  Fact,  which  is  devoted  primarily  to  recording  news  which 
has  been  suppressed,  wholly  or  in  part,  by  the  conventional  American 
newspapers,  or  has  been  grossly  distorted  by  them.  Nevertheless  it  is  a 
considerable  advantage  for  our  newspapers  to  be  able  legally  to  print  all 
of  the  news  if  they  wish  to  do  so. 

The  freedom  of  the  press  had  disappeared  from  the  greater  part  of 
Europe  long  before  1939.  In  some  of  the  totalitarian  states  the  govern- 
ment actually  ran  the  press,  and  in  all  of  them  it  told  the  press  what  it 
could  publish.37 

The  whole  question  of  freedom  of  the  press  in  Britain  before  the 
war  broke  out  was  surveyed  in  an  admirable  article  on  "Legal  Restrictions 
upon  the  British  Press"  in  The  United  States  Law  Review,  this  being 
a  reprint  of  the  comprehensive  report  by  the  Political  and  Economic 
Planning  Group  in  London.  There  was  no  open  and  overt  censorship 
of  the  press  in  England  before  1939.  This  was  invoked  only  in  war  time. 
But  the  police  could  exercise  an  unofficial  censorship,  especially  of  small 
and  radical  publications.  For  example,  the  police  seized  the  copies 
of  a  radical  sheet  for  criticizing  a  foreign  monarch,  at  the  very  moment 
that  they  left  unmolested  the  London  Times,  which  was  publishing  letters 
advocating  the  same  monarch's  assassination. 

The  freedom  of  the  press  in  Britain  was  definitely  curtailed  by  con- 
tempt of  court  proceedings.  This  power  to  muzzle  the  press  was  so 
vague,  broad,  and  uncertain  that  newspapers  did  not  know  where  they, 
stood  and,  hence,  tended  to  refrain  from  even  reasonable  and  very  desir- 
able criticism  of  the  administration  of  justice.  Also,  contempt  proceed- 
ings were  extremely  arbitrary  because  the  court  is  always  the  plaintiff, 
judge,  jury,  and  witness  in  its  own  cause. 

The  British  press  was,  like  the  American  press,  restricted  by  the 
familiar  legislation  against  blasphemy,  obscenity,  and  libel.  These  re- 
strictions were  justified  on  the  ground  that  they  protected  the  public 
morals  and  safeguarded  the  individual  against  defamation.  There  were 
many  nuisances  associated  with  the  restrictions  in  behalf  of  public  morals, 
but  they  were  not  significant  in  the  way  of  crippling  the  freedom  of  the 
press.  Those  restrictions  relating  to  libel  were,  however,  more  serious. 
They  created  a  veritable  paradise  for  gold-diggers  and  blackmailers. 
There  was  a  literal  racket  run  by  those  who  made  a  living  out  of 
searching  for  possible  libels,  revealing  them  to  the  aggrieved  persons, 
bringing  suit  against  newspapers,  getting  the  case  settled  out  of  court,  and 
then  splitting  the  damages  collected.  The  fear  of  irresponsible  juries  has 
prevented  the  newspapers  from  breaking  up  this  racket. 


37  See  0.  W.  Riegel,  Mobilizing  for  Chaos,  Yale  University  Press,  1934,  pp.  155-156. 


502      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

The  more  serious  forms  of  menace  to  the  freedom  of  the  British  press 
before  1939  related  to  those  restrictions  upon  criticizing  the  government 
or  publishing  the  full  truth  about  governmental  activities.  The  restric- 
tions under  the  head  of  seditious  libel  curbed  critics  of  the  government 
and  social  reformers.  Those  who  criticized  the  government  could  be 
arrested  for  inciting  disaffection  and  disloyalty  to  government,  while 
reformers  might  be  punished  for  promoting  ill-will  and  hostility  between 
the  different  classes  of  His  Majesty's  subjects.  At  the  same  time,  how- 
ever, the  partisans  of  the  government  were  allowed  to  go  to  any  extreme 
in  maligning  the  critics  of  government. 

Especially  dangerous  to  journalism  were  the  restrictions  growing  out  of 
the  taboo  upon  revealing  official  secrets.  Ostensibly  designed  to  protect 
the  government  against  espionage  and  the  disclosure  of  state  secrets,  this 
had  been  carried  so  far  that  the  British  press  was  even  not  allowed  to  say 
anything  about  the  concentration  of  the  British  navy  in  the  eastern  Medi- 
terranean in  the  autumn  of  1935. 

Worst  of  all  was  the  Incitement  to  Disaffection  Act  of  1934.  This 
made  it  a  crime  to  publish,  or  even  to  possess,  anything  which  "might 
seduce  a  member  of  His  Majesty's  forces  from  his  duty  or  allegiance." 
This  made  it  literally  criminal  to  publish  or  possess  anything  openly 
advocating  pacifism  or  revolution.  It  would  actually  have  been  possible 
to  imprison  British  subjects  for  possessing  not  only  Quaker  literature, 
but  even  a  copy  of  the  New  Testament.  One  printer  actually  refused 
an  order  for  a  large  number  of  Christmas  cards  because  they  carried  the 
admonition  to  "peace  on  earth  and  good-will  to  men." 

The  authors  of  this  report  concluded  that  "it  is  useless  in  present 
European  conditions  to  hope  for  relaxation"  of  any  of  these  laws  which 
give  the  government  a  strangle-hold  over  the  freedom  and  candor  of  the 
British  press.  This  conclusion  proved  prophetic,  for  when  the  second 
World  War  broke  out  in  1939  government  censorship  was  immediately 
imposed  on  the  British  press. 

As  to  the  future  conflict  between  the  newspaper  and  the  radio,  this  is 
purely  a  matter  of  guesswork  at  present.  Already,  however,  the  radio 
announcer  has  killed  the  journalistic  "flash  extra/7  But  this  has  not 
been  a  total  loss  to  the  newspapers,  because  the  announcement  of  some 
sensational  news  over  the  radio  usually  increases  the  sales  of  the  next 
editions  of  the  newspapers,  for  the  people  want  to  read  about  such  an 
event  in  full.  So  far,  the  newspapers  have  been  relatively  safe  from 
radio  competition,  because  the  people  have  wanted  a  news  medium  which 
they  could  consult  at  their  convenience.  But  there  has  already  been 
made  available  for  sale  at  a  relatively  low  price  a  radio  attachment 
which  will  print  the  important  news  broadcasts  as  they  are  sent  out  over 
the  radio.  These  can  be  gathered  together  by  the  owner  and  read  when- 
ever he  pleases.  Just  what  effect  the  radio  newspaper  will  have  on  the 
future  of  printed  journalism  cannot  be  predicted. 

Certain  newspaper  publishers  have  decided  to  take  no  chances  and 
have  gone  extensively  into  the  radio  business,  although  the  radio  field 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      503 

had  been  rather  thoroughly  preempted  by  the  National  Broadcasting 
Company  and  the  Columbia  Broadcasting  System  before  the  newspapers 
awakened  to  the  threat.37a  There  are  now  about  300  radio  outlets  linked 
with  newspapers.  The  newspapers  also  control  some  large  local  stations 
affiliated  with  the  big  radio  chains.  The  most  serious  result  of  radio 
competition  is  the  inroad  of  the  radio  into  the  newspaper  advertising 
revenue.  A  considerable  portion  of  the  total  advertising  budget,  which 
once  went  almost  entirely  to  newspapers,  is  now  being  diverted  to  the 
radio.  Whereas  the  income  from  newspaper  advertising  dropped  from 
over  800  million  dollars  in  1929  to  525  million  dollars  in  1939,  radio  adver- 
tising jumped  from  40  million  dollars  in  1929  to  170  million  dollars  in 
1939,  and  to  185  million  dollars  in  1940. 

The  Periodical   Press 

Periodical  literature  represents  an  important  phase  of  contemporary 
journalism.  There  were  7,124  periodicals  published  in  the  United  States 
in  1940.  Most  of  these  were  trade  papers  and  pulp  magazines.38 

Our  magazines  not  only  publish  the  shorter  works  of  some  of  the  most 
important  contemporary  writers;  they  also  furnish  us  with  most  of  our 
information  about  books  and  our  judgments  on  them.  Reputable  maga- 
zines, reflecting  primarily  the  literary  and  social  interests  of  capitalistic 
society  and  the  leisure  class,  were  well  established  in  the  nineteenth  cen- 
tury. Representative  of  these  are  the  Fortnightly  Review,  the  Contem- 
porary Review,  the  Nineteenth  Century,  the  Revue  des  deux  mondes,  the 
Deutsche  Rundschau,  The  North  American  Review,  the  Atlantic  Monthly, 
Scribner's,  Century,  Harper's,  and  the  Outlook,  some  of  which  have  now 
ceased  publication.  There  are  some  very  interesting  and  valuable  peri- 
odicals devoted  almost  exclusively  to  literary  criticism  and  book-review- 
ing, such  as  the  London  Athenaeum,  and  the  Saturday  Review  of  Litera- 
ture, founded  by  Henry  Seidel  Canby.  Iconoclastic  criticism  was 
represented  in  such  periodicals  as  the  Smart  Set,  followed  in  a  different 
pattern  and  on  a  more  pretentious  scale  by  The  American  Mercury,  both 
magazines  long  edited  by  H.  L.  Mencken  and  George  Jean  Nathan. 
Resolute  political  and  social  criticism  have  dominated  the  pages  of  the 
Forum,  the  New  Republic,  the  Nation,  Common  Sense,  and  a  number  of 
other  liberal  periodicals.  Advanced  modernistic  trends  in  literature  have 
found  expression  in  such  publications  as  the  Dial  and  Hound  and  Horn. 

Periodical  literature  has  mirrored  the  economic  currents  in  the  contem- 
porary scene.  In  Europe,  especially  in  England,  there  are  some  staid 
and  respectable  organs  that  reflect  the  interests  of  the  agrarian  aristoc- 
racy, and  the  industrial  oligarchy.  But  in  the  United  States,  especially 
since  the  first  World  War,  there  have  been  few  if  any  important  periodi- 
cals exclusively  expressive  of  upper-class  conservative  opinion.  The 


37«  See  below,  pp.  517-520. 

38  See  F.  L.  Mott,  A  History  of  American  Magazines,  3  Vols.,  Harvard  University 
Press,  1939. 


504      TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION 

Bookman  took  on  such  a  cast  for  a  time,  but  its  circulation  and  influence 
were  limited.  Even  the  Atlantic  Monthly  and  Scribner's  have  published 
much  important  material  severely  criticizing  rugged  individualism  and 
plutocracy.  Likewise  Fortune,  a  sumptuous  monthly,  created  for  exclu- 
sive "class"  circulation,  has  not  hesitated  at  times  to  include  material 
as  devastating  as  that  which  was  called  "muckraking"  in  the  era  of 
Theodore  Roosevelt,  when  carried  in  McClure's  and  other  reformist 
journals  of  that  time.  The  closest  to  upper-class  periodical  literature 
in  the  United  States  are  such  purely  entertaining  appeals  to  the  leisure 
class  as  Vanity  Fair,  the  New  Yorker,  and  Esquire.  Here  again,  however, 
the  critical  note  has  not  been  absent.  Once  mildly  conservative  periodi- 
cals like  the  Forum 80  and  Harper's  Magazine  became  leading  agencies  of 
social  controversy  and  advanced  liberal  opinion.  The  lively  American 
Mercury  was  founded  by  Mencken  and  Nathan  in  1923  as  an  antireform- 
ist,  antidemocratic  magazine  for  the  more  cynical  and  detached  members 
of  the  leisure  class,  but  after  1933,  under  the  editorship  of  Charles  Angoff, 
it  tended  for  a  brief  period  to  rival  the  Forum  and  Harper's  in  the  zeal  and 
resolution  with  which  it  presented  social,  economic,  and  political  criticism. 
Under  the  current  editorship  of  Eugene  Lyons,  it  has  combined  the  old 
social  criticism  with  Red-baiting  and  rabid  interventionism,  since  1940. 
Such  weekly  periodicals  as  the  Nation  and  the  New  Republic  passed  from 
organs  of  liberalism  to  at  least  mild  radicalism,  while  the  New  Masses 
is  frankly  Communistic  in  tone.  Critical  humorous  magazines  enjoyed 
wide  popularity,  among  the  leaders  being  Simplicissimus,  Puck,  Life,  and 
Judge.40 

As  is  the  case  with  liberal  newspapers,  the  outlook  for  liberal  periodicals 
is  not  bright.  The  great  majority  of  the  formerly  liberal  periodicals 
joined  heartily  in  the  crusade  for  a  foreign  war  and  developed  an  attitude 
of  intellectual  dogmatism,  arrogance,  and  intolerance,  highly  symptomatic 
of  proto-Fascism.  They  quickly  found  themselves  in  the  inevitable 
dilemma  of  fighting  for  domestic  causes  and  internal  reforms  that  war 
and  war  preparations  invariably  curtail  or  suppress.  Few  of  these  jour- 
nals learned  the  clear  lesson  taught  by  the  first  World  War,  namely,  that 
they  cannot  have  their  cake  and  eat  it,  too.  They  cannot  logically  expect 
both  to  perpetuate  social  reform  and  live  under  a  war  economy  and  psy- 
chology which  ruthlessly  oppose  reform. and  social  justice. 

With  the  decline  of  the  editorial  domination  of  American  newspapers 
and  the  growth  of  a  mass  appeal  through  sensational  news,  the  intellectual 
leadership  in  American  journalism  has  assuredly  passed  from  the  news- 
papers to  periodical  literature.  Periodicals  have,  of  late,  very  definitely 
even  invaded  the  newspaper  realm.  Certain  magazines,  of  which  Time 
and  Newsweek  are  the  most  notable  examples,  are  really  crisp  and  pun- 
gent weekly  newspapers  in  something  like  the  tabloid  format.  They 
provide  a  racy  and  cryptic  summary  of  tlie  more  important  news  of  the 


89  The  Forum  is  now  incorporated  in  Current  History. 

40  Life  and  Judge   have   ceased  publication.    There   is   no   high-class   humorous 
periodical  in  *he  United  States  today. 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      505 

week,  written  in  brilliant  fashion  and  considerably  above  the  intellectual 
level  of  the  average  newspaper  product.  The  enormous  success  of  Time 
shows  that  the  American  population  not  only  appreciates  the  crisp  mode 
of  presentation  but  also  seemingly  finds  the  news  presented  in  the  news- 
papers so  extensive  and  diffuse  that  it  seeks  an  authoritative  and  readable 
summary. 

Periodicals  have  also  aped  the  ideals  and  technique  of  the  tabloid 
and  have  sought  to  exploit  the  appeal  made  to  the  average  reader  by 
visual  imagery.  Such  magazines  are  devoted  primarily  to  pictures  with 
explanatory  text.  These  pictures  present  the  more  important  news 
developments  of  the  current  period  in  visual  form.  Ltfe,  affiliated  with 
Time,  has  been  the  most  notably  successful  of  these.  It  built  a  circula- 
tion running  into  the  millions  within  a  very  short  time.  It  has  been 
followed  by  Look,  also  very  popular,  and  by  other  less  creditable  imita- 
tors. 

Great  commercial  magazines  with  a  wide  appeal  and  large  advertising 
revenue  have  flourished  in  the  recent  period,  paralleling  the  rise  of  the 
commercial  newspaper.  Such  are  the  Saturday  Evening  Post,  Collier's, 
the  American  Magazine,  the  Cosmopolitan,  Liberty,  the  Delineator,  the 
Woman's  Home  Companion,  and  the  like.  Their  editorial  courage  and 
social  enlightenment  have  usually  declined  in  proportion  to  their  com- 
mercial success.  The  zest  for  compactness  and  astute  condensation  has 
given  rise  to  the  Reader's  Digest  and  innumerable  imitations.  The 
Reader's  Digest  publishes  condensations  of  some  of  the  best  periodical 
literature  and  popular  books,  along  with  many  brief  original  articles.  It 
has  gained  an  enormous  popularity — the  largest  circulation  of  any  pe- 
riodical— and  makes  fabulous  profits  without  resort  to  any  commercial 
advertising. 

Monthly  magazines  represent  the  most  numerous  class  of  periodicals. 
In  1940,  they  numbered  3,946  in  the  United  States,  as  against  1,482 
weeklies.  Especially  popular  have  been  the  women's  magazines,  nine 
of  which  had  a  circulation,  in  1930,  in  excess  of  a  million  a  month.  Five 
of  the  general  monthlies  have  each  a  circulation  of  more  than  2,000,000.41 
There  are  several  agricultural  journals  which  have  a  monthly  circulation 
of  a  million  or  more.  The  remarkable  success  of  Time  and  Life  has  im- 
proved the  showing  of  the  weekly  periodicals  in  recent  circulation  gains. 
The  advertising  income  of  national  magazines  is  impressive.  In  1935, 
it  was  $123,093,000,  and  this  was  a  considerable  drop  from  the  high  of 
1929. 

Motion   Pictures  as  a   Factor   in  Communication 

The  motion  picture  shares  with  radio  the  distinction  of  being  the  unique 
contribution  of  the  twentieth  century  to  the  remarkable  developments  in 
communication.  The  first  public  showing  of  a  moving  picture  was  pre- 
sented on  May  21,  1895.  The  motion  picture  was  a  result  of  advances 


41  Saturday   Evening   Post   has   a    circulation    of    3,104,208;    Colliers,   2,745,051; 
Liberty,  2,358,661;  American  Magazine,  2,189,217;  and  True  Story,  2,005,139. 


506      TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION 

in  optics,  the  camera,  and  film.  The  elements  of  photography  were  dis- 
covered by  two  Frenchmen,  Louis  Daguerre  and  Joseph  Niepce,  between 
1826  and  1839,  and  extended  in  the  next  generation  by  W.  H.  Fox  Talbot 
in  England  and  by  J.  W.  Draper  in  the  United  States.  But  photography 
could  make  little  commercial  headway  until  the  celluloid  film  was  pro- 
duced at  the  end  of  the  century.  An  important  aid  to  the  moving  picture 
was  the  kinetoscope  of  Thomas  A.  Edison  and  the  projector  of  Thomas 
Armat,  invented  in  1895.  The  first  "movie"  consisted  in  the  rapid  shift- 
ing of  a  series  of  still  pictures. 

By  1900,  crude  movies  of  animated  scenes,  such  as  a  train  passing  or  a 
Negro  boy  eating  a  watermelon,  were  produced.  The  first  story  movie 
was  turned  out  in  1905.  It  was  made  up  of  one  reel  of  a  thousand  feet. 
The  technique  of  large-scale  movie  production  was  revolutionized  by 
D.  W.  Griffith,  with  his  handling  of  massed  actors  and  his  use  of  the 
"close-up,"  "cut-back,"  and  "fade-out,"  These  innovations  were  com- 
bined in  the  film  "The  Birth  of  a  Nation"  (1915),  which  revolutionized 
the  movie  art  and  inaugurated  a  movie  industry. 

The  next  advance  was  one  that  exploited  popular  personalities  to 
achieve  mass  appeal.  This  brought  in  the  "star"  system,  first  promoted 
by  Adolph  Zukor.  Such  celebrities  as  Mary  Pickford,  Douglas  Fair- 
banks, Charlie  Chaplin,  Theda  Bara,  Clara  Kimball  Young  and  Bill  Hart 
established  the  popularity  of  star  performers.  The  sound  picture  was 
introduced  in  1927  and  helped  to  increase  the  following  of  the  movies. 
By  1930,  the  average  weekly  attendance  at  movies  in  the  United  States 
was  somewhere  between  90  and  110  millions. 

In  addition  to  entertainment,  the  movies  contribute  an  important 
element  to  American  information.  The  newsreels  present  a  vivid  visual 
reproduction  of  events  that  have  happened  in  various  parts  of  the  world 
in  the  very  recent  past.  Newsreels  will  probably  make  use  of  the  recent 
development  whereby  photographs  are  transmitted  by  cable  and  radio. 
An  audience  in  Kansas  City  may  then  see  upon  the  screen  in  the  evening 
events  that  took  place  in  Capetown,  South  Africa,  the  same  morning. 
Many  excellent  scientific  films  and  medical  films  are  produced. 

The  motion  picture  has  not  only  provided  new  and  diverting  types 
of  entertainment  and  communication  facilities,  but  has  developed  into 
one  of  the  major  industries  of  the  country.  The  average  weekly  attend- 
ance at  movies  was  estimated  as  85  millions  in  1939.42  It  has  been  esti- 
mated that,  of  this  weekly  movie-going  population,  around  25  millions 
are  minors.  In  1940,  there  were  approximately  17,000  motion  picture 
theaters  available  in  the  United  States,  seating  10,460,000  persons. 
Many  of  these  theaters  are  controlled  by,  or  affiliated  with,  the  big  pro- 
ducers of  Hollywood,  a  practice  developed  under  the  leadership  of  Adolph 
Zukor,  with  what  many  observers  regard  as  disastrous  results  for  the 
quality  of  movie  production  and  the  freedom  of  exhibition. 


42  Some  authorities  put  it  at  only  70  millions.  At  any  rate,  movie  attendance  has 
fallen  off  notably  from  its  high  of  1930,  at  around  100  million,  a  mattep  which  we 
shall  shortly  consider. 


TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION      507 

In  1939  the  total  investment  in  the  motion  picture  industry  in  the 
United  States  was  estimated  to  be  slightly  over  $2,000,000,000,  having 
grown  from  some  96  million  dollars  in  1921.  The  total  value  of  Holly- 
wood studio  investment  in  1939  was  117  million  dollars.  In  1939  some 
130  motion  picture  studios  in  the  country  produced  films  valued,  on 
a  production-cost  basis,  at  165  million  dollars.  Approximately  300,000 
persons  were  employed  in  the  industry  in  1939,  receiving  some  $410,- 
760,000  in  salaries  and  wages.  Of  this  total,  32,000  were  employed  in 
producing  films.  Some  760  feature  pictures  were  released  in  1939. 
About  41,850  feature  films  and  "shorts"  have  been  produced  in  the 
history  of  the  American  film  industry.  The  film  industry  spent  $80,000,- 
000  for  advertising  in  1939.  Some  22,000  advertisers  used  the  films  for 
advertising  and  spent  about  $2,000,000  thereon.  About  $350,000,000 
were  paid  in  taxes  by  the  film  industry  in  1939. 

There  has  been  a  vast  amount  of  waste  and  extravagance  in  the  movies, 
growing  out  of  fantastic  salaries  to  stars,  large  salaries  for  advisors  and 
consultants  who  frequently  did  nothing,  extensive  payments  for  movie 
rights  to  books  and  plays  which  might  or  might  not  be  used,  and  the  like. 
While  the  lavish  "Birth  of  a  Nation"  cost  Griffith  only  $100,000,  Cecil  B. 
DeMille  spent  $2,300,000  on  "The  King  of  Kings,"  and  Metro-Goldwyn- 
Mayer  paid  $4,000,000  for  a  half-interest  in  "Ben  Hur."  RKO  is  said 
by  Herbert  Harris  to  have  paid  $300,000  to  build  a  single  stage-setting 
for  "Cain  and  Mabel."  MGM  paid  Rachel  Crothers  $2,500  a  week  for  20 
weeks  and  used  one  line  she  had  written.  Fox  kept  Philip  Merivale  under 
contract  at  $1,000  a  week  for  11  months  without  using  him  in  a  single 
film.  In  spite  of  these  wastes  and  fabulous  salaries  paid  to  stars,  such 
as  nearly  $400,000  per  annum  to  Mae  West,  the  rank-and-file  in  movie- 
dom  are  not  well  paid.  The  average  income  of  this  group  on  the  Pacific 
Coast  is  between  $1,400  and  $1,500  a  year.  The  depression  rendered 
necessary  the  introduction  of  economies  and  better  business  methods,  so 
that  in  1939  feature  pictures  were  produced  for  an  average  cost  of  $300,- 
000.  Tremendous  sums  are,  however,  still  spent  on  more  spectacular 
movies.  "Gone  With  the  Wind"  cost  over  $4,000,000  to  produce.  Its 
gross  earnings  were  about  $20,000,000.  We  present  below  an  interest- 
ing itemized  account  of  the  outlay  for  "Gone  With  the  Wind."  The 
salaries  paid  to  some  stars  still  exceed  the  salaries  of  most  leading  busi- 
ness executives  in  the  United  States. 

As  soon  as  the  movie  business  became  a  major  industry  it  became 
involved  in  business  consolidation  and  high  finance.  Eight  giant  movie 
corporations  dominate  the  film  industry — Columbia,  Metro-Goldwyn- 
Mayer,  Radio-Keith-Orpheum,  20th  Century-Fox,  United  Artists,  Warner 
Brothers,  Paramount,  and  Universal.  The  great  eastern  banks — often 
the  same  that  are  back  of  radio — gradually  came  into  control.  For  ex- 
ample, Paramount  is  controlled  by  the  Public  National  Bank  and  Trust 
Company  of  New  York,  Lehman  Brothers,  and  certain  affiliated  banking 
groups;  20th  Century-Fox  is  an  appendage  of  the  Chase  National  Bank; 
Stanley  Brothers  dominate  Warner  Brothers;  Columbia  is  dominated  by 


COST  SCHEDULE  OF 

"Gun  WITH  T 


Salaries  of  Stars  and  Cast  and  Extra  Talent , 466,688.00 

Cameramen,  wardrobe  workers,  property  men,  make-up  artists,  hairdressers,  musicians, 
copyists,  transportation  drivers,  carpenters,  grips,  painters,  plasterers,  laborers, 
electricians,  projectionists,  machinists,  tractor  drivers,  prop-makers,  drapers,  uphol- 
sterers, sound  crew,  special  effects  men , 961,215.00 

Film  cutters,  assistant  directors,  unit  managers,  artists  (set  designers),  scrip!  clerks 119,433.00 

Extras 108,469.00 

Department  heads,  technical  advisers,  stenographers,  watchmen,  interior  decorators,  ward- 
robe manufacturers,  clerks,  messenger  boys,  telephone  operators 328,349.00 

Total  cost  of  Sets  (as  per  detail  below) 197,877.00 

Exterior  Atlanta  Street $31,155  Interior  Armory 3,397 

Exterior  and  Interior  Tara  and  Gardens  28,149  Exterior  Twelve,  Oaks — Barbecue  Pits..     2,764 

Exterior  and  Interior  Twelve  Oaks. . . .  20,372  Interfor  Melanie's  House 2,714 

Exterior  and  Interior  Rhett's  Home. .       17,035  Exlerior  Road_E8Cape   2,449 

Railway  Station,  Including  Tracks  and  ^^  McDonough  Road 2,083 

Exre^rVeach^e'stVeVt:::;::::::::::  £S£     ******** u» 

Interior  Aunt  Pitty's  Home 7.236  Jump  Sequence  1.145 

Exterior  of  Church 5,573  Road  to  Twelve  Oaks 1.070 

Exterior  and  Interior  Frank  Kennedy's  Exterior  Shantytown 1.069 

Store    3.991  Backings,  Miniatures,  Flats,  etc 13,589 

Interior  Church  Hospital 3,959  Miscellaneous  Small  Sets,  etc. 22,603 

Total  cost  of  Women's  Wardrobe. $  98,154.00 

Total  cost  of  Men's  Wardrobe 55.664.00 

Total  cost  of  Wardrobe 153,818.00 

Projection  cost 11.376.00 

Picture  Raw  Stock  (474,538  feet)  cost 109,974.00 

(Since  the  Technicolor  process  uses  three  negatives  this  total  should  be  multiplied  by 
three  to  arrive  at  the  total  of  1,423,614  lineal  feet  of  negative  raw  stock.) 

Picture  Negative  developed  (390,792  feet— 1,172,376  lineal  feet)  cost 23.448.00 

and  Picture  Negative  printed  (272,658  feet)  cost 33,701.00 

Sound  Track  Raw  Stock  (535,000  feet)  cost 5.511.00 

Sound  Track  developed  (221.303  feet)  cost 2,213.00 

and  Sound  Track  Printed  and  reprints  (232,885  feet)  cost 8,150.00 

Lighting  cost,  which  includes  Electricians,  Equipment  Rentals  and  Electric  Power  and 

Supplies 134.497.00 

It  is  estimated  we  used  1,000,000  board  feet  of  lumber.  Estimated  cost 35.000.00 

Cost  of  Research 9.987.40 

The  Transportation  cost  (Auto  and  Truck  hire)  was 59,917.00 

location  Expenses  were 54.341.00 

The  cost  of  Props  purchased,  manufactured  and  rented  was 90,758.00 

The  estimated  cost  of  Music,  which  Includes  the  salaries  of  Lou  Forbes,  head  of  the  Selznick 
International  Pictures'  Music  Department,  and  Secretary,  Max  Steiner,  Musicians  and 

Copyists,  also  Miscellaneous  License  Fees  and  Supplies  and  Expenses $  99,822.00 

Price  Paid  for  the  Novel  was  $50,000,  largest  ever  paid  for  a  first  novel. 

Cost  of  the  Search  for  Scarlett  OUara  has  been  computed  by  studio  accountants  at  $92.000,  of  which 

about  2/3  represents  cost  of  screen  tests. 
Negative  Cost  of  G.W.T.W.  is  computed  at  $3,957,000. 
Fined  computation  of  the  production  will  be  higher. 

From  Film  Daily  Yearbook,  1941. 


508 


TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION       509 

Eastman,  Dillon  and  Company  and  the  California  banking  interests  of 
A.  P.  Giannini;  and  RKO  is  controlled  by  Lehman  Brothers,  Lazard 
Frferes,  the  Atlas  Corporation,  and  the  Chase  National  Bank.48  One 
of  the  more  dramatic  espisodes  in  this  assumption  of  financial  domina- 
tion over  the  movies  by  the  banks  is  unfolded  by  Upton  Sinclair  in  his 
book,  Upton  Sinclair  Presents  William  Fox,  which  deals  with  a  broader 
field  than  the  Fox  movie  interests.44 

There  has  been  the  usual  tendency  toward  concentration  in  the  control 
of  motion  picture  theaters.  Extensive  chains  of  theaters  have  been 
created  and  have  either  been  merged  with  big  producing  companies  or 
definitely  affiliated  with  them.  By  1929,  out  of  533  motion  picture 
exchanges,  some  444  were  controlled  by  producers,  and  they  handled 
approximately  95  per  cent  of  the  total  motion  picture  business.  In 
1929,  the  Allied  States  Association  of  Motion  Picture  Exhibitors  was 
created  to  protect  independent  exhibitors.  It  has  done  good  work  but 
has  not  been  able  materially  to  reduce  the  control  of  the  big  producers 
and  chain  theaters  over  motion  picture  distribution. 

The  sale  of  motion  picture  exhibition  rights  to  theaters  is  still  handled 
by  direct  negotiation  and  bargaining.  Producers  can  place  their  pictures 
in  their  own  chain  of  theaters,  but  they  never  produce  enough  pictures 
to  take  up  all  the  time  of  each  theater.  Therefore,  the  managers  of 
the  latter  must  buy  pictures  from  producers  other  than  those  who  may 
own  or  control  the  theater.  Elaborate  arrangements  have  been  made 
to  protect  local  exhibitors  against  competition  by  the  duplicate  local 
showing  of  any  feature  picture  and  to  give  the  exhibitor  a  monopoly  in 
his  locality,  especially  as  regards  the  first  showing  of  a  picture.  Pictures 
have  usually  been  distributed  according  to  what  is  known  as  the  "block 
system,"  which  had  the  advantage  of  allowing  the  exhibitor  to  buy  a 
year's  supply  of  pictures  in  a  few  purchases.  However,  it  often  forced 
an  exhibitor  to  buy  mediocre  pictures  which  had  little  audience  interest 
and  prevented  him  from  buying  others  he  preferred.  Recently,  under 
government  pressure,  the  studios  have  agreed  to  modify  the  block  sales 
system,  limiting  the  number  of  sales  in  a  block  to  five  and  giving  the 
exhibitor  the  privilege  of  viewing  the  pictures  before  buying. 

American  producers  have  sold  movies  extensively  to  Europe  and  other 
foreign  areas.  Between  30  and  40  per  cent  of  the  revenue  of  some  of  the 
largest  producers  was  derived  from  foreign  sales  of  their  products  before 
the  second  World  War  broke  out.  This  often  produces  some  special 
problems  of  censorship.  For  example,  Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer  suppressed 
the  production  of  Sinclair  Lewis's  It  Can't  Happen  Here,  after  it  had 
spent  a  large  sum  of  money  for  movie  rights  and  partial  production. 
It  was  feared  that  it  might  offend  German  Nazis  and  harm  the  German 
market  for  Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer  films.  In  this  way,  Herr  Hitler  and 


43  On  the  business  and  financial  aspects  of  moviedom,  see  Herbert  Harris,  "Snow 
White  and  the  Eight  Giants,"  Common  Sense,  November,  1938,  and  January,  Febru- 
ary, 1939. 

**  Sinclair,  1933. 


510      TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION 

Dr.  Goebbels  were  able  indirectly  to  determine  what  movies  may  be 
shown,  even  in  the  United  States. 

In  the  last  few  years  there  has  been  a  marked  falling  off  in  movie 
attendance.  This  may  have  been  due,  in  part,  to  radio  competition, 
but  the  slump  has  been  laid  mainly  to  inferior  movie  production,  and 
the  stultifying  influence  of  movie  censorship  on  the  best  movie  art.  Such 
is  the  opinion,  for  example,  of  J.  P.  McEvoy,  in  an  article  in  Reader's 
Digest,™  "Fear  over  Hollywood."  He  believes  the  greed  and  ambition 
of  the  movie  producers  started  the  trouble.  They  were  not  satisfied  with 
dominating  the  production  field  but  started  out  to  control  the  theaters 
as  well.  Having  built  many  theaters,  they  had  to  supply  them  with 
pictures,  but  there  was  not  sufficient  talent  available  at  any  price  to  make 
enough  good  pictures.  Hence  the  producers  had  to  make  up  the  deficiency 
by  supplying  inferior  films,  to  the  disgust  of  all  save  the  more  unintelli- 
gent adults,  and  juveniles.  The  proportion  of  inferior  films  was  further 
increased  by  the  introduction  of  double-features: 

Adolph  Zukor  started  the  disastrous  chain  of  events  which  led  to  block  booking, 
B  pictures,  and  double  features  when,  after  cornering  the  star  market,  he  set  out 
to  ouy.  build,  or  control  all  the  theatres.  Naturally,  the  other  companies  started 
to  outouy  or  outbuild  Adolph.  Result:  Paramount  at  its  peak  owned  or  con- 
trolled 1600  theatres;  Fox  1000;  Warners  600;  Loew  and  RKO  200  apiece.  Re- 
sult :  enough  pictures,  good,  bad,  or  indifferent,  had  to  be  made  to  supply  all  these 
theatres.  Result :  The  necessity  of  making  more  than  600  feature-length  pictures 
a  year.  And  there  aren't  that  many  good  actors  and  directors  or  good  stories. 
How  many  good  plays  are  there  a  year?  Half  a  dozen.  Good  novels?  Fifty? 
Generous. 

Saddled  by  a  production  curse  grown  out  of  real  estate  greed,  Hollywood  never 
could  have  enough  of  any  ingredient  to  supply  it,  except  raw  film.  That  comes 
in  by  the  carload,  is  run  through  the  studio  sausage  mills,  flavored  with  syn- 
thetic comedy,  drama,  love  and  hooey,  chopped  into  convenient  lengths,  and 
shipped  to  some  17,000  theatres  for  the  edification  of  some  umpty-million  cus- 
tomers a  week.  .  .  . 

Nobody  in  Hollywood  wants  double  features.  Theatre  owners  unanimously 
oppose  them.  Women's  clubs,  parents,  teachers,  decry  them.  Your  neighbor 
hates  them.  So  do  you. 

Then  who  likes  them?  The  juvenile  public  that  wants  two  lollipops  for  the 
price  of  one.  And  ages  13  to  21  go  to  movies  more  than  once  a  week,  while  the 
people  over  that  age,  who  form  the  bulk  of  the  publication  and  are  best  able  to 
afford  movies,  support  them  the  least.46 

The  solution  of  the  problem,  both  financial  and  artistic,  is  to  produce 
better  pictures,  to  attract  the  adult  population.  Juveniles  will  go  any- 
way. The  improvement  of  pictures  can  be  brought  about,  in  part,  by 
reducing  the  output  and  giving  more  attention  to  fewer  and  better  pic- 
tures. But  we  shall  never  have  as  good  pictures  as  might  be  made  until 
the  curse  of  movie  censorship  is  relaxed: 

The  cure  is  a  drastic  reduction  of  excess  theatres  and  surplus  pictures.  There 
is  plenty  of  first-rate  talent  in  Hollywood  to  make  a  limited  number  of  good 


45  January,  1941. 

46  McEvoy,  loc.  cit.,  pp.  62-63.    Courtesy  of  Reader's  Digest  and  Stage  Magazine. 


TRANSPORTATION   AND   COMMUNICATION      511 

pictures.    There  is  sufficient  extraordinary  talent  to  make  a  few  extra-good 
pictures. 

But  even  this  talent  cannot  function  at  its  best  until  it  is  freed  from  a  censor- 
ship which  puts  a  premium  on  the  innocuous.  Adult  talent  cannot  make  adult 
pictures  under  a  juvenile  code.  There  is  no  more  reason  why  all  pictures  should 
be  made  for  children  than  that  all  books,  all  art  and  music  be  under  censorship 
that  boils  everything  down  to  an  insipid  infantile  mush.  A  free  screen  is  as 
necessary  to  vital  pictures  as  a  free  press  is  to  vital  literature.  To  each  and 
every  minority  pressure  group  hell  bent  on  saving  the  movies  from  sin  and  suc- 
ceeding only  too  well  in  sapping  them  of  substance,  Hollywood  should  cry  out, 
in  the  words  of  the  distressed  maiden,  "Unhand  me,  villain."  47 

For  better  or  for  worse,  the  movies  are  a  social  force  we  cannot  ignore. 
From  the  standpoint  of  communication  and  intellectual  services,  far 
and  away  the  most  important  contribution  of  the  movies  has  been  the 
newsreel,  travel  films,  educational  films  and  the  like.  TKe  newsreels 
in  making  a  showing  of  recent  events  possess  the  intellectual  character 
of  the  current  newspaper  material.  They  display  the  same  tendency  to 
select  the  more  sensational  occurrences,  with  special  stress  upon  military 
events  and  natural  calamities.  Hence  they  are  overweighted  with  mili- 
tarism, patriotism  and  morbidity.  Occasionally,  they  possess  a  consid- 
erable educational  value. 

Too  much  praise  cannot  be  bestowed  upon  some  educational  films. 
One  of  the  most  remarkable  of  these  was  the  film  "The  River,"  directed 
and  produced  by  Pare  Lorentz.48  There  are  excellent  travel  films  which 
filter  into  general  exhibition.  Some  educational  films  are  rather  daring 
in  their  scope  and  import.  Such  was  the  evolution  film  some  years  ago 
which  featured  Clarence  Darrow  and  Professor  H.  M,  Parshlcy.  But 
these  educational  films  have  a  highly  limited  audience.  Strictly  educa- 
tional films1  for  use  in  the  schools  are  becoming  more  numerous  and  better 
in  quality.  They  may  ultimately  revolutionize  visual  instruction. 

So  far  as  entertainment  is  concerned,  one  may  conclude  that,  on  the 
whole,  the  movies,  even  at  their  worst,  have  provided  a  definite  improve- 
ment of  the  entertainment  available  to  the  masses  in  the  pre-movie  era. 
The  better  movies  are  surely  superior  to  the  old-time  vaudeville  shows, 
burlesque  shows,  and  legitimate  stage  productions  which  the  masses  could 
afford  to  attend.  The  great  appeal  of  the  movies  to  the  masses  is  that  it 
provides  an  escape  from  the  drabncss  of  everyday  life.  The  patrons  of 
the  movies  identify  themselves  with  the  principals  in  the  movie,  project 
themselves  into  the  picture,  and  thereby  enjoy  a  vicarious  social  and 
intellectual  adventure.  The  essential  facts  in  this  respect  are  well  stated 
by  a  former  movie  star,  Milton  Sills: 

Just  how  does  this  form  of  amusement  function  as  compensation  to  the  drudg- 
ing millions  ?  By  providing  a  means  of  escape  from  the  intolerable  pressure  and 
incidence  of  reality.  The  motion  picture  enables  the  spectators  to  live  vicariously 
the  more  brilliant,  interesting,  adventurous,  romantic,  successful,  or  comic  lives 


47  Ibid.,  pp.  64-65. 

48  On  this  phase  of  movie  development,  see  Paul  Rotha,  The  Documentary  Film, 
Norton,  1940. 


512      TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION 

of  the  shadow  figures  before  them  on  the  screen.  .  .  .  The  film  offers  them  a 
Freudian  journey  into  made-to-order  reverie,  reverie  by  experts.  Now  reverie 
may  be  unwholesome — our  psychological  studies  are  still  too  immature  to  decide 
this  question — but  in  our  present  form  of  culture  it  seems  to  be  necessary.  In 
any  case,  reverie  engendered  by  motion  pictures  is  certainly  more  wholesome 
than  that  engendered  by  the  corner  saloon  or  the  drab  walls  of  a  tenement  house. 
For  an  hour  or  two  the  spectator  identifies  himself  with  the  hero  or  heroine; 
potential  adventurer  at  heart,  he  becomes  for  the  moment  an  actual  imaginative 
adventurer  in  a  splendid  world  where  things  seem  to  go  right.40 

Because  of  this  widespread  identification  of  the  observer  with  the  ideals 
and  personages  in  the  film,  it  is  important  that  the  mental  excursion 
should  not  be  too  anti-social  in  its  fundamental  import,  especially  in  view 
of  the  fact  that  about  one  fourth  of  the  movie  patrons  are  children.  The 
broad  implications  of  motion  pictures  with  respect  to  social  attitudes 
and  social  values  have  been  summarized  by  Professors  Willey  and  Rice: 

Although  the  motion  picture  is  primarily  an  agency  for  amusement,  it  is  no 
less  important  as  an  influence  in  shaping  attitudes  and  social  values.  The  fact 
that  it  is  enjoyed  as  entertainment  may  even  enhance  its  importance  in  this 
respect.  Any  discussion  of  this  topic  must  start  with  a  realization  that  for  the 
vast  audience  the  pictures  and  "filmland0  have  tremendous  vitality.  Pictures 
and  actors  arc  regarded  with  a  seriousness  that  is  likely  to  escape  the  casual 
observer  who  employs  formal  criteria  of  judgment.  Editors  of  popular  motion 
picture  magazines  are  deluged  with  letters  from  motion  picture  patrons,  un- 
burdening themselves  of  an  infinite  variety  of  feelings  and  attitudes,  deeply  per- 
sonal, which  focus  around  the  lives  and  activities  of  those  inhabiting  the  screen 
world.  One  editor  receives  over  80,000  such  letters  a  year.  These  are  filled 
with  self-revelations  which  indicate,  sometimes  deliberately,  often  unconsciously, 
the  influence  of  the  screen  upon  manners,  dress,  codes  and  matters  of  romance. 
They  disclose  the  degree  to  which  ego  stereotypes  may  be  moulded  by  the  stars 
of  the  screen.  Commercial  interests  appreciate  the  role  of  the  motion  picture  as 
a  fashioner  of  tastes,  and  clothes  patterned  after  the  apparel  of  popular  stars, 
and  for  which  it  is  known  there  will  be  a  demand,  are  manufactured  in  advance 
of  the  release  of  the  pictures  in  which  these  stars  will  appear.  Names  and  por- 
traits of  moving  picture  actors  and  actresses  have  also  been  extensively  used  for 
prestige  purposes  in  the  advertisements '  of  various  commodities. 

While  it  is  the  dramatic  subjects  that  are  of  major  interest  in  the  study  of  the 
motion  picture,  the  news  reel  also  has  won  popular  favor.  With  its  subjects 
selected  from  a  wide  range  of  events  that  might  be  filmed,  it  presumably  plays 
a  part  in  inculcating  values,  althqugh  its  role  has  never  been  adequately  studied. 

It  is  because  of  its  influence  in  shaping  attitudes  and  inculcating  values  and 
standards  that  there  has  been  widespread  discussion  of  motion  picture  censor- 
ship. On  one  hand  are  those  urging  extreme  control,  and  on  the  other  those 
who  seek  unfettered  development.  Because  of  variation  in  local  standards,  it  is 
extremely  difficult  to  establish  a  common  basis  for  film  eliminations  where  censor- 
ship exists.  Not  infrequently  producers  must  cut  pictures  after  production  at 
considerable  expense  to  meet  local  requirements.  In  attempts  to  avoid  this, 
censorship  within  the  industry  has  developed  in  the  National  Board  of  Review. 
The  need  for  thoroughgoing  study  of  the  social  effects  of  the  motion  picture  seems 
clear.50 

The  organization  which  has  interested  itself  most  directly  in  the  intel- 
lectual, social  and  moral  aspects  of  pictures  has  been  the  Motion  Picture 


49  Encyclopedia  of  the  Social  Sciences,  Macmillan,  Vol.  11,  p.  67. 
*°  Recent  Social  Trends,  McGraw-Hill,  Vol.  I,  pp.  209-210. 


TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION      513 

Research  Council.  Beginning  in  1929,  it  was  able  to  make  use  of  the 
resources  of  the  Payne  Fund,  an  endowment  interested  in  the  reaction  of 
motion  pictures,  radio  and  the  like  upon  children.  A  series  of  investiga- 
tions were  made  between  1929  and  1933  by  such  competent  scholars  as 
Mark  A.  May,  Herbert  Blumer,  and  Frederic  M.  Thrasher.  The  results 
of  these  studies  were  summarized  and  digested  by  Herbert  James  Forman 
in  an  important  book,  Our  Movie-made  Children. 

The  facts  uncovered  indicate  clearly  that  motion  pictures  have  assumed 
so  large  a  part  in  the  social  attitudes  and  life  of  the  nation  that  they 
require  social  inspection  and  regulation,  though  probably  of  a  far  different 
sort  from  that  which  now  dominates  motion  picture  censorship.  Professor 
Blumer  discovered  that  American  children  are  now  primarily  movie- 
minded  in  their  mental  imagery.  Contrary  to  popular  impression,  chil- 
dren do  not  forget  what  they  have  seen  on  the  film  as  soon  as  they  leave 
the  picture  theater.  It  has  been  estimated  that  they  carry  away  from 
a  picture  more  than  half  as  many  impressions  as  the  average  adult. 
Thurstone  and  Peterson  found  that  movies  have  a  very  definite  influence 
in  altering  and  fixing  the  mental  attitudes  of  children.  Their  ideas  and 
practices  in  regard  to  life  responsibilities,  love-making,  adventure,  and 
moral  ideals  are  deeply  influenced  by  movie  plots  and  portrayals.  Over- 
exciting  pictures  lead  to  serious  disturbance  of  the  sleep  of  children. 

Blumer  and  Hauser  clearly  revealed  the  fact  that  movies  may  fre- 
quently stimulate  delinquency  and  immorality.  The  glamorous  portrayal 
of  crime,  the  desire  to  get  easy  money  and  have  fine  clothes,  or  the  allure- 
ment of  adventure  and  excitement,  incites  those  who  live  under  drab 
circumstances  to  imitate  the  methods  followed  in  the  movies  to  secure 
wealth,  excitement,  leisure,  and  romance.  This  is  particularly  the  case 
with  girls.  While  the  movies  usually  attempt  to  point  a  moral  and  wind 
up  with  the  conclusion  that  "you  can't  win"  in  crime,  there  are  plenty 
of  characters  in  the  films  who  seem  to  get  away  with  it.  A  typical  ex- 
ample of  the  way  in  which  the  movies  may  promote  anti-social  conduct 
is  revealed  by  the  following  story  of  a  seventeen-year-old  girl  who  was 
held  as  a  sexual  delinquent: 

I  would  love  to  have  nice  clothes  and  plenty  of  money  and  nothing  to  do  but 
have  a  good  time.  When  I  see  movies  of  that  type,  it  makes  me  want  to  get 
out  and  go  somewhere  where  things  happen.  Like  the  picture,  "Gold-diggers  of 
Broadway."  The  girls  were  nothing  but  adventuresses  and  look  what  great  times 
they  had.  I  always  wanted  to  live  with  a  girl  chum.  I  saw  many  pictures 
where  two  or  three  girls  roomed  together.  It  showed  all  the  fun  they  had.  I 
decided  I  would,  too.  I  ran  away  from  home  and  lived  with  my  girl  friend,  but 
she  was  older  than  I  and  had  different  ideas,  and  of  course  she  led  me  and  led 
me  in  the  wrong  way.51 

Of  course,  there  is  another  side  to  the  matter.  If  the  movies  are  able 
to  exert  a  profound  influence  upon  the  mentality  of  children  they  may 
exert  a  good  as  well  as  a  bad  effect.  Certain  pictures  stimulate  the 
ambition  for  study  and  travel,  others  promote  an  intensification  of  family 

51  Forman,  op.  cit.,  Macmillan,  1933,  p.  219. 


514      TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION 

affection;  some  teach  better  manners  and  greater  ease  in  personal  conduct. 
As  to  whether  the  net  social  and  moral  influence  of  the  movies  today  is 
on  the  good  or  bad  side  of  the  ledger,  no  one  can  say  with  any  dogmatism. 
But  certainly  the  facts  justify  the  following  statement  by  Professor  W.  W. 
Charters,  to  the  effect  that  the  movies  exert  a  powerful  influence  on  the 
mentality  of  American  children.  He  contends  that: 

Tho  motion  picture  is  powerful  to  an  unexpected  degree  in  affecting  the  infor- 
mation, attitudes,  emotional  experiences  and  conduct  patterns  of  children;  that 
the  content  of  current  commercial  motion  pictures  constitutes  a  valid  basis  for 
apprehension  about  their  influence  upon  children;  and  that  the  commercial 
movies  present  a  critical  and  complicated  situation  in  which  the  whole-hearted 
and  sincere  cooperation  of  the  producers  with  parents  and  public  is  essential  to 
discover  how  to  use  motion  pictures  to  the  best  advantage  of  children.52 

In  conclusion,  one  may  say  that,  when  compared  to  many  other  forces 
and  factors  in  American  life,  motion  pictures  are  nothing  to  get  highly 
excited  about  as  a  force  for  either  good  or  evil.  They  have  presented  an 
unusually  varied  type  of  entertainment,  at  prices  far  below  anything 
imaginable  in  the  old-time  theater  and  accessible  to  an  infinitely  larger 
group  of  patrons.  While  the  movies  have  undoubtedly  incited  to  crim- 
inality and  delinquency  in  many  cases,  they  have  taken  many  more 
persons  from  streets,  saloons,  gambling  dens  and  dance  halls  and  put  them 
in  the  movie  theaters.  This  has  certainly  been  an  intellectual  and  moral 
advance.  We  can  hardly  expect  the  movies,  as  at  present  constituted  and 
controlled,  to  be  a  force  for  social  progress.  We  can  only  thank  God 
that  an  occasional  mental  jolt  sneaks  by  the  censors.  We  may  look 
forward  to  a  society  in  which  the  mass  experience  of  social  well-being 
will  not  have  to  be  a  vicarious  mental  flight  in  a  movie  theater.  But 
until  this  time  arrives  the  movies  will  undoubtedly  supply  important  relief 
for  the  millions  condemned  to  live  under  drab  circumstances  and  with 
entirely  inadequate  standards  of  living. 

The  Radio  in  Modern   Life 

The  radio  or  wireless  telephony  has  been  a  natural  outgrowth  of  the 
scientific  discoveries  and  electro-magnetic  theories  which  made  possible 
Marconi's  invention  of  the  wireless  telegraph.  De  Forest,  Fessenden, 
Poulsen,  and  Colpitts  made  an  application  of  these  electrical  theories  to 
the  transmission  of  the  human  voice  over  long  distances  without  the 
necessity  of  a  material  conductor.  In  the  form  that  it  assumed,  as  a 
result  of  the  work  of  the  above  scientists  and  engineers,  the  wireless  tele- 
phone has  already  gone  far  toward  revolutionizing  the  methods  of  long- 
distance communication  of  information  through  the  direct  transmission 
of  the  human  voice.  A  revolutionary  development  in  radio  has  come 
about  since  1939,  in  what  is  known  as  "frequency  modulation,"  a  device 


52Forman,  pp.  cit.,  p.  viii.  On  the  other  hand,  Raymond  Moley,  in  his  book, 
Are  We  Movie-Made?  Macy-Masius,  1938,  vigorously  maintains  that  moving  pic- 
tures have  relatively  little  permanent  influence  over  the  minds  of  either  children  or 
adults, 


TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION      515 

invented  by  Edwin  H.  Armstrong  and  others,  which  produces  for  the  first 
time  a  staticless  radio.  There  are  already  some  forty  "FM"  stations, 
eleven  of  them  commercial,  and  this  type  of  broadcasting  and  reception 
will  probably  come  to  dominate  the  radio  industry  in  the  near  future. 

Aside  from  its  commercial  and  recreational  uses,  radio  has  already 
demonstrated  its  social  usefulness  in  such  forms  as  transoceanic  telephone 
messages,  communication  with  remote  and  inaccessible  points,  radios  in 
police  automobiles,  and  radio  control  of  airplane  travel. 

The  relation  of  wireless  telephony  to  the  development  of  the  radio  is 
well  understood  and  generally  taken  for  granted.  But  we  are  less  aware 
of  the  degree  to  which  the  radio,  at  least  radio  broadcasting,  depends 
upon  the  wire  telephone: 

It  is  to  the  telephone,  not  to  radio,  that  we  owe  the  development  of  the  equip- 
ment whereby  speech  and  music  are  made  available  for  broadcasting. 

More  than  this,  it  is  the  telephone  wire,  not  radio,  which  carries  programs  the 
length  and  breadth  of  the  country.  John  Smith,  in  San  Francisco,  listens  on  a 
Sunday  afternoon  to  the  New  York  Philharmonic  orchestra  playing  in  Carnegie 
Hall.  For  3,200  miles  the  telephone  wire  carries  the  program  so  faithfully 
that  scarcely  an  overtone  is  lost;  for  perhaps  15  miles  it  travels  by  radio  to  enter 
John  Smith's  house.  And  then  he  wonders  at  the  marvels  of  radio. 

But  what  about  programs  from  overseas?  Here  indeed  wireless  telephony 
steps  in,  but  not  broadcasting  in  the  ordinary  sense.  The  program  from  London 
is  telephoned  across  the  Atlantic  by  radio,  but  on  frequencies  entirely  outside  of 
the  broadcast  band.53 

When  we  think  of  radio  we  ordinarily  have  in  mind  the  broadcasting 
and  reception  of  programs  of  entertainment  or  education.  We  often 
overlook  a  very  important  phase  of  radio,  namely,  commercial  communi- 
cation by  means  of  radio  telegraphy  and  radio  telephony.  In  this  field 
of  commercial  communication  by  wireless  there  were  in  the  United  States, 
in  1937,  1,154  point-to-point  telegraph  stations,  and  132  point-to-point 
telephone  stations  which  were  licensed  by  the  Federal  Radio  Commission 
to  extend  fixed  public  service,  including  use  by  the  press.  These  were 
operated  by  some  11  different  companies.  Facilities  existed  for  communi- 
cation between  the  United  States  and  53  foreign  countries  by  means  of 
radio  telephone  stations.  Through  wire  line  extensions  these  provided 
contact  with  92  per  cent  of  the  telephones  existing  in  the  world.  As  early 
as  1927, -some  3,777,538  wireless  telegraph  messages  were  transmitted  by 
commercial  companies  in  the  United  States.  The  number  has  increased 
since,  8,042,535  messages  having  been  sent  in  1937. 

The  commercial  use  of  the  wireless  telephone  began  in  the  United  States 
about  1925,  and  the  first  commercial  service  was  opened  between  New 
York  and  London  on  January  7,  1927.  Some  6  million  dollars  worth  ol 
business  was  transacted  during  the  first  day  of  its  operation,  and  there 
were  many  personal  calls  made  as  well.  Our  wire  telephone  facilities  are 
so  extensive  and  efficient  in  this  country  that  there  is  no  particular  need 


53  H,  A.  Bellows,  Technological  Trends  and  National  Policy,  p.  221,  Government 
Printing  Office,  1937. 


516      TRANSPORTATION   AND   COMMUNICATION 

for  any  elaborate  development  of  domestic  wireless  telephony.  Never- 
theless a  considerable  number  of  messages  are  sent  each  day.  In  1937, 
there  were  132  radio  telephone  stations  in  the  United  States  and  147,596 
completed  revenue  calls  were  made  in  that  year  in  the  domestic  and  for- 
eign service  combined.  As  important  as  the  public  use  of  the  radio 
telephone  is  its  employment  in  police  and  aviation  services.  It  is  im- 
portant for  the  former  and  indispensable  for  the  latter.  Wireless  teleph- 
ony is  also  highly  important  for  maintaining  connection  with  moving 
vessels  at  sea  and  in  inland  waters. 

The  major  development  of  the  radio  industry  has  taken  place,  however, 
in  radio  manufacturing  and  distribution  and  in  the  broadcasting  field. 
The  development  of  the  radio  industry  in  the  decade  of  the  'twenties  was 
one  of  the  outstanding  new  industrial  booms  of  that  notable  era/'4  The 
sales  of  radio  sets  and  other  accessory  equipment  rose  from  2  million 
dollars  in  1920  to  the  high  of  $842,548,000  in  1929.  About  630  million 
dollars  was  spent  for  this  purpose  in  1939,  and  it  is  estimated  that  the 
total  expenditures  for  radio  sets  and  equipment  from  1920  to  1940  has 
been  in  excess  of  4%  billion  dollars.  In  1941,  approximately  50  million 
radio  sets  were  owned  in  the  United  States.  The  most  notable  recent 
innovation  in  radio  sales  has  been  radio  sets  for  automobiles.  About 
8  million  automobile  sets  were  in  use  by  1941. 

The  total  investment  in  the  radio  industry  as  a  whole  (exclusive  of 
radio  sets),  including  broadcasting,  was  about  525  million  dollars  in  1941. 
In  1940,  about  255,000  persons  were  regularly  employed  in  the  whole  radio 
industry,  with  an  annual  payroll  of  approximately  360  million  dollars. 
The  radio  statistics  for  1940  indicate  a  substantial  growth  of  the  radio 
manufacturing  industry.  Some  1,064  establishments  were  engaged  in  the 
manufacture  of  radios,  radio  apparatus,  and  phonographs,  employing 
75,000  persons,  with  an  annual  payroll  of  80  million  dollars  and  an  annual 
product  valued,  at  wholesale  prices,  at  around  300  millions.  Some 
11,750,000  radio  sets  were  sold,  at  a  total  retail  value  of  400  millions. 
The  notable  growth  of  the  radio  manufacturing  industry  between  1933 
and  1940  may  be  seen  in  the  fact  that  the  total  retail  value  of  the  product 
in  1933  was  122  million  as  against  400  million  dollars  for  1940.  Radio 
distributors  and  dealers  represented  the  largest  single  element  in  the  radio 
industry.  They  had  an  investment  of  some  350  million  dollars,  a  gross 
revenue  of  600  millions,  150,000  employees,  and  a  payroll  of  225  million 
dollars. 

In  1941,  some  883  commercial  broadcasting  stations  had  a  gross  rev- 
enue of  185  million  dollars  from  the  sale  of  time  and  other  incidental  serv- 
ices. Some  20,000  persons  were  regularly  employed,  and  at  least  25,000 
more  were  employed  on  part  time.  The  total  payroll  was  50  million 
dollars.  In  1941,  there  was  a  total  investment  in  the  broadcasting  indus- 
try of  over  80  millions.  The  income  of  185  million  dollars  was  thus 


54  See,  especially,  J.  M.  Herring  and  G.  C.  Gross,  Telecommunication:  Economics 
and  Regulation,  McGraw-Hill,  1936. 


TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION      517 

over  twice  the  total  investment  in  the  physical  plant  of  the  industry. 
The  net  profits  of  the  National  Broadcasting  Company  were  $5,800,000, 
and  of  the  Columbia  Broadcasting  System,  $7,400,000,  which  in  each  case 
represented  over  75  per  cent  of  their  investments  in  tangible  property. 
The  tables  on  pages  518  and  519  give  a  comprehensive  summary  of  the 
radio  industry,  as  of  1940. 

Since  advertisers  wish  to  present  their  sales  material  to  as  large  an 
audience  as  possible,  only  chains,  with  a  large  number  of  stations  under 
their  control,  can  bring  about  this  desired  result.  Local  stations  can, 
however,  perform  a  useful  service  in  the  matter  of  purely  local  advertising. 
The  value  of  the  radio  to  advertisers  may  be  discerned  from  the  fact  that 
the  National  Broadcasting  Company  has  been  able  to  charge  as  high  as 
$15,000  an  hour  for  the  use  of  its  system. 

Even  more  than  is  true  of  the  movies,  the  ownership  and  control  of  the 
radio  industry  of  the  United  States  are  concentrated  in  a  few  large  com- 
panies, of  which  the  Radio  Corporation  of  America  is  far  and  away  the 
most  important.  The  Radio  Corporation  (RCA)  is  really  a  subsidiary  of 
the  General  Electric  Company.  The  latter  organized  RCA  as  a  Delaware 
corporation  in  1919  to  get  an  outlet  for  its  basic  radio  patent,  the  Alex- 
anderson  alternator.  In  1920-21  an  arrangement  was  entered  into  be- 
tween RCA,  General  Electric,  Western  Electric,  Westing-house,  and 
A.T.&T.,  permitting  all  of  them  to  use  the  basic  patents  owned  by  each. 
Behind  all  of  these  electric  and  radio  companies  stand  the  great  New  York 
banks,  especially  the  Rockefeller  Chase  National  Bank  and  the  Morgan 
interests.  The  Radio  Corporation  controls  many  of  the  basic  patents 
connected  with  both  the  manufacture  of  radio  sets  and  radio  broadcast- 
ing apparatus.  It  has  an  extensive  industry  in  the  way  of  manufacturing 
radio  sets,  and  also  dominates  the  broadcasting  field  through  its  owner- 
ship of  the  National  Broadcasting  Company.  It  has  an  important  hold 
on  theaters  and  amusement  enterprises  through  its  control  of  the  Radio- 
Keith-Orpheum  Corporation.  The  chief  figures  connected  with  the  early 
business  organization  of  the  American  radio  industry  and  RCA  were 
Owen  D.  Young  and  David  Sarnoff.  The  latter  is  to  radio  what  T.  N. 
Vail  was  to  the  business,  organization  of  American  telephony  and  teleg- 
raphy. 

Inasmuch  as  the  initial  period  of  radio  development  fell  in  the  decade 
of  the  'twenties,  RCA  was  caught  up  in  the  grip  of  the  speculative  finance 
capitalism  of  that  era,  and  there  was  particularly  wild  speculation  in  the 
common  stock  of  RCA  in  1928-29.  Few  other  important  stocks  ex- 
perienced such  a  tremendous  shift  of  paper  values  before  and  after  the 
crash  of  1929.  There  are  many  small  companies  engaged  in  the  manu- 
facture of  radio  sets,  but  they  are  in  part  dependent  upon  RCA's  control 
of  the  patents  governing  the  manufacture  of  many  radio  essentials. 

The  concentration  of  control  in  broadcasting  manifests  an  extreme 
hardly  matched  in  any  other  American  industry.  American  broadcast- 
ing is  dominated  by  the  National  Broadcasting  Company,  a  subsidiary 
of  RCA,  by  the  Columbia  Broadcasting  System,  and  by  the  more  re- 


O 

5 
< 


u. 

O 

HI 

N 


X 


CK 

<: 


CM 

</> 


8 


«/> 

=> 

00 


o 

to 


<* 

s 
19 

Ul  c 


*0 


«     § 


Q 

ft: 


^      8888 

•       ^  r-«  <N  r*  i^» 


I 


ii§ 


<fSi! 


«2  zzz 


I 

c 
o 


:-s  w  *» 

0  tf  :55jfa  j. 
"     *c   •  o  -O-T:  w  **- 

-°     S   '•'o'aa^  3 

X       «     '  £   W   3   O  '5 

-°       ^     '^^  ^^  a 

eficc88#2  -« 

1  o^§»5q 5  a>  3 
«-  u  « -5  cTo  Q..E  => 

JJI^li!  5 

^t2S     PS«2^  3 


518 


nrocoro>o< 

N  CXI  -Or-  CO  C 


'<*-CKOrox5O4'^i'O'OO4 
- 00 •«•  CO -^r  r- CN r-  in r-  r- 

r-          W  " 


Tr-"     O'in'o" 
-- 


II 


S8j 

w. ~ 

3CN  O400C 

hSSSc,- 

h      r-CO^T-C 


ill 


in  en  CN  m  rCX 


iltl 


>> 

rt 

Q 


:3 
i  3 


UooS/>  §  w.y.sS'g  I^-TB^ 

zQlJ^l^fe^ 


—  Om 


88888J 


?  CH  «M  in  CM  CN  OMn  un      •<• 
5  T- r-»  r*.  co  o  r- 04  ^f     O^ 


CN  O  O  O  in 


O 
o- 


T 

oc 
-  ro  c 


=; 
ss 

=! 


•~li 


O  O  O  *»  Jg^  t.        -"m-vx-s 

111 81  Si i||  jlJl 

*ososo"o^'o  S'-w-l  j  3  -2  I 


h-K 


^  Sl^  ^S-eSs^^S  tm 
isili^ScS^cmrz 


519 


520      TRANSPORTATION   AND   COMMUNICATION 

cently  created  Mutual  Broadcasting  System.  These  three  giants  are 
at  least  loosely  affiliated  through  underlying  banking  control  and  certain 
common  amusement  interests.  The  NBC  System  controls  some  223 
stations,  and  the  Columbia  System  has  control  of  about  123.  Mutual 
controls  168  stations  but  they  are  not  usually  as  important  as  the  NBC 
and  Columbia  stations.  The  dominance  of  these  three  in  the  broadcast- 
ing world  is  brought  about  by  their  control  over  the  best  air  channels 
which  may  be  used  for  broadcasting  programs  even  more  than  as  a  result 
of  the  large  number  of  stations  they  dominate.  As  we  shall  see,  the  new 
regulations  of  the  Federal  Communications  Commission  in  the  spring 
of  1941  sought  to  undermine  the  grip  of  NBC  and  CBS  on  the  radio 
broadcasting  situation.  How  well  the  FCC  will  succeed  in  this  aim  re- 
mains to  be  seen. 

Now  there  is  a  great  advantage  in  this  concentration  of  radio  power 
and  efficiency.  It  certainly  insures  better  programs.  But  this  should 
not  be  gained  at  the  expense  of  the  freedom  of  opinion.  Thus  far,  there 
is  no  adequate  guaranty  that  the  latter  can  be  secured  and  will  be  pro- 
tected. The  independents  are  pitifully  impotent  and  inconsequential. 
The  matter  rests  in  the  hands  of  the  NBC  and  the  other  chains.  Essen- 
tially, it  comes  down  to  NBC  and  Columbia  policy.  There  is  only  one 
independent  station  in  the  country  frankly  devoted  to  the  presentation  of 
the  point  of  view  of  labor  and  radicalism,  namely,  Station  WEVD,  made 
possible  by  a  gift  from  the  American  Fund  for  Public  Service. 

As  radio  grew  in  popularity,  chaos  was  threatened  through  crossing 
and  confusion  of  programs.  There  was  no  adequate  regulation  of  the 
hours,  power,  and  frequencies  used  by  broadcasting  stations.  In  Febru- 
ary, 1927,  President  Coolidge  signed  the  Radio  Act,  which  created  the 
Federal  Radio  Commission.  This  consisted  of  five  members,  appointed 
for  a  term  of  six  years  by  the  President.  It  was  given  power  to  regulate 
the  use  of  air  channels,  to  assign  wave-lengths,  to  control  the  increase  of 
radio  facilities  and  the  establishment  of  new  stations,  to  license  all 
broadcasting  stations,  and  to  have  charge  of  engineering  regulations 
related  to  transmission.  It  was  given  little  or  no  direct  control  over  the 
programs  which  are  broadcast.  In  1934,  the  Communications  Act  was 
parsed,  which  supplanted  the  Federal  Radio  Commission  by  the  Federal 
Communications  Commission  (FCC),  with  practically  the  same  powers 
as  those  possessed  by  its  predecessor. 

The  broadcasting  stations  are  classified  according  to  the  type  of  service 
they  render,  whether  local,  regional,  or  national.  The  appropriate 
amounts  of  power  are  assigned  to  the  various  stations,  according  to  their 
class,  and  they  are  authorized  to  operate  on  frequencies  compatible  with 
th^  type  of  service  and  the  licensed  power  of  each  station.  On  March  29, 
1941,  the  government  assigned  new  frequencies  to  795  out  of  the  883 
standard  broadcasting  stations  of  the  country. 

Perhaps  the  least  defensible  phase  of  the  FCC  policy  has  been  its 
reluctance  to  grant  reasonably  long  licenses  to  the  broadcasting  stations. 
Although  the  1927  law  permitted  the  granting  of  licenses  for  a  period  of 


TRANSPORTATION    AND  COMMUNICATION      521 

five  years  and  the  law  of  1934  for  three  years,  not  until  1939  were  licenses 
granted  for  more  than  a  six-month  period.  Since  1939  they  haye  been 
extended  to  one  year.  This  is  manifestly  unfair,  since  stations  must 
often  make  contracts  running  over  several  years,  especially  in  making 
payment  for  expensive  equipment.  So  long  as  this  policy  continues, 
broadcasting  must  remain  a  gamble  rather  than  a*  sound  investment. 
Licenses  have  rarely  been  revoked  or  reasonable  requests  for  new  licenses 
refused,  but  the  possibility  of  such  action  always  exists. 

When  James  Lawrence  Fly  became  chairman  of  the  FCC  in  1939 
the  Commission  evidently  determined  to  lessen  the  alleged  monopolistic 
domination  of  radio  broadcasting  by  the  National  Broadcasting  Company 
and  the  Columbia  Broadcasting  System.  One  evidence  of  this  was  the 
greater  liberality  in  granting  licenses  to  new  stations.  In  the  previous 
17  years,  only  750  stations  had  been  licensed.  Since  1939  about  130 
new  stations  have  been  licensed.  Far  more  drastic  was  the  adoption  of 
eight  new  regulations  by  the  FCC  in  the  spring  of  1941,  which  directly 
aimed  at  curtailing  the  control  of  NBC  and  CBS  over  the  broadcasting 
industry.  Especially  important  were  the  regulations  making  it  illegal 
for  one  company  to  own  two  national  networks,  those  seeking  to  prevent 
special  favoritism  to  stations  affiliated  with  great  networks,  and  that 
which  outlawed  collusion  in  rate-fixing  between  an  individual  station  and 
a  network.  Specifically,  the  FCC  announced  that  it  would  not,  after  a 
period  of  90  days,  license  any  station  that: 

(1)  Has  any  contract,  arrangement  or  understanding,  express  or  implied,  with 
a  network  organization  under  which  the  station  is  prevented  or  hindered  from,  or 
penalized  for,  broadcasting  the  programs  of  any  other  network  organization. 

(2)  Has  ,any  arrangement  preventing  or  hindering  another  station  in  the  same 
area  from  broadcasting  the  network's  programs  not  taken  by  the  former  station. 

(3)  Has  had  a  network  contract  of  affiliation  for  a  period  of  more  than  one 
year. 

(4)  Has  a  network  contract  requiring  it  to  give  up  programs  already  scheduled 
in  order  to  air  a  network  show. 

(5)  Has  a  network  contract  restraining  its  right  to  reject  programs. 

(6)  Is  owned  by  or  controlled  by  a  network  serving  substantially  the  same 
area. 

(7)  Is  affiliated  with  a  network  organization  which  maintains  more  than  one 
network. 

(8)  Has  a  contract  which  prevents,  hinders  or  penalizes  it  from  fixing  or  alter- 
ing its  rates  for  the  sale  of  broadcast  time  for  other  than  the  network's  programs. 

These  new  restrictions  provoked  a  storm  and  bitter  controversy.  The 
new  regulations  were  violently  assailed  by  NBC  and  CBS  and  were 
warmly  defended  by  the  Mutual  Broadcasting  Company,  which  stood  to 
gain  by  cutting  down  the  "monopoly"  of  NBC  and  CBS.55 

The  fact  that  Mutual  vigorously  upholds  the  new  regulations  seems 
to  indicate  that  they  do  not  threaten  radio.  What  they  may  threaten 
are  the  special  services  which  NBC  and  CBS  have  given  without  sponsors 


55  See  "What  the  New  Radio  Rules  Mean,"  Columbia  Broadcasting  System,  May 
17,  1941;  and  "Mutual's  White  Paper,"  Mutual  Broadcasting  System,  June,  1941. 


522      TRANSPORTATION   AND   COMMUNICATION 

with  some  of  the  large  profits  which  their  near  monopoly  of  the  air  has 
enabled  them  to  earn.  These  include  much  of  the  important  musical  and 
educational  material  on  the  air.  All  that  the  impartial  observer  can 
do  is  to  wait  and  note  the  results  of  the  new  regulations  in  operation  over 
a  period  of  some  years.  The  same  legalistic  legerdemain  which  has  nulli- 
fied most  other  government  efforts  to  undermine  monopoly  may  be 
brought  into  play  to  preserve  the  control  of  the  great  networks  over 
radio.  The  crisis  and  test  in  these  new  regulations  were  modified  or  post- 
poned by  amendments  adopted  by  the  FCC  on  October  11,  1941.  The 
main  features  of  these  amendments  were  the  following: 

1.  The  original  regulations  completely  prohibited  network  option-time.    The 
amendments  make  liberal  provision  for  option-time  up  to  a  total  of  12  hours 
daily  (3  hours  in  each  of  4  "segments"  into  which  the  day  is  divided),  subject  only 
to  common-sense  restrictions  designed  to  prevent  the  stifling  of  competition. 

2.  The  original  regulations  fixed  the  maximum  period  for  network-affiliate 
contrasts  at  one  year,  with  an  advance  period  for  negotiation  of  only  60  days. 
The  amendments  increase  these  periods  to  2  years  and  to  120  days  respectively. 
At  the  same  time,  the  license  period  for  standard  broadcast  stations  is  increased 
from  one  year  to  2  years. 

3.  The  original  regulations  prohibited  operation  of  more  than  one  competing 
network  by  one  network  company.    The  amendments  indefinitely  postpone  the 
effective  date  of  this  prohibition,  but  do  not  eliminate  it. 

4.  With  respect  to  existing  contracts,  arrangements  or  understandings,  or  net- 
work organization  station  licenses,  the  amendments  postpone  the  effective  date 
to  November  15,  1941.56 

The  big  broadcasting  chains  appealed  to  the  courts,  and  at  the  present 
writing  the  fate  of  the  new  FCC  regulations  has  not  been  decided. 

Far  more  ominous  than  such  federal  regulation  is  the  trend  towards 
government  censorship  of  radio  programs.  We  shall  consider  the  problem 
of  radio  censorship  more  thoroughly  later  on  in  this  book,  but  a  word  may 
profitably  be  said  on  the  subject  at  this  time.  The  short-period  licensing 
procedure  very  definitely  holds  an  axe  over  the  head  of  the  stations,  and 
the  FCC  has  not  been  loath  to  remind  stations  of  this  fact,  sometimes  for 
trivial  causes.  The  most  notorious  instance  was  when  the  FCC  threat- 
ened to  revoke,  or  to  fail  to  renew,  the  licenses  of  NBC  and  affiliated 
stations  because  of  the  innocuous  Mae  West-Charley  McCarthy  broad- 
cast in  December,  1937.  Early  in  1941,  Station  WAAB  in  Boston  was 
compelled  to  agree  to  conform  to  government  policy  and  ideas  before  its 
license  would  be  renewed.  After  the  summer  of  1940,  the  government 
made  it  increasingly  evident  that  it  frowned  on  broadcasts  supporting 
non-intervention  in  the  European  war.  Thoroughgoing  censorship  of 
broadcasting  was  imposed  a  few  days  after  Pearl  Harbor,  a  censorship 
which  extended  even  to  the  broadcasting  of  weather  reports. 

The  size  of  the  radio  audience  has  been  estimated  by  experts  as  run- 
ning somewhere  between  40  and  70  million  persons  daily.  Willey  and 
Rice  estimate  that  more  than  8  out  of  every  10  sets  owned  in  the  United 


5*Mutual's  Second  White  Paper,  Mutual  Broadcasting  System,  October  20,  1941, 
p.  2. 


TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION      523 

States  are  used  at  some  time  during  each  day,  about  half  of  the  total 
sets  being  in  use  when  the  most  popular  programs  are  on  the  air.  By  far 
the  greatest  use  of  radio  sets  comes  between  8  p.m.  and  10  p.m.  In  1938, 
the  National  Association  of  Broadcasters  estimated  that  approximately 
27  million  families  in  the  United  States  owned  about  37  million  radio 
receiving  sets;  that  approximately  75  per  cent  of  these  are  turned  on  at 
some  time  each  day;  and  that  each  set  operates  on  an  average  5.1  hours 
daily.  The  popularity  of  radio  programs  can  be  measured  to  some  degree 
by  fan  mail,  about  20  million  letters  being  received  annually  from  radio 
listeners.  NBC  received  4,703,321  letters  in  1937.  One  single  address 
on  a  religious  subject  over  the  Columbia  Network  brought  in  no  less  than 
438,000  letters.  An  interesting  sidelight  upon  the  mental  level  of  fan 
mail  is  to  be  seen  in  the  fact  that  the  astrologer,  Evangeline  Adams, 
received  more  fan  mail  in  a  single  week  than  President  Hoover  did  in  the 
week  after  his  election  to  the  Presidency  in  1928.  Telephone  calls  to 
stations  are  also  an  indication  of  public  response  to  programs. 

The  social  and  intellectual  significance  of  the  radio  can  hardly  be  over- 
estimated. Even  as  early  as  1931,  W.  F.  Ogburn  was  able  to  list  no  less 
than  150  different  effects  of  radio  upon  American  society.57  It  has 
brought  an  enormous  extension  of  public  education,  mass  entertainment, 
propaganda,  and  misinformation.  The  events  and  thoughts  of  the  world 
are  made  available  to  nearly  every  household  in  the  land.  But  the  ma- 
terial is  pretty  well  filtered  through  a  prolonged  process  of  selection,  so 
that  the  product  actually  presented  tends  to  be  of  a  traditional  character 
and  to  uphold  the  present  order.  In  Russia,  the  radio  is  equally  devoted 
to  propaganda  in  behalf  of  revolution,  collectivism,  and  the  totalitarian 
state.  A  conservative  and  capitalistic  radio  station  in  Russia  is  even 
more  rare  than  a  radical  station  in  the  United  States. 

The  influence  of  radio  news  commentators  in  shaping  public  opinion 
is  constantly  increasing,  especially  since  the  Munich  Conference  and  the 
outbreak  of  the  European  war  in  1939.  The  broadcasters  are  rapidly 
usurping  the  position  once  held  by  powerful  editorial  writers  in  the  edi- 
torial stage  of  American  journalism.  Broadcasters  like  H.  V.  Kaltenborn, 
Raymond  Gram  Swing,  Elmer  Davis,  and  Upton  Close  exert  an  influence 
on  public  opinion  comparable  to  that  once  exerted  by  Horace  Greeley 
and  Charles  Dana.  They  are  supposed  merely  to  give  the  news,  but,  as 
their  very  title  of  "commentator"  implies,  they  not  only  comment  on  the 
news  but  edit  it  as  severely  as  any  editor  in  the  days  of  pre-commercial 
journalism.  This  makes  it  difficult  to  get  unbiased  news  reporting  over 
the  radio.  Some  broadcasters  make  few  comments  on  the  news,  but 
this  is  not  true  of  the  leading  figures  on  the  air  today.  And  the  radio 
audience  selects  its  favorite  commentator,  as  the  reading  public  used  to 
select  its  editor  and  newspaper — because  it  likes  a  particular  bias  or  slant 
on  public  affairs.  If  unpopular  or  minority  attitudes  had  anything  like 
an  equal  chance  to  be  heard  over  the  air,  radio  would  be  of  vast  impor- 


57  Recent  Social  Trends,  Vol.  I,  pp.  153-156. 


524      TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION 

tance  in  the  preservation  of  democratic  society.  But  the  radio  authorities 
are  even  more  sensitive  to  popular  opinion  and  governmental  suggestions 
than  are  newspaper  publishers.68 

After  the  European  war  broke  out  in  1939,  increasing  use  was  made  of 
radio  by  governments  in  waging  a  propaganda  war.  In  addition  to 
warring  against  each  other  over  the  air,  both  sides  strove  ardently  to 
influence  American  opinion.59 

Nothing  in  American  life  is  more  varied  than  the  programs  presented  by 
radio  broadcasting  companies.  The  offering  is  even  more  diversified  than 
that  which  comes  to  us  through  the  movies  and  the  newspapers.  But 
through  most  of  it  there  runs  one  common  ideal  and  requirement,  namely, 
that  there  must  be  mass  appeal.  This  means  rather  general  banality. 
This  sentiment  was  expressed  by  a  president  of  the  National  Broadcasting 
Company  when  he  said  that  "in  broadcasting  we  are  dealing  with  a  mass 
message,  and  the  material  delivered  must  be  suitable  for  mass  consump- 
tion." The  same  considerations  dominate  here  that  operate  in  connection 
with  the  attempt  of  newspapers  to  get  a  large  circulation. 

The  radio  broadcasting  industry  depends  for  its  income  almost  entirely 
upon  advertising,  which  brings  in  nearly  $200,000,000  yearly.  And 
advertisers  naturally  want  to  present  their  sales  talk  to  as  large  an  audi- 
ence as  possible.  For  this  reason,  the  broadcasting  companies  have  a  par- 
ticularly acute  regard  for  material  which  will  appeal  to  a  large  audience. 
They  are  not  especially  concerned  with  the  intellectual  or  esthetic 
quality  of  the  entertainment,  provided  it  is  surely  safe  and  popular.  Only 
on  a  sustaining  program,  namely,  one  presented  by  the  station  without 
any  compensation,  can  we  normally  expect  any  program  of  a  specially 
high-grade  quality — one  which  overlooks  to  some  slight  degree  the  tastes 
of  the  mass  of  listeners.  Sustaining  and  advertising  programs  divide 
about  equally  the  total  radio  time  on  the  majority  of  stations,  but  adver- 
tising programs,  especially  serials,  dominate  during  the  daytime.  Of  the 
advertising  programs,  about  one  fifth  of  the  time  is  devoted  to  sales  talk 
and  four-fifths  to  some  kind  of  entertainment. 

Taking  the  broadcasting  material  as  a  whole,  it  runs  the  whole  gamut 
from  the  sublime  to  the  ridiculous  to  a  degree  which,  perhaps,  exceeds  the 
variation  in  the  movies.  At  one  extreme,  we  have  the  Town  Meeting 
of  the  Air  and  comparable  educational  broadcasts  of  a  very  high  order. 
At  the  other,  we  run  into  the  abysmal  depths  of  "soap  opera,"  and  the  ex- 
traordinarily banal  and  unreal  dramatic  serials  presented  during  the  day 
for  the  diversion  of  bored  and  frustrated  housewives.  These  serials  now 
take  up  84.9  per  cent  of  all  commercially  sponsored  time.  Their  charac- 
ter has  been  well  described  by  Whitfield  Cook,  in  an  article  on  "Be  Sure 
to  Listen  In,"  in  The  American  Mercury,  March,  1940;  and  by  Thomas 


68  For  a  critical  and  an  official  appraisal  of  radio  broadcasts  and  public  opinion, 
see  Arthur  Garfield  Hays,  "Civic  Discussion  over  the  Air/*  in  Annals  of  the  American 
Academy,  January,  1941,  pp.  37-46;  and  William  S.  Paley,  "Broadcasting  and  Ameri- 
can Society,"  Ibid.,  pp.  62-38. 

59  See  Harold  N.  Graves,  Jr.,  "War  on  the  Short  Wave,"  Foreign  Policy  Associa- 
tion, May,  1941. 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      525 

Wood,  in  an  article  on  "My  Morning  with  Radio,"  in  Scribner's  Com- 
mentator, January,  1941.  Mr.  Cook  summarizes  his  impressions,  which 
would  probably  be  shared  by  most  literate  listeners,  as  follows: 

Now  I  know  all.  I  have  heard  the  worst.  For  I  have  listened  for  ten  con- 
consecutive  daylight  hours  to  life's  sorrows  according  to  the  gospel  of  Bi-So-Dol, 
Pillsbury,  Camay,  and  Kix.  And  let  me  tell  you,  it  almost  got  me  down.  .  .  . 

I  investigated  and  discovered  that  there  are  no  less  than  sixty-live  five-day-a- 
woek  serials  on  daytime  programs  of  the  four  major  stations  in  the  New  York 
area.  Then  I  knew  I'd  have  to  listen  to  those  sixty  serials.  They  use  up  eighty- 
two  and  a  half  hours  per  week — almost  a  third  of  the  total  number  of  daytime 
hours  of  WEAF,  WOR,  WJZ,  and  WABC.  During  an  average  week,  only  about 
eighteen  day-time  hours  are  devoted  to  serious  music,  for  instance,  and  perhaps 
twenty-five  hours  to  news.  .  .  . 

The  heroines  continued  to  be  simple,  upright  and  ready  to  give  advice  at  the 
drop  of  a  hat.  And  Life  continued  to  hand  them  raw  deals.  They  were  always 
brave,  of  course.  I  began  to  long  for  just  one  little  miss  who  might  suspect 
that  rain  was  rain  and  not  violets.  And  why  was  there  so  little  humor  in  these 
sentimental  capsules?  Whenever  any  light  comedy  was  attempted  to  relieve  the 
gloom,  it  sounded  like  second-rate  Noel  Coward  rewritten  by  Kathleen  Norris. 
Always  life  was  real  and  life  was  earnest.  About  as  real  and  earnest  as  it  used 
to  be  iri  dime  novels.  .  .  . 

Will  the  listener  ever  recover  from  this  terrific  strain?  Can  he  go  on  with 
his  life  after  this  terrible  revelation?  Will  he  ever  be  the  same  again?  Is  the 
great  big  radio  audience  happy?  Is  Bab-0  happy?  And  Ivory?  and  Crisco, 
Super  Suds,  and  Kix?  And  what  do  the  children  learn  from  it  all?  And  the 
ghost  of  Marconi? 

Be  sure  to  listen  in  each  week  day.    And  see  your  psychiatrist  twice  a  year!  60 

The  problems  of  life  are  combed  over  by  broadcasters,  running  all  the 
way  from  professional  psychoanalysts  to  the  "Voice  of  Experience."  In 
music,  we  find  everything  from  a  concert  of  the  New  York  Philharmonic 
Orchestra,  or  a  performance  of  the  Metropolitan  Opera  Company,  to 
recorded  offerings  of  the  cheapest  jazz  and  swing  music.  Astrologers 
vend  their  antique  superstitions  along  with  international  broadcasts  on 
modern  astrophysics  by  Sir  James  Jeans.  Millions  are  brought  within 
earshot  of  championship  prizefights,  world  series  baseball  games,  star 
football  contests,  the  Kentucky  Derby,  and  the  like.  Nothing  like  the 
radio  has  ever  happened  before  to  jar  mankind  out  of  isolation  and  to  end 
the  inability  of  the  poor  man  to  participate  personally  in  direct  enjoyment 
of  the  more  thrilling  events  in  the  world  of  sport  and  entertainment. 
As  Kenneth  G.  Bartlett  puts  it: 

The  obvious  thing  is  that  radio  is  the  greatest  user  of  entertainment  material 
since  the  world  began.  Every  program  is  a  part  of  the  passing  parade.  It  has 
changed  the  environment  in  which  we  live,  and  because  it  is  so  complex  it  seems 
to  add  to  the  total  confusion.  It  seems  to  call  for  minds  that  can  sort  fact  from 
fiction,  values  from  passing  fancies.  It  requires  a  strong  "discount  factor"  and  a 
better  knowledge  of  the  medium  so  that  the  listener  may  the  more  accurately 
appraise  radio's  contribution  to  twentieth-century  living.61 


60  Cook,  loc.  cit.,  pp.  314-315,  . 

61 K.  G.  Bartlett,  "Trends  in  Radio  Programs,"  Annals  of  the  American  Academy, 
January,  1941,  p.  25.  For  a  survey  of  current  radio  entertainment,  see  ibid.,  pp.  2&~ 
30.  f 


526      TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION 

While  by  all  odds  the  greater  portion  of  radio  broadcasting  time  is 
consumed  with  matters  of  "entertainment/7  the  educational  opportunities 
are  truly  remarkable  for  those  who  are  really  interested  and  make  a 
careful  study  of  the  offerings.02  It  is  doubtless  true  that  a  discerning 
and  discriminating  use  of  the  radio  in  any  large  city  in  any  given  week 
would  provide  far  more  educational  material  than  any  student  would  be 
likely  to  obtain  from  the  same  period  of  attending  university  lectures. 
Special  attention  is  given  to  science,  health  talks,  travel,  and  literature. 
Several  excellent  forums  exist  for  the  discussion  of  scientific  problems 
and  the  "great  books"  as  well  as  current  literature.  Not  much  of  value 
in  the  social  sciences  is  presented,  for  this  field  is  too  "controversial," 
and  radio  seeks  to  avoid  the  controversial,  or  at  least  the  progressive  side 
of  controversial  topics. 

Of  the  various  social  and  intellectual  influences  exerted  by  the  radio, 
Willey  and  Rice  have  selected  for  special  emphasis  the  tendency  toward 
cultural  leveling  and  the  breaking  down  of  caste  and  isolation: 

Certain  it  is  that  the  radio  tends  to  promote  cultural  levelling.  Negroes  barred 
from  entering  universities  can  receive  instruction  from  the  same  institutions  by 
radio;  residents  outside  of  the  large  cities  who  never  have  seen  the  inside  of  an 
opera  house  can  become  familiar  with  the  works  of  the  masters;  communities 
where  no  hall  exists  large  enough  for  a  symphony  concert  can  listen  to  the  largest 
orchestras  of  the  country ;  and  the  fortunes  of  a  Negro  comedy  pair  can  provide 
social  talk  throughout  the  nation.  Isolation  of  backward  regions  is  lessened 
by  the  new  agency  of  communication,  and  moreover,  by  short  wave  transmission 
national  as  well  as  local  isolation  is  broken,  for  events  in  foreign  nations  are 
thereby  brought  to  the  United  States.  The  radio,  like  the  newspaper,  has 
widened  the  horizons  of  the  individual,  but  more  vitally,  since  it  makes  him  an 
auditory  participant  in  distant  events  as  they  transpire  and  communicates 
to  him  some  of  the  emotional  values  that  inhere  in  them.63 

It  took  the  newspapers  many  years  to  develop  a  relatively  high  stand- 
ard of  advertising  ethics,  to  be  able  somewhat  to  curtail  their  desire  for 
profits  in  the  interest  of  public  welfare,  and  to  demand  an  approximation 
to  truth  on  the  part  of  advertisers.  Radio  is  new  in  the  advertising  busi- 
ness, and  has  not  yet  had  time  to  develop,  or  at  least  to  apply,  comparable 
standards.  Further,  it  cannot  be  controlled  by  the  necessity  of  conform- 
ing to  post  office  regulations  and  the  strict  limitations  with  respect  to  the 
use  of  the  mails  for  fraudulent  advertising. 

The  formal  ideals  of  the  big  chains  are  high  enough.  For  example, 
NBC  has  announced  that  "false  or  questionable  statements  and  all  other 
forms  of  misrepresentation  must  be  eliminated."  But,  in  practice,  these 
ideals  are  often  conveniently  forgotten.  An  impressive  exhibit  of 
fraudulent  advertising  over  the  radio  today  has  been  prepared  by  Peter 
Morell  in  his  book  Poisons,  Potions  and  Profits** 

Flagrant  frauds  are  frequently  presented  in  the  most  sanctimonious 


62  See  M.  H.  Neumeyer,  "Radio  and  Social  Research,"  in  Sociology  and  Social 
Research,  November-December,  1940,  pp.  114-124. 
•8  Recent  Social  Trends,  McGraw-Hill,  Vol.  I,  p.  215. 
«*  Knight,  1937. 


TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION      527 

manner.  On  one  program  overheard  by  the  writer,  the  announcer  was 
presenting  the  virtues  of  a  once  popular  horse  remedy,  being  recommended 
over  the  radio  for  human  use  under  a  trade  name,  at  many  times  the 
price  of  the  product  under  its  natural  name.  This  was  followed  by  a 
feeling  rendition  of  the  old  hymn,  "My  Faith  looks  up  to  Thee,  Thou 
Lamb  of  Calvary."  Some  of  the  most  legitimate  and  effective  advertising 
in  the  world  today  is  presented  over  the  radio,  but  it  is  unquestionably 
true  that  frauds  and  fakes  can  be  ballyhooed  over  the  air  with  a  freedom 
and  facility  denied  to  them  in  any  other  legitimate  advertising  medium 
except  the  movies.  There  is,  however,  evidence  that  the  ethical  level  of 
radio  advertising  has  improved  in  the  last  few  years. 

We  have  already  referred  briefly  to  the  radio  newspaper,  an  innovation 
which  has  only  recently  been  made  practicable.  This  has  been  called 
"potentially  the  most  socially  significant  invention  since  the  development 
of  the  printing  press."  This  so-called  radio  newspaper  is  a  facsimile  re- 
ceiving set,  about  the  size  of  a  table  radio.  By  attaching  it  to  an  ordinary 
radio  one  can  provide  himself  with  a  sort  of  electric  printing  press  which 
is  able  to  pick  news  and  pictures  out  of  the  air  and  put  them  down  in 
black  and  white.  It  prints  without  ink  and  without  type  under  a  com- 
plicated form  of  electrical  operation.  One  of  these  attachments  can 
print  a  three-  or  five-column  paper.  Unbelievably  economical,  it  can  be 
produced  to  sell  at  a  profit  for  40  dollars  or  less.  The  potential  signifi- 
cance of  this  device  has  been  summarized  by  Miss  Ruth  Brindze: 

The  technical  problems  are  far  simpler  than  the  social  and  economic  ones,  for 
if  the  development  of  facsimile  broadcasting  continues,  as  there  is  every  reason 
to  believe  that  it  will,  city  folks  as  well  as  those  who  live  on  the  farms  can  be 
supplied  with  newspapers  and  other  reading  material  by  radio.  The  Radio  Cor- 
poration's facsimile  receiver  is  already  equipped  with  a  blade  for  cutting  the 
printed  rolls  of  paper  into  convenient  page  sizes.  With  the  addition  of  a  simple 
binding  device,  books  and  magazines  may  be  produced  by  the  little  radio  printing 
machine.  The  possibilities  are  unlimited.  As  events  take  place,  as  history  is 
made,  the  facsimile  machines  will  produce  directly  in  the  home  a  contemporaneous 
printed  record.  No  newspapers  will  be  able  to  compete.  Facsimile  will  be 
faster,  more  convenient,  cheaper.  At  the  trivial  cost  of  the  rolls  of  paper  and 
the  electric  current,  the  audience  will  be  supplied  with  more  printed  matter  than 
it  can  read.  Every  day's  paper  may  be  as  bulky  as  the  Sunday  Times;  magazines 
and  books  will  achieve  a  circulation  of  a  hundred  million.65 

Television   Emerges 

Another  striking  invention  connected  with  the  radio  which  is  no  longer 
"just  around  the  corner"  is  television.66  Most  of  the  scientific  and 
engineering  problems  connected  with  it  have  already  been  solved,  though 
there  are  some  difficulties  remaining  to  be  overcome  before  television  can 
be  made  technically  perfect.  As  Mr.  Craven  points  out,  the  problems 
lying  ahead  are  chiefly  economic  and  social.  It  is  a  question  of  whether 
there  will  be  an  adequate  market  for  television  instruments  and  whether 


65  "Next—the  Radio  Newspaper,"  the  Nation,  February  5,  1938,  pp.  154-155.    See 
also  J.  F.  L.  Hogan,  "Facsimile  and  Its  Future  Uses,"  The  Annals,  January,  1941, 
pp.  162-169. 

66  On  the  current  status  of  television,  see  The  Annals,  January,  1941,  pp.  130-152. 


528      TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION 

there  will  be  a  large  public  willing  to  remain  at  home  and  use  television 
apparatus  instead  of  going  to  moving  picture  houses  and  watching  the 
newsreels,  which  may  then  be  almost  as  simultaneous  in  the  reproduction 
of  events  as  television: 

The  next  corner  to  be  turned,  however,  is  an  economic  rather  than  an  engineer- 
ing one,  and  it  can  be  stated  briefly  in  one  short  question  "Who  is  to  pay  for 
television?"  Will  the  public  accept  a  television  service  based  upon  a  continuance 
of  the  present  system  of  commercial  aural  broadcasting  and  its  extension  into 
television?  Will  a  "looker-in"  be  willing  to  sit  in  a  darkened  living-room  at  home 
intently  peering  into  the  screen  of  his  television  receiver?  67 

The  General  Electric  Company  made  a  prediction  as  to  the  growth  of 
television  in  the  next  few  years,  as  follows:  68 

Year  Sets  Sold  Average  Price 

1940 199,000                                               $250 

1941 414,000                                                 200 

1942 846,000                                                   160 

1943 1,371,000                                                150 

1944 1,903,000                                                   150 

By  1945,  there  would  be  about  4,700,000  home  receiving  sets,  valued  at 
about  750  million  dollars,  served  by  512  transmitting  stations,  costing 
54  millions. 

In  an  article  on  "Where  Does  Television  Belong?"  in  Harper's,  Febru- 
ary, 1940,  a  radio  engineer,  Irving  Fiske,  is  sceptical  about  the  realization 
of  this  program  of  television  expansion.  He  doubts  that  television  can 
ever  be  made  as  popular  in  the  home  as  the  radio.  He  holds  that  tele- 
vision requires  a  degree  of  constant  attention  that  only  group  participa- 
tion in  a  common  experience  can  produce.  Hence  he  sees  the  main  future 
of  television  in  theatres,  where  it  may  replace  the  current  news-reels. 
As  Mr.  Fiske  summarizes  the  matter: 

The  only  place  in  which  television  can  adequately  meet  the  basic  human  needs 
is  the  theatre;  and  abroad,  at  least,  theatre  television  has  come  forward  in  re- 
sponse. Overemphasis  on  home  television  seems  so  far  to  have  paralyzed  efforts 
in  that  direction  here.69 

The  failure  of  a  home  demand  for  television  to  keep  pace  with  technical 
facilities  in  this  field  seems  to  give  some  confirmation  to  Mr.  Fiske's  ideas. 
If  television  should  be  confined  mainly  to  the  theatre,  it  would  mean  that, 
while  a  large  public  might  be  served,  the  number  of  sets  that  could  be  sold 
would  be  relatively  few,  as  compared  with  the  radio  sets  used  by  the  vast 
army  of  radio  listeners. 

Perhaps  the  most  searching  discussion  of  the  present  status  and  future 
possibilities  of  television  is  an  anonymous  but  authoritative  contribution 
on  "What's  Happened  to  Television?"  in  the  Saturday  Review  of  Liter  a- 


67  Technological  Trends  and  National  Policy,  Government  Printing  Office,  1937, 
p.  233. 

68  Harpers,  February,  1940,  p.  265. 

69  Fiske,  loc.  cit.,  p.  268. 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      529 

ture.™  Pointing  out  that  television  has  overcome  most  of  its  technical 
problems,  the  author  considers  the  chief  factors  which  are  retarding  the 
rapid  advance  of  television.  He  does  not  share  Mr.  Fiske's  view  that  its 
future  lies  mainly  in  theatres,  but  holds  that  it  has  great  possibilities  of 
popular  adoption  under  proper  encouragement.  While  not  hostile  in 
principle  to  television,  the  Federal  Communications  Commission  has 
placed  a  fatal  barrier  in  the  way  of  its  progress  by  banning  television 
networks.  Without  networks,  the  cost  of  excellent  television  programs 
will  prove  prohibitive.  They  can  only  be  made  practicable  by  serving 
many  communities  at  once  and  thus  cutting  the  costs.  The  moving 
pictures  refuse  to  cooperate  with  television  for  fear  of  the  competition 
which  may  be  offered  by  a  full-blown  television  industry.  The  news- 
papers show  the  same  hostility  to  television  that  they  do  to  radio.  They 
give  little  publicity  to  television  and  what  they  do  give  is  usually  adverse 
and  discouraging  to  potential  television  users.  Even  the  radio  industry, 
which  is  responsible  for  television,  has  of  late  refused  to  promote  it  vigor- 
ously or  intelligently  for  fear  that  it  may  be  ruinous  to  the  heavy  invest- 
ment in  conventional  radio  equipment  and  activities: 

While  television  is  a  penned-up  dragon  to  the  movies  and  the  press,  and  a 
Pandora's  box  to  the  government,  it  is  strictly  a  hot  potato  to  the  radio  indus- 
try  

That's  what  happened  to  television  after  its  brief  flurry  a  year  ago.  The  pow- 
erful interests  in  the  press,  the  movies,  and  the  radio  put  it  as  far  back  on  the 
shelf  as  they  could  because  they  saw  in  it  a  threat  to  their  status  quo.  They 
shelved  it  because  the  public  was  beginning  to  get  interested  in  it,  and  they  knew 
that  whatever  the  American  public  interests  itself  in,  it  usually  gets.71 

Despite,  these  obstacles,  television  has  not  been  suppressed.  Gilbert 
Seldes  thus  describes  the  impressive  number  and  variety  of  programs  put 
on  by  the  Television  department  of  the  Columbia  Broadcasting  System  in 
the  two  months  after  December  7,  1941: 

240  programs  of  fully  visualized  news. 
38  programs  of  special  war  features;   including  programs  devoted  to  the 

armed  forces,  production  and  civilian  morale. 
33  programs  by  the  Red  Cross  devoted  to  first  aid  instruction. 
24  programs  by  the  Metropolitan  Museum  of  Art. 

24  programs  of  sports,  including  tournaments  staged  in  the  television  studio. 
12  programs  of  country  dances. 
12  round  table  discussions — generally  by  authorities  in  their  respective  fields 

— on  subjects  foremost  in  the  American  mind. 
12  programs  devoted  to  dancing  instruction. 
12  visual  quizzes. 
12  variety  shows. 

In  addition,  a  number  of  special  programs  were  put  on,  along  with  an 
hour  program  every  week  devoted  to  experimental  work  with  color  tele- 


70  February  21,  1942.    The  anonymous  author  is  actually  a  leading  expert  in  the 
field  of  television. 

71  Loc.  cit.,  p.  17. 


530      TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION 

vision  broadcasts.72  The  above  data  will  give  some  indication  of  the 
current  achievements  and  activities  of  television  and  will  afford  some 
reassurance  that  this  important  innovation  in  communication  will  not  be 
indefinitely  delayed  in  making  its  potential  contribution  to  American 
enlightenment  and  entertainment. 

The  future  possibilities  of  television,  provided  it  comes  into  general 
use,  have  been  well  described  by  Karl  A.  Bickel: 

The  twist  of  a  dial  and  the  throw  of  a  switch  will  enable  you,  in  your  sitting 
room,  to  see  and  hear  the  Kentucky  Derby,  to  have  a  better  vision  of  a  great 
prizefight  or  athletic  contest  than  even  the  box-holders,  to  range  the  world, 
attending  the  theater  or  opera,  visiting  important  banquets,  sitting  in  with 
Congress  in  Washington,  or  viewing  an  airplane  meet  in  Africa.73 

Because  of  its  close  connection  with  radio,  we  might  say  a  word  here 
about  the  current  status  of  the  phonograph,  which  represents  an  im- 
portant, if  highly  specialized,  type  of  communication.  The  sale  of  phono- 
graph records  reached  its  peak  in  1921,  at  100  million.  With  the  growth 
of  radio  in  the  '20's,  record  sales  fell  off  sharply  and  the  industry  was  all 
but  given  up  for  dead.  But  in  the  '30's  there  was  a  marked  pick-up.  In 
1938,  some  35  million  records  were  sold  and  all  manufacturers  were  far 
behind  their  orders.  Sales  have  gained  since. 

There  were  a  number  of  reasons  for  this  revival  of  the  phonograph, 
particularly  the  provision  of  the  combination  radio  and  phonograph  and 
the  record-playing  radio  attachment,  the  interest  in  swing  and  classical 
music,  essentially  created  by  the  radio,  and  the  rebellion  against  radio 
commercials  and  serials.  The  phonograph  enables  us  to  get  immediately 
and  directly  the  music  we  wish,  without  having  to  listen  to  other  features 
which  we  regard  with  either  indifference  or  repugnance.  Much  of  the 
phonograph  and  record  business  of  the  country  is  controlled  by  the  Radio 
Corporation  of  America. 

Communications  and  the  Social   Future 

The  enormous  influence  exerted  by  the  new  instruments  of  communi- 
cation upon  human  life  and  social  institutions  in  the  immediate  past  is 
obyious  to  all  careful  observers.  Their  future  effects  may  be  even  more 
far-reaching,  because  many  of  these  instruments  of  communication 
have  only  been  recently  developed,  and  others  of  an  even  more  impres- 
sive and  upsetting  character  may  be  provided  within  the  present,  or 
coming  generation: 

It  is  impossible  to  discuss  here  the  ramifications  of  the  most  obvious  changes 
in  American  life  summarized  by  the  preceding  data.  On  the  one  hand  is  a  process 
of  integration  and  adjustment ;  on  the  other  is  a  lively  competition  accompanied 
by  mutual  fears:  railroad  fighting  bus;  bus  fighting  street  car;  newspapers  con- 
cerned over  radio  advertising;  moving  picture  competing  with  radio;  hotel 
fighting  with  tourist  camp.  The  ultimate  outcome  cannot  be  predicted;  one  can 

72  Saturday  Review  of  Literature,  March  14,  1942,  p.  13. 

73  Bickel,  New  Empires,  Lippincott,  1930,  p.  43;  see  also,  David  Sarnoff,  "Possible 
Social  Effects  of  Television,"  The  Annals,  January,  1941,  pp.  145-152. 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  COMMUNICATION      531 

only  be  impressed  with  the  changes  that  go  on  before  the  eyes  and  marvel  at  the 
way  in  which  American  life,  and  the  habits  of  the  individual  citizens,  are  being 
transformed.74 

The  social  and  cultural  impact  of  our  new  agencies  of  communication 
has  been  powerful  and  pervasive.  The  speed,  scope  and  diversity  of 
human  contacts  have  been  multiplied  on  a  scale  never  before  imagined. 
Devices  of  untold  potency  for  mass  impression  have  come  into  being. 
Social  groups  and  entire  nations  may  be  manipulated  by  propaganda  as 
never  before.  The  great  danger  in  these  remarkable  transformations  lies 
in  the  fact  that  they  have  been  brought  into  being  in  planless  fashion, 
purely  as  a  product  of  the  competitive  system  and  motivated  almost  solely 
by  the  desire  for  pecuniary  profits.  There  has  been  little  opportunity  to 
guide  their  development  in  such  a  fashion  as  to  make  a  maximum  con- 
tribution to  the  well-being  of  human  society.  They  may  confer  upon 
us  untold  benefits  or  may  lead  to  domestic  confusion  and  international 
chaos: 

It  is  as  agencies  of  control  that  the  newspaper,  the  motion  picture  and  the 
radio  raise  problems  of  social  importance.  The  brief  survey  of  their  development 
in  each  instance  shows  increased  utilization  coupled  with  concentration  of  facili- 
ties. For  his  news,  the  reader  of  the  paper  is  dependent  largely  upon  the  great 
news  gathering  agencies;  for  his  motion  pictures,  there  is  dependency  upon  a 
group  of  well  organized  producers;  for  his  radio,  he  comes  more  and  more  in 
contact  with  large  and  powerful  stations,  dominated  increasingly  by  the  nation- 
wide broadcasting  organizations.  Mass  impression  on  so  vast  a  scale  has  never 
before  been  possible. 

The  effects  produced  may  now  be  quite  unpremeditated,  although  the  machin- 
ery opens  the  way  for  mass  impression  in  keeping  with  special  ends,  private  or 
public.  The  individual,  the  figures  show,  increasingly  utilizes  these  media  and 
they  inevitably  modify  his  attitudes  and  behavior.  What  these  modifications 
are  to  be  depends  entirely  upon  those  who  control  the  agencies.  Greater  possi- 
bilities for  social  manipulation,  for  ends  that  are  selfish  or  socially  desirable,  have 
never  existed.  The  major  problem  is  to  protect  the  interests  and  welfare  of  the 
individual  citizen.  .  .  . 

In  short,  an  interconnecting,  interconnected  web  of  communication  lines  has 
been  woven  about  the  individual.  It  has  transformed  his  behavior  and  his  atti- 
tudes no  less  than  it  has  transformed  social  organization  itself.  The  web  has 
developed  largely  without  plan  or  aim.  The  integration  has  been  in  consequence 
of  competitive  forces,  not  social  desirability.  In  this  competition  the  destruction 
of  old  and  established  agencies  is  threatened.75 

As  to  the  immediate  future  of  communication  agencies  Mr.  Craven 
believes  that  their  most  desirable  services  would  be  the  penetration  of 
hitherto  inaccessible  regions,  and  the  use  of  existing  communication 
agencies  to  improve  international  goodwill: 

It  is  believed  that  the  greatest  service  which  communications  can  do  in  the 
future  will  be  to  provide  extensions  into  the  hitherto  remote  and  inaccessible 
places  whereby  people  who  formerly  had  no  means  of  communication  can  be 
connected  with  the  communication  arteries  of  the  world.  Tremendous  progress 


74  M.  M.  Wilky  and  S.  A.  Rice,  "Communication,"  The  American  Journal  of 
Sociology,  University  of  Chicago  Press,  May,  1931,  p.  977. 

™  M.  M,  Willey  and  S.  A.  Rice,  Recent  Social  Trends,  McGraw-Hill,  pp.  215-217. 


532      TRANSPORTATION   AND  COMMUNICATION 

has  been  made  during  the  last  decade  in  this  direction  and,  undoubtedly,  tremen- 
dous progress  will  take  place  in  the  future. 

The  other  great  forward  step  in  world  civilization  which  can  be  made  is  in 
the  effective  use  of  communications,  both  telegraph  and  telephone  by  wire,  but 
more  especially  by  radio,  in  the  development  of  understanding,  mutual  respect 
and  tolerance  among  the  nations  of  the  world.  Much  has  been  done  along  these 
lines  in  the  past  and  a  great  deal  more  is  expected  in  the  future.76 

This  is  certainly  a  high  and  noble  ideal,  but  as  O.  W.  Riegel  has  pointed 
out  in  his  important  book,  Mobilizing  for  Chaos ,  there  is  grave  danger 
that  the  new  agencies  of  communication  may  be  utilized  in  the  interest 
of  super-patriotism  and  militarism,  with  the  wrecking  of  civilization  at 
the  end  of  the  line.77  At  least,  they  are  likely  to  do  so  unless  we  take 
prompt  steps  to  safeguard  ourselves  against  this  disaster. 


76  Technological  Trends  and  National  Policy,  p.  233. 

77  See  below,  pp.  557  ff.,  583-585. 


CHAPTER  XIV 

Molding  Public  Opinion:  Prejudice/  Propaganda, 
and  Censorship 

The  Role  of  Prejudice  in  Modern  Life 

Causes  of  Prejudice.  In  this  chapter  we  shall  consider  various  prac- 
tices and  attitudes  concerned  with  the  control  of  both  individual  and 
public  opinion.  In  order  to  gain  proper  perspective  and  understanding 
of  such  efforts,  it  is  necessary  to  comprehend  the  origins  and  character  of 
the  prejudices  and  biases  that  operate  upon  the  human  mind. 

The  word  prejudice  is  derived  from  the  Latin  word  praejudicium, 
meaning  a  judicial  examination  before  trial.  In  literal  English,  prejudice 
means  a  decision  arrived  at  without  examination  of  the  facts.  It  is  an 
automatic  or  spontaneous  bias,  which  may  be  either  favorable  or  un- 
favorable. We  may  be  prejudiced  in  favor  of  something  or  against  it. 
Most  commonly,  however,  we  think  of  a  prejudice  as  an  unfavorable  bias 
or  antipathy  toward  something.  In  its  most  elementary  sense,  this 
prejudice  or  spontaneous  bias  may  be  purely  physical,  in  the  sense  that 
the  human  organism  favors  something  warm  and  comfortable  as  against 
something  cold  and  rough.  But,  in  a  cultural  or  institutional  sense,  a 
prejudice  is  always  a  psycho-physical  reaction,  a  conditioned  response, 
shaped  by  our  life  experiences.  Whatever  the  prejudice,  whether  favor- 
able or  unfavorable  and  regardless  of  the  type  of  prejudice,  it  is  always 
an  emotional  response.  As  soon  as  reason  enters  the  picture,  the  potency 
of  the  prejudice  is  diminished.  Most  prejudices,  however,  are  so  highly 
charged  with  emotion  that  they  automatically  exclude  reason  from  the 
premises. 

Perhaps  the  underlying  cause  of  prejudice  is  the  automatic  antipathy 
to  ideas  and  experiences  markedly  different  from  those  with  which  we  are 
familiar.  Franklin  Henry  Giddings  contended  that  the  chief  force  hold- 
ing men  together  in  society  is  "the  consciousness  of  kind."  People  natu- 
rally react  cordially  to  the  familiar,  and  are  spontaneously  hostile  to  the 
strange  and  different.  As  David  S.  Muzzey  has  put  the  matter: 

Our  own  views  seem  to  us  right,  or  they  would  not  be  our  views.  How 
readily  we  warm  to  a  person  who  agrees  with  us  in  a  judgment  or  an  argument, 
even  though  his  opinion  be  far  less  entitled  to  respect  than  that  of  our  opponent. 
We  hanker  for  confirmation,  because  of  the  subtle  flattery  it  brings  to  our  self- 
esteem.  Hobbes'  characterization  of  mankind  as  a  "race  of  unmitigated  ego- 
maniacs" may  be  a  bit  too  severe,  but  it  is  nevertheless  true  that  one  of  the  most 

533 


534    PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

difficult  things  in  the  world  is  to  wean  a  mind  from  the  precarious  self-assurance 
on  which  it  has  been  fed  by  centuries  of  custom  and  conformity.1 

It  has  been  necessary  for  man  to  demand  a  high  degree  of  uniformity  in 
social  behavior.2  Man  is  relatively  helpless  by  himself.  Group  life  has 
always  been  essential  to  human  safety  and  progress.  For  this  reason, 
group  discipline  must  be  enforced,  in  order  to  unify  the  community  and 
make  it  more  safe  and  efficient.  Rules  of  conduct  and  thought  must  be 
prescribed  and  the  violators  thereof  made  to  suffer.  This  group  disci- 
pline, so  essential  to  human  survival,  has  exacted  a  high  price  in  the  way 
of  ruthlessly  stamping  out  the  innovator  and  the  rebel.  The  history  of 
civilization  is,  in  a  sense,  a  record  of  the  extension  of  the  variety  and  area 
of  dissent  that  society  will  tolerate: 

After  all,  intolerance  is  merely  the  manifestation  of  the  protective  instinct  of 
the  herd.  The  life  of  the  individuals  is  so  dependent  upon  the  life  of  the  group, 
that  the  group,  and  the  various  individuals  in  the  group,  are  afraid  to  let  any 
individual  say  or  do  anything  that  might  endanger  the  protective  power  of  the 
group. 

Thus  a  pack  of  wolves  is  intolerant  of  the  wolf  that  is  different  and  invariably 
gets  rid  of  this  offending  individual.  A  tribe  of  cannibals  is  intolerant  of  the 
individual  who  threatens  to  provoke  the  wrath  of  the  gods  and  bring  disaster 
ujxm  the  whole  community,  and  so  drives  him  into  the  wilderness.  The  Greek 
commonwealth  cannot  afford  to  harbor  within  its  sacred  walls  one  who  dares  to 
question  the  very  basis  of  its  organization,  and  so  in  an  outburst  of  intolerance 
condemns  the  offender  to  drink  the  poison.  The  Roman  cannot  hope  to  survive 
if  a  small  group  of  zealots  play  fast  and  loose  with  laws  held  indispensable  since 
the  days  of  Romulus,  and  so  is  driven  into  deeds  of  intolerance.  The  Church 
depended  in  early  days  for  her  continued  existence  upon  the  absolute  obedience 
of  even  the  humblest  of  her  subjects  and  is  driven  to  such  extremes  of  suppres- 
sion and  cruelty  that  many  prefer  the  ruthlessness  of  the  Turk  to  the  charity 
of  the  Christian.  And  in  a  period  of  hysterical  fear,  even  we  Americans  are 
assured  that  our  government  cannot  withstand  criticism,  and  so  we  throw  into 
prison  or  deport  from  our  shores  those  who  dare  offer  it. 

And  so  it  goes  throughout  the  ages  until  life,  which  might  be  a  glorious  adven- 
ture, is  turned  into  a  horrible  experience,  and  all  this  happens  because  human 
existence  so  far  has  been  entirely  dominated  by  fear.8 

Custom  and  habit  have  also  played  their  part  in  prejudicing  us  in  favor 
of  th6  familiar.  The  habitual  and  the  traditional  are  not  only  safe,  they 
are  also  easy.  Our  muscular  reflexes  and  our  mental  patterns  are  adapted 
to  doing  things  in  the  way  we  have  been  taught  to  do  them.  It  is  easiest 
to  think  and  act  in  the  old  grooves  to  which  we  have  been  accustomed 
since  childhood.  Habit,  as  William  James  pointed  out,  is  the  great  fly- 
wheel of  society.  We  need  give  little  attention  to  habitual  modes  of 
thought  and  behavior.  Years  of  adjustment  have  made  us  largely  un- 
conscious of  their  operation.  New  ways  and  thoughts,  on  the  other  hand, 
are  troublesome  and  painful.  This  pain  is  not  only  psychological,  it  is 


1  David  S.  Muzzey,  Essays  in  Intellectual  History,  Dedicated  to  James  Harvey 
Robinson,  Harper,  1929,  pp.  7-8. 

2  See  above,  pp.  16  ff.,  29  ff. 

8  J.  H.  Dietrich,  The  Road  to  Tolerance,  privately  published,  Minneapolis,  1929. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP    535 

also  mildly  physiological,  as  the  new  science  of  endocrinology  has  made 
clear.  When  something  strange  challenges  our  customary  way  of  doing 
things,  we  automatically  become  angry.  And  anger  is  accompanied  by 
definite  physiological  changes  in  the  body.  The  adrenal  glands  secrete 
their  mysterious  chemical  substance  into  the  blood.  The  liver  releases 
more  sugar  which  is  burned  up  rapidly  and  gives  us  a  temporary  increase 
of  energy.  Any  innovation  upsets  our  whole  established  scheme  of 
things,  cuts  across  our  habitual  reactions,  and  forces  readjustments  that 
our  timid  and  lazy  nature  resents  and  resists.  New  ways  and  ideas  are 
also  a  challenge  to  our  self-esteem.  They  imply  a  questioning  of  our 
fundamental  ideas  and  of  the  correctness  of  our  beliefs.  They  threaten 
our  life  philosophy. 

Man's  attitude  toward  the  supernatural  world  has  been  an  important 
source  of  prejudice.  It  has  been  believed  that  the  spirit  world  brings 
man  both  his  good  luck  and  his  bad.  If  the  gods  of  the  group  are  properly 
obeyed  and  propitiated,  good  luck  will  follow.  Strange  gods  are  the 
natural  enemy  of  any  given  social  group.  Strangers  worship  strange 
gods,  and  to  tolerate  them  would  both  enrage  the  gods  of  the  group  and 
expose  its  members  to  the  possible  evil  action  of  the  gods  of  the  stranger. 
Down  to  modern  times  the  stranger  has  always  been  viewed  as  a  potential 
enemy.4  This  was  due,  in  part,  to  his  worship  of  strange  gods  and,  in 
part,  to  the  fact  that  his  behavior  and  ideas  differed  from  those  of  the 
group. 

Geography  has  also  played  its  part  in  both  creating  and  mitigating 
prejudice.  The  greater  the  social  and  cultural  contacts  of  any  group, 
the  more  it  is  inclined  to  be  tolerant.  Geographical  conditions  help  along 
the  growth  and  persistence  of  prejudice.  People  shut  off  from  outside 
contacts  tend  to  build  an  ingrowing  culture.  Almost  everything  in  the 
world  outside  is  strange  to  them,  and  they  react  with  characteristic 
antipathy  to  the  new  and  the  strange.  It  is  natural  that  the  most  preju- 
diced and  intolerant  of  peoples  have  been  those  who  live  in  mountainous 
and  other  isolated  areas,  while  the  most  tolerant  populations  have  lived 
along  seacoasts  and  other  natural  routes  of  trade,  thus  coining  into  con- 
tact with  new  ideas  and  customs  as  well  as  new  commodities. 

Divisions  into  social  and  economic  classes  beget  prejudice.  The  no- 
bility has  looked  down  upon  the  trader  and  the  toiler,  while  the  latter 
types  have  naturally  resented  the  exploitation  practiced  by  the  nobility. 
In  our  day,  industrialists  have  exhibited  widespread  prejudices  against 
the  industrial  proletariat.  They  have  associated  the  latter  with  servility. 
The  whole  psychology  of  the  leisure  class  has  been  built  up  around  the 
desire  to  abstain  from  all  manual  labor  for  this  is  contaminated  with 
the  stigma  of  servility.  On  its  side,  the  proletariat  has  built  up  a  philoso- 
phy of  hostility  to  its  industrial  masters,  even  going  so  far  as  to  create  the 
doctrine  of  inevitable  and  eternal  class  war  between  capital  and  labor. 


/.  Mary  Wood,  The  Stranger,  Columbia  University  Press,  1934. 


536    PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

Definite  prejudices  are  also  based  upon  social  rank  and  grades.  Dwellers 
in  our  palatial  city  apartments  and  penthouses  look  down  on  those  who 
inhabit  the  slums.  The  latter  resent  the  wealth  and  display  of  the  rich. 

Differences  in  race  and  culture  have  always  been  a  source  of  prejudice, 
from  the  days  of  the  distinction  between  Jew  and  Gentile  and  Greek  and 
Barbarian.  This  has  been  due,  in  part,  merely  to  the  simple  recognition 
of  physical  differences.  But  race  prejudices  rest  upon  many  other  ele- 
ments. Variations  in  religion,  customs,  and  beliefs,  all  of  which  are 
thought  to  undermine  the  culture  and  stability  of  the  group,  are  held  to 
be  carried  by  strange  races.  Neighboring  races  have  also  very  frequently 
been  political  and  military  enemies,  thus  giving  a  realistic  basis  for  race 
prejudice. 

Social  taste  and  etiquette  contribute  their  quota  to  prejudice.  What 
is  accepted  among  the  elite  is  regarded  as  right.  Different  ways  of  doing 
things  and  conducting  oneself  are  an  affront  to  taste.  They  also  upset 
the  social  regimen  and  tend  to  create  confusion  and  trouble.  There  may 
be  no  substantial  scientific  foundation  for  standards  of  etiquette.  There 
seems  to  be  no  valid  logical  reason  why  a  man  should  remove  his  hat  in 
the  presence  of  women  in  an  elevator  in  an  apartment  house  and  keep  it 
on  while  in  an  elevator  in  a  department  store.  But  society  sets  its 
standards  and  is  outraged  when  they  are  challenged.  The  manners  and 
etiquette  of  a  person  from  a  different  culture  may  actually  be  far  more 
polished,  but  the  standards  of  taste  are  those  of  the  group. 

Closely  associated  with  taste  and  etiquette  as  a  source  of  prejudice  is 
self-esteem.  One  of  the  things  which  makes  life  agreeable  to  us  is  our 
personal  conviction  that  we  are  doing  the  right  things  in  the  right  way. 
Any  differences  of  belief  and  conduct  are  a  challenge  to  our  philosophy  of 
life  and  our  standards  of  behavior. 

Education  should  be  a  leading  instrument  for  combating  prejudice,  by 
revealing  the  spontaneous  and  primitive  character  of  group  behavior  and 
prejudice.  It  should  make  us  more  tolerant  of  differences.  Unfortu- 
nately, however,  most  education  down  to  our  time  has  intensified  prejudice 
instead  of  dissipating  it.  Education  has  been  devoted  primarily  to  the 
perpetuation  of  the  ideas  and  prejudices  of  any  given  group.  It  has 
supplemented  the  spontaneous  element  in  the  acquisition  of  prejudice. 
Many  pseudo-scientific  doctrines  and  religious  dogmas  have  been  em- 
bodied in  the  educational  tradition  and  are  thus  given  prestige  and  in- 
creased influence  in  conserving  and  passing  on  prejudices.  The  tendency 
in  education  to  glorify  the  culture  of  the  group  and  represent  it  as  superior 
to  that  of  others  has  been  an  important  factor  in  the  increased  prominence 
of  nationalism,  the  modern  and  inflated  version  of  primitive  group  preju- 
dice. 

A  conspicuous  fact  about  the  origin  of  our  prejudices  is  that  we  pick 
them  up  automatically  and  unconsciously  in  the  process  of  our  psycho- 
logical development.  They  become  a  part  of  our  mental  equipment. 
Most  of  them  are  acquired  in  childhood  before  the  individual  possesses 
any  substantial  body  of  accurate  knowledge  that  might  enable  him  to 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP    537 

recognize  and  discount  them.     This  fact  has  been  very  clearly  pointed  out 
by  Robert  L.  Duffus: 

Children  acquire  beliefs  like  this  exactly  as  they  acquire  their  language,  their 
games,  and  their  gang  traditions.  They  learn  from  their  parents^  their  school 
teachers,  their  companions,  and,  as  they  grow  older,  from  motion  pictures,  news- 
papers, magazines,  and  books.  Being  human,  they  learn  what  isn't  so  just  as 
thoroughly  as  what  is  so  and  believe  it  just  as  firmly. 

The^most  primitive  form  of  race  prejudice  is  fear — the  savage's  hostility  to  a 
member  of  a  tribe  not  his  own,  the  child's  dread  of  a  stranger  who  differs  in 
some  marked  way  from  its  own  father  or  mother.  But  even  this  doesn't  seem 
to  be  inborn.  It  is  put  into  the  child's  nature  by  some  outside  influence,  or 
influences,  after  the  child  comes  into  the  world.  Let  a  parent  manifest  race 
prejudice  by  a  word  or  even  a  gesture,  or  a  facial  expression,  and  the  child  will 
imitate.  Race  prejudice  may  begin  before  the  boy  or  girl  has  learned  to  talk. 

When  the  child  is  five  or  six  years  old  the  fear  may  turn  into  hostility — a  race 
riot  in  miniature.  There  will  be  a  stage  when  foreigners  are  merely  absurd  and 
amusing.  Finally,  among  children  of  different  races  attending  the  higher  grades 
of  the  same  school  there  will  be  jealousy  arising  out  of  the  competition  for  marks 
and  honors.  By  this  time  the  child  of  the  "superior"  breed  has  learned  that  the 
child  of  the  "inferior"  should  be  kept  in  his  place.  Groups  form,  sharp  social 
lines  are  drawn,  and  the  chasm  between  black  and  white,  white  and  yellow,  or 
"American"  and  "Wop"  is  likely  to  become  permanent.  Even  though  in  a  fit 
of  deliberate  liberalism  we  try  to  bridge  it  in  later  life,  we  frequently  cannot. 

Most  of  us  don't  try.  We  merely  rationalize.  The  middle-aged  business  man 
who  swallows  the  Nordic  gospel  hook,  line,  and  sinker  today,  may  believe  that 
he  got  his  reasons  from  Lothrop  Stodclard,  or  that  his  shrinking  from  contact 
with  the  lesser  breeds  is  the  will  of  God.  But  the  chances  are  that  he  learned 
it  all  at  school,  along  with  his  arithmetic  and  geography,  or  at  home,  along  with 
his  table  manners. 

Girls,  being  earlier  responsive  to  group  traditions  and  loyalties,  are  found  to 
become  race  conscious  sooner  than  their  brothers.  As  they  grow  older  the  social 
pressure  arising  from  a  dread  of  inter-marriage  becomes  stronger.  They  begin 
to  fear,  not  without  reason,  that  broadmindedness  in  their  relations  with  the 
"inferior"  races  may  cause  them  to  lose  caste.  A  boy's  caste,  somehow,  seems  less 
fragile. .  Yet  boys  of  sixteen  are  commonly  found  to  be  more  snobbish  than  boys 
of  twelve.  There  has  been  more  time  and  more  experiences  with  which  to  build 
prejudice — to  educate  in  jealousy  and  dislike. 

All  this  affords  a  hint  as  to  how  our  opinions  get  into  us.  They  are  not  made 
what  they  are  by  heredity.  They  are  not  produced  by  accurately  digested  facts. 
They  are  all  that  our  lives  are— colorful,  unreasonable,  egoistic.5 

Types  of  Prejudice.  The  prejudices  associated  with  nationalism  are 
the  most  prevalent  and  dangerous  prejudices  of  our  era.6  They  provide 
the  main  psychological  impulse  to  war  and  thus  place  civilization  in  seri- 
ous jeopardy.  Nationalism  gained  rather  than  declined  after  the 
first  World  War.  Fascism,  in  fact,  elevated  nationalism  to  the  status  of 
a  religion.  Intense  nationalism  makes  it  quite  impossible  to  view  toler- 
antly and  rationally  the  culture  and  conduct  of  other  nations.  It  teaches 
us  to  follow  our  country  slavishly,  whether  right  or  wrong.  Moreover, 
there  is  a  notable  tendency  to  emphasize  the  fact  that  our  country  is 
always  right,  whatever  the  historical  facts.  Germanic  historians  have 


5  "Where  Do  We  Get  Our  Prejudices?"  Harper's,  September,  1926,  p.  507. 

6  See  above,  pp.  219  ff. 


538    PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

represented  medieval  culture  as  a  product  of  Germanic  and  Anglo-Saxon 
civilization,  while  the  French  historians  trace  it  back  to  the  culture  of 
Roman  Gaul.  Many  Germans  have  derided  the  French  Revolution  as 
a  brutal  orgy,  conducted  by  a  race  incapable  of  self-discipline,  while 
French  historians  have  praised  it  as  an  epic  of  deliverance  from  tyranny 
and  a  great  contribution  to  democracy  and  liberty.  French  and  British 
historians  tend  to  have  a  markedly  different  interpretation  of  the  role 
and  achievements  of  Napoleon.  Only  a  few  historians  in  any  country 
have  been  able  to  arrive  at  an  accurate  and  dispassionate  notion  of  the 
outbreak  of  the  first  World  War,  and  our  ideas  of  the  second  World  War 
are  as  yet  no  more  than  sheer  fantasy.  Intense  nationalism  makes  it 
difficult,  if  not  impossible,  to  preserve  a  rational  and  understanding  atti- 
tude in  respect  to  foreign  affairs  and  international  relations. 

There  are,  of  course,  many  other  forms  of  political  prejudice.  We  have 
the  prejudice  of  the  conservative  against  the  radical,  and  of  the  radical 
against  the  conservative.  Likewise,  the  middle-of-the-road  liberals  tend 
to  be  hostile  to  both  extreme  groups.  It  is  difficult  for  any  one  of  the 
three  types  to  possess  an  unbiased  and  intelligent  view  of  the  merits  of 
the  others.  Then  there  are  the  well-known  prejudices  associated  with 
political  parties.  With  many,  loyalty  to  party  almost  exceeds  loyalty  to 
the  nation.  Members  of  other  parties  are  viewed  as  inferior  beings,  or  as 
the  natural  enemies  of  humanity.  The  party  becomes  a  vested  political 
interest,  which  is  defended  with  great  fervor.  Party  names,  symbols,  and 
catchwords  are  adopted  and  serve  to  vivify  and  perpetuate  these  party 
prejudices.  The  latter  are  capable  of  producing  an  entirely  false  notion 
of  the  character  of  political  parties. 

This  is  admirably  illustrated  by  the  situation  in  the  United  States  for 
the  last  half  century  or  more.  There  have  been  no  striking  differences 
between  the  Republican  and  Democratic  parties.  Both  have  been  com- 
mitted to  the  capitalistic  system  and  have  represented  essentially  the  same 
type  of  economic  interests.  The  differences  between  them  have  been  of 
an  entirely  minor  nature.  Yet,  party  prejudice  has  been  able  to  create 
the  illusion  that  the  contest  between  the  Republicans  and  Democrats  is 
very  real  and  a  matter  of  intense  moment  to  the  country.  The  partisan 
conflicts  have  often  attained  a  bitterness,  as  in  the  campaign  of  1936, 
exceeding  that  manifested  in  the  very  real  class  differences  between,  let 
us  say,  the  conservative  and  labor  parties  in  Great  Britain. 

Finally  we  may  refer  to  the  long-enduring  prejudice  against  allowing 
women  to  participate  in  politics.  This  was  simply  a  rationalization  of 
political  facts  as  they  existed  in  an  early  patriarchal  order.  In  those 
days  women's  physical  weakness  subordinated  them  to  males  and  thus 
they  could  not  share  political  equality  with  men.  This  prejudice  endured 
for  many  millenniums.  In  the  nineteenth  century,  feminism  appeared, 
with  a  contrary  set  of  prejudices.  Some  of  the  feminists  merely  argued 
that  women  possess  as  much  political  ability  as  men — certainly  a 
modest  and  defensible  contention ;  but  others,  in  an  excess  of  zeal,  argued 
that  women  are  endowed  with  special  forms  of  political  sagacity  superior 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP    539 

to  any  which  men  can  display.  The  political  prejudice  against  women 
in  politics  has,  in  our  day,  been  more  successfully  done  away  with  than 
the  other  forms  of  political  prejudice.  But  it  has  been  revived  in  various 
Fascist  states. 

Economic  prejudices  are  so  obvious  and  powerful  that  whole  philoso- 
phies of  history  have  been  constructed  which  argue  that  civilization  must 
be  entrusted  to  the  agricultural  nobility,  the  commercial  and  industrial 
middle  class,  or  the  industrial  proletariat.  In  early  days,  the  pastoral 
peoples  and  those  engaged  in  agriculture  warred  against  each  other  for 
millenniums.  Then,  in  turn,  the  agricultural  classes  feared  and  hated  the 
rising  commercial  groups  who  inhabited  the  towns.  The  great  political 
struggles  of  early  modern  times  were  primarily  manifestations  of  the 
struggle  of  the  rising  commercial  or  bourgeois  class  for  political  equality 
with  the  vested  agricultural  interests.  Then,  after  the  Industrial  Revo- 
lution, which  began  in  the  eighteenth  century,  the  commercial  and  indus- 
trial classes  became  suspicious  and  fearful  of  the  factory  workers.  The 
political  battles  of  the  last  century  have  been  colored  by  the  efforts  of  the 
laboring  class  in  the  cities  to  participate  in  politics  and  gain  a  prominent 
role  in  political  life.  In  every  case,  the  vested  economic  interests  desired 
to  hold  on  to  their  possessions  and  advantages  and  they  attacked  vigor- 
ously the  pretensions  and  virtues  of  those  who  contested  with  them  for 
power.  This  has  proved  true,  even  when  the  proletariat  has  come  into  a 
position  of  domination.  The  Communists  in  Soviet  Russia  are  as  bitterly 
hostile  to  the  capitalists  as  the  latter  are  to  the  Reds. 

Not  only  do  these  economic  prejudices  exist  between  major  economic 
classes;  they  are  sometimes  even  more  intense  between  various  sectors  of 
the  same  economic  class.  This  can  be  well  illustrated  by  the  situation  in 
contemporary  America.  The  hatred  between  various  groups  of  capitalists 
is  almost  as  great  as  that  between  the  latter  and  the  radicals.  The 
Liberty  Leaguers  attacked  the  New  Deal  with  as  great  vehemence  as 
they  did  the  Communists  and  Socialists,  and  the  advocates  of  the  New 
Deal  returned  the  compliment  with  vigor  and  enthusiasm,  denouncing 
their  opponents  as  Economic  Royalists.  Likewise,  the  Socialists  war 
against  the  Communists,  and  vice  versa.  Even  among  the  Communists 
there  are  cliques  whose  hatreds  are  even  more  intense  than  the  antipathy 
of  all  radicals  to  Wall  Street.  The  Trotskyites  hate  the  Stalinists  more 
than  either  hate  the  House  of  Morgan  or  the  Bank  of  England.  Finally, 
even  in  the  Labor  movement,  outside  of  truly  radical  circles,  there  are 
vigorous  prejudices,  as  witnessed  by  the  battles  between  the  American 
Federation  of  Labor  and  the  Congress  of  Industrial  Organizations. 

Law  is  a  powerful  instrument  for  upholding  and  executing  both  political 
and  economic  prejudices.  In  the  United  States,  especially  since  the 
Civil  War,  our  constitutional  law  has  operated  as  a  defense  of  capitalism 
against  reform  by  either  progressives  or  radicals.7  It  has  stood  in  the  way 
of  social  progress  through  declaring  reform  legislation  unconstitutional, 


7  See  above,  pp.  406  ff. 


540    PREJUDICE,    PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

making  special  use  of  the  due-process  clause  of  the  Fourteenth  Amend- 
ment. It  has  usually  exhibited  a  definite  hostility  toward  organized 
labor  through  ordering  the  enforcement  of  yellow-dog  contracts  and  freely 
granting  injunctions  against  strikers.  However,  under  the  New  Deal 
and  the  Wagner  Act,  the  force  of  the  law  was  invoked  to  legalize  trade 
unionism  and  collective  bargaining.  In  Soviet  Russia,  the  law  imposed 
even  more  severe  disabilities  upon  capitalism  than  it  did  upon  labor  and 
radicalism  in  the  United  States. 

Law  has  also  upheld  various  types  of  political  prejudices.  It  has  been 
used  to  exclude  the  propertyless  classes  and  women  from  the  right  to 
participate  in  political  life.  In  a  number  of  American  states  the  law 
excludes  Communists  and  other  radicals  from  the  right  to  organize 
as  a  political  party.  Despite  the  fact  that  our  country  was  founded 
through  revolution,  more  than  half  of  the  states  have  passed  laws  which 
outlaw  the  preaching  of  political  revolution  and  impose  serious  penalties 
therefor.  Law  has  also  been  used  to  uphold  nationalism  and  militarism 
by  denying  citizenship  to  those  who  will  not  promise  to  bear  arms  under 
all  circumstances. 

Law  has  also  been  exploited  in  behalf  of  religious  and  race  prejudices. 
In  the  early  history  of  our  country  the  right  to  vote  was  denied  to  un- 
believers. Today,  in  certain  states,  the  testimony  of  unbelievers  is  not 
accepted  in  court.  Religious  observances  in  the  schools  are  frequently 
prescribed  by  law.  On  the  other  hand,  when  certain  religious  prejudices 
conflict  with  patriotic  legislation  the  holders  of  such  religious  beliefs  are 
penalized,  as,  for  example,  in  the  present  legal  persecution  of  Jehovah's 
Witnesses.  Race  discrimination  exists  in  our  law  in  such  manifestations 
as  the  legislation  against  the  immigration  of  Orientals  and  the  many  and 
numerous  forms  of  discrimination  against  the  Negroes  in  the  South. 

Not  only  does  law  uphold  many  other  types  of  prejudices,  but  it  also 
supplies  an  important  group  of  prejudices  all  its  own.8  The  attitude  of 
the  mass  of  the  American  public  toward  law  itself  represents  a  definite 
sort  of  prejudice.  Laws,  which  are  the  product  of  fallible  human  law- 
makers, are  held  in  awe  and  respect.  There  is  a  prevalent  notion  that 
law  is  something  above  and  superior  to  man.  This  constitutes  a  definite 
hangover  from  the  primitive  reverence  and  taboos  associated  with  early 
legal  codes.  Constitutional  law  is  particularly  subject  to  reverence  by 
the  unthinking.  This  was  clearly  manifested  during  the  struggle  over 
the  reorganization  of  the  Supreme  Court  in  1937.  Judges  take  on  by 
contagion  the  sanctity  which  attaches  to  law  itself.  When  on  the  bench 
men  who  have  been  shrewd  practicing  politicians  or  enthusiastic  servants 
of  corporate  wealth  come  to  be  endowed,  in  the  popular  imagination,  with 
super-human  qualities  of  probity  and  detachment.  The  whole  concept 
of  contempt  of  court  reflects  the  popular  reverence  for  law  and  judges. 
The  judge  is  endowed  with  the  same  sanctity  which  earlier  attached  to 
the  medicine-man  and  magician.  The  whole  courtroom  procedure  is 


8  See  above,  pp.  37S-391. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP    541 

colored  by  a  complex  of  traditional  prejudices  with  respect  to  the  nature 
and  conduct  of  the  law. 

Within  the  legal  profession  itself  there  are  many  conflicting  prejudices. 
Professor  Fred  RodelPs  Woe  Unto  You,  Lawyers,  is  an  expression  of 
a  progressive  lawyer's  prejudice  against  the  dominant  prejudices  of  the 
legal  profession.9  Most  lawyers  look  upon  law  as  the  custodian  of  things 
as  they  are  and  the  protector  of  private  property.  Others  regard  it  as 
primarily  the  instrument  of  social  engineering  and  human  progress.  The 
code  of  ethics  of  the  legal  profession  is  colored  by  prejudice.  There  is 
no  taboo  placed  upon  directing  rich  corporations  as  to  ways  of  evading 
the  law,  but  such  practices  as  ambulance-chasing  are  fiercely  condemned. 

Religious  prejudices  are  numerous  and  bitter,  although  we  no  longer 
put  thousands  of  people  to  death  because  of  their  religious  beliefs,  as  they 
used  to  do  in  the  days  of  the  medieval  heresies  and  the  Spanish  Inquisi- 
tion. The  religious  person  looks  upon  the  unbeliever  as  a  monster  of  vice. 
The  militant  atheist,  equally  vehement,  sees  the  faithful  as  feeble- 
minded dupes.  Religious  prejudices  tend  to  be  particularly  vigorous 
and  dogmatic,  because  it  is  assumed  that  God  stands  behind  our  particular 
variety  of  religious  prejudice.  Further,  it  is  believed  that  our  earthly 
good  luck  and  fortune  depend  upon  vigorous  adherence  to  our  religious 
faith. 

There  is  still  a  good  deal  of  bitterness  of  feeling  and  marked  prejudices 
among  Jews,  Catholics,  and  Protestants ;  also  between  and  within  Protes- 
tant sects.  Where  the  feeling  between  Catholics  and  Protestants  is  most 
intense,  neither  group  is  really  willing  to  concede  that  the  other  is  entitled 
to  full  standing  as  members  of  the  human  race.  Anti-Semitism  and  the 
Ku  Klux  Klan  have  been  testimonials  to  the  extent  and  intensity  of 
Protestant  prejudice.  Catholic  prejudice  expresses  itself  in  a  more  adroit 
and  underground  fashion  than  Protestant  prejudice,  but  it  is  just  as 
vigorous.  The  very  existence  and  perpetuation  of  Judaism  rests  con- 
siderably upon  ancient  prejudices  against  other  religious  groups. 

The  slight  historical  and  factual  basis  for  all  this  religious  prejudice  is 
demonstrated  by  the  fact  that  there  is  little  fundamental  diff erence  among 
the  basic  beliefs  of  Jews,  Catholics,  and  Protestants.  They  accept,  with 
slight  variations,  the  same  holy  book,  the  same  philosophy  of  history  and 
salvation,  and  revere  the  same  religious  characters.  On  over  90  per  cent 
of  all  the  fundamental  elements  in  Christian  beliefs,  the  Catholics  and 
Protestants  are  united.  But  over  the  10  per  cent  of  difference  oceans  of 
blood  have  been  shed. 

Race  prejudice  is  one  of  the  most  obvious  of  the  antipathies  which  have 
afflicted  mankind  from  early  days.  This  has  been  due,  in  part,  merely  to 
the  automatic  perception  of  physical  differences.  But  race  prejudice  rests 
upon  many  other  factors.  Differences  in  religion,  customs,  and  beliefs, 
all  of  which  are  thought  to  threaten  the  culture  and  stability  of  the  group, 
are  supposed  to  be  carried  by  strange  races.  Different  races  have  very 


8  See  above,  pp.  376-380. 


542    PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

frequently  been  also  political  and  military  enemies,  thus  giving  a  prac- 
tical foundation  for  mutual  hostility.  However,  there  is  a  tendency  even 
when  peaceful  relations  have  been  established  for  many  generations  for 
the  hostility  to  persist  as  a  tradition.  In  the  United  States  it  manifests 
itself  chiefly  in  the  prejudice  of  the  Southern  whites  against  the  Negroes. 
When,  however,  Negroes  assert  real  racial  equality  in  the  North,  they  run 
up  against  much  the  same  prejudices  that  they  meet  in  the  South.  We 
have  also  manifested  race  prejudice  against  Mongolian  Orientals  in  our 
immigration  restriction  laws,  and  in  discriminating  legislation  passed  by 
Pacific  states.  Economic  interests  often  merge  with  race  prejudice  in 
our  attitude  towards  other  types.  The  Southerners  have  a  definite 
economic  interest  in  keeping  the  Negroes  in  a  position  of  inferiority. 
The  legislation  against  Orientals  was  motivated  in  part  by  the  challenge 
of  the  Chinese  to  white  labor  in  the  West  and  of  the  Japanese  to  white 
agricultural  interests  on  the  Pacific  coast.  Race  prejudice  operates  even 
where  therfc  are  no  essential  race  differences.  We  tend  to  regard  the 
foreigner  as  of  a  different  race,  even  when  he  comes  of  essentially  the 
same  physical  stocks  as  those  which  built  up  the  original  population  of 
the  United  States. 

The  most  evident  example  of  racial  prejudice,  which  has  no  real  rela- 
tion to  race  as  a  scientific  fact,  is  anti-Semitism.  The  Jews  are  in  no 
sense  a  cohesive,  separate  race.  The  real  differences  which  stir  up  anti- 
Semitic  prejudices  are  of  a  cultural  character,  such  as  religious  practices, 
social  customs,  and  the  reluctance  to  intermarry  with  Gentiles.  Then 
there  is  a  long  tradition  of  anti-Semitism  brought  to  this  country  by  the 
European  settlers.  The  financial  and  commercial  sagacity  of  the  Jews 
and  their  prominence  in  the  professions  have  also  fostered  hostility. 
Anti-Semitism  was  revived  in  most  flagrant  fashion  by  Hitler  and  the 
Nazis,  and  imitated  by  Mussolini,  but  there  have  been  many  flare-ups  in 
England  and  the  United  States  since  the  first  World  War. 

Professional  Semitism  and  pro-Semitism  are  as  much  the  product  of 
prejudice  as  anti-Semitism.10  In  the  face  of  enforced  social  inferiority, 
the  Jews  have  asserted  their  superior  cultural  capacity.  Persecuted  as 
a  race,  they  have  maintained  a  fictitious  racial  identity.  Being  treated 
as  inferiors,  they  have  naturally  developed  a  compensatory  assertiveness 
and  aggressiveness  which  the  Gentiles  mistakenly  interpret  as  a  racial 
characteristic  of  the  Jews.  If  prejudices  were  removed  from  both  sides 
of  the  question,  there  would  be  neither  anti-Semitism  nor  Jewish  opposi- 
tion to  speedy  assimilation  with  Gentiles. 

Moral  prejudice  is  closely  associated  with  religious  prejudice.  Indeed, 
it  is  a  sort  of  synthesis  of  religious,  economic,  and  social  prejudices.  It 
also  embraces  certain  prejudices  which  are  derived  from  etiquette.  Acts 
which  grossly  offend  our  sense  of  propriety  tend  to  be  regarded  as  im- 
moral. Like  religious  prejudice,  moral  prejudice  is  especially  full  of 
vehemence  and  self-assurance.  We  take  it  for  granted  that  God  approves 


10  Cf.  H.  L.  Mencken,  in  American  Hebrew,  September  7,  1934. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND   CENSORSHIP    543 

the  brand  of  narrow-mindedness  we  employ  in  appraising  our  own  con- 
duct and  that  of  others.  Since  conventional  morality  is  closely  associated 
with  supernatural  religion,  it  is  rare  that  a  person  examines  his  own 
moral  convictions  objectively.  They  are  taken  for  granted  to  be  sound, 
impeccable,  and  quite  unchallengeable.  As  Mencken  and  others  have 
pointed  out,  another  strong  source  of  moral  prejudice  is  the  sentiment 
of  the  invidious.11  We  disapprove  of  those  things  which  our  limited  cir- 
cumstances prevent  us  from  doing.  Then  there  is  the  influence  of  right- 
eous hypocrisy.  A  person  guilty  of  one  form  or  another  of  anti-social 
conduct  often  seeks  to  compensate  and  to  give  himself  mental  calm  by 
ostentatious  correctness  with  regard  to  certain  other  conventionalities, 
and  gives  evidence  of  a  holy  wrath  against  those  who  violate  them.  A 
case  in  point  is  the  support  of  anti-vice  societies  by  financial  and  corpo- 
rate moguls. 

Our  educational  prejudices  are  numerous.  Our  entire  culture  is,  in 
part,  a  mosaic  of  traditional  prejudices,  and  it  is  the  function  ef  education 
to  transmit  this  culture.  A  traditional  form  of  educational  prejudice 
upholds  the  punitive  ideals  of  education.  It  lays  great  stress  upon  edu- 
cation as  the  disciplinarian  of  the  will.  The  latter  is  to  be  strengthened 
through  imposing  unpleasant  tasks,  the  execution  of  which  is  insisted 
upon  with  vigor  and  thoroughness.  Much  of  the  traditional  curriculum 
represents  archaic  prejudices  which  have  grown  up  in  various  periods  of 
the  history  of  civilization  and  have  been  handed  down  in  the  educational 
process.  Such  are  the  notions  of  the  special  educational  virtues  of  the 
classics  and  mathematics.  Another  example  is  afforded  by  the  leisure- 
class  bias  in  education  which  leads  us  to  regard  most  really  useful,  practi- 
cal, and  utilitarian  subjects  as  base,  "sloppy,"  and  quite  incompatible 
with  sound  educational  philosophy  and  practice. 

The  whole  "cultural"  ideal  in  education  is,  to  a  considerable  extent,  an 
outgrowth  of  the  prejudices  associated  with  the  leisure  class  and  the  idea 
that  the  lady  and  gentleman  must  be  freed  from  all  trace  of  servility.  It 
is  this  which  lies  at  the  foundation  of  the  deep-seated  prejudice  against 
vocational  education  that  regards  practical  subjects  as  non-educational 
or  anti-educational.  The  natural  reaction  against  traditional  education 
has  produced  a  comparable  prejudice  in  favor  of  complete  personal  free- 
dom and  thorough  devotion  to  spontaneous  development.  It  revives  the 
old  revolt  of  Rousseau  against  the  pedants  of  the  eighteenth  century. 
Progressive  education  is  the  best  example  of  this  prejudice  in  educational 
revolt. 

Most  social  scientists  regard  prejudice  as  unfortunate  and  detrimental 
to  human  well-being.  This  point  of  view  is  shared  by  the  present  writer. 
But,  in  all  fairness,  we  should  point  out  that  very  distinguished  scholars 
and  cultivated  gentlemen  have  sharply  challenged  this  attitude.  A  good 
example  is  a  famous  British  anthropologist  and  amiable  savant,  Sir  Arthur 
Keith,  who  wrote  a  little  book  on  The  Place  of  Prejudice  in  Modern 


11  Cf.  H.  L.  Mencken,  Notes  on  Democracy,  Knopf,  1926,  pp.  35-43. 


544    PREJUDICE,    PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

Civilization  to  expound  the  thesis  that  prejudice  is  a  positive  and  benefi- 
cial factor  in  human  culture,  giving  pride  to  human  beings  and  vitality  to 
human  effort.  Prejudice  stimulates  competition  and  argument  and  thus 
promotes  the  progress  of  civilization.  Keith  praises  super-patriotism  and 
race  prejudice,  and  holds  that  even  if  they  lead  to  war  they  are  an  asset 
to  the  race,  since  "war  is  nature's  pruning-hook."  "Race  prejudice,  I 
believe,  works  for  the  ultimate  good  of  mankind  and  must  be  given  a 
recognized  place  in  all  our  efforts  to  obtain  natural  justice  for  the 
world."  12 

Some  Suggested  Remedies  for  Our  Prejudices.  Travel  leads  us  to 
understand  that  there  are  many  people  with  views  and  customs  that  differ 
markedly  from  our  own,  and  we  must  ultimately  concede  that  there  are 
certain  virtues  in  the  beliefs  and  habits  of  others.  Education  of  a  critical 
type,  particularly  in  the  fields  of  history  and  sociology,  has  an  under- 
mining effect  on  prejudice.  History  shows  the  mundane  origins  of  our 
prejudices  And  tears  away  their  pretense  to  sanctity  or  invincibility. 
Such  a  sociological  work  as  William  Graham  Sumner's  Folkways,  if  read 
with  understanding,  should  do  a  great  deal  to  dissipate  prejudice.  Here 
we  discover  that  what  is  right  is  usually  no  more  than  what  is  currently 
done  in  any  group. 

The  elimination  of  belief  in  the  supernatural  helps  to  discredit  preju- 
dice. It  permits  us  to  examine  our  beliefs  and  discover  that  they  are  of 
purely  earthly  origin ;  that  they  are,  for  the  most  part,  the  product  of  a 
generation  less  equipped  with  earthly  knowledge  than  our  own.  Another 
important  exercise  which  promotes  the  destruction  of  prejudice  is  the 
study  of  comparative  religion.  This  shows  the  common  elements  in  all 
the  great  world-religions  and  exposes  the  errors  and  follies  embodied  in 
religious  narrow-mindedness. 

The  cultivation  of  an  international  point  of  view  in  culture  and  public 
problems  also  assists  greatly  in  allaying  prejudices.  We  find  that  it  is 
rare  that  any  nation  has  exclusively  created  all  the  cultural  possessions 
it  prizes.  We  can  see  clearly  the  contributions  of  other  peoples  to  our 
own  culture  and  institutions  through  the* ages. 

Likewise,  the  scientific  study  of  race  reveals  the  fallacies  in  racial  arro- 
gance, and  disproves  the  assumption  that  one  race  monopolizes  all  the 
virtues  of  humanity.  Such  study  also  demonstrates  that  there  is  no  such 
thing  as  a  pure  race  today,  Aryan  or  other. 

The  outlook  for  the  elimination  of  prejudice  in  our  generation  is  not 
especially  bright.  We  are  living  in  a  great  transitional  age,  when  old 
institutions  are  crumbling  and  new  ones  are  seeking  to  supplant  them. 
Under  such  conditions,  the  vested  economic  and  social  interests  become 
especially  ferocious  in  attempting  to  protect  their  hitherto  dominant 
position.  Similarly,  the  exponents  of  the  new  order  are  especially  in- 
tolerant in  their  programs  of  reform.  We  see  this  trend  manifested  in  its 
extreme  form  in  Fascism  and  Communism.  Both  display  ferocity  in 


*2  Keith,  op.  cit.f  p.  49. 


PREJUDICE,    PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP    545 

stamping  out  any  deviation  from  the  form  of  thought  and  conduct  they 
set  up  for  the  group. 

Though  nationalism  was  clearly  shown  to  be  a  major  cause  of  the 
first  World  War,  we  learned  little  from  the  lesson.  We  created  more 
national  states,  and  they  were  even  more  guilty  of  exaggerated  national- 
ism, both  political  and  economic,  than  were  the  nations  before  the  war. 

Racial  prejudice  seems  to  be  gaining.  The  effort  of  the  Negroes  in 
the  United  States  to  gain  economic  emancipation  has  intensified  repressive 
measures  against  them.  Hitler  and  Rosenberg  have  given  racial  dogmas 
and  arrogance  unprecedented  standing  and  power.  Anti-Semitism  is 
likely  to  spread  elsewhere,  in  the  wake  of  the  second  World  War.  And, 
back  of  all  older  race  conflicts,  lies  the  possibility  of  sharp  racial  conflicts 
between  the  Yellow  and  Black  races,  on  the  one  hand,  and  the  White  race 
on  the  other.  It  is  predicted  by  many  that  these  suppressed  races  are  on 
the  eve  of  a  world-wide  revolt  against  their  white  masters.  Realistic 
observers  of  even  the  most  extreme  interventionist  bias  are  already  con- 
ceding that,  whatever  the  outcome  of  the  second  World  War,  there  is  no 
likelihood  that  white  dominion  will  ever  be  restored  over  the  Far  East. 

Political  prejudice  also  seems  likely  to  grow  more  bitter.  Political 
parties  are  taking  on  a  fundamentally  economic  cast.  They  are  lining 
up  with  capitalism  or  radicalism.  The  bitterness  of  the  economic  struggle 
is  thus  reflected  in  the  political  conflict.  In  the  United  States,  our 
political  parties  have  possessed  little  realism  of  late,  and  they  rely  upon 
the  inflation  of  political  prejudices  to  give  them  vitality. 

The  manner  in  which  our  leading  prejudices  express  themselves  and 
operate  to  influence  public  opinion  will  be  considered  in  our  analysis  of 
contemporary  propaganda. 

Contemporary  Propaganda  and  Mass  Persuasion 

The  Nature  and  History  of  Propaganda.  No  factor  in  contemporary 
social  control  is  more  potent,  universal,  and  persuasive  than  propaganda, 
Its  novelty,  power,  and  significance  have  been  well  emphasized  by  Luther 
H.  Gulick: 

Another  striking  new  factor  in  the  modern  world  is  propaganda.  Mass  pro- 
duction needs  mass  consumption,  pressure  groups  seek  mass  action,  politicians 
rely  on  the  magic  of  phrases  with  the  multitude,  and  whole  nations  are  more  than 
ever  compelling  the  assent  of  the  governed  by  manipulating  mass  emotions. 
New  developments  and  inventions  in  newspaper  chains  and  services,  cheap  print- 
ing, rapid  communication  and  the  radio,  and  the  prevalence  of  shallow  education 
have  combined  with  world-wide  unrest  to  make  propaganda  a  new  and  challeng- 
ing problem  for  education.13 

There  have  been  a  number  of  attempts  to  define  propaganda.  Clyde 
R.  Miller,  of  the  Institute  for  Propaganda  Analysis,  offers  the  following 
informal  definition:  "Propaganda  is  the  attempt  to  influence  others  to 
some  predetermined  end  by  appealing  to  their  thought  and  feeling." 


18  L.  H.  Gulick,  Education  for  American  Life,  The  Regents'  Inquiry,  McGraw-Hill, 
1938,  pp.  33-34. 


546    PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

Stuart  Ayres  holds  that  "propaganda  is  the  planned  attempt  to  control 
and  regiment  the  thought  and  action  of  the  public."  Shepard  Stone  is 
content  to  define  propaganda  as  an  effort  "to  put  something  across." 
Harold  Lasswell  contends  that,  in  its  broadest  sense,  "propaganda  is  the 
technique  of  influencing  human  action  by  the  manipulation  of  representa- 
tions. These  representations  may  take  spoken,  written,  pictorial  or 
musical  form."  In  one  of  the  best  books  on  the  subject,  Leonard  W. 
Doob  holds  that  propaganda  is  "a  systematic  attempt  by  an  interested 
individual  (or  individuals)  to  control  the  attitudes  of  groups  of  individuals 
through  the  use  of  suggestion  and,  consequently,  to  control  their  actions." 
Professor  Doob  divides  propaganda  into  two  types,  intentional  and  un- 
intentional. The  type  of  propaganda  with  which  we  arc  concerned  is 
intentional  propaganda. 

In  a  strict  scientific  sense,  the  test  of  propaganda  has  no  relation  to 
its  being  reactionary  or  liberal;  yet,  propaganda  is  generally  thought  of 
as  an  attempt  to  influence  opinion  in  unorthodox  and  novel  fashion.  In 
other  words,  propaganda  is  usually  regarded  as  something  which  deviates 
from  the  norm  of  conventional  attitudes.  For  example,  the  methods  em- 
ployed by  conservative  newspapers  like  the  New  York  Herald-Tribune 
are  conventionally  assumed  to  produce  unbiased  "news."  On  the  other 
hand,  a  paper  no  more  to  the  Left  than  the  Herald-Tribune  is  to  the 
Right,  say  the  Daily  Worker,  is  customarily  regarded  as  turning  out 
nothing  except  "propaganda."  In  any  scholarly  analysis  of  propaganda 
we  must  be  quick  to  recognize  that  any  deliberate  attempt  to  influence 
attitudes  to  a  predetermined  end  is  propaganda,  whether  it  emerges  from 
the  Right  or  the  Left,  whether  it  be  true  as  to  fact  or  not,  and  whether  we 
agree  with  it  or  not. 

Propaganda  is  nothing  new  in  history.14  The  novelty  in  contemporary 
propaganda  is  to  be  found  in  the  unprecedented  variety  and  potency  of 
the  new  agencies  through  which  suggestion  may  be  applied.  Propaganda 
is  about  as  old  as  human  speech  itself.  Primitive  tradition,  handed  on 
by  word  of  mouth,  was  virtually  propaganda  in  favor  of  the  prevailing 
customs  and  folkways.  The  social  conscience  of  mankind  was  developed 
as  a  phase  of  counter-propaganda.  As  J.  H.  Breasted  has  pointed  out, 
the  first  social  reformers  on  record  were  Egyptian  social  idealists  who, 
about  2000  B.C.,  carried  on  a  vigorous  propaganda  against  the  injustices 
of  the  ruling  class  of  their  day.  Much  of  Hebrew  theology  turned  about 
the  propaganda  of  the  prophets  against  the  priests,  and  vice  versa.  A 
great  deal  of  Greek  philosophy  could  be  called  a  manifestation  of  propa- 
ganda. The  Sophists  attacked  the  traditional  thinkers  and,  in  turn, 


14  On  the  history  of  propaganda,  see  H.  E.  Barnes,  A  History  of  Historical  Writing, 
University  of  Oklahoma  Press,  1937;  Gorham  Munson,  Twelve  Decisive  Battles  of 
the  Mind,  Greystone  Press,  1942;  P.  A.  Throop,  Criticism  of  the  Crusade:  A  Study 
of  Public  Opinion  and  Crusade  Propaganda,  Swets  and  Zeitlinger,  1940;  Philip 
Davidson,  Propaganda  and  the  American  Revolution,  University  of  North  Carolina 
Press,  1941;  C.  E.  Merriam,  A  History  of  American  Political  Theories,  Macmillan, 
1918:  H.  C.  Peterson,  Propaganda  for  War,  University  of  Oklahoma  Press,  1939; 
and  Porter  Sargent,  Getting  US  into  War,  Sargent,  1941. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP    547 

Socrates  and  Plato  devoted  their  lives  to  refuting  the  Sophists.  The 
famous  funeral  speech  that  Thucydides  put  in  the  mouth  of  Pericles  was 
a  masterpiece  of  Athenian  propaganda.  Few  contemporary  professional 
boosters  could  do  as  well.  Cato  the  Elder  was  a  better  propagandist  for 
agriculture  than  Henry  Wallace.  Cicero  had  mastered  most  of  the 
propaganda  techniques  with  which  we  are  familiar  today.  Caesar's  Com- 
mentaries provided  some  of  the  cleverest  propaganda  ever  written.  In- 
deed, Caesar  could  show  the  way  to  many  modern  masters  of  propaganda, 
such  as  Ivy  Lee  and  E.  L.  Bernays.  The  historian  Tacitus  carried  on  a 
vigorous  propaganda  in  behalf  of  Roman  republican  institutions  and  in 
opposition  to  the  new  imperial  tendencies.  Juvenal  was  an  extraordi- 
narily effective  propagandist  against  the  abuses  of  Roman  imperial 
society. 

Christianity  was  well-propagandized  by  the  Fathers,  who  wrote  ve- 
hemently against  the  Pagans,  against  heritical  sects,  and  against  the 
doctrines  of  other  orthodox  Christians  of  whose  dogmas  they  disapproved. 
Perhaps  the  greatest  single  collection  of  propaganda  ever  published  is  to 
be  found  in  the  collected  writings  of  the  Christian  Fathers  from  Paul  to 
Augustine  and  Isidore.  The  Secret  History  of  Procopius  was  a  masterly 
bit  of  propaganda  against  Justinian  and  the  practices  of  the  Byzantine 
court.  Einhard,  the  biographer  of  Charlemagne,  wrote  such  good  Caro- 
lingian  propaganda  that  it  has  colored  our  interpretation  of  early  medieval 
history  for  centuries.  The  Crusades  were  brought  on  mainly  by  Peter 
the  Hermit  and  Pope  Urban,  who  conducted  a  spirited  propaganda  against 
Islam  and  the  Mohammedan  occupants  of  the  Holy  Land.  From  Luther 
onward,  the  Protestants  directed  a  voluminous  and  vigorous  propaganda 
against  the  Catholics,  which  was  returned  in  kind.  The  Magdeburg 
Centurians  synthesized  early  Protestant  propaganda  and  were  answered 
by  Cardinal  Baronius  from  the  Catholic  point  of  view.  Fox,  Buchanan, 
and  others  continued  the  Protestant  propaganda,  and  the  Jesuits  at- 
tempted to  refute  it.  The  struggle  between  absolute  monarchs  and  the 
middle  class  was  enveloped  in  propaganda,  exemplified  by  such  things 
as  the  doctrine  of  the  divine  right  of  kings  and  the  justification  of  the 
right  of  revolution.  James  I,  Filmer,  and  Salamasius  expounded  the 
divine  right  of  kings,  while  Locke  and  Sydney  defended  the  right  of 
revolution.  Bossuet  extolled  royal  absolutism,  while  Rousseau  praised 
the  social  contract  and  revolution.  The  French  Revolution  produced  a 
voluminous  propaganda  for  and  against  the  revolutionists.  The  most 
notable  example  of  propaganda  against  the  Revolution  was  Edmund 
Burke's  Reflections  on  the  French  Revolution.  The  ablest  propaganda  on 
behalf  of  the  Revolution  was  Thomas  Paine's  answer  to  Burke,  in  his 
Rights  of  Man. 

The  United  States  was  the  result  of  one  of  the  greatest  campaigns  of 
propaganda  before  the  first  World  War.  James  Otis,  Samuel  Adams, 
Patrick  Henry,  and  others  led  in  the  propaganda  against  the  new  British 
imperial  policy.  The  work  of  the  Committees  of  Correspondence,  in 
organizing  resistance  to  Britain,  represented  successful  propaganda  on  a 


548    PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

scale  hitherto  unknown.  The  Declaration  cff  Independence  is  a  masterly 
bit  of  propaganda,  and  was  intended  to  be  such  by  its  author,  Thomas 
Jefferson.  Our  Federal  Constitution  was  adopted  mainly  as  a  result  of 
the  able  propaganda  embodied  in  The  Federalist.  Even  more  vehement 
propaganda  against  the  Constitution  was  set  forth  in  the  Centinel  Letters 
and  similar  publications.  Powerful  propaganda  for  democracy  was  car- 
ried on  in  the  Jacksonian  period  by  George  Bancroft,  Horace  Mann, 
Henry  Barnard,  and  others. 

The  struggle  over  slavery  produced  a  great  wave  of  propaganda.  The 
Abolitionists,  led  by  William  Lloyd  Garrison,  published  bitter  anti-slavery 
propaganda  in  The  Liberator.  Harriet  Beecher  Stowe's  Uncle  Tom's 
Cabin  was  probably  the  most  potent  anti-slavery  propaganda  ever 
written.  The  slave  owners  answered  in  kind,  though  they  never  produced 
anything  so  dramatic  or  so  widely  read  as  Uncle  Tom's  Cabin.  The 
nearest  thing  to  it  came  in  our  own  day  with  the  publication  of  Margaret 
Mitchell's  Gone  With  the  Wind.  The  period  of  Reconstruction  produced 
bitter  propaganda  against  the  Southerners,  led  by  Thaddeus  Stevens. 
President  Andrew  Johnson  carried  on  hopeless  counter-propaganda 
against  his  Congressional  adversaries.  The  Republican  party  waved  the 
"bloody  shirt"  for  more  than  a  generation  after  the  Civil  War,  in  order 
to  prejudice  the  public  mind  against  the  Democratic  party  as  the  party 
of  rebellion.  The  conservative  press  of  our  country  launched  a  propa- 
ganda campaign  of  unprecedented  venom  against  William  Jennings  Bryan 
in  1896  and  accomplished  his  defeat  thereby. 

The  American  colonial  empire  arose  on  the  crest  of  notorious  newspaper 
propaganda  carried  on  by  Hearst,  Pulitzer,  and  others,  who  urged  our 
government  to  make  war  on  Spain.  The  United  States  was  brought  into 
the  first  World  War  on  the  side  of  the  Allies  by  the  most  comprehensive 
and  carefully  planned  propaganda  in  history  before  1939.  We  need  only 
mention  characteristic  atrocity  tales  that  were  spread:  British  nurses  in 
Belgium  tortured  and  mutilated ;  the  hands  of  Belgian  children  cut  off  by 
the  German  soldiers;  Belgian  women  and  girls  ravished;  Canadian 
soldiers  crucified;  tongues  of  captured  British  soldiers  torn  out;  cobras 
tattooed  on  the  cheeks  of  Entente  prisoners;  French  juvenile  war  heroes 
brutally  shot.  Other  tales  described  the  German  corpse  factory;  the 
ghoulish  glee  and  enthusiasm  of  the  German  Crown  Prince  as  he  per- 
sonally led  in  the  looting  of  captured  churches,  palaces,  and  jewelry 
stores ;  the  bombing  of  hospitals  and  hospital  ships ;  the  favorite  recrea- 
tion of  submarine  gunners,  who  picked  off  sailors  struggling  in  the  water 
after  their  ship  had  been  torpedoed;  and  the  willful  German  devastation 
of  libraries,  works  of  art,  and  religious  relics.15  Along  with  these 
stories  went  the  larger  propaganda  myth  that  Germany  was  solely  re- 
sponsible for  the  outbreak  of  the  first  World  War.  The  coming  of  peace 
produced  vigorous  propaganda,  such  as  that  arising  out  of  the  controversy 
between  President  Wilson  and  the  Senate  over  the  desirability  of  our 
entering  the  League  of  Nations,  and  the  long  debate  over  the  responsi- 
bility for  the  outbreak  of  the  war  in  1914. 


15  See  J.  M.  Read,  Atrocity  Propaganda,  1914-1919,  Yale  Press,  1941. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP    549 

The  approximately  fifteen  years  of  the  "Noble  Experiment"  with 
Prohibition  brought  about  extensive  propaganda  in  the  battle  between 
th$  "Wets"  and  the  "Drys."  Other  prominent  examples  of  propaganda 
since  the  World  War  have  been  the  intermittent  spasms  of  Red-baiting, 
most  notable  being  the  orgy  of  Attorney  General  Mitchell  Palmer  and  the 
deportation  delirium  of  1919-20,  the  Lusk  Committee  in  New  York  State, 
and  the  Congressional  investigations  by  Congressmen  Fish  and  Dies; 
the  propaganda  carried  on  by  the  munitions  makers;  and  that  set  forth 
by  the  electric  utilities  in  their  effort  to  forestall  or  prevent  government 
ownership  or  too  stringent  government  regulation.  The  presidential  cam- 
paign in  1928  produced  political  and  religious  propaganda  unmatched 
since  the  election  of  1896;  and  the  campaigns  of  1936  and  1940  were 
notable  for  bitter  economic  propaganda.  The  New  Dealers  presented 
propaganda  in  support  of  the  new  economic  experiments,  while  Economic 
Royalists  and  Liberty  Leaguers  countered  with  propaganda  against  them. 
The  threat  of  world  war  after  1939  promoted  vigorous  interventionist  and 
isolationist  propaganda  in  the  United  States. 

This  brief  review  of  some  of  the  outstanding  examples  of  propaganda 
in  the  past  will  suffice  to  demonstrate  that  the  use  of  propaganda  is  no 
novelty  in  human  life,  least  of  all  in  the  history  of  our  own  country.  The 
propaganda  of  our  own  day  differs  from  earlier  propaganda  only  in  its 
more  universal  exploitation  and  the  superior  devices  for  making  it  an 
overwhelming  instrument  of  mass  appeal. 

Propaganda  during  the  first  World  War  demonstrated  its  enormous 
efficiency  in  molding  public  opinion.  The  results  accomplished  by  Ivy 
Lee  after  1914  in  completely  transforming  the  public  attitude  towards 
John  D.  Rockefeller  revealed  the  potentialities  of  the  Public  Relations 
Counsel  in  influencing  public  opinion.  Then  we  witnessed  the  remark- 
able development  of  commercial  advertising  as  a  veritable  science  and 
art  of  mass  appeal.  This  achievement  has  been  well  described  in  James 
Rorty's  book  Our  Master's  Voice,  and  Helen  Woodward's  It's  An  Art. 
Both  the  public  relations  counsellors  and  the  commercial  advertisers  have 
made  a  wide  use  of  social  psychology,  now  available  for  propagandists  to 
an  unprecedented  degree,  both  in  volume  and  technical  accuracy.  The 
propagandists  have  also  used  devices  and  instruments  of  communication 
hitherto  unknown.  In  addition  to  the  use  of  the  press  and  the  distribu- 
tion of  handbills,  leaflets,  pamphlets,  and  so  on,  they  have  been  able  to 
exploit  the  telegraph,  the  movies,  and  the  radio. 

The  most  diverse  and  varied  groups  have  recognized  the  value  of 
propaganda,  so  that  today  we  have  more  than  a  thousand  organizations 
created  primarily  for  the  purpose  of  molding  public  opinion.  In  at- 
tempts to  reach  the  mass  of  Americans,  it  was  inevitable  that  the  intellec- 
tual content  of  propaganda  would  be  lowered  so  as  to  appeal  to  anyone 
capable  of  understanding  the  simplest  language.  As  Federal  Communi- 
cations Commissioner  Payne  once  put  it:  "There  is  the  danger  that  radio 
and  the  movies  will,  in  time,  make  us  a  nation  of  grown-up  children. 
Like  the  moving  pictures,  the  average  program  of  the  broadcasters  is  ad- 
dressed to  an  intelligence  possessed  by  a  child  of  twelve."  Joseph  Jastrow 


550    PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

has,  indeed,  accused  our  contemporary  propagandists  of  trying  to  "mo- 
ronize"  the  American  public. 

Devices  and  Processes  of  Propaganda.  Clyde  R.  Miller,  when  director 
of  the  important  Institute  for  Propaganda  Analysis,  brought  together 
in  systematic  form  what  he  regards  as  the  seven  most  common  devices 
of  contemporary  propaganda: 

1.  The  Name-Calling  device. 

2.  The  Glittering  Generalities  device. 

3.  The  Transfer  device. 

4.  The  Testimonial  device. 

5.  The  Plain  Folks  device. 

6.  The  Card-Stacking  device. 

7.  The  Band  Wagon  device.16 

The  name-calling  device  is  an  application  of  the  old  adage  of  "giving  a 
dog  a  bad  name."  By  calling  names,  we  associate  the  person  or  move- 
ment we  would  disparage  with  something  undesirable  or  socially  disap- 
proved. For  example,  members  of  the  Liberty  League  called  President 
Roosevelt,  directly  or  by  implication,  a  Communist  and  a  Socialist.  Mr. 
Roosevelt  in  turn  designated  his  opponents  as  Economic  Royalists.  Re- 
ttctionary  employers  are  fond  of  calling  John  L.  Lewis  a  Communist. 
Al  Smith  sought  to  discredit  President  Roosevelt's  financial  policies  by 
reference  to  "the  baloney  dollar."  After  1939,  interventionists  delighted 
in  calling  their  opponents  Fifth  Columnists,  while  the  isolationists  coun- 
tered by  designating  the  interventionists  as  war-mongers. 

The  use  of  glittering  generalities  is  an  exploitation  of  what  Stuart  Chase 
has  called  "the  tyranny  of  words."  The  propagandist  seeks  to  invest  his 
program  with  dignity  and  nobility  by  associating  it  with  worthy  but 
vague  sentiments,  like  love,  generosity,  truth,  and  honor.  Through  this 
association  he  hopes  to  achieve  spontaneous  and  universal  approval  for 
his  special  interest.  Reactionary  employers  seek  to  undermine  collective 
bargaining  by  attacking  strikes  through  an  appeal  for  "the  right  to  work." 
Father  Coughlin  cloaks  his  vigorous  quasi-Fascist  propaganda  under  the 
noble  phrase  of  "social  justice."  President  Roosevelt  associates  the  New 
Deal  with  "the  more  abundant  life."  His  opponents  seek  to  discredit  it 
by  calling  it  a  spendthrift  economy.  To  them  the  "abundant  life"  be- 
comes "boondoggling."  Our  reactionaries  seek  approval  for  their  eco- 
nomic program  by  defining  it  as  "the  American  way"  or  by  identifying 
it  with  the  preservation  of  the  Constitution.  In  the  winter  of  1940-41, 
President  Roosevelt  ennobled  all-out  aid  to  Britain  under  the  guise  of 
spreading  the  Four  Freedoms  throughout  the  whole  world. 

By  the  transfer  device,  the  propagandist  tries  to  get  prestige  for  his 
policies  by  associating  them  with  some  symbol  universally  respected,  like 
God,  the  Cross,  the  flag,  Uncle  Sam,  and  so  on.  Journalists  commonly 
make  use  of  cartoons  which  employ  the  figure  of  Uncle  Sam,  the  Ameri- 
can flag,  or  the  Christian  Cross  in  such  a  way  as  to  imply  that  the  Ameri- 


16  Institute   for   Propaganda   Analysis,   Bulletin,   "How   to    Detect    Propaganda/' 
November,  1937. 


PREJUDICE,    PROPAGANDA  AND   CENSORSHIP    551 

can  spirit  or  the  Church  lends  support  to  the  policies  they  favor.  Sen- 
ator Wheeler  enlisted  God  on  the  side  of  those  opposing  the  President's 
Supreme  Court  reforms  in  1937.  Henry  Wallace  and  other  intervention- 
ists invoked  the  blessing  of  God  on  their  crusade  against  Herr  Hitler. 

By  the  testimonial  device,  the  propagandist  exploits  the  approval  of 
some  policy  or  product  by  a  person  or  group  possessing  great  popular 
prestige,  such  as  the  President's  wife,  Henry  Ford,  the  American  Legion, 
the  United  States  Chamber  of  Commerce,  or  the  American  Federation 
of  Labor.  The  testimonial  is  usually  a  direct  eulogy  of  the  thing  or  pro- 
gram being  promoted.  It  is  most  commonly  used  in  commercial  adver- 
tisements. 

An  effort  to  appear  extremely  democratic,  devoid  of  snobbery,  and  in 
tune  with  the  mass  of  Americans  is  called  the  plain  folks  device.  Most 
presidents  have  been  photographed  talking  to  farmers,  to  housewives,  to 
laborers,  and  so  on.  Calvin  Coolidge  was  often  photographed  on  a  rustic 
hayrake.  Alf  Landon  returned  to  the  home  folks  where  he  was  born  to 
start  his  presidential  campaign.  When  one  of  our  masters  of  commercial 
advertising,  Bruce  Barton,  decided  to  enter  public  life,  photographs 
appeared  showing  him  talking  to  the  common  man  seated  on  a  park  bench, 
at  the  wheel  of  a  taxi,  and  so  on.  The  notorious  baby-kissing  antics  of 
politicians  during  campaigns  is  another  example  of  the  plain  folks  device. 
So  are  photographs  of  a  candidate  with  his  whole  family,  from  his 
grandfather  to  his  grandchildren,  wearing  common  clothes,  displaying  an 
interest  in  baseball  and  fishing,  attending  convivial  picnics,  and  so  on. 

The  card-stacking  device  makes  deliberate  use  of  faulty  logic  or  sup- 
presses facts  in  an  effort  to  promote  a  cause  or  candidate.  It  is  the 
combination  of  rigging  the  game  and  the  familiar  Jesuitical  method  of 
argument  through  dust-throwing.  Embarrassing  facts  are  overlooked, 
and  the  argument  is  shifted  from  major  items  to  secondary  issues.  Every 
effort  is  made  to  obscure  the  facts,  to  confuse  and  mislead.  The  familiar 
build-up  of  candidates,  pugilists,  movie  stars,  and  the  like,  by  piling  up 
alleged  virtues,  is  another  example  of  the  card-stacking  procedure. 

An  excellent  instance  of  card-stacking  was  the  statement  made  by  a 
rich  and  powerful  university  president  in  the  spring  of  1942,  endeavoring 
to  ridicule  the  attempt  of  labor  to  preserve  the  forty-hour  week.  He 
stated  that  he  had  long  wished  for  a  "forty-hour  day."  What  he  failed 
to  state  was  that,  if  he  had  a  forty-hour  day,  he  would  be  spending  part 
of  it  in  pleasant  conversation,  golf,  banquets,  travel  and  the  like,  not  in 
grueling  work  in  a  foundry.  Nor  did  he  take  the  trouble  to  point  out 
that  the  average  coalmincr  would  probably  delight  in  a  forty-hour  day  if 
he  could  spend  part  of  it  in  leisure  pursuits. 

The  band  wagon  device  attempts  to  get  approval  of  a  candidate  or  pro- 
gram by  an  appeal  to  the  notion  that  "everybody's  doing  it."  It  is  an 
application  of  the  adage  that  "nothing  succeeds  like  success."  The  aver- 
age man  wants  to  follow  the  crowd.  If  he  can  be  made  to  feel  that  a 
certain  cause  is  bound  to  win,  he  supports  it.  The  opposition  is  repre- 
sented as  hopeless  and  unpopular.  It  was  a  common  quip,  after  the  elec- 
tion of  1936,  that  Vermont  and  Maine  were  no  longer  in  the  Union,  and 


552    PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AKlD  CENSORSHIP 

their  representatives  in  Congress  were  jokingly  referred  to  as  ambas- 
sadors. After  the  election,  certain  newspapers  which  had  vehemently 
opposed  Roosevelt  during  the  campaign,  suddenly  found  him  to  be  a 
second  Jackson.  In  the  campaign  over  our  entry  into  the  second  World 
War,  the  interventionists  tried  to  show  that  only  a  few  poor  deluded 
ignoramuses  and  Fifth  Columnists  supported  isolation,  while  the  isola- 
tionists appealed  to  the  various  polls  to  prove  that  the  majority  were 
against  our  entry. 

In  all  propaganda  devices  there  is  a  strong  emotional  component.  This 
fact  has  been  emphasized  by  Professor  Miller: 

Observe  that  in  all  these  devices  our  emotion  is  the  stuff  with  which  propa- 
gandists work.  Without  it  they  are  helpless;  with  it,  harnessing  it  to  their 
purposes,  they  can  make  us  glow  with  pride  or  burn  with  hatred,  they  can  make 
us  zealots  in  behalf  of  the  program  they  espouse.17 

In  other  words,  the  propagandists  appeal  to  our  hearts  rather  than  our 
heads.  And,  as  we  have  pointed  out  above,  such  appeal  as  is  made  to  our 
heads  is  of  a  relatively  low  order,  so  designed  that  it  may  attract  even 
the  lowest  intellectual  level  and  the  least  literate  elements  of  our  popu- 
lation. The  propagandists  have  studied  our  mental  tests  and  have 
learned  that  at  least  half  the  American  population  falls  into  the  levels  of 
dull  normals  and  morons. 

To  supplement  this  list  of  basic  "devices  of  propaganda,"  the  Institute 
for  Propaganda  Analysis  has  enumerated  some  eleven  closely  related 
mental  processes  or  mechanisms  that  are  most  frequently  exploited  by 
propagandists  in  using  the  foregoing  devices.  These  processes  are: 

1.  Custom. 

2.  Simplification. 

3.  Frustration. 

4.  Displacement. 

5.  Anxiety. 

6.  Reinforcement. 

7.  Association. 

8.  Universals. 

9.  Projection. 

•  10.  Identification. 
11.  Rationalization.18 

We  may  illustrate  what  is  meant  by  these  mental  processes,  so  con- 
genial to  propaganda  activities,  by  both  foreign  and  domestic  examples. 
The  skillful  propagandist  builds  up  his  propaganda  in  terms  of  the  folk- 
ways, customs,  and  habits  of  his  own  society.  For  example,  Hitler 
builds  on  such  popular  German  themes  as  patriotism,  discipline,  loyalty, 
and  leadership.  In  our  counter-propaganda,  we  properly  stress  freedom, 
democracy,  and  liberty. 

The  more  simple  allegations  and  slogans  can  be  made,  the  more  effec- 
tive they  are.  Hitler  has  contended  that  Germany  lost  the  first  World 


17  Miller,  loc.  dt.,  p.  3. 

18  Bulletin,  "Propaganda  for  Blitzkrieg,"  August  1,  1940. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP    553 

War  simply  because  of  the  treason  of  Jews  and  Communists.  Opponents 
of  President  Roosevelt  contended  that  the  United  States  was  being 
wrecked  because  the  budget  was  not  balanced.  His  friends  asserted  that 
all  the  trouble  arose  from  the  fact  that  capital  was  ganging  up  and  con- 
ducting a  "strike  of  capital." 

The  frustration  of  the  oppressed  in  Russia,  Germany,  and  Italy  after 
the  first  World  War  made  it  easy  for  totalitarian  propagandists  to  capi- 
talize on  the  popular  psychology.  Hitler  made  particularly  good  use  of 
the  Treaty  of  Versailles  as  a  symbol  of  German  frustration  and  promised 
to  destroy  it.  In  his  first  campaign  for  the  Presidency,  Franklin  D. 
Roosevelt  exploited  the  sense  of  frustration  on  the  part  of  millions  of 
Americans  in  the  depth  of  the  depression  with  his  appeal  for  the  "for- 
gotten man" — forgotten  by  the  business  leaders  and  the  Republican 
party.  Mr.  Roosevelt's  own  sense  of  frustration  after  the  Supreme  Court 
battle  led  to  his  shift  of  interest  to  the  foreign  field  and  his  suggestion 
that  we  "quarantine  the  aggressors." 

The  displacement  process  resembles  "buck-passing"  and  the  search  for 
scapegoats.  Hitler's  use  of  Jews  and  Communists  as  scapegoats  to  ex- 
plain German  miseries  is  well-known.  After  the  second  World  War 
began,  Hitler  and  Churchill  regarded  each  other  as  the  sole  devil  in 
world  affairs.  When  the  French  and  British  failed  to  stop  the  Germans 
in  May  and  June,  1940,  they  turned  on  King  Leopold  and  made  him  the 
scapegoat  for  Allied  collapse. 

Propaganda  purposes  are  served  by  both  stirring  up  and  allaying 
anxiety.  Hitler  has  aroused  much  anxiety  abroad  by  his  Fifth  Column 
organization,  while  he  reduced  anxiety  at  home  by  his  treaty  with  Russia 
in  August,  1939,  which  removed  for  the  time  being  the  danger  of  a  two- 
front  war. 

Any  program  or  movement  frequently  needs  psychological  and  moral 
reinforcement.  Hitler  has  reinforced  the  Nazi  philosophy  and  program 
by  numerous  parades,  demonstrations,  and  education.  The  sense  of 
danger  in  the  United  States  was  further  stimulated  by  the  encourage- 
ment of  civilian  defense  activities,  and  anticipatory  preparations  against 
enemy  bombings  and  invasions. 

Association  of  ideas  is  used  for  propaganda  efforts.  Hitler  has  asso- 
ciated democracy  with  plutocracy  and,  at  other  times,  with  the  contra- 
dictory smear  of  communism.  President  Roosevelt  associated  promi- 
nent isolationists  with  the  "Copperheads."  (The  name  of  this  poisonous 
snake  was  given  during  the  Civil  War  to  Northern  sympathizers  with  the 
Southern  cause.)  After  Pearl  Harbor,  President  Roosevelt  happily  asso- 
ciated his  opponents  with  defeatism,  and  branded  them  "Sixth  Column- 
ists." This  process  of  propaganda  is,  obviously,  closely  related  to  the 
name-calling  device. 

The  use  of  universals  or  expansive  generalities  is  illustrated  by  Hitler's 
assertion  of  the  comprehensive  superiority  of  the  "Aryan"  race  and  cul- 
ture. A  more  noble  universal  is  President  Roosevelt's  ideal  of  the  Four 
Freedoms  as  a  program  for  world-wide  utopia. 

A  clever  master  of  propaganda  may  project  his  views  into  the  con- 


554    PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

sciousness  of  a  whole  people.  Hitler  created  a  Nazi  program  out  of  his 
own  convictions  and  then  imposed  them  upon  Germany  through  persistent 
propaganda.  President  Roosevelt  was  almost  equally  successful  with  the 
New  Deal  arid  preparedness  before  our  entry  into  the  second  World  War. 

Through  identification  of  a  program  with  a  person  of  great  prestige,  a 
large  following  can  be  gathered  and  great  repute  attached  to  the  move- 
ment. Hitler  built  up  the  early  Nazi  movement  around  the  personality, 
or  symbol,  of  Ludendorff.  Later  he  made  use  of  Siegfried  and  other 
heroes  of  German  mythology.  President  Roosevelt  secured  even  greater 
prestige  for  his  foreign  policy  by  identifying  it  with  God's  will.  In  his 
remarkable  speech  of  May  8,  1942,  Vice-President  Wallace  identified  the 
war  of  the  United  Nations  with  the  notion  of  a  crusade  for  humanity 
under  divine  leadership:  "The  people's  revolution  is  on  the  march  and 
the  devil  and  all  his  angels  cannot  prevail  against  it.  They  cannot 
prevail  for  on  the  side  of  the  people  is  the  Lord." 

Rationalization  is  a  process  of  congenial  self-deception.  For  example, 
Hitler  rationalized  away  German  defeat  in  1918  as  a  treasonable  Jewish- 
Communist  plot  and  disposed  of  German  mistakes  after  1918  as  wholly 
due  to  the  Treaty  of  Versailles.  Republicans  rationalized  their  timidity 
and  conservatism  from  1929  to  1933  by  holding  that  "deflation"  had 
worked  and  that  prosperity  was  actually  coming  back  around  the  corner 
when  the  New  Deal  drove  her  into  a  side  alley.  The  decay  of  the  New 
Deal  after  1937  was  rationalized  by  its  supporters  as  being  a  result  of 
the  malevolence  of  reactionaries  at  home  and  Hitler  abroad.18a 

Political  Propaganda.  We  may  now  review  very  briefly  certain  char- 
acteristic types  of  propaganda  in  various  fields  of  American  life,  mainly 
for  the  purpose  of  illustrating  the  diversity  and  potency  of  this  new 
force  in  social  control.  Let  us  first  turn  to  propaganda  in  politics.19 

Usually  several  of  the  propaganda  devices  are  used  in  a  campaign. 
In  the  campaign  against  the  New  Deal,  for  instance,  an  address  made 
under  the  auspices  of  the  Liberty  League  in  Washington  in  January, 
1936,  by  Alfred  E.  Smith,  combined  the  devices  of  glittering  generalities, 
card-stacking,  and  name-calling  by  insisting  that  the  American  people 
must  choose  between  the  way  of  Moscow  and  the  American  way,  laid 
down  by  the  Fathers  in  the  Constitutional  Convention  at  Philadelphia. 
There  was  no  suggestion  in  Mr.  Smith's  speech  that  the  philosophy  of 
the  Liberty  League  was  almost  as  far  from  that  of  the  Constitutional 
Convention  as  the  tenets  of  Moscow.  The  direct  implication  was  that 
the  New  Deal  was  following  the  pattern  of  the  Soviet  Union.  Mr.  Smith's 
speech  also  illustrated  the  fact  that  propaganda  devices,  to  be  successful, 
must  be  used  to  give  an  impression  of  factuality.  To  compare  the  New 
Deal  with  Moscow  was  so  absurd  that  the  Smith  speech  fell  flat  and  did 
not  provoke  the  secession  from  the  Democratic  party  which  the  enemies 
of  Mr.  Roosevelt  had  predicted. 


i8aWe  do  not,  obviously,  equate  Nazi  and  American  propaganda.    The  former 
is  evil  and  the  latter  is  good,  but  the  same  devices  and  mechanisms  are  used  in  both, 
10  Sec  F.  C.  Bartlett,  Political  Propaganda,  Cambridge  University  Press,  1940, 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP    555 

For  the  New  Deal,  Secretary  Ickes  and  Attorney-General  Jackson 
once  launched  a  vigorous  propaganda  against  monopoly,  as  a  barrage 
under  which  the  Administration  investigation  of  monopoly  could  proceed 
safely.  David  Cushman  Coyle  made  clever  use  of  the  transfer  device  by 
presenting  the  New  Deal  program  as  a  "national  or  human  budget,"  of 
far  greater  importance  than  any  mere  treasury  budget.  In  his  address 
at  the  opening  of  Congress  on  January  4,  1939,  President  Roosevelt  made 
a  very  effective  use  of  the  transfer  device  by  linking  up  the  New  Deal 
with  patriotism,  national  defense,  and  religious  idealism. 

The  resources  of  the  telegraph  for  mass  propaganda  were  first  made 
apparent  by  Father  Coughlin,  when  he  induced  thousands  of  his  radio 
listeners  to  deluge  Congress  with  telegrams  urging  it  to  vote  against  the 
entrance  of  the  United  States  into  the  World  Court.  Father  Coughlin 
became  generally  credited  with  having  thus  influenced  enough  Senators 
to  defeat  the  proposal  to  have  the  United  States  join  the  World  Court. 
Later  the  electric  utilities  showered  Congress  with  card-stacking  tele- 
grams when  the  Wheeler-Rayburn  bill  to  curb  holding  companies  was 
under  consideration.  In  this  case,  the  propaganda  was  rather  irrespon- 
sible, since  names  were  taken  at  random  from  telephone  directories  and 
signed  to  telegrams  without  any  knowledge  or  intent  on  the  part  of  the 
persons  whose  names  were  signed. 

In  the  drive  against  the  Supreme  Court  reform  bill  of  1937  and  the 
Administrative  Reorganization  Bill  of  1938,  Father  Coughlin  was  joined 
by  newspaper  columnists  like  Mark  Sullivan,  David  Lawrence,  Paul 
Mallon,  Boake  Carter,  and  Dorothy  Thompson,  and  by  powerful  pub- 
lishers, such  as  Frank  Gannett. .  They  urged  their  readers  to  put  pres- 
sure on  Congress  by  writing  and  wiring  for  the  defeat  of  the  bills.  Doro- 
thy Thompson  and  the  Scripps-Howard  newspapers  made  much  use  of 
name-calling  and  card-stacking  by  calling  the  Administrative  Reorgan- 
ization Bill  "the  Dictatorship  Bill."  Congressmen  were  deluged  with 
letters  and  telegrams.  The  period  has  been  described  by  Secretary  Har- 
old L.  Ickes  as  one  of  "mail-order  government."  Its  dangers  have  been 
well  summarized  by  Secretary  Ickes: 

The  danger  in  mail-order  government  must  be  apparent  to  all.  If  one  small 
but  none  too  scrupulous  group  could  stir  the  passions  of  the  unthinking  to  mobbish 
action,  as  was  done  in  this  instance,  other  groups  can  incite  other  mobs  on  other 
occasions.  The  right  to  petition  for  a  redress  of  grievances  and  the  right  to 
express  oneself  on  any  matter  of  common  interest  are  precious  rights  that  should 
be  jealously  guarded.  But  the  right  to  petition  Congress  is  based  upon  the 
presumption  of  a  thoughtful  and  informed  consideration  of  the  subject-matter 
involved.20 

It  may  be  observed,  however,  that  when  "mail-order  government"  got 
behind  the  interventionist  movement  with  which  Mr.  Ickes  was  in  thor- 
ough sympathy  after  1939,  he  found  it  eminently  satisfactory. 

Political  propaganda  has  gone  beyond  the  mere  matter  of  supporting 
or  opposing  particular  laws  or  political  policies.  Whole  systems  of  gov- 


20  Harold  L.  Ickes,  "Mail-Order  Government,"  Collier's,  February  18,  1939,  p.  15. 


556    PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

ernment  are  today  founded  upon  and  supported  by  propaganda.  For 
example,  the  government  of  Nazi  Germany  21  has  a  definite  Ministry  for 
Propaganda,  presided  over  by  the  remarkably  capable  and  cynical  Dr. 
Joseph  Goebbels,  who  has  openly  expressed  his  contempt  for  mass  intelli- 
gence and  has  shown  himself  a  master  in  manipulating  the  mass-mind. 
The  Institute  of  Propaganda  Analysis  summarized  the  methods  of  the 
Nazi  propaganda  in  its  Bulletin  of  May,  1938,  devoted  to  "Propaganda 
Techniques  of  German  Fascism."  The  name-calling  device,  which  ap- 
peals to  hate  and  fear,  was  utilized  in  the  denunciation  of  the  former 
Republic,  radicals  (all  of  whom  are  regarded  as  Communists),  liberals, 
and,  above  all,  the  German  Jews,  whom  the  German  people  had  been 
made  to  hate  as  the  cause  of  all  their  miseries. 

Use  was  made  of  glittering  generalities  in  arousing  the  patriotic  senti- 
ments of  the  Germans.  Much  was  made  of  vague  and  high-sounding 
words  such  as  "honor,"  "sacrifice,"  "leadership,"  and  "comradeship." 
An  appeal  was  made  to  the  historic  traditions  and  alleged  racial  purity  of 
the  Germans — for  example,  the  Nazi  slogan  of  "One  Race,  One  Nation, 
One  Leader."  Stress  was  laid  upon  the  fact  that  the  Nazis  worked  only 
for  the  common  good  and  the  deliverance  of  German  national  honor  from 
the  disgrace  of  the  first  World  War  and  the  Treaty  of  Versailles. 

The  transfer  trick  was  exploited  to  confer  prestige  and  reverence  upon 
Hitler  and  his  associates.  An  effort  was  made  to  invest  Hitler  with  the 
qualities  of  divinity.  The  prestige  and  authority  of  God  were  freely 
used  to  buttress  the  personnel  and  policies  of  the  Nazis,  with  regard  to 
both  the  domestic  program  and  foreign  policy. 

The  testimonial  subterfuge  was  copiously  employed  to  give  prestige  to 
Nazi  policies.  Thus  nothing  was  right  which  Hitler  did  not  approve, 
and  nothing  could  be  wrong  which  he  sanctioned.  The  propagandists 
then  saw  to  it  that  Hitler  conferred  his  blessing  upon  all  major  policies. 

The  plain  folks  strategy  was  used  to  give  the  Nazi  regime  popular  sup- 
port. Hitler  was  photographed  fondling  babies.  The  Nazi  leaders  were 
represented  as  good  family  men. 

An  elaborate  censorship  system  enabled  the  Nazis  to  make  wide  use  of 
the  card-stacking  device.  Only  those  things  could  be  said  that  the  gov- 
ernment wished  to  have  said.  The  country  was  thus  spoon-fed  and  the 
opposition  had  no  opportunity  to  correct  false  impressions.  Finally,  the 
band  wagon  procedure  was  thoroughly  exploited  in  great  patriotic  demon- 
strations like  the  Nazi  congresses  at  Nuremberg.  These  gave  the  impres- 
sion that  everybody  in  Germany  was  heartily  behind  Hitler  and  his 
policies. 

The  result  of  all  this  was  the  promotion  of  a  close  mental  unity  among 
the  German  people  and  the  development  of  a  common  front  in  favor  of 
Nazi  policy  at  home  and  abroad.  But,  at  the  same  time,  it  suppressed 
objective  thinking  and  thus  impaired  initiative  and  inventiveness. 

Fascism  has  many  supporters  in  the  United  States,  and  they  have 


21  See  below,  p,  582. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP    557 

profited  by  the  impressive  example  of  what  propaganda  was  able  to 
accomplish  in  the  destruction  of  democracy  in  Germany.  The  imitation 
of  Nazi  methods  by  American  sympathizers  is  considered  at  length  by 
the  Institute  for  Propaganda  Analysis: 

Today  in  the  United  States  there  are  some  800  organizations  that  could  be 
called  pro-fascist  or  pro-Nazi.  Some  flaunt  the  word  "Fascist"  in  their  name,  or 
use  the  swastika  as  their  insignia.  Others — the  great  majority — talk  blithely  of 
democracy,  or  ("Constitutional  Democracy")  but  work  hand  in  glove  with  the 
outspokenly-fascist  groups  and  distribute  their  literature.  All  sing  the  same  tune 
— words  and  music  by  Adolf  Hitler,  orchestration  by  Dr.  Paul  Joseph  Goebbcls, 
the  Reich-minister  of  Public  Enlightenment  and  Propaganda.  That  song  be- 
witched the  German  people,  as  the  song  of  the  Lorelei  bewitched  the  mariners  of 
antiquity;  it  lured  them  headlong  onto  the  reefs  of  fascism.  It  can  be  sung  with 
variations,  but  always  the  refrain  is  "Jew!"  and  "Communist!"23 

The  would-be  American  dictators  are  imitating  the  methods  of  the 
Nazi  dictators,  particularly  in  their  use  of  card-stacking,  testimonials,  and 
name-calling.  The  card-stacking  technique  is  used  to  make  the  words 
Jew  and  Communist  particularly  odious:  "The  American  Fascists,  like 
the  German  Nazis,  have  no  qualms  whatsoever  about  telling  out-and- 
out  lies,  misquoting  documents,  or  even  forging  documents."  Well-known 
Americans,  such  as  Chief  Justice  Hughes,  Matthew  Woll,  the  late  Mayor 
Hylan,  and  former  President  Garfield,  are  invoked  for  testimonials 
against  the  Jews.  There  is  also  card-stacking,  for  these  quotations  fail 
to  hold  water: 

It  would  be  impossible  to  identify  these  men  with  Jew-baiting,  and,  in  fact, 
the  quotations  cited  make  no  mention  whatsoever  of  the  Jews,  even  by  implica- 
tion. The  reasoning  of  the  Silver-shirts,  however,  is  something  like  this;  Garfield 
and  Hylan  attacked  the  bankers,  they  must  have  been  Jew-baiting  because  most 
bankers  are  Jews;  Justice  Hughes  said  that  voters  should  be  well  informed,  he 
must  have  been  attacking  the  Jews  because  voters  are  ill-informed  and  the  Jews 
own  most  of  the  newspapers  in  the  United  States.23 

As  the  editors  point  out,  the  card-stacking  technique  in  the  foregoing 
quotation  is  well  illustrated  by  the  fact  that  very  few  bankers  are  Jewish; 
that  only  an  insignificant  number  of  newspapers  are  owned  and  operated 
by  Jews ;  and  that  the  Communist  party  here  is  headed  mainly  by  Ameri- 
cans who  could  qualify  as  full-blooded  Aryans  in  Germany  itself. 

The  invariable  procedure  of  the  American  Fascists  is  to  resort  to  name- 
calling  when  they  are  attacked.  When  Dorothy  Thompson  assaulted  the 
Nazi  government  in  Germany,  the  Silver-shirts  asserted  that  her  real 
name  is  Dorothy  Thompson  Levy.  When  Governor  Alf  M.  Landon  of 
Kansas  attacked  Rev.  Gerald  Winrod,  alleged  leader  of  Fascism  in  that 
state,  the  charge  came  right  back  that  Landon's  middle  name  is  Mossman, 
which  proves  that  he  is  a  Jew. 

It  is  estimated  that  one  voter  out  of  every  three  in  the  United  States 
has  been  subjected  directly  to  Fascist  propaganda.  While  it  has  been 


22  Bulletin,  "The  Attack  on  Democracy,"  January,  1939. 

23  Ibid.,  pp.  2-5. 


558    PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

fed  out  directly  by  American  organizations,  it  has  been  shown  that  some 
have  had  direct  tie-up  with  Germany  and  made  use  of  the  tons  of  Nazi 
propaganda  which  were  being  shipped  to  this  country. 

After  1939  a  comprehensive  anti-Fascist  propaganda  was  developed  by 
interventionists,  some  of  their  organizations  having  high-sounding  titles 
like  "The  Friends  of  Democracy."  Their  intolerance  and  their  flagrant 
use  of  all  the  cherished  Nazi  propaganda  methods  gave  point  to  the  late 
Huey  Long's  prediction  that  Fascism  would  come  to  America  in  the 
name  of  "anti-Fascism." 

Propaganda  also  plays  a  dominant  role  in  foreign  affairs  today. 
Through  propaganda,  the  Fascist  countries  got  control  of  their  foreign 
policy  as  completely  and  ruthlessly  as  they  controlled  domestic  political 
policies.  All  news  going  into  and  coming  out  of  Fascist  states  is  thor- 
oughly censored.  No  foreign  correspondent  dares  to  challenge  this  cen- 
sorship if  he  hopes  to  remain  in  a  Fascist  country.  The  situation  in 
Germany  is  well  described  in  a  Bulletin  of  the  Institute  for  Propaganda 
Analysis: 

If  the  story  is  considered  unfriendly  to  Adolf  Hitler,  the  censor  may  warn 
the  correspondent  to  watch  his  step.  If  the  correspondent  persists  in  sending 
unfriendly  stories,  he  will  find  that  his  news-sources  are  closed  to  him;  party  and 
government  officials  will  refuse  to  speak  to  him;  government  bureaus  will  refuse 
to  give  him  information.  Later  may  come  expulsion  from  the  country.24 

But  progaganda  in  foreign  policy  is  not,  unfortunately,  limited  to  the 
dictatorships.  It  is  a  sad  fact  that  the  major  European  democracies  ap- 
parently collaborated  with  the  Fascist  countries  in  putting  over  on  the 
world  the  most  notorious  propaganda  hoax  in  the  history  of  diplomacy. 
We  have  reference  here  to  the  official  version  of  the  diplomatic  events 
leading  up  to  and  including  the  Munich  Conference  of  late  September, 
1938. 

We  were  promised  in  the  Allied  propaganda  during  the  first  World  War 
that  an  Allied  victory  would  put  an  end  to  secret  diplomacy.  Yet,  there 
seems  to  be  good  evidence  that  the  most  sinister  secret  diplomacy  in  mod- 
ern history  was  carried  out  by  these  former  Allied  powers  during  1938. 

When  our  historians,  after  the  first  World  War,  demonstrated  that  the 
Russian  diplomat  Alexander  Isvolsky  brought  about  the  War  through  a 
plot  to  secure  for  Russia  the  Straits  leading  out  of  the  Black  Sea,  the 
public  was  at  first  so  Stunned  as  to  regard  any  such  notion  as  utterly 
incredible.  Today,  this  plot  is  so  well  established  a  fact  that  only  the 
most  obtuse  "bitter-enders"  among  historians  refuse  to  accept  it  as  a 
commonplace  of  diplomatic  history. 

But  our  more  astute  diplomatic  historians  have  assembled  evidence 
to  prove  that  Isvolsky  was  a  "piker"  compared  with  Neville  Chamberlain, 
the  Cliveden  gang,  Montagu  Norman,  the  British  financial  Tories,  and 
their  French  stooges,  when  it  comes  to  secret  diplomacy  and  duping  the 
public.  It  now  seems  that  the  events  leading  up  to  the  Munich  Confer- 


24  Op.  cit.,  October  1,  1938,  p.  2. 


PREJUDICE,    PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP    559 

ence  of  the  end  of  September,  1938,  were  all  arranged  for  months  before 
by  the  British  Foreign  Office,  Germany,  and  Italy,  with  the  assent  of 
France.  The  doctrine  of  a  "Munich  plot"  to  betray  Czechoslovakia  and 
deceive  the  populace  of  France  and  Britain  is  well  set  forth  in  the  Novem- 
ber, 1938,  Bulletin  of  the  Institute  for  Propaganda  Analysis: 

In  brief,  the  story  is  this:  Last  May  [1938],  if  not  much  earlier,  Neville 
Chamberlain  decided  to  buy  Hitler's  friendship,  or  at  least  purchase  some  im- 
munity from  his  enmity;  and  to  do  this  by  the  sacrifice  of  Czechoslovakia.  It 
was  a  decision  beset  with  grave  risks  and  problems.  How  to  keep  France  and 
the  Soviet  Union  from  observing  solemn  treaties  and  rushing  to  Czechoslovakia's 
defense?  How  to  forestall  an  upheaval  in  England  itself  that  might  overthrow 
Chamberlain's  own  government?  To  meet  these  problems  called  for  the  highest 
talent  in  propaganda-diplomacy — card  stacking  on  a  titanic  scale.  The  peoples 
of  France  and  Britain  must  be  prepared  to  expect  the  horrors  of  war  at  any 
split-second;  and  events  were  so  ordered.  Then — presto! — in  that  darkest  hour 
came  the  Munich  Conference  in  which  Chamberlain  turned  what  appeared  to  be 
certain  war  into  "peace  with  honor."  It  was  all  planned  and  happened  according 
to  plan.25 

If  this  interpretation  is  true,  it  means  that  all  of  our  excitement  in 
September,  1938,  when  intelligent  Americans  were  momentarily  expecting 
a  European  war  and  were  feverishly  following  the  minute-by-minute 
radio  broadcasts,  was  entirely  unjustified  and  fictitious.  It  was  nothing 
more  than  stage-play,  which  was  carrying  out  the  last  phases  of  the  plot 
which  had  been  laid,  very  possibly,  as  early  as  March,  1938: 

According  to  this  explanation  of  "the  Munich  plot,"  from  the  moment  of 
Chamberlain's  decision  to  capitulate  to  Hitler,  what  happened  in  Europe  was 
mostly  "play  acting"  culminating  in  those  memorable  days  and  nights  when 
millions  of- Americans  listened  avidly  to  radio  dispatches  of  the  unfolding  drama. 
As  in  a  drama  on  the  stage,  everything  was  planned,  or  nearly  everything;  the 
fervent  speeches,  the  Runciman  report,  the  visits  to  Berchtesgaden  and  Godes- 
berg,  even  the  cablegrams  which  Franklin  D.  Roosevelt  was  persuaded  to  send 
Adolf  Hitler  and  Mussolini. 

All  this  was  arranged,  if  the  story  of  the  "Munich  plot"  is  true,  by  Mr.  Cham- 
berlain or  his  confidential  aides,  arranged  deliberately  to  stampede  public  opinion 
into  accepting  and  approving  the  Chamberlain  policy  of  appeasement  with  re- 
spect to  Rome  and  Berlin.  Troops  were  mobilized,  gas  masks  were  given  to  the 
peoples,  evacuation  of  Paris  was  begun,  trenches  were  dug  in  London  parks, 
armies  were  mobilized,  and  the  might  of  the  British  navy  was  gathered  in  the 
North  Sea.  German  passenger  liners  were  ordered  to  rush  back  to  their  home 
ports.  Everything  was  done  to  make  the  British  and  French  peoples  believe 
that  Europe  teetered  on  the  brink  of  war.26 

Not  only  have  the  brighter  journalists  and  more  alert  historians  ac- 
cepted this  interpretation,  but,  as  the  late  Paul  Y.  Anderson  pointed  out 


25  Op.  cit.,  p.  1.    Even  the  interpretation  of  Munich  given  in  the  above  quotation 
is  somewhat  misleading.    Czechoslovakia  was  not  sacrificed  by  Chamberlain  to  gain 
Hitler's  friendship,  which  was  already  assured  by  Hitler's  notorious  Anglophile  senti- 
ments.   Munich  was  "plotted"  to  strengthen  Hitler  for  the  attack  upon  Russia  which 
the  British  Tories  expected  him  to  launch  soon. 

26  Ibid.,  p.  2. 


560    PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

in  The  Nation,  it  was  accepted  by  many  in  high  official  circles  in  Wash- 
ington: 

One  encounters  a  deepening  belief  in  high  official  circles  here  that  the  Munich 
betrayal  was  actually  arranged  far  in  advance  of  its  public  announcement,  and 
thut  the  September  war  scare  was  deliberately  staged  m  England  and  France  to 
frighten  the  people  of  those  countries  into  acceptance  of  terms  which  had  already 
been  secretly  agreed  on.  That  hypothesis  would  serve  to  clarify  many  things 
which  have  puzzled  the  world.  The  failure  of  the  Germans  to  dig  trenches  in 
streets  and  parks,  to  issue  gas-masks  by  the  millions,  to  plan  the  mass  evacuation 
of  their  cities,  or  engage  in  any  of  the  spectacular  preparations  which  terrified 
London  and  Paris  is  understandable  if  Hitler  knew  there  was  to  be  no  war. 
Unlike  Chamberlain  and  Daladier,  he  was  under  no  compulsion  to  create  a  public 
opinion.  That  the  danger  of  gas  attacks  on  London  and  Paris  was  enormously 
exaggerated  by  the  government  is  now  admitted.  Gas  has  not  been  employed 
against  civilians  in  Spain  or  China,  for  the  very  practical  reason — upon  which 
experts  agree — that  gas  is  much  less  effective  than  explosives  or  incendiary 
bombs.  That  the  heads  of  the  British  and  French  governments  would  perpetrate 
such  a  monstrous  hoax  upon  their  peoples  is  a  horrifying  thought,  but  is  it  any 
lows  horrifying  than  the  final  betrayal?  I  think  not,  and  there  arc  others  here, 
far  more  important,  who  agree.27 

Another  hideous  world  war  has  now  broken  out.  The  foremost  pub- 
lic problem  of  our  age  is  how  to  interpret  it  accurately  and  soundly.  We 
have  new  methods  of  warfare  which  are  much  more  ingenious  and  efficient 
than  those  known  at  any  earlier  age.  Do  we  have  comparable  new  de- 
vices to  enable  us  to  ward  off  the  deadly  military  involvements  of  our 
age? 

Dr.  John  W.  Studebaker,  United  States  Commissioner  of  Education, 
believed  in  1938  that  we  did.  In  an  article,  "Can  Discussion  Muzzle  the 
Guns,"  issued  by  his  office,  he  suggested  that  the  press  and  the  radio,  with 
the  new  facilities  which  they  provide  for  discussion,  might  inform  the 
people  to  such  a  degree  that  they  would  be  able  to  move  effectively  against 
our  entry  into  the  war  while  there  was  yet  time.  War  could  no  longer 
sneak  up  on  us  unawares.  Dr.  Studebaker  used  President  Roosevelt's 
message  to  Hitler  and  Mussolini  in  September,  1938,  as  an  illustration  of 
how  the  radio  and  press  have  annihilated  time  and  space,  when  it  comes 
to  giving  the  public  information  on  a  great  world  crisis: 

Within  six  hours  from  the  time  a  typewriter  had  made  the  final  draft,  that 
message  was  the  topic  of  discussion  in  all  parts  of  the  civilized  world.  People 
heard  it  on  loud-speakers,  then  read  it  in  the  morning  newspapers.  This  strange 
and  yet  powerful  thing  we  call  public  opinion  was  feeding  on  that  message.  In 
the  time  that  it  would  have  taken  Paul  Revere  to  ride  less  than  100  miles  with 
his  message,  the  appeal  of  the  President  of  the  United  States  for  peace  went 
around  the  globe  and  became  a  part  of  world  public  opinion.  This  serves  merely 
to  illustrate  how  we  have  annihilated  time  and  made  it  possible  for  people  to  get 
an  accurate  and  exact  statement  of  an  important  message  together  with  clarify- 
ing comment  on  its  implications  for  peace  or  war.28 

Never  before  in  the  history  of  man  were  the  apparent  facts  of  a  world 
crisis  so  speedily  and  comprehensively  presented  to  the  public.  It  was  a 

27  Nation,  November  19,  1938,  pp.  52S-529. 

28  Op.  cit.,  pp.  1-2. 


PREJUDICE,    PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP    561 

moment  of  impressive  mass  education  on  the  most  critical  issue  of  the 
day: 

Historical  facts  were  marshaled  and  presented  to  us  in  order  that  we  might 
understand  the  background  of  the  situation.  Conflicting  opinions  and  views  were 
presented  from  all  parts  of  the  world.  The  issue  was  approached  from  every 
angle  and  sharpened  by  critical  comment.  We  learned  much  in  a  very  short 
time.  This  achievement  in  making  the  major  crisis  in  this  decade  vivid  and 
understandable  to  the  masses  of  people  calls  for  the  unreserved  praise  of  edu- 
cators. But  it  calls  for  more  than  praise.  In  my  judgment,  it  is  the  responsi- 
bility of  the  educational  forces  to  keep  the  discussion  going  and  to  prepare  for 
better  use  of  the  press  and  radio  in  organized  education  in  the  future.29 

Dr.  Studebaker  contended  that  we  must  not  only  make  sure  that  this 
sort  of  public  discussion  will  go  on  in  future  crises,  but  must  also  take 
steps  to  see  that  it  will  be  continued  in  the  interval  between  such  major 
disturbances.  We  must  understand  and  discuss  the  issues  which  underlie 
war  as  well  as  military  crises.  Otherwise,  the  latter  will  become  ever 
more  frequent  and  more  menacing. 

There  is  much  to  be  said  for  Dr.  Studebaker's  contentions,  but  the  actual 
technique  of  modern  mass  discussion  holds  within  it  grave  dangers,  as  well 
as  new  promise.  This  was  well  illustrated  by  the  very  crisis  of  Septem- 
ber, 1938.  The  public  was  quickly  educated  as  to  the  external  and 
superficial  events  of  the  crisis,  but  in  this  very  process  they  were  grossly 
deceived  as  to  the  fundamental  facts.  We  all  thought  that  war  was 
imminent  at  any  moment.  Now  we  know  that  it  was  a  fake  crisis  and 
that  all  the  diplomatic  maneuvers  were  only  stage  play,  designed  to 
deceive  a  gullible  public. 

Moreover,  it  was  hard  to  undo  the  damage.  Our  scholars  now  know 
the  truth,  but  the  masses  still  believe  the  "story  for  babes,"  as  it  came 
over  the  air  late  in  September,  1938.  There  is  no  way  whereby  the  real 
facts,  now  known  by  scholars,  can  be  set  forth  with  the  same  comprehen- 
sive effect  and  wide  publicity  as  was  the  stage  play  which  most  of  us 
accepted  as  accurate  at  the  time  of  the  Munich  Conference.  The  stage 
play  carried  on  by  Chamberlain,  Daladier,  Hitler  and  Mussolini  was 
spread  to  the  four  corners  of  the  world  by  the  press,  radio,  and  newsreels. 
The  striking  articles  of  Ladislas  Farago  and  Frederick  L.  Schuman, 
which  have  correctly  revealed  the  hoax,  are  hidden  away  in  Ken  Maga- 
zine, the  New  Republic,  and  Events,  and  other  excellent  magazines  read 
by  only  a  small  section  of  the  public.  This  illustrates  how  an  honest 
effort  to  inform  the  public  and  discuss  world  affairs  may  quite  unwit- 
tingly become  the  means  for  gross  misinformation  and  dangerous  decep- 
tion. 

The  events  of  1940-1941  revealed  the  pathetic  inadequacy  of  Dr. 
Studebaker's  hoped-for  safeguards  against  our  involvement  in  war.  At 
the  very  moment  when  open-minded  discussion  was  most  necessary,  it 
became  all  but  impossible.  The  press,  radio,  and  movies  were  heavily 
weighted  with  interventionist  propaganda.  "Name-calling"  was  rampant. 


™Ibid.,  p.  2. 


562    PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

Objective  analysis  of  the  real  issues  was  difficult,  and  it  was  all  but  impos- 
sible to  get  it  before  the  mass  of  the  people.  Hence  it  was  possible  for 
the  Roosevelt  administration  in  Washington  to  move  gradually,  step 
by  step,  on  the  road  to  war  and  to  block  or  undermine  any  serious  move 
for  peace.  Then,  when  the  final  crisis  came  on  December  7,  1941,  it 
dropped  on  us  with  such  speed  and  shocking  power  as  to  rule  out  any 
possibility  of  sane  discussion. 

The  most  appalling  aspect  of  the  power  of  propaganda  in  foreign  affairs 
is  its  current  effect,  now  that  the  second  World  War  has  finally  broken 
out.  The  propaganda  designed  to  involve  us  in  war  was  far  more  potent 
than  it  was  between  1914  and  191 7.30  Propaganda  methods  had  been 
much  improved  in  their  technique.  The  belligerents  had  more  and  better 
things  with  which  to  stir  up  our  emotions.  They  also  had  far  more 
numerous  and  potent  communication  facilities  to  make  use  of. 

When  the  first  World  War  broke  out,  the  propagandists  were  still  only 
amateurs  at  the  game.  But  after  1939  they  had  at  their  disposal  all 
the  lessons  about  successful  propaganda  they  learned  during  the  previous 
twenty-five  years.  This  material  had  been  gathered  together  in  sys- 
tematic fashion  by  Harold  D.  Lasswcll  and  others.  The  propagandists 
of  the  present  war  also  had  all  the  accumulated  skill,  experience,  and 
strategy  of  commercial  advertising  and  propaganda,  which  had  been 
mastered  since  1918,  to  draw  upon.  Hence,  "propaganda  technique  in 
wartime"  was  far  more  adroit  and  ruthless  after  hostilities  broke  out  in 
September,  1939. 

There  were,also  more  and  better  things  to  exploit.  In  1914-17,  those 
who  sought  to  propagandize  our  country  had  to  stick  pretty  closely 
to  Germany  and  the  Kaiser.  But  millions  of  Americans  were  of  German 
descent  and  the  Kaiser  was  a  highly  respected  person  in  this  country,  as 
late  as  July,  1914.  In  June,  1913,  William  Howard  Taft  had  called  him 
the  greatest  friend  of  world  peace  in  the  previous  quarter  of  a  century. 
Theodore  Roosevelt  said  that  the  Kaiser  aided  him  more  than  any  other 
monarch  in  promoting  world  peace.  Nicholas  Murray  Butler  outdid 
them  all  by  asserting  that,  if  the  Kaiser  had  been  born  in  the  United 
States,  he  would  have  been  made  President  by  acclamation  without  even 
waiting  to  be  nominated  and  elected.31 

Fascism,  National  Socialism,  Mussolini,  Hitler,  Japan  and  the  "Yellow 
Peril"  have  provided  far  more  numerous  and  effective  things  to  denounce 
than  Germany  and  the  Kaiser.  The  propagandists  of  1914-1917  were 
able  to  make  devils  out  of  the  German  people  and  a  gorilla  out  of  the 
Kaiser.  What  they  have  been  able  to  do  with  Fascism,  Hitler,  and 
Mussolini,  to  say  nothing  of  Japan  and  the  Yellow  Peril,  almost  defies 
rational  description.  And  they  were  able  to  do  about  as  well  with  the 
"Red  Menace,"  "purges,"  and  Stalin  before  June  22,  1941. 


30  See  Porter  Sargent,  Getting  Us  into  War,  Sargent,  1941. 
aiSee  The  New  York  Times,  June  8,  1913. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP    563 

If  the  propagandists  have  had  better  things  to  denounce,  they  also 
surely  have  had  far  more  varied  and  effective  agencies  of  publicity.  In 
the  first  World  War,  Lord  Northcliffe,  Sir  Gilbert  Parker,  George  Creel, 
and  their  like,  had  to  rely  almost  wholly  upon  the  printed  page  to  spread 
their  falsehoods  and  line  up  the  "suckers."  Today,  along  with  the  print- 
ing-press, we  have  the  radio  and  newsreels,  to  say  nothing  of  the  prob- 
ability that  television  will  be  extensively  installed  before  the  second 
World  War  comes  to  an  end.  Hence,  impressive  and  pervasive  as  war- 
time propaganda  may  have  been  during  the  first  World  War,  it  was  only 
an  amateurish  flurry  compared  with  what  we  have  had  since  the  second 
World  War  came  along.33 

In  order  to  combat  Axis,  and  "Fifth"  and  "Sixth"  Column  propaganda, 
information  agencies  were  set  up  in  the  Federal  Government  at  Washing- 
ton. The  most  important  were  the  Office  of  Coordinator  of  Information, 
under  Col.  William  J.  Donovan;  the  Division  of  Government  Reports, 
presided  over  by  Lowell  Mellett;  and  the  Office  of  Facts  and  Figures, 
under  the  direction  of  Archibald  MacLeish.  There  are  numerous  other 
cooperating  bureaus  and  agencies.  Strong  pressure  was  exerted  to  create  a 
supreme  head  of  official  information  about  the  war,  and  late  in  June,  1942, 
the  Office  of  War  Information  was  created  with  Elmer  Davis  at  its  head. 

The  first  important  propaganda  pamphlet  against  our  enemies  was 
issued  in  March,  1942,  by  the  Office  of  Facts  and  Figures,  and  was  en- 
titled "Divide  and  Conquer."  It  was  an  able  blast,  directed  against 
Hitler  rather  than  the  Japanese,  and  could  fill  Americans  with  pride  as 
they  realized  that  we  can  match  Herr  Goebbels  at  his  own  game.  Espe- 
cially clever,  adroit,  and  timely  was  the  masterly  use  of  the  card-stacking 
device  (p. ,  14) ,  in  listing  all  the  more  important  potential  arguments 
against  Administration  policy  and  then  attributing  them  to  Axis  sources. 
In  this  way,  critics  could  be  identified  with  foreign  propaganda  or  domes- 
tic defeatism,  and  thus  quickly  silenced.  The  technique  was  almost 
immediately  applied  to  Father  Coughlin,  and  it  brought  speedy  results, 
including  the  suspension  of  his  paper,  Social  Justice. 

While  our  attention  is  usually  directed  to  propaganda  carried  on  by 
war-mongers  and  munition  makers,  there  has  also  been  much  propaganda 
carried  on  for  peace.  This  may  take  on  all  forms,  from  the  dignified 
and  scholarly  monographs  issued  by  the  World  Peace  Foundation,  which 
was  created  by  the  late  Edward  Ginn,  to  the  spectacular  but  effective 
campaign  of  the  World  Peaceways,  which  put  on  peace  parades  and 
demonstrations  in  most  American  cities  of  importance  and  also  carried 
on  an  extensive  advertising  campaign  in  behalf  of  peace.  Incidentally, 
this  peace  campaign  was  financed  by  a  private  commercial  corporation, 
the  Squibb  Drug  Company,  which  sought  thereby  to  create  a  favorable 


82  On  propaganda  in  the  second  World  War,  see  Sargent,  op.  cit.;  F.  A.  Mercer  and 
G.  L.  Fraser,  Modern  Publicity  in  War,  Studio  Publications,  1941;  Cedric  Larson, 
Official  Information  for  America  at  War,  Rudge,  1942;  John  Hargrave,  Words  Win 
Wars,  Gardner,  Darton,  1940;  and  Harold  Lavine  and  James  Wechsler,  War  Propa* 
ganda  and  the  United  States,  Yale  University  Press,  1940. 


564    PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

impression  towards  Squibb  products  on  the  part  of  American  peace  lovers 
— a  clever  use  of  the  transfer  device. 

Propaganda  in  Business.  The  broad  field  of  business  probably  exploits 
propaganda  more  widely  than  any  other  element  in  modern  society.  We 
are,  of  course,  familiar  with  the  use  of  propaganda  in  every  type  of  adver- 
tising, whether  printed,  pictorial  or  vocal.33  In  commercial  advertising, 
especially  wide  use  is  made  of  glittering  generalities,  transfer,  testimonial 
and  the  band-wagon  devices.  Even  reverse  card-stacking  is  em- 
ployed. There  have  been  uncovered,  for  example,  malicious  whispering 
campaigns  against  manufacturers  of  certain  leading  brands  of  cigarettes. 
A  few  years  ago  the  whispers  suggested  that  one  prominent  tobacco  firm 
employed  lepers  in  making  its  cigarettes.  Another  whispering  campaign 
insinuated  that  a  tobacco  company  was  donating  money  liberally  to  the 
support  of  the  Nazi  regime  in  Germany.  There  was  not  the  slightest 
foundation  in  fact  for  these  whispering  campaigns.  But  investigators 
incidentally  discovered  that  there  are  actually  commercial  propaganda 
organizations  which  specialize  in  inventing  and  circulating  such  malicious 
rumors  and  gossip.  This  is  probably  the  lowest  level  to  which  propa- 
ganda has  fallen  in  our  day. 

Another  type  of  propaganda  in  the  field  of  business  has  been  the  attack 
of  reactionary  business  upon  the  New  Deal,  and  particularly  upon  its 
labor  policy.  The  card-stacking  device  has  been  exploited  in  the  oft- 
repeated  assertion  that  the  depression  was  really  ended  by  November, 
1932,  and  that  the  election  of  Mr.  Roosevelt  only  set  business  back  and 
retarded  recovery.  Equally  a  product  of  card-stacking  was  the  charge 
that  the  business  recession  of  1937  was  due  to  the  failure  of  the  New  Deal 
to  balance  the  budget.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  the  recession  was  hastened 
and  augmented  by  governmeYital  economies,  made  as  a  sop  to  big  busi- 
ness in  an  attempt  to  balance  the  budget. 

The  attacks  upon  the  labor  movement  have  made  a  clever  use  of  glit- 
tering generalities,  card-stacking,  and  the  testimonial  device.  The  glit- 
tering slogan  of  "the  right  to  work"  and  the  transfer  device,  the  "American 
way,"  have  both  been  invoked  against  the  CIO  and  the  Wagner  Act. 
Reactionary  industrialists  have  particularly  exploited  the  program  of  the 
so-called  Mohawk  Valley  Plan,  which  embodies  all  of  the  familiar  propa- 
ganda devices.84  Indeed,  the  whole  Mohawk  Valley  Plan  revolves  about 
the  substitution,  so  far  as  possible,  of  propaganda  for  bullets  in  battling 
labor  unionism.  Among  the  outstanding  tenets  of  the  Mohawk  Valley 
Plan,  originally  drawn  up  by  an  able  public  relations  counsellor,  are  the 
following:  (1)  union  leaders  are  to  be  denounced  as  radical  agitators; 
(2)  the  employers  are  to  be  identified  with  the  principles  of  law  and 
order;  (3)  the  citizens  and  police  are  to  be  organized  in  such  a  fashion 


83  See  Helen  Woodward,  It's  an  Art,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1938. 

84  The  term  "Mohawk  Valley  Plan"  arose  from  the  fact  that  the  program  was  first 
worked  out  and  applied  in  the  Mohawk  Valley  plants  of  the  Remington-Rand  Com- 
pany. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP    565 

as  to  bring  both  public  opinion  and  physical  force  to  bear  upon  strikers; 
(4)  much  publicity  is  to  be  given  to  a  "back  to  work"  movement,  indi- 
cating that  the  strike  is  failing;  (5)  the  "back  to  work"  movement  should 
be  staged  theatrically  at  the  proper  moment,  with  all  possible  publicity 
given  to  it;  (6)  news  should  be  manipulated  so  as  to  create  the  impression 
that  the  strikers  are  a  lawless  lot,  endeavoring  to  obstruct  the  right  of 
every  American  to  work:  and  (7)  as  much  publicity  as  possible  should  be 
given  to  the  assertion  that  the  strike  has  failed,  whether  this  be  the  truth 
or  not.  For  the  most  part,  employers  utilizing  the  Mohawk  Valley  for- 
mula have  arranged  to  have  their  publicity  handled  by  some  skillful  pub- 
lic relations  firm. 

The  counter-testimonial  device  was  used  by  the  Little  Steel  officials  in 
battling  the  Wagner  Act.  George  Sokolsky  was  played  up  as  a  syndi- 
cated columnist  in  a  number  of  American  newspapers.85  He  posed  as  an 
impartial  authority  on  labor  problems.  Hence,  what  he  wrote  against 
the  CIO  had  unusual  prestige,  as  presumably  an  authoritative  and  im- 
partial view  of  any  labor  question.  But  it  was  brought  out  that  he  had 
the  backing  of  the  National  Association  of  Manufacturers,  operating 
through  the  public  relations  house  of  Hill  &  Knowlton,  of  Cleveland, 
Ohio.SGa 

In  its  attack  upon  so-called  radicalism,  business  has  resorted  to  the 
name-calling  device,  as  well  as  to  the  use  of  the  counter-transfer,  by 
denouncing  anything  allegedly  radical  as  "un-American."  The  Dies 
Committee,  investigating  un-American  activities,  has  been  flagrantly 
guilty  of  name-calling,  transfer  and  card-stacking.  A  good  example  of 
the  latter  was  the  calling  of  Homer  Martin,  a  bitter  opponent  of  radicals, 
to  testify  relative  to  Communism  in  the  CIO. 

One  of  the  most  obvious  examples  of  card-stacking  in  the  whole  range 
of  contemporary  business  propaganda  is  the  following  paragraph  from  a 
speech  made  by  Bruce  Barton,  a  leading  advertising  magnate,  before  the 
Illinois  Manufacturers7  Association  on  May  12,  1936.  He  thus  tried  to 
rationalize  and  justify  the  inequalities  of  income  and  power  under  the 
capitalistic  system: 

Any  man  in  this  room  who  has  served  on  the  handicap  committee  of  a  golf 
club  has  learned  something  of  the  curious  involutions  of  the  human  heart.  The 
handicap  system  is  an  instrument  of  social  justice.  It  recognizes  the  hollowness 
of  that  ancient  lie  that  all  men  are  created  free  and  equal.  A  golf  club  knows 
that  all  men  are  not  created  free  and  equal.  It  knows  that  there  are  a  few  men 
out  of  every  generation  who,  by  native  talent,  are  able  to  play  in  the  seventies. 
That  there  are  a  few  more,  who  because  of  youthful  opportunity  or  self -sacrificing 
practice,  can  score  in  the  eighties,  that  a  somewhat  larger  number,  by  virtue  of 
honest  lives  and  undying  hope,  manage  to  get  into  the  nineties.  But  beyond  these 
favored  groups  lies  the  great  mass  of  stnigglers,  who,  however  virtuous  their  pri- 
vate lives,  however  noble  their  devotion  to  their  task,  pound  around  from  trap 
to  trap  and  never  crack  a  hundred.  If  the  handicaps  can  be  reasonably  fair 


85  For  an  appraisal  of  Mr.  Sokolsky  as  a  labor  expert,  see  Robert  Forsythe,  Reading 
from  Left  to  Right,  Covici-Friede,  1938,  pp.  122  ff. 
85aSee  Institute  for  Propaganda  Analysis,  Bulletin,  September,  1938,  pp.  65-66. 


566     PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

and  honest,  a  spirit  of  wholesome  endeavor  and  mutual  good  feeling  results.  If 
the  poor  players  are  unfairly  handicapped  they  will  protest  and  throw  out 
the  officers.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  the  good  players  are  too  much  burdened  they 
-will  not  compete.  The  management  of  the  dub  passes  into  the  hands  of  the 
dubs;  the  club  is  likely  to  lose  tone  and  eventually  break  up.36 

The  use  of  the  card-stacking  device  by  Mr.  Barton  in  the  above 
statement  has  been  clearly  exposed  by  Robert  A.  Brady,  one  of  our  lead- 
ing critical  experts  on  the  subject  of  propaganda: 

Tfc  apparently  has  not  occurred  to  Mr.  Barton  that,  however  satisfactory  he 
may  find  his  illustration  for  purposes  of  explaining  variations  in  human  ability, 
it  is  completely  inverted  when  applied  to  the  facts  of  relative  economic  oppor- 
tunity. There  is  a  handicap  system  in  business  life,  but  it  is  a  handicap  scheme 
not  for  offsetting  the  advantage  of  the  strong,  but  for  underwriting  it  against  the 
weak.  To  make  his  illustration  stick  [as  descriptive  of  the  capitalistic  system], 
Mr.  Barton  would  need  u  golf  club  where  the  players  in  the  seventies  were  given 
the  handicap  advantages  and  the  players  in  the  hundreds  had  handicaps  assessed 
against  thorn.  That  a  situation  analogous  to  this  obtains  in  business  life  is  so 
notoriously  true  that  Mr.  Harton  will  rind  no  one,  left  or  right,  prepared  to  deny 
it.  If  the  initial  argument  regarding  ability  gradations  is  no  more  than  naive, 
the  implications  drawn  from  it  are  directly  contrary  to  indisputable  fact.87 

An  interesting  phase  of  the  use  of  propaganda  by  business  has  been  the 
development,  during  the  last  few  years,  of  a  subtle  campaign  to  sell  the 
general  idea  of  big  business  and  capitalism  to  the  American  public.  The 
"message  of  business"  has  been  formulated  and  a  program  drawn  up  for 
putting  it  across.  This  message  has  been  very  well  stated  by  Bruce  Bar- 
ton: "Research,  mass  production,  and  low  prices  are  the  offspring  of  busi- 
ness bigness  and  its  only  justification.  This  story  should  be  told  with  all 
the  imagination  and  art  of  which  modern  advertising  is  capable.  It 
should  be  told  just  as  continuously  as  the  people  are  told  that  Ivory  Soap 
floats  or  that  children  cry  for  Castoria." 88  The  National  Association  of 
Manufacturers,  the  United  States  Chamber  of  Commerce,  and  other  or- 
ganizations of  business,  as  well  as  the  Ford  Motor  Company,  have  taken 
Mr.  Barton's  advice  to  heart  and  have  organized  skillful  and  comprehen- 
sive propaganda  programs  designed  to  sell  business  to  the  country.  The 
comprehensiveness  and  subtlety  of  this  propaganda  campaign  can  only  be 
comprehended  after  a  careful  perusal  of  the  articles  on  "Business  Finds 
Its  Voice,"  by  S.  H.  Walker  and  Paul  Sklar,  published  in  Harper's*9 

While  all  the  devices  of  propaganda  have  been  utilized  in  this  program 
of  selling  business  to  the  American  people,  special  use  has  been  made  of 
glittering  generalities  and  the  transfer  devices.  For  example,  one  of  the 
leading  slogans  in  the  propaganda  campaign  has  been  that  "What  serves 
progress,  serves  America,"  the  implication  being  that  big  business  renders 
an  outstanding  service  to  progress.  Of  late,  big  business  has  done  much 


36  From  The  Spirit  and  Structure  of  German  Fascism,  by  Robert  A.  Brady.    Copy- 
right 1937  by  Robert  A.  Brady.    By  permission  of  The  Viking  Press,  Inc.,  New  York 
Pp.  74-75. 

37  Ibid.,  p.  75. 

38  S.  H.  Walker  and  Paul  Sklar,  "Business  Finds  Its  Voice:  A  New  Trend  in  Public 
Relations,"  Harper's,  January,  1938,  p.  115. 

»8  January,  February  and  March,  1938.    See  also  Woodward,  It's  an  Art,  Chap.  20. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP     567 

along  this  line  of  trying  to  identify  its  policies  with  "the  American  way" 
of  doing  things.  In  so  doing,  they  have  been  helped  greatly  by  the  Dies 
Committee  investigating  so-called  un-American  activities.  Congressman 
Dies  has  been  just  as  much  interested  as  big  business  in  trying  to  identify 
progressivism  and  labor  unionism  with  things  "un-American," 

Big  business  has  made  the  most  of  the  facilities  of  the  press,  the  movies, 
and  the  radio  in  selling  business  to  the  American  public.  The  National 
Association  of  Manufacturers  syndicated  to  the  newspapers  a  daily  edi- 
torial feature,  known  as  "You  and  Your  Nation's  Affairs,"  a  weekly 
"Industrial  Press  Service,"  and  a  cartoon  known  as  "Uncle  Abner."  All 
of  these  stress  the  social  contributions  of  business,  the  virtues  of  com- 
petition, and  the  evils  of  government  interference.  The  National  Asso- 
ciation of  Manufacturers  has  also  issued  a  series  of  films,  among  which 
are  "The  Light  of  a  Nation,"  "Men  and  Machines,"  "The  Floodtide," 
"The  Constitution,"  and  "American  Standards  of  Living."  These  films 
are  designed  to  discredit  radicalism,  to  controvert  the  theory  that  ma- 
chines destroy  jobs,  to  denounce  government  spending,  to  defend  free 
competition,  and  to  extol  the  high  standards  of  living  enjoyed  under  the 
"American  way"  of  the  open  shop.  Nothing  is  said  about  the  fact  that 
three  quarters  of  our  American  families  could  not  buy  enough  to  eat 
under  the  "American  way"  even  at  the  height  of  the  Coolidge  prosperity. 
The  most  popular  radio  program  distributed  and  exploited  by  the  Na- 
tional Association  of  Manufacturers  was  the  "The  American  Family 
Robinson,"  which  extolled  the  virtues  of  free  business  enterprise  and 
denounced  the  evils  of  labor  unionism  and  governmental  interference.  In 
its  radio  programs  the  business  propagandists  make  special  use  of  the 
small  independent  stations,  where  they  escape  any  editorial  supervision 
and  find  great  willingness  to  use  the  material  supplied.3"" 

Another  effective  radio  program  in  behalf  of  big  business  was  the 
"Ford  Sunday  Evening  Hour,"  which  featured  the  talks  of  William  J. 
Cameron,  who  handles  public  relations  for  Mr.  Ford.  Mr.  Cameron 
made  clever  use  of  all  the  propaganda  devices.  By  use  of  the  transfer 
device,  he  identified  the  "Ford  way"  with  the  "American  way."  The 
plain-folks  device  was  much  utilized  and  Mr.  Ford's  homely  and  bucolic 
ways  were  played  up  frequently.  The  music  of  the  hour  usually  ended 
with  some  good  old  hymn,  popular  in  rural  areas.  Glittering  generalities 
were  employed  in  identifying  the  Ford  policy  with  such  virtue  words  as 
freedom,  independence,  initiative,  industry,  truth,  and  loyalty.  Card- 
stacking  was  resorted  to  in  attacks  on  governmental  interference.  Mr. 
Cameron  never  mentioned  the  fact  that  the  highways,  built  at  govern- 
ment expense,  have  enormously  facilitated  the  growth  of  the  motor  indus- 
try. The  Institute  for  Propaganda  Analysis  remarks  that  Mr.  Cameron 
implied  that  Mr.  Ford  is  so  little  interested  in  profits  that  "it  makes 
hard-fisted  money  makers  wonder  why  Mr.  Ford  is  in  business  at  all." 
Mr.  Cameron  was  particularly  insistent  in  his  contention  that  modern 


^  89a  por  the  extensive  educational  and  propaganda  activity  of  the  National  Asso-* 
ciation  of  Manufacturers,  see  Bibliography  of  Economic  and  Social  Study  Material, 
New  York,  N.A.M.,  1942. 


568     PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND   CENSORSHIP 

machines  do  not  destroy  jobs  and  create  technological  unemployment. 
In  short,  as  the  Institute  for  Propaganda  Analysis  puts  it:  "Mr.  Cameron's 
talks  stack  the  cards  in  favor  of  the  Ford  Motor  Company  and  against 
writers,  government  officials,  labor  leaders,  and  others  who  do  not  approve 
of  Ford  policies.  This  obviously  is  what  he  is  paid  to  do.  He  certainly 
does  it  effectively."  40 

Quite  naturally,  big  business  has  made  much  use  of  public  relations 
counsellors,  and  in  1934  the  National  Association  of  Manufacturers 
organized  a  Public  Relations  Committee,  which  has  taken  charge  of  its 
campaign  of  selling  business  to  the  public. 

The  institution  of  the  Public  Relations  Counsel  represents  the  most 
sophisticated  and  subtle  development  of  business  propaganda.  The  two 
most  distinguished  masters  of  this  type  of  propaganda  have  been  Ivy  Lee 
and  Edward  L.  Bernays.  The  success  of  the  public  relations  counsellor 
was  first  demonstrated  by  Mr.  Lee  when  he  was  engaged  to  alter  the 
public  attitude  towards  John  D,  Rockefeller  in  1914.  He  succeeded  in 
transforming  the  public  notion  of  Mr.  Rockefeller  from  an  avaricious 
ogre  into  a  kindly  old  gentleman,  chiefly  interested  in  giving  away  his 
fortune  to  establish  foundations  for  the  benefit  of  mankind  and  in  hand- 
ing out  dimes  to  little  children  in  Florida. 

In  promoting  personalities,  products  or  movements,  these  public  rela- 
tions counsellors  have  found  that  direct  and  blatant  propaganda  is  very 
often  more  harmful  than  helpful.  It  only  serves  to  increase  the  preju- 
dices already  in  the  minds  of  those  to  be  converted.  Therefore,  an  in- 
direct line  of  approach  is  formulated.  So-callecl  Institutes  are  created 
to  give  an  ostensible  voice  of  authority  to  the  interests  served.  This 
confers  a  sense  of  research  and  dignity  on  the  propaganda  which  is  issued. 
Even  reputable  scholars  are  employed  to  make  "studies"  which  seem  to 
support  the  contentions  advanced  in  the  propaganda.  These  are  inno- 
cently circulated  among  members  of  responsible  local  organizations, 
under  the  guise  of  information  rather  than  propaganda.  In  this  way, 
resistance  is  lessened  and  the  entry  of  propaganda  made  far  more  subtle 
and  effective.  As  we  have  noted,  the  public  relations  counsellors  have 
been  made  use  of  rather  extensively  of  late  in  attacking  the  labor  move- 
ment. 

Another  very  sophisticated  development  of  the  public  relations  subtlety 
has  been  the  endowment  of  foundations  by  the  rich,  as  a  means  of  re- 
habilitating their  reputation.  Much  publicity  has  been  given  to  their 
benevolences.  As  Horace  Coon  has  pointed  out  in  his  notable  book, 
Money  to  Burn,4*  endowments  have  become  a  potent  defense  of  busi- 
ness, since  it  is  alleged  that  all  attacks  upon  business  undermine  these 
humanitarian  organizations,  and  menace  the  research  and  education 
which  are  supported  by  endowments. 


40  "The  Ford  Sunday  Evening  Hour,"  Bulletin,  July,  1938,  p.  4.    The  Ford  Hour  was 
suspended  on  March  1,  1942. 

41  Longmans,  Green,  1938. 


PREJUDICE,    PROPAGANDA  AND   CENSORSHIP     569 

One  of  the  most  conspicuous  examples  of  business  propaganda  was 
that  carried  on,  over  a  decade  ago,  by  the  Electric  Utilities  under  the 
direction  of  the  National  Electric  Light  Association.  This  was  brought 
to  light  as  a  result  of  an  investigation  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission. 
The  propaganda  was  carried  on  primarily  to  check  the  trend  of  opinion 
in  favor  of  government  ownership  of  electric  utilities.  It  was  also 
sought  to  combat  the  idea  of  more  stringent  governmental  regulation. 
Special  stress  was  laid  upon  the  allegation  that  privately-owned  electrical 
utilities  furnish  electricity  at  a  cheaper  rate  than  government-owned 
systems.  This  campaign  of  propaganda  centered  particularly  upon  public 
education.  College  professors  and  school  teachers  were  offered  liberal 
subsidies  if  they  would  write  books  and  pamphlets  favorable  to  the 
electric  utilities  under  private  ownership.  Many  of  them  succumbed 
to  the  bait,  and  some  of  them  even  prepared  general  textbooks  on  eco- 
nomics approved  by  the  N.E.L.A.  It  was  agreed  that  the  cost  of  this 
propaganda  should  be  passed  on  to  the  public,  in  the  form  of  higher  rates 
for  electricity  and  other  increased  charges.  This  propaganda  has  been  de- 
scribed in  such  books  as  Ernest  Gruening's  The  Public  Pays;  Jack  Levin's 
Power  Ethics;  and  Carl  D.  Thompson's  Confessions  of  the  Power  Trust. 

Since  the  second  World  War  broke  out  and  the  United  States  entered 
vigorously  into  defense  industry,  business  has  taken  advantage  of  the 
psychology  of  patriotism  to  promote  its  interests  and  discredit  labor. 
Special  use  has  been  made  of  transfer,  in  exploiting  patriotism,  and  of 
card-stacking,  in  building  up  a  case  against  labor.  Business  has  accused 
labor  of  being  unpatriotic  in  demanding  higher  wages,  and  has  charged 
labor  with  having  sabotaged  defense  through  strikes.  Nothing  was  said 
about  how  industry  had  frustrated  defense  industry  through  prolonged 
refusal  to  suspend  "business  as  usual"  and  go  on  war  work;  nor  was  any 
publicity  given  by  business  to  the  fact  that  profits  had  grown  much 
faster  than  wages  in  defense  industries.41*  The  National  Association  of 
Manufacturers  engaged  Fulton  Lewis  Jr.  as  radio  commentator,  and 
made  clever  use  of  transfer  by  designating  him  as  "Your  Defense  Re- 
porter." 

At  times,  however,  the  public  may  directly  benefit  from  self-interested 
business  propaganda.  A  notable  instance  has  been  the  health  campaign 
conducted  by  the  Metropolitan  Life  Insurance  Company.  This  company 
has  conducted  a  beneficial  health  propaganda  with  regard  to  the  menace 
of  tuberculosis,  cancer,  syphilis,  and  the  like.  It  long  antedated  Surgeon- 
General  Parran's  campaign  against  venereal  diseases,  being  the  first 
organization  really  to  blast  public  indifference  and  prudery  in  this  field. 
It  has  also  been  helpful  in  urging  periodical  medical  examinations.  That 
this  propaganda  has  also  paid  the  company  handsomely  is  to  be  seen 
by  the  fact  that,  between  1909  and  1929,  the  Metropolitan  spent  $32,000,- 
000  on  health  propaganda  and  saved  over  $75,000,000  in  death  payments. 


41aSee  Institute  for  Propaganda  Analysis,  Bulletin,  "Strikes,  Profits,  and  Defense," 
April  29,  1941,  passim. 


570     PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

Propaganda  in  Religion  and  Education.  Propaganda  is  carried  on  in 
many  other  fields.  In  religion,  the  most  active  propaganda  of  late  has 
been  that  of  the  Catholic  Church  against  Communism.  Father  Coughlin 
has  linked  this  up  with  a  joint  attack  upon  the  Jews,  alleging  that  Com- 
munism is  primarily  the  product  of  Jewish  thinkers  and  leaders.42  He 
has  made  liberal  use  of  card-stacking,  transfer,  glittering  generalities 
and  name-calling.  The  New  York  Post  published  "deadly  parallels"  be- 
tween some  of  his  remarks  and  speeches  made  by  Propaganda  Minister, 
Goebbels,  in  Germany.  Likewise,  *thc  Catholics  have  led  the  most  active 
moral  propaganda  of  recent  times  in  their  drive  against  even  mildly  sala- 
cious aspects  of  the  theater,  movies  and  periodical  literature.  Catholic 
writers,  like  Margaret  Culkin  Banning,  have,  while  carefully  conceal- 
ing their  Catholic  connections,  written  clever  articles  and  books  uphold- 
ing the  Catholic  view  on  sexual  matters.  A  good  example  of  counter- 
propaganda  against  such  Catholic  propaganda  was  the  articles  by  Dr. 
Leo  H.  Lehman  on  "The  Catholic  Church  in  Politics,"  published  in  the 
New  Republic  in  the  latter  months  of  1938. 

In  addition  to  the  more  general  religious  propaganda,  there  arc  special 
religious  organizations  carrying  on  propaganda  to  advance  a  particular 
policy.  Such  are  "The  Lord's  Day  Alliance,"  which  has  carried  on  an 
extensive  propaganda  designed  to  perpetuate  the  "Blue  Sunday"  and  to 
prevent  saloons,  recreation  places  and  other  distracting  emporia  from 
remaining  open  on  Sunday.  A  powerful  type  of  combined  religious  and 
moral  propaganda  was  conducted  by  the  Anti-saloon  League  and  other 
organizations  in  defending  prohibition.  This  propaganda  is  well  de- 
scribed by  Peter  Odegard  in  his  book,  Pressure  Politics. 

In  the  educational  field,  Mr.  Hearst  led  a  vigorous  propaganda  against 
realistic  educators  for  some  years  following  1932,  making  wide  use  of 
card-stacking  and  name-calling.  He  alleged  that  a  number  of  highly 
reputable,  and  no  more  than  liberal,  educators  were  really  "Reds,"  subtly 
spreading  Muscovite  propaganda.  Mr.  Hearst's  campaign  received  a 
notable  setback  as  a  result  of  the  ingenuity  of  Clyde  R.  Miller  and  George 
S.  Counts  of  Columbia  University,  and  Robert  K.  Specr  of  New  York 
'  University,  who  out-generaled  Mr.  Hearst  and  exposed  his  methods  with 
fatal  effect.  But  his  propaganda  did  result  in  the  passage  of  laws  in 
many  states  requiring  teachers  to  take  loyalty  oaths.43 

Another  way  in  which  education,  especially  American  higher  education, 
is  directly  linked  up  with  the  vested  interests  and  their  propaganda  is  the 
support  of  private  universities  and  endowments  by  representatives  of  big 
business  and  finance.  This  enables  them  to  make  good  use  of  the  transfer 
device.  For  example,  at  the  dedication  of  the  Metcalf  Research  Labora- 
tory at  Brown  University,  on  December  28,  1938,  Frederick  G.  Keyes  of 
the  Massachusetts  Institute  of  Technology  warned  that  the  taxation  and 
public  spending  policies  of  the  New  Deal  were  a  menace  to  science  and 


42  Some  liberal  Catholic  leaders,  such  as  Cardinal  Mundelin  of  Chicago,  repudiated 
Father  Coughlin. 

43  See  below,  pp.  783-784. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND   CENSORSHIP     571 

American  higher  education.  He  held  that,  if  we  tax  great  wealth,  we 
shall  cut  off  the  chief  source  of  support  for  our  institutions  of  higher 
learning,  namely,  benefactions  from  the  wealthy.  In  his  above-men- 
tioned study  of  foundations,  entitled  Money  to  Burn,  Horace  Coon  has 
called  attention  to  the  same  situation  with  respect  to  our  Foundations  for 
scientific  research,  and  the  like.  He  points  out  how  any  important  pro- 
gram designed  to  bring  about  economic  reform  is  forthwith  assailed  as  a 
blow  to  science,  learning  and  humanitariamsm.  As  we  have  noted  above 
in  connection  with  the  N.E.L.A.  propaganda,  prominent  educators  at 
times  deliberately  sell  their  services  to  specific  economic  interests. 

Within  education  itself  there  are  powerful  propaganda  influences  and 
activities.  Perhaps  most  important  is  the  propaganda  in  favor  of  the 
traditional  and  archaic  curriculum,  which  is  safe  and  sound  from  the 
standpoint  of  the  vested  interests  in  business  and  education  alike.  Only 
a  small  portion  of  the  studies  pursued  under  this  system  has  any  contact 
whatever  with  our  social  and  economic  order.  Hence,  criticism  of  the 
latter  is  automatically  excluded.  Important  innovations  in  education, 
such  as  Progressive  Education,  vocational  instruction,  and  the  like,  are 
represented  as  so  many  expensive  and  useless  "frills."  Liberal  teachers 
are  accused  of  "indoctrination,"  a  matter  to  which  we  give  attention  later. 
The  most  publicized  propaganda  in  behalf  of  reactionary  educational 
interests  has  been  that  carried  on  during  the  last  few  years  by  President 
Robert  Maynard  Hutchins  of  the  University  of  Chicago.  He  is  not 
even  satisfied  with  the  safety  and  soundness  of  the  traditional  curriculum, 
but  advocates  going  back  to  the  medieval  disciplines  of  grammar, 
rhetoric,  and  logic.  He  makes  use  of  the  transfer  device  and  of  glitter- 
ing generalities  in  his  alleged  ambition  to  promote  "straight  thinking/' 
but  it  is  obvious  that  such  thinking,  however  "straight,"  will  not  be 
directed  toward  any  dangerous  criticism  of  the  existing  order.  His 
theories  have  been  thoroughly  applied  at  St.  John's  College.44 

Probably  the  most  notable  example  of  propaganda  in  the  educational 
process  is  super-patriotic  teachings.  Such  instruction  gives  the  impression 
that  the  institutions,  particularly  the  political  institutions,  of  any  given 
country  are  superior  to  the  institutions  of  any  other  country.  It  instills 
the  idea  that  such  a  country  has  always  been  right  in  its  dealings  with 
other  states,  and  has  always  waged  just  wars.  This  superpatriotic 
instruction  has  reached  its  most  absurd  expression  in  Fascist  states,  but,  as 
Jonathan  F.  Scott  has  made  clear,  the  democracies  have  also  been  notable 
offenders  in  this  matter.45  In  spite  of  the  warnings  afforded  by  the  first 
World  War  and  war  propaganda,  instruction  of  this  sort  has  become  far 
worse  since  1918  than  it  was  before  1914.  It  renders  almost  impossible 


44  See  article,  "Classics  at  St.  John's  Come  into  Their  Own  Once  More,"  in  Life, 
February  5,  1940.    President  Hutchins  is  not  a  social  and  economic  reactionary,  but 
seems  to  have  derived  his  paradoxical  educational  philosophy  from  the  occult  influ- 
ence of  Professor  Mortimer  J.  Adler.    See  the  articles  by  John  Dewey,  in  the  Social 
Frontier,  January  and  March,  1937. 

45  J.  F.  Scott,  Patriots  in  the  Making,  Appleton-Century,  1916;  and  The  Menace  of 
Nationalism  in  Education,  Macmillan,  1926. 


572     PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

any  objective  attitude  towards  either  domestic  political  institutions  or 
international  relations. 

One  might  observe,  in  passing,  that  even  certain  phases  of  the  salutary 
movement  against  propaganda  have  in  themselves  become  a  type  of  prop- 
aganda. A  good  example  is  "the  statistical  mania."  There  is  a  common 
tendency  among  certain  extreme  exponents  of  statistical  research  to  brand 
any  statement  which  is  not  made  in  the  form  of  statistical  tables  and 
graphs  as  propaganda.  Particularly  is  this  the  case  if  the  statement 
lias  a  liberal  or  progressive  tone.  We  should  all  have  proper  respect  for 
statistical  investigation,  which  is  the  basis  of  all  true  social  science.  But 
statistics  have  themselves  been  a  notorious  instrument  of  propaganda, 
justifying  in  all  too  many  cases  the  old  gag  that  there  are  three  grades  of 
liars — ordinary  liars,  damned  liars,  and  statisticians.46 

Another  form  of  protective  propaganda,  fostered  in  part  by  statistics, 
is  the  assertion  that  social  scientists  should  search  for  facts  and  then  stop. 
They  should  not  use  these  facts  as  the  basis  for  recommending  desirable 
social  and  economic  reforms.  Just  as  soon  as  they  do  this,  they  become 
propagandists  rather  than  social  scientists.  It  is  obvious  that,  so  long 
as  this  attitude  prevails,  social  science  will  be  "safe,"  and  will  not  upset 
the  existing  social  order.  This  "quietism"  in  social  science  has  been 
effectively  assailed  by  Robert  S.  Lynd  of  Columbia  University,  who  be- 
came well  known  as  the  author  of  Middletown*7 

Akin  to  this  is  the  propaganda  against  indoctrination  in  education. 
Certain  leading  educators  are  denounced  as  propagandists  because  they 
inculcate  a  definite  type  of  educational  philosophy.  It  turns  out,  in  every 
case,  that  these  men  teach  a  liberal  type  of  educational  philosophy. 
There  is  almost  never  any  criticism  of  educators  who,  even  more  dog- 
matically, inculcate  a  reactionary  form  of  educational  theory.  The  war 
against  indoctrination  thus  turns  out  to  be  little  more  than  subtle  propa- 
ganda against  liberal  pedagogy,  making  use  of  the  devices  of  glittering 
generalities,  card-stacking  and  name-calling. 

Propaganda  and  Democracy.  It  is  obvious  that  propaganda  holds 
within  itself  a  great  menace  to  democracy  and  liberalism.48  Even  in  a 
•  country  where  there  is  the  utmost  freedom  of  speech  and  the  press,  the 
exponents  of  democracy  and  liberty  are  at  a  great  disadvantage.  To 
carry  on  mass  propaganda  requires  large  expenditures,  and  the  wealthy 
interests  have  far  greater  resources  than  the  friends  of  democracy  and 
progress.  They  can  command  more  space  in  newspapers  and  buy  time 
on  the  air  much  more  generously.  Moreover,  such  censorship  as  exists 
in  the  United  States  in  time  of  peace  operates  mainly  against  democratic 
and  liberal  propaganda.  Further,  the  wealthy  alone  can  command  the 
services  of  the  great  geniuses  of  contemporary  advertising  and  propa- 


46  See  C.  A.  Ellwood,  Methods  in  Sociology,  Duke  University  Press,  1933,  Chaps,  ii, 
iii,  v,  vii. 

47  See  R.  S.  Lynd,  Knowledge  for  What?  Princeton  University  Press,  1939;  and 
H.  D.  Langford,  Education  and  the  Social  Conflict,  Macmillan,  1936. 

48  H.  D.  Lasswell,  Democracy  through  Publi-c  Opinion,  Banta,  1941. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP     573 

ganda.    From  the  outset,  the  cards  are  stacked  against  progressive  and 
democratic  propaganda. 

In  another  way,  propaganda  is  a  menace  to  democracy.  The  latter  de- 
pends upon  a  clear  command  of  the  facts  by  the  average  citizen,  so  that 
he  can  vote  intelligently.  But  our  contemporary  propaganda  either 
stimulates  and  intensifies  the  existing  prejudices  of  the  ordinary  citizen 
or  completely  confuses  him.49  He  has  no  adequate  fund  of  knowledge  to 
guide  him  amidst  the  overwhelming  mass  of  conflicting  types  of  propa- 
ganda. Nor  is  he  adequately  aware  of  the  devices  of  propaganda,  so 
that  he  can  effectively  recognize  and  discount  them.  At  the  very  time 
when  extensive  knowledge  and  clear  perception  are  most  needed  by  our 
citizenry,  neither  one  is  available,  and  the  mind  of  the  average  American 
is  simply  immersed  in  floods  of  propaganda,  much  of  which  is  deliberately 
designed  to  deceive  and  mislead  him.  The  nature  of  this  confusion  of  the 
public  mind  by  propaganda  was  well  illustrated  by  the  interventionist 
propaganda  in  1940-41.  The  polls  showed  that  over  80  per  cent  of  the 
people  were  opposed  to  our  entering  the  European  war,  yet  over  60  per 
cent  were  willing  to  give  all-out  aid  to  Britain,  even  if  it  involved  us  in 
war.60 

The  Problem  of  Censorship 

Nature  and  History  of  Censorship.  Censorship  is  the  attempt  to  im- 
pose restraints  on  the  expression  of  ideas  by  human  beings.  There  are 
mental  restraints,  often  self-restraints,  which  are  an  outgrowth  of  custom 
and  taste.  But  we  are  here  concerned  with  official  restraints.  These 
fall  under  three  main  headings:  (1)  obscenity  laws,  which  restrain  ex- 
pression with  regard  to  matters  of  sex  and  lewdness;  (2)  libel  and  slander 
laws,  which  restrain  expression  with  respect  to  persons  and  business  con- 
cerns; and  (3)  sedition  laws,  which  restrict  expression  in  respect  to  the 
government  and  public  officials.  In  addition  to  laws  restraining  ideas  we 
have  both  informal  practices  and  legal  regulations  that  control  the  publi- 
cation of  news  in  each  country  and  its  transmission  by  foreign  corre- 
spondents resident  therein. 

The  censor  is  an  ancient  official.  In  Roman  times  he  was  at  first  the 
collector  of  taxes.  Later  on  he  also  became  the  arbiter  of  public  morals. 
Following  the  invention  of  printing,  the  censor  became  an  official  who 
superintended  the  licensing  of  the  press.  Today  he  is  an  officer  who,  in 
one  way  or  another,  has  authority  over  what  can  be  printed,  produced  in 
the  theater,  shown  in  the  films,  or  broadcast  over  the  air. 

In  Greek  and  Roman  times,  books  were  rarely  censored.  Authors  such 
as  Aristophanes  and  Juvenal  freely  criticized  the  government  and  society, 
and  writers  like  Sappho  and  Ovid  produced  very  racy  material.  Occa- 
sionally, however,  an  author  was  banished  or  otherwise  punished.  In  the 


49  Ellis  Freeman,  Conquering  the  Man  in  the  Street,  Vanguard,  1940. 
so  See  Hadley  Cantrill,  "Present  State  and  Trends  of  Public  Opinion,"  The  New 
York  Times,  May  11,  1941. 


574     PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

medieval  age,  there  was  little  systematic  censorship  by  the  Church,  since 
there  was  no  serious  problem  in  keeping  dangerous  ideas  from  literate 
persons.  The  manufacture  and  sale  of  books  were  chiefly  in  the  hands  of 
monks,  although  some  secular  persons  engaged  in  the  book  business  in 
the  later  Middle  Ages.  Relatively  few  copies  of  any  "dangerous"  book 
could  be  made  by  hand  and  circulated  and  its  author  could  be  made  to 
swing  back  into  line  quickly  with  the  threat  of  excommunication  or  con- 
viction  of  heresy.  When  printing  came  into  existence,  however,  a  whole 
new  set  of  problems  arose,  since  thousands  of  copies  of  subversive  books 
and  pamphlets  could  be  quickly  struck  off  and  distributed.  The  answer 
to  this  challenge  to  pious  obscurantism  was  the  licensing  of  presses,  the 
preparation  of  indices  of  prohibited  and  expurgated  books,  and  the  im- 
position of  heavy  penalties  on  those  who  printed  books  without  a  license, 
who  sold  forbidden  books,  or  who  had  in  their  possession  outlawed  printed 
material. 

The  first  recorded  licensing  of  the  press  appeared  in  an  edict  of  the 
Archbishop  of  Mainz,  in  1485.  The  Council  of  Trent,  in  1546,  prohibited 
the  unlicensed  printing  of  anonymous  books  and  of  any  works  on  religious 
subjects.  In  1557,  the  Roman  Inquisition  listed  many  books  to  be  burned 
— beginning  a  long  series  of  prohibitions  issued  by  the  Catholic  church 
down  to  our  own  day.  The  Council  of  Trent  authorized  the  preparation 
of  an  index  of  books  forbidden  to  Catholics.  Pope  Paul  IV  published 
the  first  formal  Catholic  Index  of  Prohibited  Books  in  1559.  Pius  IV 
issued  a  much  more  complete  index  in  1562  and  threatened  with  excom- 
munication all  Catholics  who  read  any  of  these  banned  books. 

In  Protestant  as  well  as  Catholic  countries,  governments  imposed  severe 
penalties  on  those  who  sold  banned  books  or  operated  unlicensed  presses. 
In  Catholic  countries — in  Spain  and  the  Spanish  Netherlands,  in  particu- 
lar— severe  punishment  was  meted  out  to  those  who  merely  possessed  for- 
bidden books. 

The  general  effect  of  this  sweeping  and  stupid  censorship  was  greatly 
to  curtail  the  spread  of  information  and  the  progress  of  enlightenment. 
Protestant  countries  repudiated  censorship  most  rapidly,  and  hence  the 
disastrous  effects  of  censorship  there  were  not  so  serious  or  prolonged. 
Commenting  on  the  Catholic  Index  and  censorship,  Preserved  Smith 
makes  the  very  restrained  statement  that: 

It  is  not  too  much  to  say  that  most  of  the  important  works  of  modern  science, 
philosophy  and  learning,  and  not  a  few  of  the  chief  products  of  Catholic  piety, 
have  been  forbidden  by  the  church  as  dangerous  to  the  faith  of  her  children; 
and  that,  in  addition,  many  of  the  ornaments  of  fair  letters  have  been  tampered 
with  in  order  to  protect  the  sensitive  pride  of  ecclesiastics  or  the  squeamish 
prudery  of  priests.  .  .  .  That  servile  faith,  bigotry,  and  obscurantism  have  been 
fostered,  and  that  science,  philosophy,  and  liberty  were  long  sorely  hampered 
in  Catholic  lands,  is  due  to  the  Index  even  more  than  to  the  Inquisition.51 

The  more  liberal  intellects  in  the  seventeenth  and  eighteenth  centuries 
fought  vigorously  against  the  censorship  of  the  press.  Among  the  writers 

ci  History  of  Modern  Culture,  Holt,  1930,  Vol.  I,  pp.  51S-514. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND   CENSORSHIP     575 

who  took  a  leading  part  in  the  campaign  were  John  Milton,  Charles 
Blount;  Matthew  Tindal,  and  the  leading  French  Philosophcs,  such  as 
Montesquieu,  Voltaire,  and  Helvetius.  It  is  pretty  generally  conceded 
that  Milton's  Areopagitica  was  the  ablest  of  all  these  early  books  against 
censorship,  yet  Milton  consented  to  acting  as  something  pretty  close  to  a 
censor  for  his  friend  Oliver  Cromwell.  In  the  United  States,  the  cause 
of  the  freedom  of  the  press  was  taken  up  by  Thomas  Jefferson  and  his 
associates.  Notable  free  press  cases,  such  as  the  Zenger  case  in  the 
Colony  of  New  York  in  1734,  and  the  John  Wilkes  case  in  England  over 
a  generation  later,  helped  along  the  cause  of  the  freedom  of  the  press. 
Holland  was  generally  free  from  censorship  in  an  era  when  it  was  almost 
universal  elsewhere.  England  permitted  the  law  providing  for  the  licens- 
ing of  the  press  to  lapse  in  1695.  Sweden  abolished  all  censorship  in 
1766.  Frederick  the  Great  accorded  wide  freedom  to  the  press,  even  to 
books  attacking  the  monarch  himself. 

While  there  never  was  complete  tolerance  and  freedom  of  the  press,  it 
is  probable  that  the  greatest  degree  of  freedom  existed  in  the  United 
States  around  1850,  and  in  the  Third  French  Republic  between  1880  and 
1914.  About  1850,  there  were  as  yet  no  obscenity  laws  on  the  books  in 
the  United  States,  the  old  religious  and  property  disabilities  had  been 
abolished,  and  the  right  of  debate  and  petition  was  freely  recognized. 
Many  of  the  most  distinguished  American  literati  were  followers  of 
Fourier  and  other  European  radical  idealists.  The  New  York  Tribune, 
under  Horace  Greeley,  was  a  radical  and  reformist  sheet.  A  little  later, 
Greeley  employed  Karl  Marx  as  his  European  correspondent.  Abraham 
Lincoln  declared  that  the  international  bond  of  the  workingman  is  more 
sacred  and  binding  than  any  other  save  the  family  bond,  and  William 
Henry  Seward  was  talking  about  a  "higher  law  than  the  Constitution." 
After  the  Civil  War,  the  growth  of  plutocracy  lessened  the  scope  of  free 
expression  in  the  United  States.  Economic  dissent  was  discouraged,  and 
suppressed  when  possible. 

In  France,  under  the  Third  Republic,  anticlericalism  became  domi- 
nant, and  fimilc  Zola,  in  his  realistic  portraits  of  life,  made  moral  candor 
more  facile  and  reputable.  On  the  other  hand,  such  episodes  as  the 
Dreyfus  case  showed  that  French  liberty  was  by  no  means  complete. 

Aside  from  certain  obscenity  statutes  in  the  United  States,  to  which 
we  shall  soon  make  reference,  the  press  remained  relatively  uncensored 
until  the  time  of  the  first  World  War.  Then,  there  arose  an  almost 
universal  system  of  thorough-going  censorship.  After  the  first  World 
War,  the  censorship  was  relaxed  to  a  certain  degree  but  freedom  of  publi- 
cation was  never  fully  restored.  With  the  rise  of  totalitarian  states,  since 
the  first  World  War,  there  has  come  a  degree  of  peace-time  censorship 
about  as  stringent  as  that  which  existed  during  the  first  World  War.  To 
this  subject  we  shall  recur  later  on. 

There  is,  today,  little  literary  pre-censorship  in  the  United  States, 
namely  censorship  of  books  or  newspapers  before  printing.  Hence  it  has 
been  contended  by  some  that  there  is  no  censorship  of  printed  materials. 


576     PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

As  we  shall  see  later  on,  there  is  plenty  of  censorship  in  advance  of  pub- 
lication in  most  of  the  European  countries.  Certain  forms  of  pre-censor- 
ship  exist  in  the  United  States.  There  is  a  considerable  amount  of  pre- 
censorship  of  radio  speeches  and  a  vast  amount  of  pre*- censor  ship  in  the 
moving-picture  industry.  To  these  matters  we  shall  make  more  extended 
reference  later  on. 

Leading  Types  of  Censors.  There  are  today  in  the  United  States 
various  types  of  censors.  First  we  have  the  voluntary,  unofficial  censors, 
persons  who  use  their  freedom  of  expression  in  an  attempt  to  suppress  the 
use  of  this  right  by  persons  whose  ideas  they  do  not  approve.  Protesting 
against  some  printed  material;  play,  or  movie  they  do  not  like,  they  go 
to  legislators  and  demand  censorship  laws,  or  approach  the  police  and 
importune  the  latter  to  arrest  a  publisher  or  close  a  theater.  While  these 
censors  have  no  official  authority,  they  exert  a  considerable  pressure  upon 
the  free  expression  of  opinion  by  frightening  authors,  producers,  public 
speakers,  and  forum  authorities. 

Then  we  have  the  semi-official  censors,  namely,  private  individuals  or 
organizations  who  work  in  collaboration  with  the  public  authorities. 
Notable  examples  are  the  New  York  Society  for  the  Suppression  of  Vice, 
founded  by  the  late  Anthony  Comstock  in  New  York  City,  and  the  Watch 
and  Ward  Society  of  Boston.  They  bring  materials  which  they  believe 
should  be  censored  to  the  attention  of  public  authorities  and  obtain  special 
privileges  in  the  courts  in  aiding  the  prosecutors.  Another  form  of  semi- 
official censorship  exists  in  connection  with  the  central  bureaus  of 
publicity,  which  were  set  up  in  the  cabinet  departments  at  Washington 
during  the  first  World  War  and  have  been  continued  since  that  time. 
They  thoroughly  control  the  information  which  is  given  out  about  the 
doings  of  the  government. 

Official  censors  in  the  states  include  the  police,  commissioners  of  licenses, 
educational  departments,  and  moving  picture  censors.  In  the  federal 
government,  wide  censorship  powers  are  lodged  with  the  Post  Office  De- 
partment, Customs  House  officials,  the  Federal  Communications  Commis- 
sion, and  certain  other  agencies.  The  most  important  is  the  censorship 
exerted  by  the  Post  Office  Department.  The  latter  can  deny  the  use  of 
the  mails  to  materials  it  does  not  think  proper.  It  can  also  suggest  the 
prosecution  of  those  who  use  the  mails  to  send  materials  which  the  Post 
Office  Department  regards  as  improper  and  forbidden.  It  has  made  wide 
use  of  the  Comstock  Law  of  1873  to  deny  the  use  of  the  mails  to  such 
literature  as  birth-control  information  and  educational  and  sociological 
material  on  sex  problems.  It  has  also  restrained  radical  publications 
which  possess  no  suspicion  of  obscenity.  For  example,  it  denied  mailing 
privileges  to  Jay  Lovestone's  paper  the  "Revolutionary  Age."  And  the 
action  was  upheld  by  the  same  Federal  judge,  John  Munro  Woolsey, 
who  had  shown  a  surprising  liberality  with  books  which  were  alleged  to 
be  obscene.  The  Post  Office  Department  can  thus  exert  a  great  restraint 
upon  what  the  public  may  read  in  all  cases  where  distribution  is  chiefly 
dependent  upon  the  mails.  The  Customs  House  officials  decide  what 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP     577 

books  may  be  admitted  from  abroad.  The  appointment  of  a  brilliant 
liberal  lawyer,  Huntington  Cairns,  to  handle  this  phase  of  Customs  House 
activities  under  the  Roosevelt  Administration  did  much  to  promote  an 
intelligent  administration  of  this  responsibility. 

Censorship  of  Books,  the  Theater,  and  Art.  It  is  usually  taken  for 
granted  that  legislation  against  obscene  literature  52  and  plays  is  abso- 
lutely necessary  to  protect  the  public  against  demoralization.  However, 
there  were  no  obscenity  laws  in  the  United  States  until  after  1870.  Yet 
the  country  seemed  to  endure,  and  there  was  no  evidence  of  a  demoralizing 
wave  of  obscenity  anywhere.  In  the  decade  of  the  'seventies,  federal 
obscenity  statutes  were  passed,  mainly  owing  to  the  propaganda  of  An- 
thony Comstock,  the  first  great  American  purist.  His  life  and  doings 
have  been  chronicled  by  Heywood  Broun  and  Margaret  Leech  in  their 
work,  Anthony  Comstock:  Roundsman  of  the  Lord.  The  federal  and 
state  legislation  on  this  matter  has  imposed  frequent  and  extensive 
censorship  of  books,  pamphlets,  and  other  publications  alleged  to  contain 
obscene  material.  The  test  of  obscenity  is  the  alleged  primary  purpose 
of  any  publication  "to  incite  to  lustful  and  lecherous  desire." 

At  present  there  is  no  sure  test  or  pre-censorship  of  a  publication  to 
give  the  author  and  publisher  assurance  that  it  will  not  be  regarded  as 
obscene.  The  procedure  is  to  print  the  material,  await  arrest,  stand  trial, 
and  await  the  verdict.  If  there  is  an  acquittal,  the  publication  is  regarded 
as  pure.  If  there  is  a  conviction,  it  is  deemed  obscene. 

For  a  long  time,  publications  were  suppressed  as  obscene  when  isolated 
passages  alone  were  alleged  to  possess  obscene  words,  even  if  the  work  as 
a  whole  was  admittedly  not  obscene.  A  broader  and  more  sensible  test 
was  later  set  up  by  the  Court  of  Appeals  in  New  York  State,  which  ruled 
that  a  book  could  not  be  banned  just  because,  here  and  there,  in  its  con- 
tents there  were  alleged  obscene  words  or  phrases.  The  nature  and 
import  of  the  book  as  a  whole  must  be  obscene,  if  it  is  to  be  banned  as 
such.  Yet  this  enlightened  ruling  has  produced  neither  consistency  nor 
common  sense  in  censorship.  Erskine  Caldwell's  racy  and  irreverent 
God's  Little  Acre  was  allowed  to  circulate,  while  Arthur  Schnitzler's 
much  more  refined  Hands  Around  was  banned. 

The  most  active  organization  in  attempting  to  promote  prosecutions 
for  obscenity  has  been  the  New  York  Society  for  the  Suppression  of  Vice, 
founded  by  Anthony  Comstock  and  supported  liberally  by  J.  P.  Morgan 
and  other  wealthy  citizens.  In  our  generation,  it  has  been  conducted  by 
John  S.  Sumner.  It  is  this  Society  which  has  been  responsible  for  the 
greatest  proportion  of  the  obscenity  censorship  in  the  United  States.  Most 
of  the  publications  and  plays  which  have  been  censored  have  been  brought 
to  the  attention  of  the  public  authorities  by  Mr.  Comstock  and  Mr. 
Sumner,  who  demanded  summary  prosecution.  This  may  all  be  fit  and 
proper,  but  the  Society  has  been  allowed  to  exert  an  altogether  improper 


52  For  attempts  to  censor  literature,  see  M.  L.  Ernst  and  Alexander  Lindey,  The 
Censor  Marches  On,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1940,  Chaps.  I-III. 


578     PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND   CENSORSHIP 

influence  upon  the  trial  of  authors  and  publishers  prosecuted  on  its 
initiative.53 

The  Society  for  the  Suppression  of  Vice  has  from  time  to  time  given  out 
advance  opinion  on  the  fitness  of  judges,  when  their  nomination  and 
election  are  under  consideration.  In  this  way  it  has  sought  to  keep  off 
the  bench  judges  with  whom  it  disagrees  on  what  is  or  is  not  obscene. 
Moreover,  its  representative  during  obscenity  trials  has  been  allowed 
about  as  much  latitude  in  court  as  though  he  were  the  prosecuting  attor- 
ney. It  has  even  branded  some  judges  as  being  themselves  fond  of 
obscenity  and  willing  to  promote  the  demoralization  of  the  public.  Many 
judges  fear  such  criticism  and  hence  have  been  reluctant  to  apply  to 
Mr.  Sumner  the  restrictions  which  could  be  easily  imposed  under  the 
concept  of  contempt  of  court. 

The  usual  way  in  which  publishers  dealt  with  the  Society's  inquisition, 
after  it  had  brought  a  book  to  the  attention  of  authorities,  was  to  plead 
guilty  and  take  a  light  fine,  after  agreeing  to  withdraw  the  book  from 
publication. 

However,  Morris  L.  Ernst,  a  brilliant  and  progressive  New  York 
attorney  (and  co-author  of  a  notable  book  on  obscenity  censorship,  To 
the  Pure)  j  determined  to  fight  out  obscenity  cases  with  the  Society.  He 
started  his  campaign  with  the  case  of  Mary  Ware  Dennett's  able  and 
dignified  pamphlet,  The  Sex  Side  of  Life,  in  1929.  He  carried  the  case 
to  the  Federal  Court,  and  Judges  Hand,  Swan,  and  Chase  ordered  the 
book  released  by  the  Post  Office  Department  and  also  praised  its  contents. 
Ernst  has  since  won  his  point  in  the  case  of  a  number  of  books  which 
authorities  have  since  attempted  to  suppress,  such  as  Pay  Day,  Married 
Love,  Contraception,  Female,  A  World  I  Never  Made,  and  Ulysses.  He 
was  also  able,  in  1936,  to  get  the  Federal  Court,  for  all  practical  purposes, 
to  sot  aside  the  Comstock  Law  of  1873  banning  the  mailing  of  material 
containing  birth-control  information  and  devices. 

The  Watch  and  Ward  Society  of  Boston  attempted  to  imitate  the  work 
of  the  New  York  Society  for  the  Suppression  of  Vice.  But  the  Watch 
and  Ward  overshot  the  mark  in  attempting  to  suppress  the  April,  1926, 
issue  of  The  American  Mercury.  The  upstanding  editor,  H.  L.  Mencken, 
went  personally  to  Boston,  fought  out  the  case,  and  gained  a  victory  in 
the  court.5*  The  Watch  and  Ward  Society  was  further  discredited  by 
its  irresponsible  use  of  stool-pigeons  in  attempting  to  incriminate  book 
stores  in  the  Boston  area. 

As  with  books,  there  is  no  pre-censorship  of  the  theater.  The  producer 
simply  has  to  put  on  his  play  and  then  see  what  Mr.  Sumner,  the  Watch 
and  Ward  Society,  the  mayor,  or  the  police  think  about  it.  If  the  latter 
regard  it  as  obscene,  the  play  is  suppressed.  In  the  suppression  of  plays, 
the  censors  have  gone  to  an  extreme  not  achieved  in  censoring  books  and 
pamphlets.  They  have,  in  certain  places,  secured  the  right  to  padlock  a 


68  See  Ernst  and  Lindey,  The  Censor  Marches  On,  passim. 

e^See  A.  G.  Hays,  Let  Freedom  Ring,  Boni  &  Liveright,  1929,  pp.  160  ff. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP     579 

theater,  thus  denying  the  author  and  producer  the  right  of  trial  by  jury. 
In  certain  cities,  the  commissioner  of  licenses  is  able  to  bulldoze  producers 
by  holding  over  them  the  threat  of  a  revocation  of  the  license  of  the 
theater.  Religious  influences  have  been  also  strong  in  promoting  theater 
censorship.  The  humor  and  inconsistency  which  prevail  in  theater  cen- 
sorship may  be  seen  from  the  fact  that  Mayor  Edward  Kellcy  of  Chicago 
freely  permits  burlesque  and  strip-tease  to  ply  their  trade  in  Chicago, 
but  was  inexpressibly  shocked  by  "Tobacco  Road,"  which  he  promptly 
suppressed.  On  the  other  hand,  "Tobacco  Road"  ran  in  New  York  all 
through  Fiorello  La  Guardia's  first  two  terms  as  mayor,  but  he  clamped 
down  on  "strip-tease,"  the  only  bit  of  art  that  burlesque  has  ever  provided. 
The  extreme  to  which  theater  censorship  has  gone  at  times  can  be  seen 
in  the  refusal  to  allow  such  serious  plays  as  Eugene  O'Neill's  "Desire 
Under  the  Elms"  and  "Strange  Interlude"  to  be  shown  in  Boston,  the 
alleged  "Athens  of  America,"  at  the  same  time  that  the  utmost  freedom 
was  given  to  wide-open  burlesque  shows. 

There  have  been  extensive  efforts  to  censor  art  on  the  ground  of  ob- 
scenity.05 The  first  much-publicized  case  was  Anthony  Comstock's 
attack  on  "September  Morn,"  an  extremely  chaste  and  frigid  nude,  in 
1913.  His  successor,  Mr.  Sumner,  in  1930,  attempted  to  restrain  a 
gallery  which  was  exhibiting  classic  pictures  by  Rembrandt  and  Goya. 
The  Post  Office  has  also  taken  a  hand,  as,  for  example,  when  it  revoked 
the  second-class  mailing  permit  of  the  serious  Studio  magazine  in  1939 
for  carrying  some  classics  of  art.  Nudism  has  been  vigorously  attacked. 
The  Nudist  magazine  was  suppressed  and  the  importation  of  nudist  books 
from  abroad  has  been  banned  in  many  cases. 

The  opponents  of  obscenity  censorship  advance  a  number  of  arguments 
against  it.50  In  the  first  place,  they  maintain  the  value  of  sophistication. 
They  hold  that  it  is  beneficial  to  society  to  have  realities  and  evils  made 
known  early  in  life.  They  point  to  the  proud  record  and  notable  achieve- 
ments of  our  country  before  any  obscenity  statutes  had  been  enacted. 
They  contend  that  the  censors  only  advertise  and  promote  the  circulation 
of  the  materials  they  ostensibly  seek  to  suppress.  For  example,  the 
Well  of  Loneliness  sold  only  5,000  copies  in  England  before  it  was  cen- 
sored, but  200,000  copies  were  disposed  of  in  the  United  States  after  it 
had  been  given  the  publicity  associated  with  the  attempt  to  suppress  it 
here.  Further,  it  is  alleged  that,  in  their  effort  to  protect  other  people's 
morals,  the  censors  forget  their  own.  Critics  point  to  the  reprehensible 
system  of  using  stool-pigeons  and  the  like.  Further,  it  is  contended  that 
the  censors  are  highly  illogical  in  their  attitude  towards  the  law.  They 
are  extremely  fond  of  the  law  when  it  agrees  with  their  point  of  view  and 
upholds  their  contentions.  When  the  law  opposes  them,  they  are  ex- 
tremely vicious  and  vehement  in  condemning  it.  They  will  go  to  almost 
any  length  to  provide  subservient  judges,  but  they  are  extremely  critical 


55  Ernst  and  Lindey,  The  Censor  Marches  On,  chap.  VIII. 
06  See,  especially,  Ernst  and  Lindey,  The  Censor  Marches  On,  chaps.  XV-XVII; 
and  G.  J.  Nathan,  Autobiography  of  an  Attitude,  Knopf,  1925,  pp.  252  ff. 


580     PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

and  contemptuous  of  judges  who  possess  the  nerve  to  be  independent. 
They  even  go  so  far  as  to  denounce  such  judges  in  their  official  reports. 
The  critics  of  conventional  censorship  under  the*  obscenity  concept  do 
not  argue  that  youth  should  have  no  protection  against  any  kind  of  play 
or  publication.57  They  do  not  see,  however,  why  adults  must  be  protected 
against  a  knowledge  of  the  facts  of  life.  In  their  book  To  the  Pure,  Ernst 
and  Seagle  have  framed  what  they  regard  as  a  civilized  and  adequate 
statute  sufficient  to  protect  youth  from  all  legitimate  threat  of  exposure 
to  obscenity: 

Sec.  1.  Pornography  is  any  manner  of  thing  exhibiting  or  visually  representing 
persons  or  animals  performing  the  sexual  act,  whether  normal  or  abnormal. 

Sec.  2.  It  shall  be  criminal  for  anyone  other  than  a  teacher  in  the  course  of 
his  employment,  or  a  doctor  in  the  regular  practice  of  his  profession,  or  a  parent 
(of  the  child  in  question)  to  exhibit,  sell,  rent  or  offor  for  exhibition,  sale,  or  rent, 
any  such  pornographic  material  to  any  person  under  the  age  of  eighteen.5™ 

Our  main  protection  against  excesses  in  obscenity  censorship  is  recourse 
to  intelligent  and  independent  judges  and  to  reasonable  district  attor- 
neys. The  Court  of  Appeals  of  New  York  State  has  frequently  reversed 
decisions  made  by  lower  court  judges,  who  were  intimidated  by  John  S. 
Sumner  or  were  sympathetic  with  him.  Most  federal  judges  before 
whom  obscenity  cases  have  been  fought  with  vigor  and  courage  on  the 
part  of  defense  attorneys  have  rendered  fair  decisions.  The  work  of 
astute  and  courageous  attorneys,  like  Morris  Ernst  and  his  associates,  has 
provided  much  protection  against  excesses.  Then  crusading  newspapers 
have  been  extremely  helpful.  Mary  Ware  Dennett's  case  in  1929  was 
notably  aided  by  the  support  given  by  Roy  W.  Howard  and  his  New  York 
Telegram,  then  a  courageous  and  liberal  newspaper. 

The  Libel  Racket.  There  are  other,  in  many  ways  more  important, 
types  of  censorship  outside  the  range  of  obscenity  prosecutions.  Libel 
laws  are  a  particularly  nasty  stumbling  block  in  the  way  of  getting  the 
truth  about  commercial  commodities.58  Publishers  of  both  books  and 
newspapers  can  almost  always  be  threatened  with  a  libel  suit  if  they 
criticize,  however  honestly  and  fairly,  a  commercial  product.  If  they  are 
not  thus  easily  intimidated,  an  actual  libel  suit  may  be  started,  even  if  it 
is  never  prosecuted.  If  the  institution  of  a  libel  suit  does  not  scare  off 
criticism,  the  publisher  of  the  alleged  libel  must  go  to  considerable  ex- 
pense to  win  his  case,  even  if  he  is  sure  of  his  ground.  Therefore,  there 
is  a  natural  inclination  to  refrain  from  criticizing  commercial  products, 
whatever  the  fraud  and  dangers  connected  with  their  consumption.  As 
a  result,  it  is  difficult  for  the  average  consumer  to  get  adequate  informa- 
tion about  many,  if  not  most,  of  the  commodities  he  makes  use  of  in  daily 


57  Nathan,  op.  cit. 

57«  From  To  the  Pure,  by  Morris  L.  Ernst  and  William  Soagle,  Copyright  1928. 
By  permission  of  The  Viking  Press,  Inc.,  New  York. 

58  On  the  incredible  extent  of  liability  to  prosecution  for  libel  and  slander,  see 
M.  L.  Ernst  and  Alexander  Lindey,  Hold  Your  Tongue,  Morrow,  1932. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP     581 

life.  While  a  newspaper  is  thus  dissuaded  from  publishing  criticisms 
of  commercial  products,  the  incentive  of  large  advertising  revenue  renders 
it  cordial  towards  the  acceptance  of  advertising  material  proclaiming  the 
virtues  of  commodities  for  which  the  publisher  may  entertain  a  personal 
and  well-founded  scepticism. 

While  speaking  of  libel,  it  is  worth  while  to  point  out  that  there  is  an 
actual  libel  racket  in  existence.  Members  of  the  racket  scan  the  daily 
papers  in  search  of  news  items  which  may  be  regarded  as  potentially 
libelous  or  slanderous.  Then  they  seek  out  the  person  about  whom  it 
has  been  written  (who  usually  has  not  detected  any  libel  or  slander)  and 
urge  him  to  go  to  court  with  the  case,  offering  to  bear  the  expense  of  the 
suit  and  to  split  the  proceeds.  Newspapers  are  very  wary  about  the 
eccentricities  of  juries  and  are  likely  to  settle  quietly  out  of  court  when 
threat  of  a  suit  is  made. 

Political  Censorship.  Political  censorship  is  a  special  menace  in  our 
day.  A  majority  of  the  American  states,  during  and  after  the  first  World 
War,  passed  sedition  laws  outlawing  revolutionary  views.  More  recently, 
many  of  these  states  have  passed  laws  muzzling  teachers  through  loyalty 
oaths,  and  the  like.  More  important  is  the  general  censorship  of  news 
on  a  national  scale  which  prevents  the  citizens  from  obtaining  the  in- 
formation on  public  affairs  which  is  essential  to  the  success  of  democracy. 

Not  since  the  era  of  licensing  presses  in  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth 
centuries  has  there  existed  such  a  degree  of  censorship  as  now  prevails 
throughout  the  civilized  world  with  respect  to  the  publication  of  political 
facts  in  newspapers  and  books.  But  the  most  menacing  censorship  exists 
with  respect  to  the  suppression  of  news  which  prevents  the  citizens  from 
obtaining  'the  information  essential  to  the  operation  of  democracy.  This 
overwhelming  wave  of  censorship  started  with  the  first  World  War.  The 
censorship  system  was  part  of  the  general  campaign  of  propaganda  carried 
on  by  the  major  states  involved.  It  was  natural  that  they  would  wish  to 
publish  only  materials  favorable  to  their  side  of  the  conflict  and  to  ex- 
clude, so  far  as  possible,  any  news  favorable  to  the  enemy,  whether 
expressing  the  enemy's  viewpoint  on  the  conflict  or  recording  victories  of 
the  enemy.  It  was  also  necessary  to  keep  information  from  falling  into 
the  hands  of  the  enemy.  Not  only  newspapers  and  books  were  censored, 
but  also  the  letters  sent  by  soldiers  to  their  relatives  and  friends.59 

The  system  of  censorship,  though  relaxed  somewhat,  was  continued 
after  the  first  World  War.  Then  came  the  rise  of  totalitarian  states  in 
Russia,  Italy,  Germany,  and  elsewhere,  and  the  suppression  of  democracy 
in  many  states  which  did  not  openly  espouse  either  Fascism  or  Com- 
munism. In  the  totalitarian  states  there  was  no  pretense  of  freedom  of 
the  press.  The  people  were  told  only  those  things  which  the  government 
wished  to  tell  them.  Moreover,  these  states  became  extremely  zealous 
in  selecting  the  news  which*was  sent  abroad.  They  wished  to  have  not 


59  See  J.  R.  Mock,  Censorship,  1917,  Princeton  University  Press,  1941. 


582     PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

only  their  own  citizens  but  the  rest  of  the  world  read  only  materials 
favorable  to  their  policies.  As  a  consequence,  the  blight  of  censorship 
descended  upon  most  of  Europe. 

It  is  worth  while  to  describe  the  elaborate  machinery  for  propaganda 
and  censorship  which  was  set  up  in  Nazi  Germany,  as  an  example  of  the 
rigorous  control  created  over  thought  and  culture  in  totalitarian  countries. 
The  Ministry  fur  Propaganda  and  People's  Enlightenment  is  divided  into 
nine  main  departments:  Administration  and  Law,  Propaganda,  Radio, 
Press,  Film,  Theater,  Defense,  Writing,  Music,  and  the  Plastic  Arts.  The 
Ministry  has  thirty-one  regional  offices  scattered  throughout  Germany, 
and  all  of  the  nine  departments  are  represented  in  each  of  the  thirty-one 
regional  offices.  The  Ministry  for  Propaganda  supplies  much  of  the 
material  which  is  put  out  in  all  these  fields,  and  nothing  can  be  written, 
said,  or  done  that  is  not  approved  by  the  Ministry.  In  this  way,  complete 
censorship  is  exerted  over  German  thought  and  culture  in  the  interest  of 
protecting  and  strengthening  the  Nazi  ideology.  The  Minister  of  Propa- 
ganda is  Dr.  Paul  Joseph  Gocbbels,  who  has  held  his  office  since  it  was 
established  after  the  Nazis  came  into  power. 

Further  control  over  Nazi  culture  is  exerted  by  the  National  Chamber 
of  Culture,  which  is  divided  into  seven  constituent  chambers:  Music, 
Arts,  Theater,  Literature,  Press,  Radio  and  Film.  Each  of  these  super- 
vises the  cultural  activities  falling  within  its  field  throughout  all  Germany. 
Each  one  is  further  subdivided.  Dr.  Goebbels  is  also  president  of  the 
National  Chamber  of  Culture,  which  is  thus  linked  closely  with  the 
Propaganda  Ministry. 

In  addition  to  these  extensive  organizations,  two  other  ministries  are 
directly  related  to  the  regimentation  of  Nazi  mentality.  One  is  the 
Ministry  for  Ecclesiastical  Affairs,  which  has  charge  of  all  religious 
matters,  and  the  other  is  the  Ministry  for  Science,  Education,  and  Na- 
tional Culture,  which  has  control  over  educational  activities.  It  is 
obvious  that  this  comprehensive  machinery  makes  possible  a  meticulous 
supervision  over  all  phases  of  German  thought  and  culture. 

Much  the  same  situation  with  respect  to  censorship  exists  in  Latin 
America  and  the  Orient  as  in  totalitarian  countries  in  Europe.  Prior  to 
the  current  war  with  China,  Japan  was  more  tolerant  of  news  dis- 
patches sent  out  of  the  country  than  were  most  other  non-democratic 
states.  But  today  Japan  has  an  airtight  censorship  over  all  news. 

Even  in  the  United  States,  a  censorship  over  the  material  given  out  to 
the  newspapers,  unparalleled  in  our  history  prior  to  the  first  World  War, 
existed  unimpaired  down  to  our  entry  into  the  second  World  War.  The 
situation  has  been  described  by  Eugene  J.  Young  in  his  revealing  work, 
Looking  Behind  the  Censorships: 

Even  free  America  has  its  own  censorships.  Oftce  upon  a  time,  as  I  knew,  it 
was  possible  for  a  newsman  to  wander  about  Washington  and  talk  freely  to  any 
official  about  his  work  and  his  ideas  of  government.  A  bureau  chief  might  not 
agree  with  his  superior  and  would  say  so.  One  head  of  a  department  might  take 
issue  with  another.  Out  of  their  frankness  much  discussion — which  was  often 


PREJUDICE,    PROPAGANDA  AND   CENSORSHIP     583 

good  for  the  country — could  be  aroused.  The  public  got  most  of  the  facts 
essential  for  the  formation  of  clear  judgments. 

The  World  War  brought  about  a  change.  It  was  necessary  to  keep  our  plans 
and  preparations  secret,  lest  the  enemy  profit.  Censorship  rules  were  drawn 
up  by  the  War  Department  and  were  accepted  by  the  press.  In  the  various 
departments  having  to  do  with  the  war  central  bureaus  were  established.  Subor- 
dinates were  told  they  must  send  any  news  to  these  bureaus  and  must  not  talk 
to  correspondents.  There  were  many  leaks  but,  in  general,  outgivings  were  con- 
trolled by  the  high  authorities. 

After  the  war  this  system  was  found  to  be  highly  agreeable  to  the  men  in 
power.  They  could  manipulate  information  to  suit  their  own  ends  and  those  of 
the  administration  in  power.  So  the  central  bureaus  were  continued  under 
Presidents  Harding,  Coolidge,  Hoover  and  Roosevelt.  In  the  last  of  these  ad- 
ministrations they  were  turned  not  only  into  censorial  organs  but  into  high 
pressure  propaganda  agencies.  In  the  depression  it  was  necessary  to  find  work 
for  many  writers,  among  others  of  the  millions  who  had  been  thrown  out  of  jobs, 
and  hundreds  of  these  were  put  into  the  departments  at  Washington  and  their 
branches.  They  have  busily  turned  out  matter  favorable  to  their  bosses  and, 
under  direction,  have  suppressed  facts  that  might  be  unfavorable.  It  has  been 
virtually  impossible,  for  instance,  to  get  many  important  details  of  the  expendi- 
tures of  the  billions  of  dollars  of  relief  money. 

With  such  domestic  matters,  however,  I  am  not  concerned.  What  is  of  im- 
portance here  is  the  censorship  exercised  by  our  State  Department.  Of  that 
it  can  be  said  there  is  no  more  rigid  system  of  silence  anywhere  in  the  world. 
The  press  can  learn  virtually  nothing  of  what  is  being  done  in  our  foreign 
relations  until  the  moment  arrives  when  the  Department  decides  to  issue  its 
announcement  in  its  own  wording.  There  have  been  important  occasions  when 
I  thought  the  American  people  should  know  what  was  going  on  and  I  have 
learned  through  London  or  Paris  what  the  Washington  authorities  were  doing. 
But  in  the  matter  of  Far  Eastern  negotiations  or  activities  it  is  impossible  to 
find  out  anything  until  officials  choose  to  speak  or  events  bring  their  own 
revelations.60 

The  general  engulfing  of  the  world  by  news  censorship  in  the  'thirties  is 
admirably  summarized  in  the  following  paragraph  by  0.  W.  Riegel: 

In  summary,  the  world  is  moving  rapidly  into  an  era  of  universal  obstruction 
of  the  free  flow  of  information  and  opinion.  In  the  name  of  nationalism,  the 
fetish  of  the  decade,  freedom  of  speech  and  the  press  has  already  been  denied  to 
approximately  nine-tenths  of  the  world's  population,  including  the  populations 
of  Russia,  China,  Japan,  Germany,  Italy,  Austria,  most  colonial  possessions,  and 
smaller  states  in  the  Balkans  and  South  America.  Interference  with  the  tradi- 
tional function  of  the  press  as  a  purveyor  of  unbiased  information  is  increasing 
in  other  countries  which  preserve  meaningless  guarantees  of  freedom  of  speech 
and  the  press  in  their  constitutions  and  statutes. 

Everywhere,  the  importance  of  regimenting  the  public  mind  for  national 
progress  and  defense  has  been  recognized,  and  the  times  are  witnessing  an  un- 
precedented professionalization  of  propaganda  activities  in  the  form  of  press 
bureaus,  press  experts,  the  semidiplomatic  status  of  newspapermen,  the  emphasis 
of  economic  and  social  compulsions  affecting  the  journalist,  and  the  organization 
of  programs  to  inculcate  chauvinistic  patriotism. 

The  League  of  Nations  partakes  of  the  character  of  a  counter  propaganda 
agency,  and  its  prestige  has  lately  been  losing  ground.  The  existence  of  a  non- 
political,  fact-finding  organization  for  the  dissemination  of  world  news  is  becom- 
ing progressively  more  impossible,  and  the  immediate  prospect  is  a  checkerboard 


60  Lippincott,  1938,  pp.  32-34. 


584     PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

of  nationalistic  states  whose  populations  are  forced  to  obey  the  whims  of  their 
political  masters  by  the  deliberate  manipulation  of  public  opinion.61 

It  has  been  suggested  that  foreign  correspondents  might  escape  from 
the  censorship  by  appealing  to  the  representatives  of  their  own  govern- 
ment in  foreign  lands.  But  it  has  been  amply  shown  that  this  expedient 
is  entirely  futile.  Few  ambassadors,  ministers,  or  consuls  will  jeopardize 
their  standing  in  a  foreign  country  by  lodging  a  protest  against  the  pre- 
vailing censorship  rules.  Time  and  time  again,  major  governments  of 
the  world  have  sat  calmly  by  while  competent  correspondents  of  papers 
in  their  own  country  have  been  ousted  from  foreign  states,  simply  because 
they  desired  to  tell  some  part  of  the  truth  with  respect  to  what  was  going 
on  therein.  The  helplessness  of  the  foreign  correspondents,  in  the  face  of 
the  censorship  which  has  settled  down  over  the  world,  has  been  admirably 
described  and  analyzed  by  the  journalist  George  Seldes  in  his  important 
book,  You  Can't  Print  That.  It  is  obvious  that  all  that  has  been  said 
here  about  censorship  of  the  press  in  Europe  and  elsewhere  applies  equally 
to  the  radio.  Where  news  is  shut  off  in  the  press,  it  is  as  fully  excluded 
from  the  air. 

The  success  of  democracy  depends  upon  the  ability  of  the  average 
citizen  to  get  hold  of  the  facts  about  public  affairs.  Today  in  the  greater 
part  of  the  world,  the  truth  cannot  be  read  by  the  citizen,  and  what  he 
does  read  and  hear  is  rarely  the  truth.  Likewise,  the  censorship  gives 
citizens  a  perverted  notion  of  world  affairs,  stimulates  arrogant  patriot- 
ism, and  increases  the  danger  of  war.  As  Riegel  puts  the  matter: 

Modern  man's  curiosity  concerning  events  outside  of  his  own  immediate  circle 
and  community  is  satisfied  by  a  day-by-day  diet  of  news,  and  the  character  of  an 
average  man's  views  on  political  questions  will  be  affected  by  his  news  diet  in 
the  same  way  that  the  condition  of  his  physical  body  is  affected  by  the  kind  of 
foodstuffs  he  eats.  The  analogy  is  inadequate  in  this  sense,  that  a  man  who 
mnlnourishes  his  body  on  a  diet  exclusively  of  whiskey  or  sugar  is  injuring  chiefly 
himself,  while  a  man  who  lives  on  an  unbalanced  diet  of  news  is  not  only  injuring 
himself  but  is  a  source  of  danger  to  everyone  with  whom  he  comes  into  contact.62 

The  outbreak  of  the  second  World  War  in  September,  1939,  brought 
the  censorship  of  foreign  news  to  completion.  But  the  American  press 
insisted  on  news,  whether  it  could  be  obtained  or  not.  The  result  was  a 
vast  amount  of  fiction.  Battles  were  invented  on  the  Western  Front  from 
September,  1939,  to  May,  1940.  Gross  exaggerations  were  published 
after  extended  hostilities  actually  broke  out  in  April,  1940.  Reporters 
were  not  allowed  to  go  to  the  front  in  the  Russo-Finnish  war  in  the  winter 
of  1939-40.  Hence  the  most  grotesque  stories  were  printed,  such  as  the 
one  of  whole  regiments  of  Russian  soldiers  frozen  in  their  tracks,  still 
grasping  their  rifles.  Absurd  stories  about  Nazi  Fifth  Column  activities 
in  Norway,  France,  and  elsewhere  were  spread,  following  the  initial 
notorious  exaggerations  of  Fifth  Column  plotting  in  Norway.  The 


«  0.  W.  Riogel,  Mobilizing  for  Chaos,  Yale  Press,  1934,  pp.  167-168. 
**Ibid.,  pp.  10&-109. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP     585 

Fifth  Column  stories  replaced  the  atrocity  tales  of  the  first  World  War. 
It  was  alleged  that  Holland  was  betrayed  by  Nazi  agents  who  had  been 
circumcised  and  sent  into  Holland  in  the  guise  of  Jewish  refugees.  Num- 
erous stories  of  attempted  invasions  of  Britain  by  the  Nazis  were  pub- 
lished, some  stating  that  the  Nazis  were  burned  wholesale  when  oil 
poured  on  the  Channel  waters  was  set  afire.  Germans  were  portrayed  as 
having  occupied  the  Balkans  months  before  they  did  so.  Periodically, 
stories  were  printed  representing  a  definite  rift  between  Stalin  and  Hitler. 
The  papers  often  printed  a  formal  notice  that  European  news  was  cen- 
sored, but  they  published  such  highly  censored  news  as  though  it  had 
been  free,  comprehensive,  and  authentic.6211 

As  interventionist  sentiment  and  Administration  policies  brought  the 
United  States  closer  to  war,  non-interventionist  material  was  derided 
and  cold-shouldered  by  most  of  the  press  and  the  radio  broadcasting 
stations.  It  was  alleged  that  the  federal  government  had  already  drawn 
up  plans  for  an  elaborate  system  of  wartime  censorship.63  Soon  after 
we  entered  the  War  on  December  8,  1941,  a  sweeping  system  of  govern- 
ment censorship  of  the  press,  radio,  and  moving-pictures  was  set  up  under 
the  direction  of  Byron  Price  of  the  Associated  Press.  Special  assistants 
were  provided  to  supervise  the  press  and  radio,  and  Lowell  Mellett  was 
named  coordinator  of  moving-picture  activity.  In  February,'  1942, 
Attorney-General  Biddle  moved  for  even  more  drastic  censorship;  in  the 
form  of  a  "National  Secrets"  bill. 

Moving-Picture  Censorship.  The  great  importance  of  moving  pictures 
in  modern  communication  and  entertainment  makes  the  problem  of  movie 
censorship  one  of  much  significance  for  the  American  public.  In  a 
slashing  .criticism  of  the  existing  system  of  censorship,  in  their  book 
Censored:  The  Private  Life  of  the  Movie,  Morris  L.  Ernst  and  Pare 
Lorentz,  two  distinguished  and  competent  students  of  the  movies,  de- 
nounce movie  censorship  as  perhaps  the  greatest  racket  in  America  today. 
They  describe  the  movies  as  the  "hen-pecked"  product  of  a  group  of 
vacuous  and  idle  female  busybodies,  who  lack  both  intelligence  and 
vision.  On  the  other  hand,  we  find  the  Catholic  watchdog,  Martin 
Quigley,  in  his  Decency  in  Motion  Pictures,  denouncing  the  present  type 
of  movie  censorship  as  inadequate  and  permitting  the  exhibition  of 
grossly  and  diversely  immoral  films.  He  represents  the  point  of  view  of 
the  Catholic  element,  which,  organized  in  the  Legion  of  Decency,  has 
been  particularly  active  in  recent  years  in  attempting  to  bring  about  more 
rigorous  censorship  of  the  films.  There  is  much  to  be  said  for  both  of 
these  points  of  view,  when  one  considers  the  group  for  which  each  is  a 
spokesman.  Ernst  and  Lorentz  represent  the  point  of  view  of  open- 
minded  adults,  who  view  the  movies  as  a  potential  instrument  for  the 
production  of  a  high  grade  of  art  and  intellectual  stimulation.  Mr. 


62aSoe  Institute  for  Propaganda  Analysis,  Bulletin,  "Russia,  Finland,  and   the 
U.SA.,"  April  30,  1940;  and  "The  Fifth  Column,"  ibid.,  July  8,  1940. 
63  See  Walter  Davenport,  "You  Can't  Say  That,"  in  Collier's,  February  15,  1941. 


586     PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

Quigley  has  in  mind  the  possibly  disastrous  effects  of  movies  upon  chil- 
dren, especially  children  of  average  and  sub-normal  mentality.  That 
the  Catholics  are  still  alert  in  their  effort  to  censor  the  movies  may  be 
seen  from  the  attack  on  Greta  Garbo's  picture  "Two-Faced  Woman"  by 
the  Legion  of  Decency  in  the  autumn  and  winter  of  1941. 

The  legality  of  motion  picture  censorship  was  established  by  a  Supreme 
Court  decision  in  1915,  which  ruled  that  movies  fall  in  the  class  with 
circuses  rather  than  newspapers,  and  hence  are  legitimately  subject  to 
public  and  private  censorship.6*  The  censorship  of  films  has  extended 
to  an  almost  incredible  degree.  A  decade  ago  the  censors  in  New  York 
State  deleted  or  rejected  nearly  40  per  cent  of  all  feature  films  submitted 
to  them,  thus  throwing  out  or  censoring  more  than  a  third  of  all  the 
important  films.  And  it  should  be  kept  in  mind  that  a  very  considerable 
self-censorship  had  alreiidy  been  imposed  by  the  producers  in  making  the 
films.  The  producers  have  no  inclination  to  waste  their  money  in  making 
films,  however  excellent,  which  they  are  sure  will  be  rejected. 

The  extent  of  this  censorship  indicates  the  arbitrary  and  unpredictable 
character  of  film  censorship.  After  years  of  experience,  the  most  skillful 
producers  were  only  able  to  guess  with  an  accuracy  of  approximately  60 
per  cent  what  the  censors  would  do  to  their  product.  There  is  no  reason 
to  believe  that  the  State  Board  of  Censorship  in  New  York  is  any  more 
narrow-minded  than  other  censors.  Indeed,  it  is  probably  somewhat 
more  tolerant  than  other  state  and  local  boards  of  review.65 

Domestic  motion-picture  censorship  in  the  United  States  has  until 
recently  been  in  the  hands  of  three  different  groups.  The  first  is  the 
National  Board  of  Review,  organized  in  New  York  State  in  1909.66  It 
was  originally  founded  by  the  Peoples  Institute  of  New  York  City  with 
the  noblest  intentions.  It  assumed,  at  one  and  the  same  time,  to  protect 
morals  and  avoid  censorship.  It  proposed  to  review  films  and  suggest  to 
producers  items  that  might  well  be  left  out.  It  is  supported  mainly  by 
the  Daughters  of  the  American  Revolution,  the  International  Catholic 
Alumnae,  the  Parent-Teachers  Association,  and  the  General  Federation  of 
Women's  Clubs.  Some  of  the  members  functioned  directly  in  connection 
with  the  production  of  films,  making  suggestions  to  the  producers  and 
Will  Hays  as  to  what  should  be  left  out  of  the  film  before  it  is  offered 
for  exhibition.  The  Board  also  passed  on  completed  films  and  rated  the 
works  of  even  such  immortals  as  Shakespeare  and  Dickens  as  "good," 
"educational,"  "subversive  to  morality,"  and  so  on.  Though  without 
legal  authority,  it  exerted  a  powerful  influence  over  motion  picture  ex- 
hibition. In  the  state  of  Florida  and  in  the  City  of  Boston,  for  example, 
it  was  illegal  to  exhibit  a  film  which  did  not  have  the  approval  of  the 


64  See  Ernst  and  Lindey,  The  Censor  Marches  On,  p.  78. 

65  The  mortality  of  films  at  the  hands  of  the  New  York  censors  has  improved 
somewhat  in  the  last  ten  years.    In  1938,  it  rejected  or  deleted  135  feature  pictures 
out  of  952. 

66  On  the  National  Board  of  Review,  see  Ernst  and  Lorentz,  Censored,  Cape  and 
Smith,  1930,  Chap.  IV.    For  the  organization  of  the  Board,  see  pp.  106-107. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP     587 

National  Board  of  Review.  It  invaded  most  localities  of  the  United 
States  through  local  "better  films  committees,"  which  are,  for  the  most 
part,  made  up  of  individuals  especially  on  the  alert  to  protect  the  con- 
ventional moral  traditions  and  practices.  The  National  Board  of  Review 
has  recently  disbanded. 

In  Hollywood  itself  we  have  the  famous  organization,  the  Motion 
Picture  Producers  and  Distributors  of  America,  organized  in  1922  under 
the  direction  of  Will  Hays,  who  is  frequently  referred  to  as  "the  Bishop 
of  Hollywood."  He  draws  a  salary  of  $100,000  a  year.  This  organiza- 
tion was  set  up  by  the  motion  picture  producers  themselves  to  provide  for 
censorship  at  the  source  of  production  and  thus  head  off  more  drastic 
and  foolish  censorship  later  on.  Faced  by  the  threat  of  federal  censor- 
ship and  boycott,  the  Hays  organization  adopted,  in  1930,  a  Production 
Code  dictated  by  Catholic  critics  of  the  movies.  It  was  revised  in  1934.07 
Mr.  Hays'  organization  passes  upon  all  entertainment  films  produced  for 
commercial  purposes  in  the  United  States.  On  the  one  hand,  it  advises 
the  producers  to  omit  what  it  regards  as  objectionable  features,  when 
viewed  from  the  standpoint  of  the  movie  clientele,  particularly  of  those 
interested  in  the  censorship  of  films.  On  the  other,  it  tries  to  placate  the 
censors  and  assure  them  that  it  has  deeply  at  heart  the  responsibility  of 
seeing  to  it  that  only  safe  and  sane  movies  are  released  for  exhibition. 
Considering  the  difficulties  of  its  position,  it  has  done  fairly  well  in  the 
way  of  protecting  the  public  from  more  vicious  and  extreme  forms  of 
censorship.  Ernst  and  Lindey  give  the  following  sample  of  the  way  in 
which  the  Hollywood  Code  works  out  in  practice: 

The  administration  has  been  responsible  for  shelving  a  number  of  projected 
films,  among  them  Shaw's  Saint  Joan,  James  M.  Cain's  The  Postman  Always 
Rings  Twice,  and  Sinclair  Lewis'  It  Can't  Happen  Here.  During  1937  it  re- 
viewed no  less  than  6,663  full-length  domestic  feature  scripts  and  pictures,  and 
ordered  innumerable  cuts  and  changes.  It  tabooed  scenes  showing  kisses  on  the 
neck  and  shoulder,  ladies  removing  or  adjusting  stockings  in  the  presence  of  men, 
men  touching  ladies'  legs,  men  and  girls  lying  together  on  a  bed.68 

Finally,  we  have  the  state  boards  of  censorship  in  some  six  states. 
While  there  are  some  open-minded  and  intelligent  members  of  these 
boards,  they  are  made  up,  for  the  most  part,  of  minor  politicians  and 
busybodies.  These  six  state  boards  do  most  of  the  open  censoring. 
Their  work,  on  the  whole,  is  incompetent,  hurried,  superficial,  and  arbi- 
trary. In  New  York  State,  the  Board,  which  is  officially  lodged  in  the 
State  Education  Department,  has  at  times  been  so  busy  that  it  has  had  to 
call  in  state  troopers  to  help  them  to  review  the  films.  On  the  whole, 
they  tend  to  remove  even  moderate  sex-realism,  and,  what  is  more 
menacing,  to  discourage  frankness  in  regard  to  war,  political  graft,  and 
social  oppression.  These  six  states  which  have  boards  of  censors  are 


67  For  details  of  the  Code,  see  Ernst  and  Lindey,  The  Censor  Marches  On,  pp.  1 

68  From  The  Censor  Marches  On,  by  Morris  L.  Ernst  and  Alexander  Lindey,  copy- 
right, 1939,  1940,  reprinted  by  permission  from  Doubleday,  Doran  and  Company, 
Inc.,  p.  91. 


588     PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

New  York,  Pennsylvania,  Maryland,  Kansas,  Virginia  and  Ohio.  The 
fact  that  six  populous  key  states  have  state  boards  of  censors  affects 
motion-picture  production  for  the  country  as  a  whole.  There  might  as 
well  be  forty-eight  state  boards,  for  producers  cannot  afford  to  prepare 
separate  versions  of  pictures.  They  are  guided  by  what  the  state  boards 
are  likely  to  accept.68 

The  most  effective  exposure  of  the  activities  of  state  boards  of  censor- 
ship was  the  monograph  What  Shocked  the  Censors,  published  by  the 
National  Council  on  Freedom  from  Censorship.  It  was  a  complete 
record  of  the  cuts  in  motion-picture  films,  from  January,  1932,  to  March, 
1933,  by  the  New  York  State  censors,  who  are  considered  the  most  en- 
lightened of  the  six  boards.  The  character  and  essential  futility  of  their 
work  is  thus  summarized: 

Virtue  must  always  be  rewarded;  sin  and  crime  always  punished — even  if  only 
at  the  tail-end  of  lurid  reels  of  vice  and  violence.  Life  must  not  be  treated  as  it 
really  is,  but  as  bureaucratic  moralists  think  it  should  be.  Moral  lessons  must 
be  taught — if  not  in  newspapers  and  magazines,  and  on  the  stage,  at  least  in  the 
movies.  But  the  producers  have  learned  to  get  away  with  almost  anything 
suggestive  or  immoral,  if  it  only  has  the  proper  moral  ending.70 

State  boards  have  frequently  rejected  altogether  films  which  have  been 
approved  by  the  National  Board  of  Review.  A  notorious  case  was  that 
of  the  film  "High  Treason,"  which  was  highly  recommended  by  the 
National  Board  of  Review.  This  film  had  no  sex  element  in  it  whatever. 
It  was  a  peace  movie  dealing  with  the  problem  of  war  and  international 
organization.  Its  general  theme  was  the  triumph  of  international  organ- 
ization against  world  war.  It  was  a  highly  practical  and  valuable  presen- 
tation of  the  cause  of  peace  and  world  organization.  It  was  charged,  in 
the  case  of  the  rejection  of  the  film  by  the  Pennsylvania  State  Board,  that 
the  Pennsylvania  steel  industries  had  exerted  pressure  because  they  were 
opposed  to  anything  which  promoted  the  cause  of  peace  and  disarmament. 
At  any  rate,  it  could  hardly  be  alleged  that  this  film  was  rejected  because 
it  would  in  any  way  corrupt  the  morals  of  youth.  In  1937,  considerable 
excitement  was  raised  by  the  rejection  of  the  film  "Spain  in  Flames" 
because  it  was  alleged  that  it  presented  too  favorable  a  view  of  the  Loyal- 
ist government.  Other  important  films  which  have  been  banned  were 
"Narcotics,"  a  portrayal  of  the  drug  traffic;  "Witchcraft,"  the  story  of 
superstition  through  the  ages;  "Polygamy,"  an  account  of  polygamous 
practices  in  early  Utah  and  Arizona;  and  "The  Birth  of  a  Baby,"  a  non- 
obscene  educational  film.  "Scarface,"  the  best  of  the  gangster  films,  was 
held  up  for  months  and  it  cost  over  $100,000  to  patch  it  up  to  suit  the 
censors.  In  1938,  another  picture  of  Spain,  "Blockade,"  was  extensively 
banned  by  local  censors.  As  a  general  practice,  innumerable  and  often 
incredible  cuts  are  made  in  most  of  the  significant  pictures. 


69  For  a  description  of  the  work  of  the  state  boards  of  censors,  see  Ernst  and 
Lorentz,  Censored,  Chap.  II. 
™  Op.  cit.,  p.  15. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP     589 

The  moral  history  of  a  film  may  be  fairly  described  as  follows:  A  story 
is  offered  to  a  producer,  and  if  it  is  regarded  as  promising  material  it  is 
put  in  the  form  of  a  brief  and  sent  to  the  studio.  If  the  production  heads 
are  interested  in  it,  a  preliminary  motion-picture  version  is  prepared  and 
further  investigated  as  to  its  availability  for  production.  If  it  is  accepted 
the  script  is  completed,  being  incidentally  edited  and  censored  by  the 
producers  in  the  process.  It  is  then  submitted  to  Will  Hays'  organization, 
which  views  it  from  the  standpoint  of  its  probable  reception  by  the  various 
censorship  organizations.  An  elaborate  code  was  drawn  up,  as  we  have 
seen,  for  the  Hays'  organization  in  1930,  containing  extensive  stipulations 
as  to  the  details  of  films  which  will  be  acceptable.  Most  producers  take 
heed  of  these  stipulations,  and  prepare  their  scripts  in  accordance  with 
the  regulations.  The  Hays'  organization  takes  care  of  any  oversight  in 
this  regard.  It  may  also  suggest  more  drastic  changes,  in  the  light  of 
the  current  temper  of  censorship  opinion  in  the  country.  Of  late  years 
it  has  had  to  take  serious  account  of  the  growing  Catholic  demand  for 
drastic  censorship  of  films,  and  of  the  drive  against  social  liberalism. 
We  have  already  noted  that  Mr.  Hays  has  also  been  advised  until  re- 
cently by  twelve  club  women  in  Hollywood,  who  represented  the  National 
Board  of  Review  and  affiliated  organizations.  When  a  script  has  been 
returned  to  the  producers  by  Mr.  Hays'  organization,  the  filming  is  done, 
and  the  Hays'  organization  reviews  the  final  product.  If  so  ordered, 
further  deletions  are  then  made.  The  film,  can  then  be  released  for  dis- 
tribution and  exhibition. 

Until  recently,  the  film  then  had  to  run  the  gauntlet  of  the  National 
Board  of  Review  and  the  state  and  local  censors.  The  National  Board 
has  disbanded,  but  the  state  and  local  censors  still  persist.  We  have 
already  described  the  bannings  and  mutilations  by  state  censorship 
boards  imposed  on  films  that  have  already  been  elaborately  censored  by 
the  producers  and  the  Hays'  organization.  Local  censors,  such  as  the 
mayors  of  cities,  ban  and  cut  still  further.  Despite  all  this,  there  is  still 
a  persistent  demand  from  many  sources  for  even  more  drastic  censorship. 

The  degree  to  which  the  censors  have  intimidated  the  producers  is  well 
illustrated  by  the  experience  of  Ernst  and  Lorentz  in  gathering  the 
material  for  their  book  on  movie  censorship.  While  most  producers  are 
personally  indignant  over  censorship  rules,  they  all  refused  to  impart  to 
Ernst  and  Lorentz  a  single  bit  of  information  about  their  maltreatment 
by  censors.  The  large  body  of  information  used  by  Ernst  and  Lorentz 
was  obtained  from  Will  Hays'  office  mainly  by  strategy  and  subterfuge. 
The  producers  long  refused  to  reveal  the  full  details  of  the  Producers 
Code.  They  were  afraid  to  make  any  public  protest  or  to  have  it  known 
that  they  resented  their  treatment.  They  feared  that  to  do  so  would 
lead  to  retaliation  in  the  way  of  malicious  cutting  of  the  films  by  the 
censors.  The  exhibitors  have  even  less  nerve  than  the  producers  in 
protesting  censorship.71 


71  See  Ernst  and  Lindey,  The  Censor  Marches  On,  pp.  75-76. 


590     PREJUDICE,  PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

The  net  result  of  this  complex  web  of  censorship  is  that  the  best  we  can 
expect  from  commercial  films  is  passably  diverting  entertainment.  Items 
which  might  suggest  thinking  about  social  justice  are  as  rigorously  ex- 
cluded as  immorality.  Occasionally,  however,  a  worth-while  film,  from 
the  standpoint  of  its  sociological  import,  may  slip  by.  A  notable  ex- 
ample was  "I  am  a  Fugitive  from  a  Georgia  Chain  Gang."  This  film 
was  due,  however,  mainly  to  the  particular  social  interest  and  adventure- 
someness  of  Warner  Brothers,  and  it  was  extensively  deleted  before  it  was 
exhibited.  At  times,  some  passages  critical  of  the  existing  order  are 
permitted  to  slip  by,  as  for  example  in  "The  Lost  Horizon"  and  "Mr. 
Deeds  Goes  to  Town."  The  March  of  Time  films  also  occasionally  em- 
body material  that  is  highly  critical  by  implication.  We  have  already 
pointed  out  how  the  foreign  market  for  films  has  exerted  a  disastrous 
influence  upon  movies  shown  in  this  country.  The  suppression  of  "It 
Can't  Happen  Here"  by  Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer  indicates  that  down  to 
1939  no  picture  was  likely  to  be  produced  in  this  country  which  was 
critical  of  Fascism,  even  an  imaginary  Fascist  regime  in  the  United  States. 

By  arid  large,  the  elaborate  movie  censorship  does  not  always  eliminate 
those  items  which  are  morally  objectionable,  in  any  sensible  interpretation 
of  this  term.  Most  of  the  evil  effects  discerned  by  the  investigators  em- 
ployed by  the  Motion  Picture  Research  Council,  to  which  we  have  al- 
ready referred,  were  produced  by  movies  which  had  run  the  gauntlet  of 
the  censors.72  Intellectual  and  moral  banality,  rather  than  moral  sound- 
ness and  the  stimulation  of  personal  improvement  and  social  betterment 
seem  to  be  the  net  result  of  censorship  to  date.  It  has  wrecked  the 
prospect  that  the  movies  will  ever  be  an  intellectual  force,  promoting 
social  thought  and  human  betterment,  so  long  as  the  present  system  of 
censorship  persists. 

Obscenity,  or  alleged  obscenity,  was  the  basis  for  most  of  the  early 
censorship  of  the  movies,  but  there  has  been  a  steady  tendency  in  the  last 
decade  to  shift  the  emphasis  to  the  suppression  of  sound  social  criticism: 

Fear  of  sex  is  on  the  wane.  The  new  specter  is  "subversive"  ideas.  The 
censors  are  no  longer  concerned  with  sex  alone;  political  censorship  is  the  new 
goal. 

It  cannot  be  stressed  too  strongly  that  state  regulation  of  the  screen  was  set 
up  at  the  outset  specifically  to  combat  indecency.  The  law  is  now  being  per- 
verted to  uses  that  were  never  contemplated.73 

A  good  summary  critique  of  the  stupidity  and  futility  of  movie  censor- 
ship has  been  offered  by  the  Metropolitan  Motion  Picture  Council,  a 
research  organization  formerly  affiliated  with  the  National  Board  of  Re- 
view. It  charges  that  movie  censorship  is: 

1.  An  aspersion  on  public  morality. 

2.  An  insult  to  American  intelligence. 


"See  above,  pp.  512-514. 

™  From  The  Censor  Marches  On,  by  Morris  L.  Ernst  and  Alexander  Lmdey,  copy- 
right, 1939,  1940,  reprinted  by  permission  from  Doubleday,  Doran  and  Company, 
lie.,  p.  108. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP     591 

3.  An  excuse  for  indirect  taxation  of  the  industry. 

4.  An  opportunity  to  dispense  political  patronage. 

5.  An  obstacle  to  the  production  of  truly  entertaining  adult  films. 

6.  A  violation  of  the  Bill  of  Rights. 

7.  An  ideal  instrument  for  the  promotion  of  bigotry  and  intolerance  and  a 
possible  implementing  of  Fascism,  Nazism,  and  Communism.7* 

In  addition  to  above-described  private  and  state  censorship  of  films 
produced  in  this  country,  the  federal  government  exercises  a  censorship 
by  deciding  what  foreign  films  can  be  brought  into  this  country.  The 
customs  officials  exercise  this  power  of  exclusion,  as  they  do  in  regard  to 
literature  imported  into  the  United  States.  Some  of  the  best  and  most 
artistic  of  foreign  films  have  been  excluded  from  the  country  in  this  way.75 
When  we  entered  the  War  in  December,  1941,  federal  censorship  of 
motion  pictures  was  set  up.  A  veteran  newspaperman  and  presidential 
aide,  Lowell  Mellett,  was  appointed  coordinator  of  motion  pictures  to 
supervise  their  activities  and  output. 

Radio  Censorship.  The  influence  of  the  radio  renders  the  question  of 
the  freedom  of  the  air  of  great  social  significance.  This  is  especially  and 
emphatically  so,  since  today  freedom  of  the  air  is  vitally  related  to 
freedom  of  speech.  So  much  larger  an  audience  can  be  reached  by  radio 
than  in  any  public  meeting  that  if  one  is  denied  access  to  the  air  he  and 
his  cause  are  at  a  fatal  disadvantage.  In  other  words,  freedom  of  speech 
today  is  not  so  much  freedom  of  the  soap-box  or  platform  as  it  is  freedom 
to  use  the  broadcasting  facilities  of  radio.76 

There  is  no  doubt  that  radio  creates  new  responsibilities  and  considera- 
tions with  respect  to  freedom  of  speech.  In  addressing  a  public  meeting, 
the  speaker  is  dealing  with  an  audience  which  has  voluntarily  come  to 
hear  him.  '  The  radio  speaker,  however,  may  intrude  his  ideas  into  a 
household  that  has  no  inclination  to  listen.  They  may  be  brought  before 
children  as  well  as  adults.  To  be  sure,  owners  of  radios  can  turn  him  off 
by  a  twist  of  the  dial,  but  there  is  no  denying  the  fact  that  free  speech  on 
the  radio  is  actually  something  different  from  free  speech  from  a  soap-box 
on  a  street  corner.  This  fact  has  been  well  expressed  by  Owen  D.  Young: 

Freedom  of  speech  for  the  man  whose  voice  can  be  heard  a  few  hundred  feet 
is  one  thing.  Freedom  of  speech  for  the  man  whose  voice  can  be  heard  around 
the  world  is  another.  .  .  .  The  preservation  of  free  speech  now  depends  upon 
the  exercise  of  a  wise  discretion  by  him  who  undertakes  to  speak.  .  .  . 

No  one  can  take  any  exception  to  this  as  a  statement  of  principle ;  but 
unfortunately,  in  practice,  "a  wise  discretion  on  the  air"  means  a  high 
degree  of  sensitivity  with  respect  to  the  vested  economic  and  religious 
interests.  The  liberal  or  radical  is  the  person  who  has  to  be  discreet. 

74  Ibid.,  p.  254. 

75  For  details  of  this  censorship  and  the  films  excluded,  see  Ernst  and  Lindey,  The 
Censor  Marches  On,  pp.  83-84,  97-98,  100-103,  10&-109. 

76  For  intelligent  discussions  of  radio  censorship,  see  Mitchell  Dawson,  "Censorship 
on  the  Air,"  in  American  Mercury,  March,  1934;  M.  F.  Kassner  and  Lucien  Zacharoff, 
Radio  Is  Censored,  American  Civil  Liberties  Union,  November,  1936;   and  "New 
Horizons  in  Hadio,"  The  Annals,  January,  1941,  pp.  37-46,  69-75,  93-96,  102-115.. 


592     PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

It  is  rare  that  any  limitation  is  placed  upon  the  grossest  excesses  of  con- 
servatism and  reaction.  Moreover,  steps  are  taken  to  see  to  it  that  few 
radicals  or  noted  progressives  are  ever  given  a  chance  to  be  either  discreet 
or  indiscreet  over  the  air.  Scores  of  illustrious  reactionaries  give  vent  to 
their  conservative  views  every  week  over  the  air.  But  when  President 
William  8.  Paley  of  Columbia  Broadcasting  System  decided  to  give  Earl 
Browder,  a  Communist,  a  chance  to  speak  over  the  air,  it  created  great 
excitement. 

Radio  censorship,  which  is  extensive  and  effective,  if  very  smooth  and 
adroit,  is  executed  in  the  following  ways:77  (1)  by  refusal  to  sell  time  on 
the  air  or  to  fulfill  contracts;  (2)  by  the  demand  for  copies  of  speeches 
in  advance,  to  be  censored  as  the  station  authorities  deem  best;  (3)  by 
the  threat  of  drowning  out  or  cutting  off  the  speaker  in  the  midst  of  a 
program  when  he  utters  indiscreet  remarks  or  digresses  from  his  manu- 
script; and  (4)  by  the  relegation  of  supposedly  dangerous  speakers  to 
early  morning  hours,  when  all  but  radio  maniacs  are  in  bed.  Radio  cen- 
sorship often  extends  to  unbelievable  trivialities.  For  example,  the 
Columbia  Broadcasting  System  once  denied  the  air  to  a  famous  fisherman 
who  proposed  to  recommend  fishing  for  trout  with  worms,  even  citing  in 
his  support  Calvin  Coolidge,  who  was  then  President  of  the  United  States. 
It  was  feared  that  this  would  alienate  fly  fishermen.  One  of  the  major 
systems  canceled  a  proposed  broadcast  by  a  distinguished  scholar  on  the 
Malthusian  law  of  population,  fearing  that  it  might  offend  certain  re- 
ligious groups.  General  Johnson  was  forbidden  to  the  use  the  word 
syphilis  in  a  broadcast. 

It  has  long  been  the  policy  of  radio  to  exclude  controversial  material 
from  the  air.  Interpreted  in  any  literal  sense,  this  would  exclude  almost 
any  subject  one  might  think  of.  Fierce  controversies  are  raging  over 
even  the  most  abstruse  aspects  of  electromechanics  and  astrophysics. 
In  practice,  the  term  controversial  is  limited  to  religious,  social,  economic, 
and  political  doctrines.  Actually,  the  test  of  what  is  controversial  on  the 
radio  runs  pretty  close  to  the  primitive  conception  of  taboo.  Those  things 
are  controversial  which  are  subversive  of  conservative  opinion  and  institu- 
i^ions,  namely,  any  questioning  of  our  religion,  sex  conventions,  patriotism, 
or  the  capitalistic  system.  Yet  there  is  plenty  of  talk  over  the  air  on 
all  of  these  subjects.  There  are  many  religious  programs  from  daybreak 
to  bedtime.  One  of  our  great  religious  organizations  gives  over  much  of 
its  time  on  the  air  to  denunciation  of  divorce,  birth  control,  and  modern 
views  of  sex.  Patriotism  is  extolled  and  pacifism  is  derided  by  eminent 
defenders  of  the  public  weal.  The  virtues  of  capitalism,  general  and 
particular,  are  daily  pointed  out  with  thoroughness  and  deep  conviction. 
Therefore,  it  seems  that  "controversy"  on  the  air  really  means  the  pro- 
gressive views  on  religion,  sex,  peace,  and  the  economic  order.  Clarence 


77  For  tho  Broadcasters'  Code,  see  Ernst  and  Lindey,  The  Censor  Marches  On, 
pp.  126,  313-316. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP     593 

Darrow  could  not  talk  against  religion,  but  Dr.  S.  Parkes  Cadman  or 
any  eminent  Catholic  theologian  could  freely  speak  for  it.  Even  Harry 
Emerson  Fosdick  was  denied  the  right  to  speak  on  birth  control.  But 
there  is  no  record  of  any  objection  to  vigorous  denunciation  of  birth 
control  on  the  air.  Pacifists  have  had  their  talks  cut  short,  when  they 
were  able  to  get  on  the  air  at  all,  but  there  is  no  record  of  turning  off  a 
valiant  patrioteer.  Communism  is  frequently  assaulted,  but  no  eminent 
Communist  resident  in  this  country  was  invited  to  defend  the  Russian 
experiment  before  June,  1941. 

When  he  was  president  of  the  National  Broadcasting  Company,  M.  E. 
Aylesworth  stated  that  he  would  allow  representatives  of  various  sides  to 
controversial  questions  to  have  access  to  NBC  programs,  but  he  added 
that  they  must  be  official  and  representative  speakers.  In  other  words, 
William  Green  and  Philip  Murray  might  speak  for  organized  labor,  but 
not  John  L.  Lewis,  Norman  Thomas,  or  A.  J.  Muste.  NBC  has  an  Ad- 
visory Council  to  determine  what  material  and  speakers  are  "representa- 
tive." But  there  are  few  eminent  liberals  on  the  Council.  Mr.  Ayles- 
worth, a  shrewd  man,  advised  broadcasting  companies  to  put  a  liberal  or 
radical  on  the  air  occasionally,  so  as  to  preserve  the  illusion  of  fairness 
and  liberality.  This  may  fairly  be  regarded  as  the  general  formula  which 
is  followed,  with  much  caution. 

One  of  the  dangers  to  the  freedom  of  the  air  has  been  alleged  to  be  the 
monopolistic  character  of  radio  broadcasting.  That  there  is  a  real  danger 
in  this  fact  cannot  very  well  be  denied,  but  the  big  companies  have  be- 
haved far  better  than  the  smaller  local  stations  with  respect  to  permitting 
liberal  expressions  over  the  air.  The  Town  Meeting  of  the  Air  is  de- 
livered under  NBC  auspices.  And  it  was  the  Columbia  Broadcasting 
System  that  first  allowed  a  leading  Communist,  Earl  Browder,  to  speak 
over  a  major  chain.  This  situation  is  to  be  expected,  because  it  is  a  well- 
known  fact  that  big  business  is  far  more  enlightened  than  little  business. 
The  logic  in  the  situation  with  regard  to  radio  is  clear  enough.  The 
great  broadcasting  chains  can  exclude  critical  opinion  from  the  air  if  they 
please  to  do  so.  But  they  cannot  alter  the  actual  facts  in  the  economic, 
social,  and  political  scene  in  the  United  States.  The  facts  will  ultimately 
control  the  destiny  of  the  country  and  of  radio.  We  have  two  alterna- 
tives: (1)  Full  knowledge  of  the  facts,  free  discussion  from  different 
angles  of  opinion,  constant  readjustment,  and  peaceful  settlement  of 
class  struggles;  or  (2)  deceit,  censorship,  sullen  resentment,  and,  ulti- 
mately, resort  to  force  and  revolution.  The  interests  of  the  masters  of 
the  air  are  clearly  with  the  promotion  of  the  first  alternative,  which  can 
only  be  accomplished  by  promoting  free  discussion  on  the  air — and 
elsewhere.  The  American  Civil  Liberties  Union  has  laid  out  a  program 
with  respect  to  the  freedom  of  the  air: 

1.  That  all  radio  stations,  in  return  for  the  free  franchise  granted  by  the 
government,  be  required  to  set  aside  desirable  time  for  the  presentation  of  public 
issues.  No  requirement  is  made  as  to  the  forms  of  programs;  merely  that  the 
time  be  made  available  without  cost  for  such  a  purpose. 


594     PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

2.  That  whenever  a  radio  station  puts  on  one  side  of  a  controversial  issue,  at 
least  one  other  side  shall  be  given  an  opportunity  to  be  heard  on  equal  terms. 

3.  That  stations  but  not  speakers  shall  be  relieved  from  responsibility  for 
libel  or  slander  on  programs  given  on  free  time.    This  will  encourage  stations  to 
put  on  controversial  topics,  and  will  do  away  with  the  necessity  of  prior  censor- 
ship of  manuscripts. 

4.  That  stations  shall  keep  records  of  all  applications  for  time  refused,  as  well 
as  granted,  open  "to  reasonable  public  inspection,"  so  that  station  policies  may 
be  checked  and  censorship  recorded. 

In  addition  to  the  censorship  of  radio  by  the  broadcasting  companies, 
the  federal  government  exerts,  as  we  have  seen,  through  the  Federal 
Communications  Commission,  wide  control  over  the  air.  It  determines 
the  number  of  channels  and  stations  which  are  allowed,  licenses  the 
stations,  and  may  revoke  licenses.  It  also  has  gone  on  record  as  to  its 
ideas  respecting  "meritorious"  and  "non-meritorious"  programs.  It  has 
revoked  some  licenses,  for  example,  the  station  of  the  anti-Catholic 
preacher,  Rev.  Robert  P.  Shulcr,  in  California,  and  that  of  the  goat-gland 
therapist,  Dr.  J.  R.  Brinkley,  in  Kansas.  It  reprimanded  and  threatened 
even  the  powerful  NBC  for  the  skit  "Adam  and  Eve,"  put  on  by  Charley 
McCarthy  and  Mae  West.  The  FCC  threatened  station  WAAB  of 
Boston  and  renewed  its  license  only  after  the  station  had  agreed  to  con- 
form to  governmental  opinion  and  policies.78  A  drastic  censorship  of 
radio  was  provided  in  December,  1941,  after  we  entered  the  War,  and  a 
code  of  "wartime  practices"  for  radio  was  issued  on  January  16,  1942. 
Not  only  is  there  censorship  of  news  over  the  radio,  but  interviews  and 
quiz  programs  have  been  sharply  curtailed  or  eliminated  altogether.  So 
has  request  music  and  weather  announcements. 

Remedies  for  Prejudice,   Propaganda,  and 
Censorship 

We  may  now  consider  briefly  the  question  of  possible  remedies  for  the 
growth  of  prejudice,  propaganda,  and  censorship  in  our  era.  This  is  more 
than  a  mere  academic  question,  since  the  very  future  of  civilization  de- 
pends upon  the  possibility  of  promoting  the  cause  of  tolerance  and  truth 
in  our  complicated  age.  If  prejudices,  ever  more  effectively  inculcated 
by  propaganda,  are  to  rule  the  world,  the  outlook  for  civilization  is  dark 
indeed. 

In  totalitarian  states,  there  seems  to  be  no  remedy  whatever  for  the 
spread  of  prejudice,  the  overpowering  force  of  propaganda,  and  the  blight 
of  censorship.  The  latter  are  the  very  bone  and  marrow  of  such  states. 
Even  such  a  drastic  measure  as  the  assassination  of  a  dictator  would 
accomplish  little  in  countries  like  Germany  and  Russia.  The  systems 
of  society  and  government  are  so  well  established  there  that  they  would 
most  certainly  endure  without  the  presence  of  Hitler,  Mussolini  or  Stalin. 
The  system  of  public  education  and  propaganda  existing  in  these  coun- 


78  See  David  Lawrence,  "Censorship  by  the   Communications  Commission,"  in 
Column  Review,  February,  1941,  pp.  8&-90. 


PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP     595 

tries  increases  the  prejudices  of  the  population.  The  rigorous  system  of 
censorship  shuts  off  all  possibility  of  criticism,  and  the  exposure  of  pre- 
vailing prejudices  through  counter-propaganda  is  entirely  out  of  the 
question.  With  respect  to  these  totalitarian  states  we  can  only  await  the 
trend  of  world  events.  The  latter  may  lead  to  the  overthrow  of  such 
states  or  to  the  moderating  of  the  propaganda  and  censorship  existing 
therein. 

In  the  few  important  countries  of  the  world,  which  retain  at  least  some 
semblance  of  democracy,  it  will  still  be  possible  to  prevent  the  triumph  of 
totalitarianism  and  censorship  if  adequate  reform  measures  are  adopted 
with  sufficient  expedition.  But  democracies  must  understand  that  they 
cannot  safely  suppress  any  type  of  propaganda,  even  propaganda  for 
totalitarianism  and  censorship.  The  first  step  toward  the  suppression 
of  propaganda  in  democracy  is  also  the  first  step  toward  totalitarianism, 
and  the  censorship  which  goes  with  the  latter.  This  fact  has  been  elo- 
quently stated  by  Gerald  Johnson  in  the  Virginia  Quarterly  Review: 

When  it  is  proposed  to  suppress  propaganda — that  is  the  moment  to  erect 
a  barricade.  Propaganda  is  a  word  of  evil  repute.  It  is  a  word  that  is  bitter 
on  the  tongues  of  many  honest  men.  Nevertheless,  the  right  to  spread  propa- 
ganda must  be  defended  to  the  death  by  all  men  who  love  liberty,  for  it  is  a  two- 
sided  word,  and  what  is  your  propaganda  is  my  free  speech. 

It  may  be  a  sad  fact,  to  many  it  seems  to  be  an  almost  intolerable  fact,  but  it  is 
a  fact  that  we  cannot  guarantee  the  freedom  of  Alfred  M.  Landon  without  guar- 
anteeing that  of  Earl  Browder,  too;  and  in  a  country  which  puts  the  Communist 
candidate  in  jail  for  trying  to  make  a  political  speech,  it  is  always  possible  that 
the  Republican,  or  any  other  candidate,  might  some  day  be  jailed  for  the  same 
offense. 

The  moment  any  candidate,  however  idiotic,  is  suppressed,  that  moment  we 
make  it  theoretically  possible  to  gain  an  apparent  consent  of  the  governed  by 
fraud,  and  the  foundation  of  our  system  is  no  longer  safe;  but  as  long  as  we 
defend  resolutely  the  right  of  every  silly  ass  to  spread  nonsense,  we  make  doubly 
secure  our  own  right  to  speak  words  of  wisdom,  beauty  and  truth.79 

The  steps  to  be  followed  in  a  democracy,  if  we  wish  to  reduce  prejudice 
and  propaganda  are  perfectly  evident.  In  the  words  of  Clyde  R.  Miller, 
we  must  keep  the  channels  for  the  communication  of  ideas  thoroughly 
open  and  accessible  to  all  classes.  We  must  give  everyone  a  chance  to 
express  himself,  taking  special  care  to  see  to  it  that  those  who  oppose 
us  have  complete  freedom  of  expression. 

An  important  remedial  measure  is  to  expose  clearly  for  the  benefit  of 
the  public  the  nature,  methods,  and  devices  of  propaganda.  To  expose 
propaganda  is  not  difficult.  The  most  subtle  propagandists  are  mere 
babes  in  the  woods,  when  their  output  is  subjected  to  critical  analysis  by 
trained  psychological  experts.  The  Institute  for  Propaganda  Analysis 
has  laid  their  methods  bare  and  exposed  their  devices  with  crystal  clarity. 
In  such  books  as  those  by  Messrs.  Lumley,  Doob,  Riegel,  Seldes,  Rorty, 
Jastrow,  Albig,  and  others,  the  propagandists  are  held  up  where  the  pub- 
lic can  look  them  over  in  a  most  revealing  fashion. 


79  "When  to  Build  a  Barricade,"  in  Virginia  Quarterly  Review,  Spring,  1938,  p.  176. 


596     PREJUDICE,   PROPAGANDA  AND  CENSORSHIP 

The  great  difficulty  is  to  get  such  illuminating  material  into  the  hands 
of  the  public,  so  that  they  can  be  protected  against  the  subtle  wiles  of 
propagandists.  This  is  a  problem,  indeed,  since  the  propagandists  have 
a  strangle  hold  on  the  press,  the  radio,  the  movies,  and  many  of  the 
more  important  forums.  H,  G.  Wells  has  said  that  civilization,  today, 
is  "a  race  between  catastrophe  and  education."  The  salvation  of  public 
opinion  from  complete  domination  by  prejudice  and  propaganda  is  very 
truly  a  race  between  the  propagandists  and  those  who  seek  to  expose 
them.  Unfortunately,  the  dice  are  today  loaded  almost  exclusively  in 
favor  of  the  former.  The  propagandists  are  neither  profound  nor  funda- 
mentally clever.  As  Joseph  Jastrow  has  written: 

What  the  persuaders  and  inspirers  say  is  neither  brilliant  nor  convincing.  It 
is  only  that  you  who  fall  for  it  are  too  easy-going  in  belief.  You  figure  that 
although  this  system  and  that  scheme  may  not  be  all  true,  still  there  must  be 
something  in  it.  But  why  be  content  with  a  scrap  of  truth  salvaged  from  a 
dump?  The  essential  truth  is  not  in  any  part  of  it.  So  far  as  they  are  sincere, 
the  messages  are  trivial,  commonplace,  wordy  and  as  suspect  as  a  raised  check — 
being  worth  far  less  than  their  face  value — if,  indeed,  they  are  good  at  all.80 

Yet,  banality  and  mendacity,  when  in  command  of  the  avenues  of 
communication,  have  far  greater  power  than  the  widest  learning  and 
the  most  penetrating  intelligence,  when  the  latter  are  denied  facilities  for 
reaching  any  considerable  public. 

Propaganda  can  be  good  as  well  as  bad.  Analysis  is  needed  to  deter- 
mine what  is  good  and  what  is  bad.  In  the  United  States,  the  meas- 
uring-stick must  be  the  relation  of  propaganda  to  democratic  principles, 
broken  down  into  their  specific  and  salient  realities.  The  honest  propa- 
gandist, serving  democratic  purposes,  does  not  object  to  analysis.  Other 
propagandists  fear  and  resent  analysis.  They  seek  to  keep  all  salutary 
analysis  of  propaganda  out  of  the  schools,  newspapers,  radio,  and  moving 
pictures. 

Americans  should  be  especially  on  their  guard  against  the  menace  of 
censorship,  especially  in  the  light  of  the  tragic  lessons  afforded  by  the 
experience  of  Europe  in  the  last  twenty  years.  Never  has  it  been  more 
true  that  the  "price  of  liberty  is  eternal  vigilance."  It  was  only  a  little 
over  ten  years  ago  that  Germany  was  a  republic,  with  a  government  more 
democratic  and  liberal  than  that  of  the  United  States.  It  was,  in  name 
at  least,  a  socialist  government.  Yet,  in  the  course  of  a  few  years,  it  was 
transformed  into  a  dictatorship  as  autocratic  and  censorial  as  any  abso- 
lute monarchy  of  early  modern  times.  The  same  kind  of  transforma- 
tion can  easily  take  place  in  our  own  country  if  we  do  not  remain  alert 
to  the  symptoms  of  intolerance,  bigotry,  and  censorship,  which  are  the 
harbingers  of  totalitarianism.81  We  have  no  automatic  and  spontaneous 
safeguards  against  totalitarianism.  Indeed,  in  some  ways  we  are  better 
prepared  to  receive  and  cherish  it  than  was  Germany  in  1932. 

80  Joseph  Jastrow,  The  Betrayal  of  Intelligence,  Greenberg,  Publisher,  Inc.,  1938, 
pp.  13-14. 

81  See  above,  pp.  295  ff. 


PREJUDICE,    PROPAGANDA  AND   CENSORSHIP     597 

Nobody  has  more  briefly  and  cogently  stated  the  ease  against  the  in- 
tellectual stupidity  and  social  futility  of  all  censorship  than  has  James 
Harvey  Robinson: 

I  am  opposed  to  all  censorship,  partly  because  we  already  have  Draconian 
Jaws,  and  police  willing  to  interfere  on  slight  pretense  in  cases  in  which  the  public 
sense  of  propriety  seems  likely  to  be  shocked;  partly  because,  as  Milton  long 
ago  pointed  out,  censors  are  pretty  sure  to  be  fools,  for  otherwise  they  would 
not  consent  to  act.  Then  I  am  a  strong  believer  in  the  fundamental  value  of 
sophistication.  I  would  have  boys  and  girls  learn  early  about  certain  so-called 
"evils" — and  rightly  so-called — so  that  they  can  begin  to  reckon  with  them  in 
time.  I  have  no  confidence  in  the  suppression  of  every-day  facts.  We  are  much 
too  skittish  of  honesty.  When  we  declare  that  this  or  that  will  prove  demoraliz- 
ing, we  rarely  ask  ourselves,  demoralizing  to  whom  and  how?  We  have  a  suffi- 
ciently delicate  machinery  already  to  prevent  the  circulation  of  one  of  Thorstein 
Veblcn's  philosophic  treatises  and  Mr/  CabelPs  highly  esoteric  romance.  For 
further  particulars  see  the  late  John  Milton's  "Areopagitica"  passim.  To  judge 
by  the  conduct  of  some  of  our  college  heads  the  influence  of  this  book  is  confined 
to  a  recognition  of  its  noble  phraseology,  with  little  realization  of  the  perennial 
value  of  the  sentiments  it  contains.82 


8-  From  a  letter  to  the  editor,  Literary  Digest,  June  23,  1923. 


PART  V 
Family  and  Community  Disorganization 


CHAPTER  XV 
Marriage  and  the  Family  in  Contemporary  Society 

The  Historical   Development  of  the   Human   Family 

OUR  SIMIAN  heritage  seems  to  provide  some  of  the  leading  traits  which 
account  for  the  relative  permanence  of  human  mating.  Man,  with  other 
simians,  shares  the  unique  physiological  trait  of  having  no  distinct  mating 
season.  Among  other  animals  the  females  are  not  usually  susceptible 
to  sex  stimulation  except  during  the  mating  season,  and  the  males  are 
sexually  aggressive  only  when  the  females  are  receptive  to  their  atten- 
tions during  the  mating  period.  The  primates  and  other  simians,  on  the 
contrary,  are  constantly  accessible  to  sex  stimulation.  This  trait  natu- 
rally facilitated  and  encouraged  permanent  sex  pairing. 

Other  simian  traits  are  the  tendency  to  bear  fewer  young  than  other 
animals  and  the  longer  period  of  helplessness  on  the  part  of  offspring. 
These  characteristics  are  particularly  developed  in  the  human  race. 
Much  has  been  made  by  anthropologists  of  the  long  period  of  dependence 
of  the  human  child  upon  its  mother.  John  Fiske,  for  example,  attributed 
the  very  origins  of  organized  human  society  to  this  fact. 

Certain  sociologists  have  tried  to  find  unique  qualities  in  the  human 
pairing  relation.  They  hold,  for  example,  that  man  has  an  innate 
antipathy  to  incest  and  inbreeding,  that  there  is  an  inborn  feeling  of 
modesty  or  shame  with  respect  to  sex  matters,  that  the  affection  existing 
between  human  males  and  females  is  not  encountered  in  lower  animals, 
that  chastity  is  universally  insisted  upon  in  the  case  of  unmarried  women 
and  fidelity  in  the  case  of  married  women,  and  that  human  beings  crave 
social  approval  of  their  sexual  behavior.  That  many  of  these  traits  have 
dominated  the  historical  family  in  most  cases  is  evident,  but  this  fact 
must  be  attributed  to  cultural  factors  rather  than  psychological  or 
physiological  qualities  unique  in  the  human  race.  Modesty,  chastity, 
aversion  to  incest,  social  approval  of  sex  activities,  and  the  like,  are 
purely  cultural  in  their  origin.  None  of  these  things  can  be  called 
instinctive  with  man.  They  have  been  brought  about  by  social  experi- 
ence and  the  growth  of  folkways. 

Though  human  love  is  obviously  different  in  degree  from  the  affection 
shown  in  the  pairing  arrangements  of  even  the  higher  apes,  it  can 
scarcely  be  demonstrated  to  be  different  in  kind.  Moreover,  much  of 
the  difference  in  degree  in  the  case  of  human  love  is  a  matter  of  culture 

601 


602  CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS 

rather  than  of  biology.  The  human  family,  very  obviously,  rests  upon 
physiological  facts  and  tendencies  which  antedate  the  origins  of  the 
human  race.  The  highly  varied  forms  of  sex  relations  and  marriage 
among  human  beings  are,  however,  a  distinctly  human  contribution  and 
an  outgrowth  of  the  cultural  and  institutional  experience  of  the  human 
race. 

Before  the  rise  of  anthropology  and  historical  sociology,  it  was  thought 
that  the  monogamous  family,  namely,  the  permanent  pairing  of  one  male 
and  one  female,  was  characteristic  of  all  peoples  in  all  times.  This  was 
a  fundamental  Christian  dogma.  Every  known  form  of  family  other  than 
the  monogamous  arrangement  was  held  to  be  exceptional  and  the  work 
of  the  devil.  Indeed,  before  the  Christians,  the  Jews  had  denounced  the 
polygyny  (often  erroneously  known  as  polygamy)  of  the  Gentile  peoples, 
even  though  the  man  who  was  traditionally  the  wisest  of  all  the  Jews, 
Solomon,  was  exceptionally  successful  in  bringing  together  one  of  the 
largest  harems  of  recorded  history. 

When  the  science  of  anthropology,  or  the  study  of  primitive  peoples, 
came  into  being  on  the  heels  of  Darwin's  enunciation  of  the  doctrine  of 
evolution,  the  earlier  theories  of  the  predominance  of  monogamy  were 
very  roughly  handled.1  According  to  many  anthropologists  of  the  early 
evolutionary  school,  something  pretty  close  to  promiscuity  prevailed  in 
the  first  stages  of  primitive  society,  and  there  was  little  permanent  mating. 
The  first  system  of  mating  was  group  marriage,  out  of  which  polygyny 
arose.  In  the  earliest  period  of  polygyny,  relationships  in  the  family  were 
traced  through  the  mothers  only.  In  due  time,  as  a  result  of  wife  capture, 
wife  purchase,  and  the  economic  conditions  of  pastoral  life,  this  maternal 
system  was  transformed  into  the  paternal  family,  in  which  relationships 
were  traced  through  males,  and  the  predominant  power  in  the  family  was 
assumed  by  the  males.  Out  of  this  paternal  but  polygynous  family,  mo- 
nogamy gradually  evolved  as  the  final  stage  of  family  life. 

Some  of  the  early  writers  on  family  origins,  such  as  the  'German-Swiss 
philologist  J.  J.  Bachofen,  alleged  that  there  had  not  only  been  a  maternal 
family  but  also  a  definite  period  in  which  women  exerted  the  dominant 
authority  in  political  and  military  life,  the  age  of  the  so-called  Matri- 
archate.  Even  in  the  twentieth  century,  reputable  writers  have  revived 
something  like  this  earlier  notion  of  the  evolution  of  monogamy  from 
primitive  promiscuity  and  later  maternal  rule.  Especially  notable  in  this 
connection  was  the  voluminous  work  of  Robert  Briffault  on  The  Mothers, 
published  in  1927.  His  views  were  less  extreme  than  those  of  the  older 
anthropologists,  but  in  a  general  way  he  upheld  their  notion  of  female 
ascendency  in  primitive  society. 

The  dogmas  of  the  older  evolutionary  anthropologists  with  respect  to 
the  gradual  evolution  of  human  monogamy  out  of  a  primordial  promis- 
cuity were  first  attacked  in  sweeping  fashion  by  a  Finnish  anthropologist 
and  sociologist,  Edward  Westermarck,  who  published  the  first  edition  of 


1  See  above,  pp.  44-45. 


CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS  603 

his  famous  History  of  Human  Marriage  in  1891.  After  an  extensive  sur- 
vey of  marriage  relations  among  many  primitive  peoples,  Westermarck 
contended  that  monogamy  has  been  the  prevalent  type  of  human  family 
relationship  from  the  earliest  days.  Other  forms  of  family  arrangements 
Westermarck  believed  to  be  exceptional,  even  though  frequent  at  certain 
times  and  places.  Westermarck  tried  to  support  his  theory  by  appeals 
to  biology.  He  pointed  to  fairly  permanent  pairing  relationships  among 
the  higher  apes  and  laid  special  stress  upon  the  prolongation  of  human 
infancy  as  a  force  making  for  human  monogamy.  Westermarck's  con- 
clusions have  been  generally  accepted,  with  a  few  qualifications,  as  the 
accurate  interpretation  of  the  nature  and  development  of  the  human 
family.  They  were  the  more  convincing  because  Westermarck,  a  tolerant 
liberal  on  sexual  matters,  had  no  personal  axe  to  grind  in  defending  mo- 
nogamy. 

The  theory  that  women  once  ruled  over  society — the  notion  of  a  so- 
called  matriarchate — has  been  rather  ruthlessly  disposed  of  by  scientific 
contemporary  anthropologists.  They  have  shown  that  most  of  the  evi- 
dence upon  which  Bachofen  and  others  relied  to  support  any  such  con- 
tention was  either  unreliable  or  misinterpreted,  or  both.  It  is  well  known 
that,  in  primitive  society,  we  have  both  maternal  and  paternal  families, 
that  is,  families  in  which  relationships  are  traced  exclusively  through  the 
mother  or  solely  through  the  father.  But  Franz  Boas  and  his  disciples 
have  raised  serious  doubt  as  to  whether  the  maternal  family  was  always 
an  older  type  than  the  paternal  family,  and  they  are  even  more  inclined 
to  doubt  that  the  paternal  family  arose  out  of  the  maternal.  It  seems 
that  historic  conditions,  in  time,  favored  the  paternal  family.  Briffault's 
work  gave-  evidence  of  immense  industry  and  great  learning,  but  his 
efforts  to  rehabilitate  the  older  notions  about  human  promiscuity  and 
the  predominance  of  maternal  society  have  been  undermined  by  Bronislaw 
Malinowski,  Robert  H.  Lowie,  and  other  present-day  anthropologists. 
Malinowski's  books  on  The  Father  in  Primitive  Psychology  (1927)  and 
The  Sexual  Life  of  Savages  (1929)  are  a  convincing  answer  to  Briffault's 
notions.  The  attempt  of  Mathilde  and  Mathis  Vaerting  to  rehabilitate 
the  theory  of  the  matriarchate  on  sentimental  and  feminist  grounds  in 
their  book,  The  Dominant  Sex  (1923),  is  even  less  convincing  than 
Briffault's  erudite  labors. 

Anthropologists  warn  against  reading  back  into  primitive  times  our  own 
notions  with  respect  to  the  monogamous  family.  In  historic  times  the 
monogamous  family  has  been  the  basic  social  unit,  dominating  sex  habits, 
and  controlling  many  other  forms  of  social  usage.  But  in  primitive 
society  it  frequently  did  not  exert  anysuch  clear  dominion  over  social 
life^  The  monogamous  family  was  often  ari'ected  by  many  other  social 
usages — for  example,  by  the  marriage  class  system  among  the  natives  of 
Australia  and  by  other  complicated  relationship  systems  in  primitive 
society.  Further,  the  clan  and  gens  system  directly  modified  the  status 
of  the  monogamous  family  among  primitives.  The  clan  and  gens  system 
proclaimed  a  fictitious  relationship  among  all  members  of  a  clan  or  gens, 


604  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS 

even  though  any  direct  blood  relationship  was  non-existent  in  many  cases. 
Therefore,  while  monogamy  has  always  dominated  the  marriage  scene, 
we  must  not  think  of  primitive  monogamy  as  being  identical  in  social 
status  and  functions  with  the  monogamy  of  the  rural  Christian  family 
prior  to  the  Industrial  Revolution. 

There  have  been  other  types  of  family  relationships,  most  notable 
among  them  being  polyandry  and  polygyny.  Polyandry  means  the  mar- 
riage of  one  woman  to  several  men,  who  may  or  may  not  be  brothers. 
In  Tibet,  where  it  was  usual  for  several  brothers  to  marry  one  woman,  the 
elder  brother  usually  enjoyed  certain  special  privileges  and  powers.  In 
other  polyandrous  situations  the  husbands  might  have  equal  rights  to 
their  common  wife.  Polyandry  has  been  relatively  rare  as  a  form  of 
human  family.  The  main  explanation  offered  for  its  existence  is  that  it 
best  serves  the  sex  needs  of  man  in  regions  where  nature  is  extremely 
unproductive  and  the  resources  of  the  community  do  not  permit  universal 
monogamy — where  one  man  finds  it  difficult  to  support  a  family.  Poly- 
andry has  also  been  explained  as  being  due  to  an  excess  of  males  in  any 
given  locality,  but  this  is  probably  more  unusual  as  a  cause  than  the 
barren  character  of  natural  resources. 

In  contrast  to  polyandry,  polygyny,  or  the  marriage  of  one  man  to  sev- 
eral women,  has  usually  been  produced  by  exceptional  riches  and  pros- 
perity. In  no  instance  has  polygyny  prevailed  among  all  the  inhabitants 
of  any  given  region.  It  has  almost  always  been  restricted  to  the  more 
wealthy  in  the  population.  It  has  persisted  right  down  to  our  own  day 
in  a  sub-rosa  and  non-institutionalized  mode  of  expression,  namely  in 
the  frequent  tendency  of  rich  males  to  support,  besides  an  institution- 
alized wife  and  family,  one  or  more  mistresses. 

A  number  of  clearly  evident  factors  have  tended  to  encourage  polygyny. 
Sexual  ardor,  adventuresomeness,  the  desire  for  display  and  prestige, 
and  the  zeal  for  novelty  on  the  part  of  man  have  almost  invariably  pro- 
vided strong  psychological  motivations  for  polygyny.  Among  primitive 
peoples,  and  in  early  historic  societies,  the  capture  of  women  in  war  made 
it  natural  for  victorious  males  to  appropriate  a  number  of  captive  women. 
Slavery  also  facilitated  polygyny;  attractive  slave  women  often  became 
c6ncubines  of  their  masters,  who  were  already  equipped  with  an  institu- 
tionalized family. 

Political  and  military  considerations  have  also  been  operative.  Po- 
lygyny made  it  possible  for  the  males  of  the  ruling  class  to  beget  many 
more  children  than  would  have  been  possible  under  a  monogamous 
system.  Polygyny  was  also  frequently  conferred  as  a  reward  for  military 
valor  and  strategic  prowess.  Religion  often  rationalized  and  approved 
the  prevailing  practice  of  polygyny  among  the  ruling  class  of  society, 
whom  the  priests  desired  to  placate  and  favor,  in  return  for  support  of 
the  prevailing  cult. 

Of  all  the  moral  influences  which  have  helped  to  undermine  polygyny 
as  a  fairly  open  and  general  practice  among  wealthy  males,  the  Hebrew 
and  Christian  religions  have  probably  been  the  most  powerful.  But 


CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS  605 

they  have  more  usually  driven  it  underground  into  non-institutionalized 
manifestations  rather  than  completely  extinguished  it.  Male  sexual 
ardor  has  proved  too  powerful  for  any  type  of  religion  thoroughly  to 
uproot  or  completely  to  discipline. 

While  the  Jewish  and  Christian  religions  have  supplied  the  chief 
moral  sanction  for  monogamy,  and  have  exerted  the  main  psychological 
pressure  in  its  favor,  many  other  factors  have  tended  to  make  it  the  pre- 
dominant type  of  family.  The  extremes  of  poverty  and  prosperity  which 
favor  polyandry  or  polygyny,  respectively,  have  not  been  characteristic 
of  human  society  as  a  whole.  Also,  the  relative  equality  of  the  two  sexes 
in  numbers  has  inevitably  encouraged  monogamous  forms  of  pairing. 
Moreover,  monogamy  facilitates  devotion  to  children,  since  both  parents 
can  give  their  undivided  attention  to  the  offspring  of  a  single  woman. 
Monogamy  also  tends  to  develop  sentimental  affection.  The  monoga- 
mous family  is  a  more  cohesive  and  restricted  form  of  social  unit  and  sim- 
plifies blood  relationships.  Monogamy  also  creates  far  better  protection 
and  much  greater  solicitude  for  the  wife  than  can  prevail  under  polygyny. 
When,  to  these  many  natural  advantages  of  monogamy,  was  added  the 
sanction  of  an  authoritative  religious  system,  it  is  not  difficult  to  under- 
stand why  monogamy  has  predominated  among  the  western  Christian 
civilizations. 

In  the  ancient  Near  Orient,  the  monogamous  family  was  prevalent 
among  the  masses,  with  polygyny  relatively  common  among  the  richer 
males.  The  position  of  women  in  Egypt  was  a  favored  one,  not  matched 
in  subsequent  history  until  very  recent  times.  Many  queens  ruled  the 
country,  and,  more  than  that,  the  property  and  inheritance  rights  of 
women  were  fully  recognized.  Perhaps  most  important  of  all  was  the 
fact  that  property  was  inherited  through  the  mother: 

Egypt  had  kept  very  ancient  traditions  of  the  eminent  right  of  women  to 
inheritance  .  .  .  the  wife,  though  subordinate  in  fact,  was  independent  by  right. 
.  .  .  The  wife  of  a  prince  gave  her  sons  the  right  to  rule.  The  wife  of  royal 
race  was  the  keeper  of  the  royal  heritage  and  transmitted  the  right  of  kingship 
to  her  children  alone.2 

It  is  thought  by  many  Egyptologists  that  these  facts  indicate  the  prev- 
alence of  the  maternal  family  and  matrilineal  relationships  in  prehistoric 
Egypt. 

Among  the  Semites  of  early  western  Asia,  the  paternal  system  domi- 
nated and  rigorous  patriarchal  authority  frequently  evolved.  Polygyny 
was  very  common  among  Oriental  Semites  other  than  the  Hebrews,  and 
the  latter  were  unable  to  stamp  it  out  entirely  within  their  own  domains. 
One  of  the  chief  contributions  of  the  Hebrews  to  the  history  of  the  family 
was  their  sanctification  of  monogamy  and  the  introduction  therein  of 
strong  patriarchal  tendencies  revealed  in  the  Old  Testament.  The  au- 
thoritarian family,  which  emphasized  both  monogamy  and  male  dominion 


2  Alexandra  Moret,  The  Nile  and  Egyptian  Civilization,  Knopf,  1921,  p.  306. 


606  CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS 

and  was  adopted  by  the  Christian  Church  in  the  later  Roman  Empire, 
is  primarily  a  heritage  from  the  Hebrews.  But  polygyny  continued  to 
prevail  in  the  Orient  from  ancient  times  to  our  own.  It  was  common 
among  the  Persians  and  also  among  the  Arab  sheiks.  From  these 
sources  it  was  taken  up  by  Islam  and  was  practiced  by  the  richer  Muslims 
from  the  days  of  Mohammed  himself  to  our  own  time.  Only  in  1926 
was  it  abolished  in  Turkey,  with  the  introduction  of  the  new  social 
system  by  Mustapha  Kemal. 

Among  the  Greeks,  particularly  the  Attic  Greeks,  the  family  occupied 
a  rather  npeciul  position.  It  was  rather  thoroughly  divorced  from  the 
elements  of  romance  and  sentiment,  thus  showing  that  the  monogamous 
family  can  prevail  without  any  romantic  foundation.  The  Greek  family 
was  a  purely  practical  affair,  which  existed  primarily  for  the  purpose  of 
breeding  and  rearing  children.  The  Greek  wife  was  kept  in  the  home 
and  denied  any  legitimate  sexual  freedom  outside.  There  was  much 
sex  freedom  for  the  Greek  men,  who  found  their  romantic  attachments 
outside  the  family  with  mistresses  of  a  high  intellectual  order  or  satisfied 
their  promiscuous  sex  cravings  through  relations  with  prostitutes.  In 
Sparta,  male  adultery  was  given  a  quasi-institutional  sanction  as  a 
method  of  producing  more  male  children,  who  were  highly  prized  as 
future  members  of  the  Spartan  army  and  military  caste. 

The  Roman  family  passed  through  a  notable  historical  evolution. 
It  started  out  as  a  rather  extreme  manifestation  of  patriarchal  monogamy, 
in  which  the  father  or  eldest  living  male  had  almost  absolute  authority 
over  his  wife  and  children,  even  to  the  extent  of  inflicting  death  for 
what  were  considered  legitimate  reasons.  Adultery  on  the  part  of  the 
wife  was  severely  punished  and  divorce  was  almost  literally  unheard  of. 
Religious,  social,  and  military  considerations  made  the  early  Roman 
family  extremely  cohesive. 

During  the  later  Republic  and  the  early  Empire,  this  type  of  Roman 
family  all  but  disappeared.  The  free  Roman  peasantry,  which  provided 
the  social  and  economic  foundation  for  the  patriarchal  Roman  family, 
were  almost  extinguished  as  a  result  of  wars,  the  growth  of  great  estates, 
and  the  working  of  the  land  by  slave  gangs.  With  the  growth  of  wealth, 
as  a  result  of  conquest  and  commerce,  the  richer  Romans  desired  to  free 
themselves  from  the  older  restrictions  upon  promiscuity.  The  presence 
of  many  beautiful  captives  and  slave  women  encouraged  their  zeal  in  this 
regard.  The  dispossessed  peasants  and  others  who  flocked  to  the  cities, 
especially  Rome,  became  an  urban  rabble,  herded  together  in  miserable 
slums  and  apartments. 

These  conditions  undermined  the  old  religious  and  patriarchal  family 
of  early  rural  Rome  among  the  urban  masses.  Marriage  was  no  longer 
a  sanctified  social  institution,  but  became  a  civil  contract.  There  was  a 
limited  development  of  a  sort  of  feminist  movement  at  this  time,  giving 
the  women  the  right  to  hold  some  property  and  other  new  privileges 
which  made  for  a  greater  degree  of  female  independence.  It  was  natural 
that  divorce  would  become  far  more  common  under  these  conditions.  In- 


CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS  607 

deed,  it  became  extremely  prevalent,  particularly  among  the  upper  classes, 
and  not  even  Augustus  was  able  to  check  its  prevalence.  There  was  a 
great  deal  of  vice  among  the  city  rabble. 

The  downfall  of  the  old  Roman  family  was  most  marked  at  the  end  of 
the  Republic  and  during  the  first  century  of  the  Empire.  During  the 
latter  part  of  the  Roman  period,  marriage  was  once  more  restored,  at 
least  among  the  masses,  to  its  former  sanctity  and  cohesiveness.  The 
predominance  of  Christian  ideals  during  the  later  Roman  Empire  has 
suggested  to  scholars  that  we  must  qualify  the  older  view  that  the  Roman 
Empire  disintegrated  because  of  the  downfall  of  the  Roman  family  and 
the  increase  of  sexual  promiscuity.  The  Empire  actually  fell  apart 
during  those  centuries  when  the  Christian  influence  was  most  effective 
in  checking  the  immorality  of  the  Romans.  But,  no  doubt,  the  condi- 
tions which  had  prevailed  before  the  Christian  triumph  exerted  a  power- 
ful influence  for  many  generations  thereafter. 

Under  the  influence  of  Paul,  Augustine,  and  other  sex  purists,  marriage 
was  made  a  sacrament  and  brought  under  ecclesiastical  dominion. 
Divorce  was  outlawed,  though  separation  and  the  annulment  of  marriage 
were  sanctioned.  Patriarchal  parental  authority  was  encouraged  by 
church  doctrine.  The  chastity  of  women  was  extolled,  and  virginity 
became  a  veritable  cult.  The  fact  that  medieval  life  was  primarily  rural 
made  it  possible  for  the  church  to  carry  through  the  revolution  in  morals 
and  family  relationships  with  relative  success.  Country  life  is  far  more 
favorable  to  authoritarian  monogamy  than  the  more  complicated  con- 
ditions of  city  life.  The  chivalrous  ideals  with  respect  to  noblewomen 
eased  the  conscience  of  feudal  lords,  who  ravished  unprotected  non- 
noblewomen  almost  at  will.  By  forbidding  marriage  of  the  clergy,  the 
Catholics  deprived  religious  leaders  of  the  benefits  of  family  life,  at  the 
same  time  ridding  them  of  its  responsibilities.  While  the  formal  celibacy 
of  the  clergy  was  taken  for  granted  during  the  medieval  period,  it  was 
not  uncommon  for  priests,  monks,  and  friars  to  maintain  concubines,  and 
to  have  children  by  them.  The  church  frowned  on  this  but  was  not  able 
to  eliminate  the  practice  until  after  the  reforms  which  accompanied  the 
Counter-Reformation. 

Protestantism  brought  with  it  a  number  of  important  changes  with 
respect  to  sex  practices  and  ideals.  It  was  as  strongly  against  sexual 
sin  and  promiscuity  as  were  the  Catholics,  but  it  believed  that  the  celibacy 
of  the  clergy  increased  rather  than  reduced  clerical  immorality.  Inas- 
much as  the  Protestant  leaders  drew  many  of  their  moral  ideals  from  the 
Old  Testament  rather  than  the  New,  they  tended  to  stress  patriarchal  au- 
thority in  the  family.  With  the  Calvinistic  emphasis  on  thrift,  it  was 
natural  that  the  economic  value  of  the  housewife  would  not  be  overlooked. 
And  the  Calvinistic  stress  upon  the  moral  virtues  of  hard  work  was 
emphasized  as  of  particular  relevance  for  the  wife.  The  Protestant  ideal 
of  the  good  wife  was  one  who  was  both  obedient  unto  her  husband  and 
passionately  devoted  to  industry  and  thrift.  The  Protestants  laid  con- 
siderable stress  upon  the  values  of  education.  Since  there  were  few 


608  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS 

public  schools  for  the  masses,  the  family  long  had  to  assume  most  of  the 
responsibility  for  such  education  as  the  average  child  received. 

The  Protestant  theories  with  regard  to  the  family  were  brought  to 
America  and  received  their  most  complete  development  on  the  rural 
frontier.  The  sparsity  of  population  and  the  isolation  of  the  rural  family 
in  America  made  the  family  the  center  of  economic,  social,  educa- 
tional, and  recreational  life.  Dangers  from  natural  and  human  enemies 
encouraged  parental  authority,  discipline,  and  respect.  The  economic 
value  of  the  family  was  very  great,  because  there  was  intense  need  for 
the  labor  of  women  and  children.  Social  contacts  being  relatively  few, 
the  family  divided  with  the  rural  church  the  chief  place  in  social,  intellec- 
tual, and  recreational  life.  And  the  time  spent  in  the  family  was  far  in 
excess  of  that  devoted  to  the  worship  of  God,  even  in  those  days  when 
families  frequently  spent  all  day  Sunday  in  adoration  of  the  Deity. 
The  predominant  importance  of  the  family  during  some  two  centuries  of 
American  rural  life  gained  for  it  a  preeminent  place  in  our  institutional 
equipment  and  our  respect.  The  authoritative  rural  family  became  iden- 
tified with  the  absolute  ideal  in  matrimonial  arrangements. 

The  Break-up  of  the  Traditional   Patriarchal 
Rural   Family 

The  traditional  patriarchal  monogamy  is  now  undergoing  thorough  re- 
construction in  our  urban  era.  The  divorce  rate  has  increased  steadily 
in  the  last  half  century ;  today  there  is  one  divorce  for  every  six  marriages 
in  our  country.  Family  desertions  are  extremely  common,  though  such 
evidence  as  we  possess  about  their  number  does  not  indicate  that  they  are 
increasing  as  rapidly  as  divorce.  As  divorce  becomes  easier,  desertion 
is  less  necessary  or  attractive,  for  the  legal  responsibilities  of  family 
life  are  not  obliterated  by  desertion.  We  have  already  pointed  out  that 
there  is  a  much  greater  prevalence  of  sexual  freedom  outside  of  the  family 
than  was  common  a  half  century  ago.  Many  of  the  functions  of  the 
family  are  now  taken  over  by  other  agencies.3  In  certain  circles  of  life, 
especially  in  cities,  children  are  no  longer  an  economic  asset  but  a 
notable  financial  liability.  Some  of  the  most  sacred  ideals  of  the  older 
family  life  and  sexual  morality  are  today  often  regarded  with  much  light- 
heartedness,  especially  on  the  part  of  the  younger  generation. 

Among  the  major  reasons  for  the  undermining  of  the  traditional 
family  are  the  economic  developments  associated  with  modern  industrial- 
ism, and  the  growth  of  a  secular  outlook  which  challenges  the  authori- 
tarian religious  foundations  of  the  conventional  family.  While  the  latter 
has  been  most  influential  in  changing  our  attitudes  toward  the  family, 
there  is  little  doubt  that  economic  influences  have  been  more  immediately 
and  comprehensively  potent  in  actually  bringing  about  the  downfall  of 
the  old  rural  family.  The  latter  is  no  longer  the  center  of  economic 


See  below,  pp.  645-648. 


CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS  609 

life.  Many  more  people  buy  their  food  than  produce  it.  Most  goods 
are  now  made  in  factories  and  purchased  from  distributors.  The  work 
of  women  and  children  becomes  progressively  less  important  to  the  family 
in  an  urban  era.  Further,  legislation  limiting  the  work  of  women  and 
children,  especially  the  latter,  has  made  it  less  possible  for  these  younger 
persons  to  contribute  to  the  income  of  the  family  group.  Indeed,  in  urban 
life,  children  are  generally  a  serious  liability,  so  far  as  family  finances 
are  concerned.  Industrialism  made  possible  the  remunerative  employ- 
ment of  women  and  thus  gave  them  an  economic  independence  which  they 
have  never  previously  known  as  a  class.  Hence,  millions  of  them  no 
longer  have  to  depend  upon  a  husband  for  their  maintenance. 

Of  all  the  indirect  effects  of  modern  industrialism  upon  the  older  family, 
it  is  probable  that  the  rise  of  city  life  has  been  the  most  demoralizing. 
Almost  everything  used  by  the  city  family  is  produced  outside  the  family 
circle.  All  of  the  food  materials  are  thus  provided,  and  frequently  much 
of  the  cooking  is  done  in  commercial  bakeries.  The  declicatessen  shop  is 
slowly  but  surely  crowding  out  the  kitchen  in  the  urban  family.  In- 
deed, many  city  families  eat  almost  exclusively  in  restaurants,  so  that 
not  only  the  kitchen,  but  the  dining-room  as  well  has  been  taken  out  of 
the  home.  Likewise,  amusement  and  recreation  are  sought  mainly  out- 
side the  family  circle.  The  radio  and  television  have  modified  this  some- 
what, but  it  is  likely  that  novel  forms  of  outside  entertainment  will  also 
appear  to  offset  this. 

Social  work  and  child  welfare  activities  crowd  in  upon  the  former 
functions  and  responsibilities  of  the  family.  In  Russia,  elaborate  pro- 
visions have  been  made  to  enable  a  nursing  mother  to  work  in  factories 
and  leave,  her  infant  under  expert  care  at  public  expense.  In  the  United 
States,  day  nurseries  have  been  established  in  many  cities  where  the  work- 
ing mother  can  leave  her  child  of  pre-kindergarten  age.  Public  schools 
and  kindergartens  have  usurped  the  educational  function  of  the  tradi- 
tional family.  If  city  life  has  made  children  a  liability,  the  growing 
popularity,  effectiveness,  and  accessibility  of  birth  control  devices  have 
made  it  ever  easier  to  dodge  the  responsibility  of  child  bearing.  They 
also  encourage  the  seeking  of  sexual  satisfactions  without  the  contracting 
of  the  responsibilities  of  matrimony.  The  social  radicalism  promoted  by 
modern  industrialism  has  developed  a  philosophy  antagonistic  to  the 
conventional  family.  Early  in  the  seventeenth  century  a  radical  friar, 
Campanella,  called  attention  to  the  fact  that  the  family  is  the  chief 
bulwark  of  the  institution  of  private  property.  The  radicals,  therefore, 
often  sought  to  break  down  the  sanctity  of  the  family. 

Secularism  has  directly  attacked  supernatural  religion,  which  pro- 
vided the  intellectual  and  moral  foundations  of  the  traditional  family. 
Thoroughgoing  secularism  denies  the  existence  of  any  form  of  supernatural 
sanction  for  any  type  of  social  institution,  family  or  other.  Probably 
the  most  important  influence  of  secularism  upon  the  modern  family  is  the 
divorce  of  sc;x  from  sin.  For  the  first  time  since  the  days  of  Augustine, 
the  notion  of  the  sinfulness  of  sex  has  been  candidly  and  sharply  assailed. 


610  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS 

The  divorce  of  sex  from  supernaturalism  made  this  attitude  inevitable. 
It  is  held  that  no  form  of  sex  activity  can  be  regarded  as  an  affront  to 
the  gods  or  likely  to  place  human  souls  in  jeopardy.  The  family  and 
other  sex  practices  are  judged  by  their  contributions  to  human  welfare, 
here  and  now.  Secularism  is  not  necessarily  hostile  to  the  family  as  a 
means  of  satisfactorily  handling  the  problems  of  sex  and  reproduction. 
Indeed,  it  recommends  monogamy  as  the  normal  and  most  satisfying 
method.  But  it  is  certainly  comprehensively  hostile  to  the  tyranny  of 
indissoluble  monogamy.  The  growth  of  secularism  has  removed  the 
repugnance  from  the  employment  of  birth  control  devices,  for  it  wipes 
away  any  such  notion  as  the  traditional  religious  view  that  birth  control 
is  also  "soul  control"  and  prevents  immortal  souls  from  coming  into 
existence.  Secularism  also  sanctions  sex  satisfaction  outside  the  family 
when  individual  and  social  well-being  may  be  promoted  thereby.  It  is 
quite  possible  that  the  growth  of  secularism  may  ultimately  lead  to  a 
family  system  more  in  accord  with  scientific  facts  and  social  realities 
than  the  old-time  monogamy.  If  so,  it  will  increase  the  success  and  sta- 
bility of  family  life.  But  certainly,  the  secular  outlook  has  thus  far 
exerted  a  corrosive  and  disintegrating  influence  upon  the  traditional 
family  and  its  moral  bulwarks. 

An  able  student  of  contemporary  family  problems,  William  F.  Ogburn, 
has  suggested  that  the  best  way  of  discovering  the  degree  to  which  the 
old  rural  family  has  declined  is  to  investigate  what  has  happened,  of  late, 
to  the  traditional  functions  of  the  authoritarian  family.4  He  lists 
seven  of  these  functions:  (1)  affectional;  (2)  economic;  (3)  educational; 
(4)  protective;  (5)  recreational;  (6)  family  status;  and  (7)  religious. 

The  affectional  function  has  been  less  hard  hit  than  the  older  family 
functions  and  is  probably  the  most  powerful  function  today.  But  its 
weakness  is  shown  by  the  fact  that  about  one  family  in  six  ends  in 
divorce,  that  there  are  many  more  family  desertions,  and  that  innumer- 
able unhappy  families  persist  without  resorting  to  divorce. 

That  the  economic  function  of  the  family  is  being  undermined  by 
modern  technology  and  urban  life  may  be  seen  from  relevant  statistics. 
Tfre  output  of  bakeries  increased  four  times  as  much  between  1914  and 
1925  as  did  the  general  population.  During  the  same  period,  the  products 
of  canning  factories  and  other  food  factories  increased  over  six  times 
as  much  as  the  population.  From  1900  to  1920,  the  number  of  restau- 
rant-keepers and  waiters  increased  about  four  times  as  much  as  the 
population.  The  number  of  delicatessen  stores  increased  about  three 
times  as  rapidly  as  the  population.  The  amount  of  work  done  in  laun- 
dries increased  nearly  four  times  as  rapidly  as  the  population  from  1914 
to  1925.  The  sales  of  sewing-machines  for  home  use  have  also  markedly 
declined  since  1914.  So  have  the  number  of  domestic  servants  employed 
in  the  home,  in  spite  of  the  great  increase  in  wealth  between  1914  and 


4  W.  F.  Ogburn,  "Decline  of  the  American  Family,"  The  New  York  Times  Maga- 
zine, February  17,  1929, 


CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS  611 

1929.  The  number  of  married  women  per  capita  in  the  population  that 
are  gainfully  employed  has  more  than  doubled  since  1900.  Indeed,  about 
one  out  of  every  four  women  employed  outside  the  home  is  a  married 
woman. 

Education  has  become  almost  entirely  a  function  of  the  schools.  The 
number  of  teachers  has  increased  more  than  twice  as  rapidly  as  has  the 
number  of  parents  since  1870.  Children  are  being  taken  into  the  schools 
at  an  earlier  age  and  for  longer  periods — the  school  year  increased  from 
78  days  in  1870  to  136  days  in  1926.  The  protective  function  of  the 
family  is  also  being  appropriated  by  the  state.  The  number  of  police- 
men and  other  official  protective  functionaries  has  increased  by  over  75 
per  cent  since  1910 — about  four  times  as  rapidly  as  the  population. 
Juvenile  courts  and  social  legislation  affecting  children  are  other  exten- 
sions of  the  protective  function  beyond  the  sphere  of  the  family.  In  a 
later  chapter,  dealing  with  recreation,  we  shall  show  how  fully  the 
recreational  function  has  passed  beyond  the  family.  Bridge-playing  and 
listening  to  the  radio  are  about  the  only  forms  of  recreation  which 
remain  primarily  centered  in  the  home. 

Family  status  is  changing.  Fewer  persons  live  in  separate  houses; 
more  live  in  city  apartments,  which  cramp  the  living  habits  of  the  former 
rural  family.  Children  are  no  longer  the  aid  and  protection  they  once 
were.  They  tend  to  disperse,  and  the  parents  rely  more  and  more  on 
insurance  and  annuities  to  protect  them  in  old  age.  The  state  has  also 
stepped  in  with  old  age  insurance. 

As  secularism  undermined  the  religious  functions  of  the  family,  re- 
ligious exercises  in  the  home  became  less  frequent.  Automobiles,  movies, 
and  other  'secular  diversions  help  this  secularizing  trend.  All  in  all,  we 
may  agree  with  Professor  Ogburn's  general  conclusion: 

There  is  no  doubt  that  the  family,  as  a  social  institution,  is  declining.  This 
is  the  conclusion  from  a  series  of  quantitative  studies.  Many  of  us  do  not 
realize  that  the  family  is  declining  or  even  changing.  For  we  are  accustomed 
to  think  of  the  family  as  we  do  of  the  Rock  of  Ages,  something  that  in  the 
nature  of  things  must  always  remain  essentially  unchanged  as  the  foundation 
of  society,  otherwise  civilization  itself  would  not  exist.  And  then  when  the 
day-by-day  changes  are  slight  we  do  not  notice  them.  It  is  when  we  return 
after  a  long  absence  that  we  can  see  the  cumulative  changes  that  have  occurred, 
better  than  those  who  have  not  been  away.5 

The  problem  of  marriage  and  a  home  in  a  changing  civilization  is, 
naturally,  receiving  more  than  usually  serious  attention  from  others  than 
alarmed  traditionalists  and  purists.  Enlightened  persons  recognize  the 
transition  through  which  home  and  family  life  is  passing  and  admit  that 
this  is  not  unrelated  to  the  increase  of  divorce,  desertion,  juvenile  crime, 
juvenile  drunkenness,  and  other  evidences  of  social  demoralization.  The 
home  is  invaded  and  challenged  by  new  distractions  and  amusements. 
Marriage  itself  has  become  strikingly  unstable.  According  to  United 


6  Ogburn,  loc.  cit. 


612  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS 

States  government  statistics,  the  average  family  lasts  for  only  six  years 
and  eight  months. 

Social  historians  recognize  the  broad  economic  and  institutional  changes 
which  have  helped  bring  about  the  instability  of  marriage  and  the  revo- 
lution of  the  home.  The  growth  of  modern  industrialism,  the  rise  of  the 
factory  system,  the  entry  of  women  into  industry,  the  progress  of  univer- 
sal education,  the  appearance  of  the  single  standard  for  the  sexes,  the 
impact  of  the  automobile  upon  the  social  life  and  habits,  and  the  like, 
have,  as  we  noted  above,  all  played  their  part.  But  along  with  these  go 
the  personal  attitudes  of  those  who  approach  the  altar  seeking  holy  wed- 
lock. Some  light  will  certainly  be  thrown  on  the  complex  problems  of 
modern  marriage  by  a  study  of  the  state  of  mind  and  expectations  of 
those  upon  the  eve  of  marriage.  The  Marital  Relations  Institute  of  New 
York  submitted  over  40,000  questionnaires  to  couples  applying  for  mar- 
riage licenses  in  major  cities  of  the  United  States,  extending  all  the  way 
from  New  York  to  Sun  Francisco,  The  most  important  questions  asked 
were : 

1.  Why  arc  you  marrying? 

2.  What  do  you  expect  out  of  marriage  ? 

3.  How  long  do  you  think  your  marriage  will  last? 

4.  Do  you  expect  to  raise  a  family? 

5.  Do  you  expect  to  help  support  your  home?     (Asked  of  women  only.) 

Five  thousand  men  and  13,000  women  answered  the  questionnaire. 
The  lack  of  consideration  of  the  purpose  and  justification  of  marriages 
was  brought  out  by  the  answer  to  question  1.  Only  1,620,  or  9  per  cent 
of  those  who  replied  to  the  questionnaire,  even  attempted  to  answer  this 
question.  Apparently  over  nine  tenths  of  the  couples  could  offer  no  logi- 
cal explanation.  About  half  of  the  small  fraction  that  did  answer 
claimed  that  they  were  doing  so  for  love.  About  a  fourth  of  those  who 
answered  the  question  said  frankly  they  were  marrying  for  security.  An 
amusing  incident  of  this  justification  lay  in  the  fact  that  about  a  third 
of  those  who  claimed  that  they  were  marrying  for  financial  security  were 
men. 

,  Less  than  one  per  cent  of  those  who  answered  declared  that  they  were 
marrying  for  the  purpose  of  bearing  children.  This  means  that  less  than 
one  tenth  of  one  per  cent  of  those  who  answered  the  questionnaire  as  a 
whole  were  marrying  for  the  clear  purpose  of  rearing  progeny. 

As  to  what  the  couples  expected  out  of  marriage,  "financial  security" 
and  "a  good  home"  ran  neck-and-neck  for  first  place  among  answers  to 
question  2.  These  far  out-distanced  romance  and  the  like.  Four  women 
candidly  and  sardonically  declared  that  they  expected  "nothing." 

As  to  how  long  the  expectant  couples  believed  that  their  marriages 
would  last,  the  estimates  ranged  from  "forever"  to  two  years.  The  aver- 
age of  all  answers  submitted  to  this  question  produced  a  composite  figure 
of  a  little  over  16  years,  indicating  nearly  a  300  per  cent  optimism  when 
compared  with  government  figures  as  to  the  duration  of  the  average  mar- 
riage in  this  country  today. 


CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS  613 

Though  only  a  small  fraction  gave  the  bearing  of  children  as  their 
primary  purpose,  a  larger  per  cent  answered  that  they  expected  to  raise 
a  family.  The  men  seemed  far  more  interested  in  propagation  than 
the  women:  some  82  per  cent  of  the  men  and  only  21  per  cent  of  the 
women  intended  to  raise  a  family. 

The  inroads  on  the  theory  that  woman's  place  is  in  the  home  were 
revealed  by  the  fact  that  some  43  per  cent  of  the  women  who  answered 
question  5  expected  to  help  support  their  homes  by  work  outside. 

Thus  leading  reasons  for  the  instability  of  marriage  seem  to  be  the 
absence  of  intelligent  or  rational  consideration  of  the  object  of  matrimony, 
and  the  incidental  place  of  children  in  the  marriage  urge.  The  chief 
stabilizing  influence  would  appear  to  be  the  zeal  for  economic  security, 
but  this  is  mitigated  by  the  fact  that  so  many  women  express  their  inten- 
tion to  contribute  toward  the  support  of  the  home.  Such  women  are 
highly  unlikely  to  submit  for  long  to  an  unpleasant  or  oppressive  home 
environment. 

Feminism  and  the  Changing  Status  of  the  Sexes 

A  social  result  of  the  Industrial  Revolution  has  been  the  growing  inde- 
pendence of  women  and  the  changing  status  of  the  sexes.  In  primitive 
society,  women  often  took  a  prominent  part  in  social  relationships  and 
industrial  operations,  even  though  there  were  few,  if  any,  examples  of  the 
matriarchate  that  anthropologists  once  believed  to  exist.  But,  from  the 
so-called  dawn  of  history  down  to  the  Industrial  Revolution,  civilization 
was  male-dominated,  if  not  literally  "man-made."  The  Industrial  Revo- 
lution slowly  but  siirely  upset  this  state  of  affairs. 

The  underlying  cause  of  the  revolution  in  the  status  of  the  sexes  was 
not  any  rational  or  altruistic  conception  of  the  equality  of  women  on  the 
part  of  the  men.  The  whole  issue  turned  on  the  fact  that  the  new 
mechanical  methods  of  production  opened  the  way  for  widespread  em- 
ployment of  women,  who  were  quite  able  to  watch  and  tend  the  new 
machinery.  We  have  already  noted  in  Chapter  IV  the  deplorable  con- 
ditions under  which  women  first  worked  in  the  new  factories  of  England. 

The  entry  of  women  into  industry  progressed  steadily  in  each  country 
after  the  Industrial  Revolution  reached  it.  In  Germany,  the  number  of 
women  workers  increased  from  5,500,000  in  1882  to  11,400,000  in  1925; 
in  France,  from  6,400,000  in  1896  to  8,600,000  in  1921;  in  England  from 
3,800,000  in  1881  to  5,700,000  in  1921.  A  century  before  1881,  few  women 
were  employed  in  the  English  factories. 

Some  statistics  will  indicate  the  growing  employment  of  women  in  the 
United  States  since  1870.  In  that  year  some  13.1  per  cent  of  all  women 
over  ten  years  of  age  were  gainfully  employed.  In  1880  the  percentage 
had  increased  to  14.7;  in  1890  to  17.4;  in  1900  to  18.8;  and  in  1910  to 
23.4.  By  1920  the  figure  had  dropped  slightly,  to  21.1;  and  there  was  a 
rise  in  1930,  to  22.0.  The  apparent  decline  in  1920  was  not  actual,  but 
the  result  of  a  difference  in  computation.  In  1920,  there  were  some 


614  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS 

8,549,511  women  wage-earners  in  this  country;  and  in  1930  the  census 
listed  some  10,752,116  women  and  girls  as  gainfully  employed.  The  per- 
centage of  married  women  employed  outside  the  home  has  also  increased 
—from  5.6  per  cent  in  1890,  to  11.7  in  1930.  The  table  on  page  615  de- 
scribes in  greater  detail  the  remarkable  entry  of  American  women  into 
industry  since  1870. 

The  industrial  status  of  women  also  improved.  In  1870,  60.7  per  cent 
of  all  women  gainfully  employed  outside  of  agriculture  were  servants  of 
one  kind  or  another.  In  1920,  only  18.2  per  cent  were  listed  as  servants. 
The  occupational  distribution  of  the  10,752,000  American  women  gain- 
fully employed  in  1930  was  as  follows:  Domestic  and  personal  service, 
29.6  per  cent;  clerical,  18.5  per  cent;  manufacturing  and  mechanical, 
17.5;  professional,  14.2  per  cent;  trade,  9  per  cent;  agriculture,  8.5  per 
cent;  and  transportation,  2.6  per  cent.  The  greatest  increase  has  been 
in  business  and  the  professions.  Higher  education  of  women  has  helped 
here.  Half  of  the  graduates  of  the  better  colleges  for  women  are  gainfully 
employed. 

The  wages  and  salaries  paid  to  women  still  remain,  however,  relatively 
low.  The  average  weekly  wage  of  all  women  employed  in  American 
manufacturing  industries  was  approximately  $12  in  the  half-year  from 
July  to  December,  1933,  the  first  half-year  of  "New  Deal"  wage  scales. 
Even  before  the  depression,  the  California  minimum  wage  of  $16  a  week 
for  experienced  women  workers  was  regarded  as  high.  In  representative 
American  industries  the  earnings  of  women  have  been  from  20  to  70 
per  cent  below  men's  earnings,  having  averaged  about  41  per  cent.  By 
and  large,  the  mass  of  American  women  workers  cannot  maintain  decent 
living  standards  on  the  wages  they  receive.  Government  figures  show 
that  the  average  income  of  working  wives  in  families  with  an  annual 
income  of  $1,000  or  under  is  $205.  Of  the  nearly  700,000  women  working 
in  New  York  as  wage-earners  and  in  the  professions,  only  7  per  cent 
earned  over  $60  a  week  even  in  boom  times.  A  careful  study  of  the 
income  of  women  in  business  and  the  professions  in  the  mid-1930's  in- 
dicated that  the  median  yearly  salary  was  $1,548;  that  88  per  cent  earned 
less  than  $2,500  yearly;  that  only  6  per  cent  earned  over  $3,000;  and 
that  only  1.3  per  cent  earned  over  $5,000. 

There  are  three  main  reasons  for  the  lower  salaries  and  wages  of 
women:  (1)  Their  physical  strength  does  not  permit  them  to  carry  on 
some  of  the  heavy  mechanical  trades  for  which  men  receive  relatively 
high  wages.  (2)  There  is  a  lack  of  labor  organization  among  most 
women  workers,  so  that  they  lose  the  advantages  of  collective  bargaining. 
(3)  Many  women  hope  to  marry  and  will  accept  low  pay  rather  than 
fight  for  better  conditions,  because  they  believe  that  their  industrial 
situation  is  a  temporary  one.  Nevertheless,  the  condition  of  the  working 
woman  today  is  better  than  it  was  a  half  century  ago.  Women  held 
their  jobs  during  the  depression  better  than  men  did,  largely  because 
unemployment  was  less  severe  in  the  clothing  industries  than  in  the  heavy 
industries  where  men  predominated.  Another  reason  was  the  lower  wages 


615 


616  CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS 

of  women  at  the  outset  of  the  depression.7  The  Wages  and  Hours  Act  of 
1938  was  of  some  assistance  to  women  in  insuring  them  better  minimum 
incomes. 

The  relatively  unfortunate  position  of  women  industrially  was  one  of 
the  main  reasons  for  their  demand  for  political  equality.  By  getting  the 
vote,  they  hoped  to  pass  laws  that  would  elevate  their  status  and  do  away 
with  their  disabilities.  In  spite  of  the  growth  of  democracy  since  1825, 
only  New  Zealand  enacted  woman  suffrage  before  1900,  taking  this  step 
in  1893.  Australia  followed  suit  in  1902,  as  did  Finland  in  1906,  Norway 
in  1913,  Denmark  in  1915,  and  Sweden  in  1921.  The  devotion  and  sacri- 
fices of  women  in  the  first  World  War  hastened  the  granting  of  the 
suffrage  elsewhere.  England  conceded  limited  suffrage  rights  in  1918 
and  completed  the  process  in  1928  by  giving  the  vote  to  all  women 
over  twenty-one  years  of  age.  The  United  States  extended  the  right  of 
suffrage  to  women  through  the  Nineteenth  Amendment  in  1920.  Most 
of  the  new  constitutions  of  postwar  Europe  embodied  woman  suffrage. 
Russia  established  it  in  1917,  and  Germany  in  1918. 

The  political  equality  of  women  received  a  setback  with  the  growth  of 
dictatorship  in  Europe.  The  patriarchal  male  attitude  reasserted  itself, 
and  the  tendency  was  to  declare  once  again  that  woman's  place  is  in  the 
home,  raising  many  children  to  make  good  soldiers. 

Besides  having  the  right  to  vote,  women  have  taken  important  public 
offices.  We  have  had  women  Congressmen  and  governors — even  a  woman 
Senator.  Frances  Perkins  became  a  cabinet  member  in  March,  1933. 

Women  have  quite  generally  been  admitted  to  jury  service.  Many  of 
them  are  now  practicing  law.  Florence  Allen  was  appointed  to  the 
United  States  Circuit  Court  of  Appeals — the  second  highest  court  in  the 
land — by  President  Roosevelt  in  1934. 

Their  attainment  of  political  equality  has  spurred  women  on  to  secure 
legal  and  economic  equality.  In  the  United  States,  for  example,  in  spite 
of  woman  suffrage,  men  are  in  a  favored  position,  so  far  as  legal  and 
property  rights  are  concerned.  In  most  states  the  husband  has  special 
rights  in  his  claims  on  his  wife's  property  and  services.  He  can  legally 
absolutely  control  her  services  in  the  home  and  to  a  considerable  extent 
elsewhere.  He  is  the  "natural  guardian"  of  their  children  and  has 
special  powers  over  them.  These  privileges  are  offset  to  some  extent 
by  the  fact  that  the  husband  still  pays  alimony  in  case  of  divorce.  In 
recent  years  in  France,  according  to  Andre  Maurois: 

A  married  woman  .  .  .  cannot  have  a  bank  account  without  getting  authoriza- 
tion from  her  husband.  Though  she  may  manage  a  large  business  while  her 
husband  does  nothing,  she  can  make  no  important  agreement  without  obtaining 
his  signature.  If  she  is  a  wage-earner,  her  husband  has  a  claim  on  her  pay. 
If  she  desires  a  passport  for  foreign  travel,  she  must  have  her  husband's  consent.8 

The  State  of  Wisconsin  set  a  precedent  by  passing  an  Equal  Rights  law 
in  1921,  which  declared  that  women  should  "have  the  same  rights  and 

7  See  S.  A.  Stouffer  and  P.  F.  Lazarsfeld,  Research  Memorandum  on  the  Family  in 
the  Depression,  Social  Science  Research  Council,  1937. 
*  The  New  York  Times,  April  8, 1934,  Sec.  VI,  p.  5. 


CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS  617 

privileges  under  the  law  as  men  in  the  exercise  of  suffrage,  freedom  of 
contract,  choice  of  residence  for  voting  purposes,  jury  service,  holding 
office,  holding  and  conveying  property,  care  and  custody  of  children,  and 
in  all  other  respects."  This  act  has  not  been  widely  imitated  as  yet, 
though  the  Russian,  Spanish,  and  Mexican  revolutions  conferred  full 
equality  on  women.  There  can  be  no  true  equality  between  the  sexes, 
however,  until  the  law  takes  cognizance  of  the  special  burden  imposed 
upon  women  in  being  the  childbearing  sex  and  offers  appropriate  pro- 
tection to  motherhood.  In  Russia  alone  has  the  law  done  so  fully,  and 
this  is  one  of  the  reasons  why  the  position  of  woman  has  been  higher  in 
Soviet  Russia  than  in  any  other  important  country. 

The  first  great  feminist  was  Mary  Wollstonecraft  (1759-1797),  who 
defended  women's  rights  at  the  very  close  of  the  eighteenth  century.  A 
century  later,  Emmeline  Pankhurst  and  her  daughter  Sylvia  led  the 
struggle  in  England  for  equal  suffrage.  In  the  United  States,  Elizabeth 
Cady  Stanton  (1815-1902),  Susan  B.  Anthony  (1820-1906),  Belva  Lock- 
wood  (1830-1917),  Victoria  Woodhull  (1838-1927),  Carrie  Chapman 
Catt  (1859-  ),  and  others  have  taken  the  lead  in  working  for  woman 
suffrage  and  other  phases  of  the  recognition  of  women.  The  most  thor- 
oughgoing advocate  of  the  rights  of  women  has  been  a  Russian  crusader, 
Alexandra  Kollontay,  who  argued  for  economic  and  legal  equality  and 
also  for  full  sexual  equality.  She  has  lived  to  see  many  of  her  ideals  put 
into  practice  in  Russia  since  1917.  In  Sweden,  Ellen  Key  (1849-1926) 
valiantly  upheld  women's  rights  and  was  especially  noted  for  her  courage 
in  discussing  sex  problems.  The  birth-control  movement,  a  great  boon 
to  women,  has  been  valiantly  supported  by  Marie  Stopes  in  England  and 
Margaret  Sanger  in  the  United  States. 

The  rise  of  feminism  has  involved  a  movement  for  greater  freedom  of 
women  in  sexual  relations.  Since  human  culture  and  society  have  been 
mainly  male-dominated  down  to  the  era  of  modern  industrialism  and 
secularism,  it  was  natural  that  men  should  assume  a  great  deal  of  sex 
freedom  which  they  denied  to  women.  Further,  men  required  some  means 
of  insuring  themselves  against  conferring  their  property  upon  another 
man's  son.  There  thus  grew  up  the  "double  standard"  of  sexual  morality. 
There  was  one  standard  of  relatively  free  sex  action  for  men  and  another 
standard  for  women.  The  latter  carried  with  it  definite  restrictions. 

The  more  aggressive  feminists  have  attacked  with  some  vigor  this 
double  standard  in  both  idea  and  practice.  They  asserted  that  woman 
should  have  exactly  the  same  freedom  as  that  which  man  claims  for  him- 
self. They  maintained  that  a  single  standard  of  morality  should  prevail 
for  both  sexes.  Instead  of  demanding  that  man  limit  his  sex  activities, 
in  harmony  with  the  restricted  field  which  he  left  open  to  woman  in  this 
matter,  the  feminist  exponents  of  the  single  standard  more  usually  in- 
sisted that  women  enjoy  the  wider  freedom  that  has  hitherto  been  a  male 
prerogative. 

The  position  of  such  feminists  is  more  valid  on  moral  grounds  than 
when  based  on  psychological  and  sociological  considerations.  No  fair 
person  will  deny  that  woman  should  have  just  as  much  freedom  in  these 


618  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS 

matters  as  men.  But  the  biological  and  psychological  differences  be- 
tween men  and  women  are  such  as  to  preclude  the  practicality  of  exactly 
the  same  conduct  for  both  sexes,  even  in  the  freest  kind  of  society.  The 
danger  of  pregnancy  in  free  sexual  relations  is  a  risk  which  women  alone 
have  to  run.  Women  have  to  bear  children,  a  function  denied  to  the 
male,  whatever  his  psychological  inclinations.  This  produces  the  family 
complex  on  the  part  of  woman,  which  does  not  exist  in  so  strong  a  form 
in  the  male.  The  fiex  complex  of  women  is  much  more  complicated,  com- 
prehensive, and  diffused  than  male  sexual  attitudes.  Only  a  pathological 
female  could  have  exactly  the  same  form  of  sexual  motivation  and  aspira- 
tions as  the  normal  male.  Further,  there  seems  to  be  some  ground  for 
the  assertion  that  the  physiological  basis  of  man's  sexual  attitudes  makes 
him  more  inclined  to  what  is  conventionally  known  as  promiscuity. 
These  are  practical  facts  which  cannot  be  set  aside  by  any  emotional  zeal 
for  freedom  and  equality.  Women  should  be  free  to  do  as  they  wish  in 
such  matters,  but  for  them  to  hope  to  duplicate  precisely  male  sex  atti- 
tudes and  behavior  would  be  as  great  folly  as  for  males  to  decide  that  they 
will  usurp  the  child-bearing  function. 

An  important  social  effect  of  the  emancipation  of  woman  has  been 
the  inroads  that  feminine  independence  and  economic  initiative  have 
made  upon  the  patriarchal  home.  The  latter  dominated  human  society 
for  centuries  when  life  was  primarily  agricultural  or  pastoral  in  its  eco- 
nomic foundations  and  when  women  were  absolutely  dependent  for  their 
support  upon  men.  Today,  many  women  prefer  the  economic  inde- 
pendence offered  by  industry  and  professions  to  marriage  purchased  at 
the  price  of  economic  dependence  upon  a  man.  Moreover,  if  a  woman 
does  not  find  her  husband  congenial,  starvation  no  longer  faces  her  if  she 
leaves  him  and  tries  to  earn  her  own  living.  Many  young  women  have 
to  support  relatives  and  continue  working  to  an  age  when  marriage  be- 
comes relatively  difficult  to  contract.  Further,  when  a  woman  can  exist 
by  her  own  labors,  she  is  likely  to  be  more  discriminating  in  the  choice  of 
a  husband  and  may  never  find  one  to  her  liking. 

In  these  and  other  ways,  the  Industrial  Revolution  and  the  entry  of 
^omen  into  industry,  trade,  and  the  professions  have  led  to  ajiigher 
divorce  rate,  more  family  desertions,  and  to  a  diminished  importance 
of  the  family  as  the  elemental  unit  of  society.  It  is  logical  that  in 
Russia,  where  the  industrialization  and  the  emancipation  of  women  have 
progressed  further  than  anywhere  else  in  the  world,  we  find  the  old  type 
of  family  life  much  less  prominent  than  in  agrarian  or  bourgeois  coun- 
tries. It  is  possible  that  Plato's  idea  that  the  state  should  exert  primary 
control  and  supervision  over  children  will  ultimately  gain  greater  head- 
way. 

A  Brief  History  of  Divorce  Legislation 
and   Practices 

Divorce  seems  to  have  an  antiquity  as  great  as  that  of  the  family  itself. 
The  pairing  arrangements  of  higher  apes  and  of  the  earliest  primitive 


CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS  619 

peoples  were  often  broken  up.  In  well-developed  primitive  society, 
divorce  was  common ;  but  it  was  not  usual  to  sanction  it,  except  for  some 
reasonable  cause.  Wives  were  divorced  for  barrenness,  adultery,  general 
laziness  and  shiftlessness,  poor  cooking,  neglect  of  children,  disagreeable 
personality,  invalidism,  and  old  age.  Women  were  permitted  to  divorce 
their  husbands  for  laziness,  neglect,  and  cruelty.  The  economic  value 
of  wife  and  husband  to  each  other  in  primitive  society  helped  to  limit 
the  frequency  of  divorce.  The  woman  needed  a  hunter  and  protector, 
while  the  man  required  somebody  to  do  housework,  agricultural  labor, 
and  other  forms  of  manual  occupation.  These  economic  factors  were 
stronger  than  either  religion  or  romance  in  preserving  family  life  in 
primitive  times. 

The  high  position  of  women  in  Egypt  limited  the  freedom  of  the  male 
in  divorcing  his  wife,  a  practice  which  was  fairly  general  in  the  rest  of 
Oriental  society  where  the  patriarchal  system  prevailed.  Among  the 
Babylonians  and  Assyrians,  the  patriarchal  system  gave  the  male  relative 
freedom  to  divorce  his  wife,  but  even  here  divorce  for  trivial  causes  was 
frowned  upon.  But  adultery  was  universally  recognized  as  an  almost 
compulsory  cause  for  divorce  because  of  its  menace  to  the  efficacy  of 
ancestor  worship.  An  unrecognized  bastard  male  heir  would  nullify  the 
whole  scheme  of  ancestor  worship  in  any  given  family.  The  Jewish  law, 
mainly  drawn  up  in  the  patriarchal  period,  also  gave  the  man  great  lee- 
way in  repudiating  his  wife  and  terminating  the  family  arrangement. 
The  Mosaic  law  declared  that  for  good  purpose  a  man  could  write  his 
wife  "a  bill  of  divorcement,  and  give  it  in  her  hand  and  send  her  out  of 
his  house."  Divorce  was  also  permitted  by  the  mutual  consent  of  both 
parties,  and  the  wife  could  divorce  her  husband  for  persistent  cruelty, 
notorious  immorality,  and  neglect.  Mohammedan  law  and  tradition 
generally  favored  the  easy  repudiation  of  a  wife  by  her  husband,  though 
in  certain  Muslim  areas  divorce  has  been  relatively  rare.  The  wife  could 
divorce  her  husband,  but  under  greater  restrictions  and  only  for  rather 
extreme  cruelty  or  neglect.  The  Koran  did,  however,  permit  a  wife  to 
obtain  a  divorce  with  relative  ease  if  she  could  obtain  consent  of  her 
husband.  When  the  divorce  was  a  judicial  proceeding,  it  was  not  granted 
until  three  months  after  the  application. 

In  Attic  Greece,  divorce  was  relatively  easy.  Either  the  husband  or 
the  wife  might  have  a  bill  of  divorce  drawn  up  and  presented  to  an 
archon,  who  submitted  the  question  to  a  jury.  The  sexual  freedom 
allowed  to  the  Greek  husband,  the  economic  value  of  his  wife,  and  the 
domestic  servility  and  dependence  of  the  Greek  wife,  all  seemed  to  have 
worked  to  minimize  the  actual  frequency  of  divorce.  In  Sparta,  divorce 
was  restricted,  because  children  were  looked  upon  as  the  property  of  the 
state,  and  adultery  was  tacitly  encouraged  in  order  to  increase  the  num- 
ber of  children.  In  early  Rome,  the  patriarchal  father  could  throw  his 
wife  out  of  his  home  at  will,  as  a  manifestation  of  his  extensive  authority. 
Formal  divorce  was  permitted  for  infanticide,  adultery,  and  sterility. 
The  religious  and  economic  conditions  of  the  early  Roman  family,  how- 
ever, made  divorce  relatively  infrequent.  The  law  of  the  Twelve 


620  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS 

Tables  increased  the  freedom  of  Roman  divorce.  In  the  later  Republic 
and  the  Empire,  marriage  came  to  be  looked  upon  as  primarily  a  civil 
contract.  It  could  be  terminated  by  mutual  consent,  as  essentially  a 
private  agreement  Both  men  and  women  could  dissolve  marriage  by 
the  legal  formality  of  a  notification  of  intention  to  do  so.  Augustus  tried 
to  check  the  frequency  of  Roman  divorce  by  imposing  certain  economic 
and  social  penalties,  but  divorce  remained  common  throughout  the  Em- 
pire, and  the  legislation  of  Theodosius  and  Valentinian,  in  the  middle 
of  the  fifth  century  contained  no  drastic  restrictions.  Men  were  given  15 
grounds  for  divorce  and  women  12.  On  the  whole,  therefore,  one  may 
gay  that  relative  case  of  divorce  was  provided  for  throughout  classi- 
cal civilization,  though  in  practice  the  Romans  availed  themselves  of 
the  opportunity  far  more  frequently  than  the  Greeks.  Greek  notions 
of  the  family  and  the  use  of  mistresses  and  prostitutes  without  any 
notable  social  stigma  seemed  to  have  worked  in  the  interests  of  family 
stability. 

Christianity,  by  making  marriage  a  sacrament,  exerted  a  powerful 
influence  in  the  way  of  restricting  the  freedom  of  divorce.  But,  as  we 
have  just  noted  above,  it  was  not  able  to  influence  Roman  law  in  this 
regard  for  some  centuries,  the  legislation  of  the  middle  of  the  fifth 
century  A.D.  being  the  most  favorable  of  all  to  easy  divorce.  But,  under 
Justinian  in  the  sixth  century,  Christian  theories  prevailed  in  Roman  law. 
The  old  practice  of  divorce  by  mutual  consent  was  done  away  with  and 
divorce  was  permitted  only  for  certain  specified  and  actually  serious 
offenses,  delinquencies,  or  deficiencies.  For  example,  a  husband  was 
allowed  to  divorce  his  wife  only  for  her  failure  to  reveal  plots  against  the 
state,  plots  against  her  husband's  life,  adultery,  chronic  social  dissipation 
in  the  company  of  other  men,  running  away  from  home,  defying  her 
husband  by  attendance  at  the  circus  or  theater,  and  procuring  abortion 
against  her  husband's  will.  In  the  canon  law  of  the  Roman  Church,  no 
true  divorce  was  allowed.  Only  separation  was  permitted.  Even  this 
could  be  secured  only  through  recourse  to  an  ecclesiastical  court.  Then 
it  was  permitted  only  for  adultery,  perversion,  impotence,  cruelty,  en- 
trance into  a  religious  order,  and  marriage  within  a  tabooed  degree  of 
relationship. 

The  Roman  Catholic  substitute  for  divorce  was  what  is  known  as 
annulment.  This  could  be  permitted  on  the  ground  that  there  had  been 
some  form  of  deception  in  regard  to  premarital  sin,  impotence,  or  other 
impediments  to  complete  family  life  which  had  not  been  known  to  one  or 
both  of  the  parties  prior  to  marriage.  Therefore,  the  marriage  had  never 
actually  been  consummated  and  was  null  and  void  from  the  beginning.  It 
may  be  observed  that  the  theory  of  annulment  was  often  broadly  ration- 
alized and  rendered  extremely  flexible.  In  practice,  it  frequently 
amounted  to  easy  divorce,  especially  among  the  nobility,  who  could  make 
it  financially  worth  while  for  the  Church  to  take  a  lenient  attitude.  But 
in  theory,  at  least,  the  Roman  Catholic  Church  has  never  sanctioned 
absolute  divorce,  though  it  has  always  reserved  to  itself  the  legal  right 


CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS  621 

to  grant  one.  The  number  of  annulments  is  not  large  today.  There  are 
estimated  to  be  about  5,000  annually  in  the  United  States. 

Through  under  Protestantism  the  attitude  towards  divorce  was  relaxed, 
freedom  of  divorce  made  only  very  gradual  headway  in  Protestant  coun- 
tries. For  example,  though  the  Church  of  England  was  actually  born 
out  of  the  divorce  case  of  Henry  VIII,  it  has  maintained  a  very  stern 
attitude  toward  divorce  right  down  through  the  reign  of  Edward  VIII. 
The  Protestant  clergy  were,  however,  highly  favorable  to  increased  po- 
litical authority  and  the  sovereignty  of  the  state.  Divorce  tended  to 
become  a  matter  of  civil  rather  than  ecclesiastical  law,  though  religious 
dogmas  long  retained  a  predominant  influence  over  the  content  of  civil 
legislation  on  family  and  divorce  problems.  In  Germanic  countries 
divorce  was  permitted  for  adultery,  perversion,  bigamy,  murderous  as- 
sault, desertion,  and  extreme  cruelty,  as  well  as  for  insanity  and  certain 
other  more  unusual  causes.  Under  the  Nazis  there  have  been,  paradoxi- 
cally, both  a  tightening  and  a  relaxation  of  divorce  legislation,  in  con- 
formity with  the  racial  and  eugenic  program  of  the  new  regime.  Marriage 
between  robust  "Aryans"  is  made  rigid,  and  divorce  is  possible  only  for 
serious  cause.  On  the  other  hand,  mixed  marriages  (e.g.,  of  an  "Aryan" 
and  a  Jew)  and  marriages  of  persons  with  an  inheritable  disease  are 
readily  annulled.  France  long  opposed  any  relaxing  of  divorce  laws,  but 
in  1884  legislation  was  passed  which  permitted  divorce  for  adultery, 
cruelty,  disgrace,  assault,  and  conviction  for  an  infamous  crime.  Italy, 
strongly  Catholic,  had  relatively  strict  divorce  laws;  Fascism  strengthened 
them  in  the  interest  of  a  higher  birth  rate. 

In  Great  Britain,  down  to  1857,  absolute  divorce  could  be  secured  only 
through  an  act  of  Parliament.  In  that  year,  legislation  was  passed  to 
enable  a  husband  to  divorce  his  wife  for  adultery  and  the  wife  to  divorce 
her  husband  for  adultery,  or  adultery  combined  with  bigamy,  rape,  per- 
version, or  extreme  cruelty.  A  Royal  Commission  recommended  liberal- 
ization of  divorce  legislation  in  1912.  This  was  achieved  by  legislation  in 
1914,  1920,  1923,  1926,  and  1930.  The  legislation  of  1923  placed  the 
sexes  on  terms  of  equality,  and  legislation  of  1926  severely  restricted 
newspaper  publicity  in  regard  to  divorce  cases.  But  the  causes  for  di- 
vorce were  not  notably  extended,  with  the  result  that  there  has  been 
frequent  fakery,  perjury,  and  collusion  in  trumping  up  adultery  evidence 
to  secure  divorce. 

In  the  United  States,  divorce  was  discouraged  by  the  religious  influence 
in  Colonial  times,  but  the  practices  have  relaxed  since  the  Revolution. 
Divorce  legislation  differs  among  the  states.  There  is  no  legal  ground  for 
divorce  in  South  Carolina,  but  there  are  14  recognized  grounds  for  divorce 
in  New  Hampshire.  In  many  states,  including  New  York,  the  only 
usual  legal  ground  for  divorce  is  adultery.  This  has  produced  a  vast 
amount  of  hypocrisy,  subterfuge,  perjury,  and  collusion,  in  some  cases 
amounting  to  a  veritable  divorce  racket  which  is  morally  more  repre- 
hensible than  the  free-and-open  system  which  prevails  in  Nevada,  where 
divorce  can  be  procured  on  the  flexible  ground  of  extreme  cruelty. 


622 


CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS 


The  best-known  liberal  and  civilized  divorce  legislation  is  in  the  laws 
and  practices  of  the  Scandinavian  countries,  of  American  states  like 
Nevada,  Idaho,  and  Arkansas,  of  Mexico,  and  of  Soviet  Russia.  In  1915 
Sweden  enacted  a  law  based  upon  extended  study  of  the  whole  divorce 
problem.  It  provided  for  divorce  by  mutual  consent  in  all  cases  where 
persistent  family  discord  exists.  The  parties  must  make  an  application, 
which  must  be  followed  by  a  year's  separation  accompanied  by  efforts  at 
reconciliation  under  court  authority.  If  the  application  is  renewed  after 
the  passage  of  a  year,  the  divorce  is  granted.  Other  special  grounds  are 
provided  for  immediate  granting  of  divorce,  without  the  lapse  of  the  year 
specified  in  discord  cases.  The  example  of  Sweden  was  followed  in  1918 
by  Norway  and  in  1920  by  Denmark.  The  radical  government  in  Mexico 
eased  up  divorce  legislation,  and  Soviet  Russia  provided  for  divorce  by 
mutual  consent  or  by  the  request  of  either  party,  without  the  necessity  of 
specifying  the  grounds.9  This  relaxing  Russian  legislation  was  not 
followed  by  any  overwhelming  epidemic  of  divorces,  though  the  rate  rose 
somewhat.  The  divorce  rate  in  the  Scandinavian  countries,  in  Mexico, 
and  in  Soviet  Russia  is  far  lower  than  that  which  has  prevailed  in  the 
United  States  since  the  first  World  War.  The  divorce  legislation  of  the 
Scandinavian  countries,  Mexico,  and  Soviet  Russia  is  epoch-making  in 
that  it  is  the  first  legislation  of  the  sort  in  human  history  which  has  been 
separated  from  religious  considerations  and  has  been  based  upon  scientific 
facts  and  social  investigation. 

The  Extent  and   Prevalence  of  Divorce   in 
Contemporary  America 

The  outstanding  fact  about  divorce  is  its  steady  increase  in  most  civi- 
lized countries  during  the  last  generation.  Japan  is  an  exception;  she 
once  had  easy  divorce  laws  but  later  made  it  difficult.  The  following 
table  shows  the  tendencies  since  1890:  10 


DIVORCES  PER  100,000  POPULATION 

• 

1890 

1900 

1910 

1920 

1935 

United  States  .... 
Japan           

53 
269 
17 
13 
8 
1 

73 
143 
25 
15 
10 
2 

92 
113 
37 
24 
16 
3 

139 
94 
71 
63 
29 
17 

171 
70 
50 
74 
63 
41 

France 

Germany    

Sweden  

England  and  Wales 

9  Recent  changes,  prompted  by  military  sentiments,  have  modified  the  absolute 
freedom  of  divorce  in  Russia. 

10  J.  P.  Lichtenberger,  Divorce:  A  Social  Interpretation,  McGraw-Hill,  1931,  p.  110. 
The  figures  for  1935  were  kindly  compiited  for  me  by  Professor  Frank  H.  Hankins, 
from  W.  F.  Willcox,  Studies  in  American  Demography,  Cornell  University  Press, 
1940,  p.  342;  League  of  Nations  Yearbook,  1940;  and  S.  A.  Stouffer  and  L.  M.  Spencer, 
"Recent  Increases  in  Marriage  and  Divorce,"  American  Journal  of  Sociology,  Janu- 
ary, 1939,  pp.  551-554. 


CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY  PROBLEMS  623 

Some  true  comprehension  of  the  instability  of  the  monogamous  family 
in  America  today  can  be  gleaned  from  the  following  table,  in  which 
marriage  rates,  divorce  rates,  and  divorces  per  marriage  are  assembled: 

MARRIAGES  AND  DIVORCES  PER  1,000  OF  THE  POPULATION 

Ratio  of 

Marriages  per  Divorces  per  Marriage  to 

Year                            1,000  Population^            1,000  Population™  Divorce™ 

1890 8.72  0.53  16.3 

1895 8.57  0.58  14.6 

1900 9.01  0.73  12.3 

1905 9.60  0.81  11.9 

1910  10.25  0.92  11.0 

1915 10.67  1.07  9.9 

1920 10.83  1.39  7.7 

1925  10.52  1.55  *                         6.7 

1935 10.41  1.71  6.09 

1937 11.00  1.90  5.78 

1940 11.80 

The  divorce  rate  more  than  tripled  within  45  years.  There  was  exactly 
one  divorce  to  every  six  marriages  in  1935.  Should  divorce  continue  to 
increase  at  the  present  rate,  there  will  soon  be  one  divorce  for  every 
marriage,  and  marriages  will  have  little  permanence.  Let  us  hope  that, 
before  this  happens,  marriage  and  the  family  will  be  brought  under  scien- 
tific and  sociological  controls  that  will  eliminate  a  number  of  the  factors 
which  work  most  powerfully  today  to  increase  the  divorce  rate,  especially 
ignorance  of  the  major  facts  and  responsibilities  of  sex. 

The  divorce  rate  by  states  varies  greatly,  mainly  as  a  result  of  their 
widely  different  divorce  laws.  The  following  table  shows  the  frequency 
of  divorce  in  the  ten  highest  and  the  ten  lowest  states  in  1929: 

DIVORCE  RATE  PER  100,000  OF  THE  POPULATION,  1929 14 

Highest  Lowest 

Nevada    ! .    ...  28.1  South  Carolina  0.00 

Oklahoma   3.48  District  of  Columbia 0.24 

Oregon  3.38  New  York 0.41 

Texas    3.20  North   Carolina    0.55 

Wyoming    3.15  Delaware  0.73 

Washington    2.90  New  Jersey 0.75 

Montana   2.77  Connecticut    0.77 

California    2.74  Pennsylvania   0.82 

Missouri    2.72  North  Dakota  0.83 

Arkansas    2.67  Massachusetts   0.84 

It  is  obvious  that  the  extremely  high  rate  for  Nevada  is  due  to  the 
short  residence  requirement  of  six  weeks  for  outsiders  who  wish  to  avail 
themselves  of  the  civilized  Nevada  legislation.  The  overwhelming 


11  Lichtenberger,  Divorce:  A  Social  Interpretation,  McGraw-Hill,  1931,  p.  146. 
™Ibid.,  p.  143. 

13  Ibid.,  p.  152. 

14  Ibid.,  p.  114.    Detailed  divorce  statistics  for  recent  years  in  the  United  States 
are  difficult  to  obtain,  since  their  icgular  collection  ended  with  the  year  1932. 


624  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS 

majority  of  the  divorces  granted  in  Nevada  are  awarded  to  non-residents. 
The  divorce  rate  for  permanent  residents  of  Nevada  is  very  low,  only 
about  5  per  cent  of  the  total  divorces  granted  in  the  state  being  given  to 
actual  Nevada  residents — another  proof  that  ease  of  divorce  does  not  lead 
to  divorce  excesses. 

The  instability  of  the  monogamous  family  in  the  United  States  is  even 
greater  than  divorce  statistics  would  indicate,  for  there  are  thousands  of 
desertions  which  never  come  into  the  courts  as  the  basis  for  a  definite 
divorce  action.  As  Ernest  R.  Mowrer  has  pointed  out  in  his  notable  book 
on  Family  Discordj  desertion  is  the  "poor  man's  divorce."  Desertion  is 
especially  prevalent  in  the  poverty  group.  Divorce,  on  the  other  hand, 
is  confined  mainly  to  the  middle  and  upper  classes.  We  shall  devote  a 
later  section  to  a  consideration  of  the  extent  and  causes  of  family  deser- 
tion. 

A  number  of  explanations  have  been  offered  for  the  marked  increase 
of  divorce  in  the  United  States.  Bertrand  Russell,  for  example,  thinks 
that  "family  feeling  is  extremely  weak  here,  and  the  frequency  of  divorce 
is  a  consequence  of  this  fact.  Where  family  feeling  is  strong,  for  ex- 
ample in  France,  divorce  will  be  comparatively  rare,  even  if  it  is  equally 
easy."15  Divorce  is  a  symptom  of  deeper  social  trends,  which  have 
undermined  the  moral  and  economic  basis  of  the  monogamous  family. 
Adultery,  cruelty,  and  desertion  may  not  be  more  prevalent  today  than 
sixty  years  ago.  We  have  no  way  of  telling.  It  is  possible  that  the  less- 
ening of  the  social  taboos  and  the  general  easing  up  of  conventions  have 
given  many  couples  the  courage  to  come  out  into  the  open  and  end  their 
incompatibility  by  legal  divorce.  Moreover,  divorce  has  also  been  made 
cheaper  in  many  areas. 

The1  growth  of  industry  and  the  increase  of  wealth  in  the  United 
States  in  the  twentieth  century  undoubtedly  provide  one  explanation  of 
the  phenomenon  of  increasing  divorce.  As  we  pointed  out  in  an  earlier 
chapter,  general  social  cohesion  and,  consequently,  family  cohesion,  has 
declined,  while  all  classes  have  been  infected  with  an  eagerness  to  live 
on  an  ever-rising  scale.  The  unhappiness  produced  by  readjustments  and 
disappointed  ambitions  has  had  its  repercussions  in  the  family,  particu- 
larly in  the  case  of  young  married  couples.  A  psychological  explanation 
for  increased  divorce  is  the  strong  feeling  of  individualism  among  con- 
temporary men  and  women.  This  has  reacted  against  the  tolerant  give- 
and-take  attitude  required  in  the  monogamous  family  relationship. 
Concurrently,  female  emancipation  bolstered  woman's  ego  and  independ- 
ence, and  helped  to  destroy  the  paternal  type  of  family.  The  feminist 
movement,  while  not  handing  woman  a  passport  to  license,  has  made  her 
more  self-assertive  and  endangered  the  old  type  of  family  stability. 
Equally  demoralizing  to  stable  marriage  is  woman's  increasing  participa- 
tion in  industry,  to  which  we  have  already  called  attention.  For  the 


15  Marriage  and  Morals,  Liveright,  1929,  p.  23. 


CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS  625 

urban  working  class,  the  home  has  tended  to  become  little  more  than  a 
night  lodging-place.  When  the  effects  of  the  prevailing  zeal  for  pleasure 
and  the  abnormal  life  in  tenement  or  apartment  house  dwellings  are 
added,  it  can  be  seen  that  the  conventional  family  life,  particularly  in 
urban  centers,  is  fading  away.  Since  industrialism  has  been  undermin- 
ing the  home  for  many  years,  we  now  have  a  generation  of  undomesti- 
<?ated  children  who,  in  turn,  when  they  marry,  are  prone  to  form  unstable 
unions. 

Bertrand  Russell  insists  that  the  modern  father  is  losing  his  former 
position  in  society.  Among  the  proletariat,  he  is  so  busy  earning  a 
living  that  he  rarely  sees  his  children,  and  when  he  does  see  them,  usu- 
ally on  Sundays,  he  scarcely  knows  how  to  behave  towards  them. 
Further,  Lord  Russell  observes  that  the  state  is  increasingly  taking 
over  parental  responsibilities,  most  emphatically  among  the  submerged 
classes,  where  the  father  frequently  cannot  afford  to  feed  or  clothe  his 
offspring  decently.  Incidentally,  it  may  be  noted  that  the  depression 
after  1929  produced  a  very  notable  increase  in  desertion.  The  family 
courts  are  clogged.  Children,  bred  in  the  shadow  of  "home  relief,"  are 
losing  that  pride  in  the  father  which  used  to  be  a  natural  heritage. 
The  paternal  status  in  the  family  has  certainly  decayed  as  contem- 
porary civilization  has  progressed.  This  is  true  both  among  the  upper 
classes,  where  family  instability  seems  most  marked,  and  among  the 
lower  classes,  where  poverty  does  not  permit  the  father  to  be  much  of 
a  parent.  Among  the  middle  classes  at  present  the  father  is  of  most 
importance,  for  so  long  as  he  earns  a  good  income  he  can  provide 
adequately  for  his  offspring  and  he  has  a  certain  amount  of  leisure  to 
devote  to  their  development.  A  greater  sense  of  family  responsibility, 
too,  has  remained  here  than  among  the  richer  classes. 

Another  vital  factor  in  the  increase  of  divorce,  frequently  over- 
looked, is  that  we  have  strict  formal  standards  of  sexual  morality. 
Hence  infidelity  is  commonly  regarded  as  the  greatest  transgression, 
and  the  wronged  partner  in  the  family  usually  feels  that  both  pride 
and  decency  require  a  divorce  action.  In  a  country  like  France, 
fidelity  is  not  considered  the  most  important  factor  for  the  success  of 
a  marriage,  and  adultery  is  not  so  likely  to  provoke  the  husband  or 
wife,  when  it  is  discovered,  to  petition  for  divorce.  In  France,  each 
member  of  the  family  is  more  free  to  follow  the  dictates  of  his  con- 
science and  wishes,  and  the  family  is  not  so  frequently  split  and  shat- 
tered through  divorce  and  separation.  In  short,  the  Stress  laid  by  our 
mores  on  sexual  fidelity  as  the  indispensable  factor  in  the  marital  rela- 
tionship develops  a  spirit  of  hypocrisy  in  marriage  which,  combined  with 
the  amazing  ignorance  of  sex,  is  a  large  factor  in  divorce. 

The  Causes  of  Divorce  in  the  United  States 

The  formal  causes  for  the  granting  of  divorces  in  the  United  States 
from  1887  to  1929  are  presented  in  the  table  on  page  626. 


626  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY   PROBLEMS 

REASONS  FOR  GRANTING  DIVORCES,  1887-1929 16 

Cause  1887-1906  1916  1922  1929 

Cruelty    21.8%  28.3%  34.5%  40.8% 

Desertion    38.9  36.8  32.8  29.6 

Adultery     16.3  11.5  10.9  8.3 

Combination  of  Causes  ....       9.4  8.6  8.7  6.8 

Failure  to  Provide      3.7  4.7  4.2  3.9 

Drunkenness    3.9  3.4  1.0  1.8 

Others    6.1  6.8  7.8  8.8 

These  formal  causes  of  divorce,  which  are  listed  as  the  legal  grounds 
in  actual  divorce  cases,  are  frequently  accepted  by  writers  as  the  literal 
and  true  causes  of  family  instability.  To  do  so  is,  however,  extremely 
naive,  and  such  authors  give  a  misleading  view  of  the  major  causes  of 
divorce. 

In  the  first  place,  the  cause  which  is  offered  in  court  is,  all  too  fre- 
quently, entirely  fictitious  and  dictated  solely  by  legal  and  other  con- 
siderations which  make  it  convenient  to  advance  that  particular  ground 
for  a  divorce.  In  New  York  State,  for  example,  where  adultery  is  the 
only  usual  ground  on  which  divorce  is  granted,  the  applicant  must 
allege  adultery  by  the  other  party.  Consequently,  it  is  extremely  com- 
mon to  frame  a  case  of  fictitious  adultery,  to  be  brought  into  court  as 
evidence.  If  friends  will  not  perform  this  service,  there  are  professional 
adultery  "fixers"  of  both  sexes  who  will  stage  the  frame-up.  They  are 
known  to  every  good  divorce  lawyer.  Hence  adultery  may  be  the  ground 
advanced  to  cover  a  score  of  different  reasons  for  wishing  the  divorce. 
In  Nevada,  the  most  common  ground  for  divorce  is  "extreme  cruelty." 
This  suffices  as  an  adequate  legal  cause  and  is,  at  the  same  time,  less  likely 
than  most  others  to  afford  the  basis  for  sensational  newspaper  publicity. 
The  fact  that  Nevada  and  several  other  states  with  relatively  easy 
divorce  laws  accept  "cruelty"  as  a  legal  basis  for  divorce  accounts  for 
the  great  increase  in  cruelty  as  a  formal  cause  for  demanding  divorce  and 
as  a  ground  for  granting  it. 

Even  where  the  cause  for  divorce  alleged  in  court  is  a  real  cause, 
it  is  all  too  frequently  a  purely  superficial  one.  Suppose,  for  example, 
that  the  cause  alleged  is  desertion  and  that  a  husband  has  actually  de- 
serted his  wife  in  the  case.  The  real  cause  for  divorce  lies  in  the  reason 
for  desertion.  Was  it  from  sheer  boredom,  the  result  of  frequent  quarrels, 
the  product  of  sexual  incompatibility,  or  the  effect  of  chronic  economic 
impoverishment?  •  Moreover,  if  it  was  boredom,  why  was  the  man  bored? 
We  cannot  accept  as  adequate  the  answer  once  given  by  a  Negro  defend- 
ant in  such  a  case,  to  the  effect  that  "Well,  Jedge,  Ah  done  guess  Ah's 
just  lost  mah  taste  fur  that  ar  woman."  For  the  real  causes  of  divorce 
we  thus  have  to  turn  to  studies  of  sex  life  and  family  instability,  such  as 
have  been  made  by  G.  B.  Hamilton,  Katharine  Bement  Davis,  Dorothy 
Bromfield  Bromley,  Ernest  R.  Groves,  W.  F.  Ogburn,  W.  F.  Robie,  and 


1(5  Lichtenborger,  Divorce:  A  Social  Interpretation,  McGraw-Hill,  1931,  p.  131. 


CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS  627 

others,  and  to  statistics  of  family  income  and  studies  of  family  budgets. 

Probably  the  greatest  reason  for  the  downfall  of  the  monogamous  mar- 
riage and  the  emergence  of  a  desire  for  divorce  is  found  in  the  current 
ease  of  marriage.  In  most  states,  marriage  can  be  contracted  almost 
instantaneously.  Marriages  which  are  entered  into  as  a  result  of  a  week- 
end flair  for  adventure  or  during  a  period  of  intoxication  are  not  likely  to 
prove  successful  or  enduring. 

Another  often  neglected  but  important  incitement  to  divorce  is  brought 
about  when  marriages  are  entered  into  without  any  particular  enthusiasm 
on  the  part  of  one  of  the  persons  involved.  These  marriages  may  proceed 
out  of  kindheartedness  and  an  unwillingness  to  rebuff  pathetic  affection 
and  intense  devotion.  In  such  cases,  it  is  frequent  that  the  man  has  not 
even  realized  he  has  proposed  marriage.  Some  casual  remark  has  been 
misinterpreted;  the  man  finds  himself  trapped  in  an  embarrassing  situ- 
ation and  does  not  have  the  courage  to  be  candid.  Sinclair  Lewis's  por- 
trayal of  how  Babbitt  entered  into  his  engagement  and  marriage  is  a 
more  frequent  occurrence  than  the  ordinary  layman  appreciates.  Women 
also  frequently-give  an  impression  of  consent  to  a  proposal  when  they  had 
no  such  intention,  a  soft  answer  being  employed  to  turn  aside  disappoint- 
ment; and  find  themselves  so  implicitly  committed  to  marriage  that 
they  enter  into  it.  Marriage  and  the  family  impose  enough  difficulties 
and  responsibilities  upon  those  who  enter  upon  the  conjugal  estate  with 
great  initial  enthusiasm.  Where  this  is  lacking,  there  is  likely  to  be 
resentment  and  restlessness  from  the  beginning. 

The  failure  to  have  children  seems  to  promote  divorce  and  family 
instability,  especially  where  there  are  few  other  cohesive  forces.  In 
1928,  some  63  per  cent  of  all  divorces  were  granted  to  parties  where  there 
were  no  children  involved.  Some  20.5  per  cent  of  the  divorces  were  given 
in  cases  where  there  was  only  one  child.  One  authority  has  estimated 
that  70  per  cent  of  childless  marriages  in  the  United  States  ultimately 
wind  up  in  the  divorce  court.  The  impact  of  increasing  divorce  upon 
children  is,  thus,  less  serious  than  many  suppose,  since  there  are  few 
children  in  the  families  broken  up  by  divorce. 

Studies  of  family  discord  and  instability  reveal  the  frequency  of  eco- 
nomic causes.  The  pride  of  the  wife  and  her  natural  desire  for  display 
suffer  severely  when  her  husband  cannot  provide  enough  income  for  even 
the  necessities.  A  man  may  become  disgruntled  with  his  wife  because 
she  does  not  maintain  a  neat  and  tidy  home  and  an  attractive  table, 
though  the  responsibility  for  this  failure  may  rest  primarily  upon  his 
own  inadequacy  as  a  provider.  The  mechanism  of  "projection"  fre- 
quently comes  into  play  here.  The  guilty  party  does  not  recognize  his 
faults  and  blames  his  partner  for  the  inadequacies.  Economic  insecurity 
and  worries  put  the  nerves  of  both  husband  and  wife  on  edge  and  lead  to 
quarrels,  a  sense  of  discouragement  and  futility,  and  an  unwholesome 
atmosphere  in  the  home.  At  times,  the  economic  inadequacy  becomes 
so  great  that  it  is  literally  impossible  to  keep  the  home  together. 

Certainly,  one  of  the  most  important  causes  of  family  instability  is 


628  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY   PROBLEMS 

basic  sexual  ignorance.  Husbands  are  all  too  frequently  over-aggressive 
and  brutal  at  the  outset.  Wives  suffer  from  emotional  frigidity,  morbid 
fears,  and  psychological  unpreparedness.  Sinclair  Lewis's  portrayal  of 
the  wedding  night  of  Elmer  Gantry  provides  an  excellent  illustration  of 
a  deplorably  frequent  situation.  Closely  related  to  sex  ignorance  is  the 
matter  of  sexual  incompatibility,  a  fact  which  is  likely  to  become  known 
only  after  the  marriage  relationship  has  been  made.  Another  associated 
cause  of  unsatisfactory  marriage  relations  is  venereal  disease,  whether 
known  or  unknown  to  one  or  the  other  of  the  partners  before  marriage. 
A  husband  may  imagine  that  he  has  been  cured  of  gonorrhea,  but  has  a 
chronic  case  and  infects  his  wife  after  marriage.  Or  a  woman  may  be 
suffering  from  syphilis,  knowingly  or  unknowingly,  and  the  husband  does 
not  discover  it  until  the  wife  has  a  series  of  stillbirths. 

Though  this  fact  is  rarely  mentioned  in  any  divorce  statistics  or 
publicity,  it  is  pretty  generally  agreed  by  expert  students  that  sexual 
ignorance  and  incompatibility  are  the  foremost  causes  of  marital  discord. 
Judge  George  A.  Bartlett,  one  of  the  most  experienced  of  the  Reno  divorce 
court  judges,  who  presided  over  more  than  20,000  divorce  cases,  was  of 
the  opinion  that  more  marriages  fail  because  of  sexual  incapacity  or 
ignorance  on  the  part  of  one  or  both  of  the  partners  than  from  any  other 
cause:  "Of  all  the  factors  that  contribute  to  happy  marriage,  the  sex 
factor  is  by  far  the  most  important.  Successful  lovers  weather  storms 
that  would  crush  frail  semi-platonic  unions." 

But  many  marriages,  which  are  originally  founded  upon  romantic  en- 
thusiasm and  in  which  the  sexual  adjustment  is  satisfactory,  go  on  the 
rocks  because  of  unsatisfactory  technique  in  the  way  of  keeping  the 
monogamous  relationship  attractive.  This  problem  has  become  prevalent 
primarily  as  the  result  of  the  leisure  brought  about  by  the  machine. 
Formerly,  when  almost  the  entire  energy  and  time  of  husband  and  wife 
were  devoted  to  satisfying  the  family  needs,  it  was  hardly  necessary  to 
find  in  each  other  a  stimulating  companion.  With  leisure  time,  the 
deadly  intimacy  of  the  average  monogamous  relationship  is  a  menace  to 
the  marriage.  If  one  were  to  sit  down  and  design  the  situation  most 
perfectly  adapted  to  the  destruction  of  the  sentiment  and  novelty  so 
essential  to  long-continued  amorousness,  he  would  arrive  at  something 
bearing  a  very  close  resemblance  to  the  monogamous  family,  as  at  present 
conducted.  It  is  difficult  to  refute  the  facts  pointed  out  by  H.  L. 
Mencken  in  the  following  quotation: 

Monogamous  marriage,  by  its  very  conditions,  tends  to  break  down  strangeness 
[between  the  sexes] .  It  forces  the  two  contracting  parties  into  an  intimacy  that 
is  too  persistent  and  unmitigated;  they  are  in  contact  £t  too  many  points,  and 
too  steadily.  By  and  by,  all  the  mystery  of  the  relation  is  gone,  and  they  stand 
in  the  unsexed  position  of  brother  and  sister.  Thus  that  'maximum  of  tempta- 
tion' of  which  Shaw  speaks  has  within  itself  the  seeds  of  its  own  decay.  A  hus- 
band begins  by  kissing  a  pretty  girl,  his  wife;  it  is  pleasant  to  have  her  so  handy 
and  so  willing.  He  ends  by  making  Machiavellian  efforts  to  avoid  kissing  the 
eyery-day  sharer  of  his  meals,  books,  bath  towels,  pocketbook,  relatives,  am- 
bitions, secrets,  malaises  and  business;  a  proceeding  about  as  romantic  as  having 


CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS  629 

his  boots  blacked.  The  thing  is  too  horribly  dismal  for  words.  Not  all  the 
native  sentimentalism  of  man  can  overcome  the  distaste  and  boredom  that  get 
into  it.  Not  all  the  histrionic  capacity  of  woman  can  attach  any  appearance  of 
gusto  and  spontaneity  to  it.17 

As  we  have  pointed  out  in  an  earlier  section  of  the  chapter,  the  in- 
creasing independence  of  woman  has  been  a  significant  cause  of  the 
increase  of  divorce.  Women  are  no  longer  subjected  to  economic  slavery 
at  the  hands  of  husbands.  Many  a  woman,  if  she  does  not  like  her 
husband  or  if  he  is  a  poor  provider,  need  not  continue  to  suffer  from 
domestic  unhappiness  or  impoverishment.  She  can  get  out  and  earn  her 
own  living,  divorcing  her  unsatisfactory  spouse  and  remaining  inde- 
pendent of  him,  until  she  makes  a  more  satisfactory  marriage.  The 
lessening  of  public  opprobrium  against  divorce  and  the  tendency  to  accept 
it  more  as  a  matter  of  course  has  undoubtedly  made  divorce  somewhat 
more  frequent.  But  it  can  hardly  be  alleged  that  this  is  an  underlying 
cause  of  divorce.  It  simply  makes  dissatisfied  parties  to  a  marriage  less 
reluctant  to  take  public  steps  to  terminate  the  unsatisfactory  union.  The 
decline  of  supernatural  religion  has  eliminated  for  many  the  fear  of 
hellfire  as  an  inhibition  against  starting  a  divorce  action. 

There  are  other  real  causes  of  divorce,  but  those  which  we  have  listed 
above — ease  of  marriage,  indifference  to  marriage  at  the  outset,  child- 
lessness, economic  insecurity,  the  growing  economic  independence  of 
women,  sexual  maladjustment,  monogamous  boredom,  a  more  tolerant 
public  opinion  relative  to  divorce,  and  the  decline  of  supernatural  reli- 
gion as  a  brake  on  divorce — account  for  the  overwhelming  majority  of 
divorces  and  desertions,  and  the  many  unhappy  families  where  divorce 
never  actually  takes  place.  The  latter  instances  are  frequently  over- 
looked by  students  of  marital  problems,  but,  as  Ludwig  Lewisohn  sug- 
gested in  his  book,  Don  Juan,  they  may  account  for  a  far  greater  degree 
of  human  misery  and  suffering  than  complete  marital  ruptures  involving 
divorce. 

Some  Remedies  for  Divorce  and  Family   Instability 

The  rational  solutions  of  the  deplorable  prevalence  of  divorce  today 
are  naturally  suggested  by  the  foregoing  realistic  approach  to  the  causes 
of  divorce.  In  the  first  place,  marriage  should  be  made  more  difficult. 
Only  companionate  marriage  of  youth,  if  this  ever  becomes  prevalent, 
should  be  permitted  to  be  initiated  without  prolonged  reflection.  But 
even  a  companionate  marriage  should  not  be  contracted  lightheartedly. 
So  slight  a  restriction  as  the  New  York  State  law,  which  required  a  delay 
of  72  hours  between  the  acquisition  of  the  marriage  license  and  the 
wedding  ceremony,  reduced  the  number  of  marriages  in  the  state  by  6,610 
during  the  first  year  of  its  operation.  At  least,  there  was  this  decrease 
in  the  number  of  marriages  in  1937,  and  certainly  it  could  be  attributed 
mainly  to  the  chastening  effect  of  the  new  law.  It  would  seem  reasonable 


17  Mencken,  In  Defense  of  Women,  Knopf,  1922,  pp.  109-110. 


630  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS 

to  suggest  that  a  six-month  period  might  be  required  between  the  declara- 
tion of  intent  to  marry  and  the  consummation  of  this  intention.  If 
Sweden  can  demand  that  married  couples  wait  a  year  to  decide  whether 
or  not  they  wish  a  divorce,  certainly  it  is  not  excessive  to  demand  that 
half  this  time  be  required  for  reflection  on  the  part  of  those  who  are 
going  to  undertake  an  experiment  with  far  more  serious  social  conse- 
quences than  divorce.  Nothing  much  can  be  done  about  marriages 
which  are  unwisely  contracted  as  a  result  of  pity  or  kindheartedness, 
without  benefit  of  either  passion  or  enthusiasm.  This  is  purely  a  per- 
sonal matter  which  can  hardly  be  reached  either  by  public  education  or 
legislation.  It  may  well  be  emphasized,  however,  that  a  broken  heart 
over  a  broken  engagement  is  less  pathetic  than  an  unsuccessful  marriage 
and  a  broken  heart  after  divorce. 

We  can  never  expect  any  satisfactory  solution  of  the  problem  of  divorce 
and  desertion  unless  we  make  it  possible  for  all  able-bodied  and  energetic 
persons  to  earn  a  decent  and  respectable  livelihood.  Few  families,  how- 
ever satisfactorily  adjuster!  in  other  respects,  can  successfully  weather 
prolonged  misery  and  impoverishment.  Even  if  there  is  no  actual  deser- 
tion or  divorce,  there  is  bound  to  be  much  suffering  and  discontent. 
Moreover,  children  cannot  be  adequately  cared  for  in  the  midst  of  eco- 
nomic inadequacy  and  insecurity.  Just  how  we  shall  be  able  to  realize 
this  adequate  income  for  all  is  quite  another  question,  but  we  have  already 
made  it  plain  that  we  have  the  natural  resources  and  technological  equip- 
ment in  the  United  States  to  provide  plenty  for  everybody  with  the 
greatest  of  ease. 

Perhaps  the  most  important  remedy  for  divorce  is  realistic  sex  edu- 
cation with  respect  to  the  facts  and  responsibilities  of  the  marriage 
relationship.  And  it  is  highly  desirable  that  this  education  be  acquired 
before  marriage.  A  few  weeks  of  bungling  may  undermine  what  might 
otherwise  be  a  thoroughly  satisfactory  marriage.  If  we  wish  to  keep  the 
monogamous  family  intact,  marriage  manuals  like  those  by  W.  F.  Robie 
and  his  successors  will  probably  accomplish  far  more  than  many  volumes 
of  savage  legislation  against  divorce.  The  sex  purists,  who  are  most 
violent  against  freedom  of  divorce  and  are  most  scandalized  by  its 
prevalence,  are  themselves  mainly  responsible  for  the  existence  of  mental 
attitudes  and  ignorance  which  bring  about  more  family  discord  than  any 
other  single  cause.  As  a  phase  of  sex  education,  there  should  be  thorough 
instruction  in  birth  control  methods.  Many  a  family  is  undermined  be- 
cause of  being  burdened  by  children  who  come  before  the  family  is  ready 
to  take  care  of  them,  or  arrive  in  too  great  numbers  to  be  handled  in  an 
average  family  situation.  Compulsory  medical  examination  of  both 
parties  before  a  marriage  license  is  granted  would  go  far  toward  removing 
the  factor  of  venereal  disease  as  a  cause  of  marital  difficulties. 

Much  more  should  be  accomplished  in  the  way  of  improving  the 
attractiveness  and  novelty  of  monogamous  situations.  Many  of  the 
more  repellent  forms  of  that  familiarity  which  breeds  indifference,  if  not 
contempt,  could  be  avoided  by  those  who  are  keenly  alive  to  the  realities. 


CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS  631 

Marion  Cox  once  suggested  that  periodic  vacations  from  marriage  rela- 
tions should  be  provided  for.18  Students  of  sex  relations  and  pairing 
arrangements  among  apes  have  found  that  this  works  well  in  stabilizing 
primate  affections  and  keeping  the  pairing  arrangement  intact.  It  might 
achieve  as  much  for  human  beings.  But  it  will  prove  difficult  to  accom- 
plish much  in  the  way  of  improving  the  attractiveness  of  monogamy 
unless  decent  living  standards  can  be  secured  and  maintained.  There  is 
little  possibility  of  novelty  and  surprise  where  a  large  family  is  packed 
into  a  slum  apartment  or  a  run-down  farm  dwelling. 

Many  have  sensibly  suggested  that  we  emphasize  the  work  of  the 
domestic  relations  courts  rather  than  place  so  much  reliance  upon  divorce 
courts  in  the  handling  of  marital  problems.  There  is  much  to  be  said  in 
support  of  this  proposal.  A  reconciliation  may  often  be  substituted  for 
what  would  otherwise  be  separation,  desertion,  and  divorce.  Unfortu- 
nately, the  domestic  relations  courts  have  hitherto  been  almost  wholly 
concerned  with  discovering  the  family  basis  of  juvenile  delinquency. 

It  is  obvious  that  no  good  will  be  achieved  in  any  campaign  against 
divorce  by  attempting  to  reduce  the  economic  independence  of  women 
or  to  whip  up  public  opinion  against  divorce,  even  if  such  results  were 
possible  in  our  day. 

Much  interest  has  developed  of  late  in  marriage  counselors,  family 
advice  bureaus,  and  family  clinics.  In  these,  an  effort  is  made  to  discover 
the  causes  of  marital  discord,  and  to  reduce  or  remove  them  by  the 
application  of  psychology  and  social  work  principles.  One  of  the  most 
successful  of  these  clinics  is  the  Bureau  of  Marriage  Counsel  and  Educa- 
tion, which  has  been  maintained  for  some  years  in  New  York  City  by 
Dr.  Valeria  H.  Parker.  It  has  been  stated  that  Dr.  Parker  has  prevented 
over  2,500  divorces  in  four  years.  Certainly,  much  can  be  done  when 
the  chief  cause  of  discord  is  not  rooted  in  factors  such  as  economic  stress 
and  sterility,  which  lie  beyond  the  reach  or  control  of  the  counselor. 
On  the  other  hand,  there  is  always  the  danger  that,  despite  good  inten- 
tions, the  basic  principles  of  social  science  may  be  violated  in  these  clinics. 
This  danger  has  been  well  stated  by  Kingsley  Davis,  who  concludes  that 
to  regard  family  clinics  "as  applying  scientific  efficacy  to  the  tragic  prob- 
lems of  personal  relations  strikes  me  as  a  violation  of  fact." 19 

When  it  comes  to  the  matter  of  suggesting  divorce  legislation,  it  would 
probably  be  difficult  to  propose  anything  more  satisfactory  than  the 
Scandinavian  laws.  These  provided  for  divorce  in  all  cases  of  marital 
discord  after  a  year  of  reflection.  Temporary  anger,  sulking,  or  de- 
spondency are  not  likely  to  endure  for  a  year.  Where  the  application 
was  renewed  after  the  passage  of  twelve  months  it  was  assumed  that  the 
family  should  be  put  asunder,  making  due  provision  for  proper  support 


18  Mencken,  In  Defense  of  Women,  pp.  110-112. 

19  Dr.  Parker's  work  is  described .  with  enthusiasm  by  Greta  Palmer  in  an  article 
entitled  "Marriage  Repair  Shop,"  in  the  Survey  Graphic,  January,  1942;  Professor 
Davis's  qualms  are  embodied  Jn  an  article  on  "A  Critique  of  the  Family  Clinic 
Idea,"  in  the  American  Sociological  Review,  April,  1936,  pp.  236  ff. 


632  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS 

of  dependent  children.  The  Scandinavian  legislation  also  made  possible 
immediate  divorce  for  causes  sufficiently  serious  to  warrant  expeditious 
action.  Some  more  radically  inclined  persons  recommended  following 
the  lead  of  Soviet  Russia,  which  made  divorce  immediately  available 
upon  the  desire  of  either  party.  It  seems  to  the  writer  that  the  Swedish 
procedure  is  preferable,  though  the  Russian  practices  are  certainly 
far  saner  than  such  absurdities  at  the  other  extreme  as  the  legislation  of 
South  Carolina.20 

It  is  often  asserted  that  easy  divorce  inevitably  leads  to  a  veritable 
tidal  wave  of  divorces.  The  evidence  does  not  bear  out  any  such  asser- 
tion. The  divorces  in  Sweden  only  increased  from  847  in  1915  to  1,040 
in  1917,  and  1,310  in  1920,  the  latter  being  an  insignificant  figure  in 
proportion  to  the  total  population  of  Sweden.  In  Soviet  Russia  as  a 
whole,  under  the  freest  possible  divorce  procedure,  the  divorces  per  capita 
were  less  than  those  in  the  United  States.  Sex  education,  sexual  freedom, 
and  economic  security  for  the  whole  body  of  the  people  had  evidently 
proved  more  effective  in  Russia  in  preventing  a  high  divorce  rate  than  has 
severe  restrictive  legislation  in  many  other  countries.  The  experience 
of  the  State  of  Nevada  is  also  highly  illuminating.  It  is  literally  true 
that,  so  far  as  the  legal  aspects  are  concerned,  a  permanent  resident  of 
Nevada  may  decide  at  the  breakfast  table  that  he  wishes  a  divorce,  and 
may  procure  one  before  luncheon.  Yet  the  percentage  of  divorces  per 
capita  among  the  permanent  residents  of  Nevada  is  lower  than  the 
per  capita  divorce  rate  in  New  York  State,  with  adultery  as  the  sole 
loophole  for  those  who  seek  divorce. 

Any  intelligent  solution  of  the  divorce  problem  must  carry  with  it  the 
termination  of  the  abuses  of  the  alimony  racket.  This  is  one  of  the  two 
leading  rackets  connected  with  divorce,  the  first  being  the  collusion  and 
fixing  of  evidence,  particularly  evidence  of  adultery.  At  the  present 
time,  the  alimony  racket  is  a  fertile  field  for  cultivation  by  thrifty  and 
ruthless  gold-diggers.  They  snare  wealthy  husbands,  live  with  them 
long  enough  to  provide  a  semblance  of  honest  intent,  sue  for  divorce,  and 
get  awarded  a  large  alimony — sometimes  as  much  as  one  third  of  the 
husband's  income.  Often  these  large  alimonies  are  awarded  when  the 
wife  who  secures  the  divorce  is  perfectly  able  to  take  care  of  herself. 
Aside  from  the  purely  racketeering  aspects  of  alimony  procedure,  there 
are  other  abuses  in  the  contemporary  practice.  Alimony  for  the  divorced 
wife  has  more  logic  in  it,  in  case  the  husband  divorces  the  wife,  but 
alimony  is  very  frequently  given  today  when  the  wife  asks  for  the 
divorce  of  her  own  volition.  While  no  sane  person  can  doubt  the  moral 
right  of  granting  reasonable  alimony  to  a  dependent  divorced  woman, 
providing  the  marriage  relationship  has  been  long  enduring,  there  is  little 
justification  for  alimony  payments  to  a  young  and  recently  married 
woman  who  is  perfectly  capable  of  caring  for  herself.  The  courts,  all 
too  often,  fail  to  consider  the  question  of  need  and  desert  when  awarding 


20  There  is  no  legal  ground  for  divorce  in  South  Carolina. 


CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS  633 

alimony.  One  of  the  most  illogical  abuses  in  the  alimony  situation  is 
the  frequent  practice  of  incarcerating  husbands  for  nonpayment  of  ali- 
mony. This  is  akin  to  imprisonment  for  debt,  which  has  long  since  been 
abandoned  as  ethically  reprehensible  and  financially  illogical. 

Alimony  is  no  new  principle  or  practice.  It  goes  back  to  the  earliest 
historical  times.  The  principle  definitely  appears  in  the  Code  of  Ham- 
murabi, some  two  thousand  years  before  Christ.  Such  practices  were 
developed  more  thoroughly  by  the  Greeks  and  Romans,  though  in  cases 
of  divorce  by  mutual  consent  the  parties  involved  had  to  make  their  own 
private  arrangements  about  such  matters.  The  medieval  church  strongly 
influenced  the  development  of  alimony  practices.  Since  it  regarded  the 
family  as  indissoluble,  alimony  payments  were  made  perpetual.  The 
Protestant  cults  introduced  into  alimony  definitely  punitive  concepts, 
alimony  being  a  punishment  for  the  guilt  of  the  husband.  This  concept 
has  survived,  since  the  courts  tend  to  base  the  amount  of  alimony  more 
upon  the  degree  of  the  husband's  guilt  than  upon  the  needs  of  the  divorced 
wife.  The  more  enlightened  divorce  codes  of  our  day  have  eliminated 
the  earlier  concepts  and  abuses  with  respect  to  alimony.  Sweden  allows 
alimony  only  in  cases  of  actual  want.  In  Soviet  Russia,  where  divorce 
by  mutual  consent  has  prevailed,  any  question  of  payment  to  one  of  the 
parties  is  a  matter  for  private  arrangement  without  any  legal  compul- 
sion. Certain  American  states,  such  as  Massachusetts,  North  Dakota, 
and  Ohio  have  granted  the  husband  the  right  to  alimony  under  certain 
specific  conditions,  where  the  husband  is  the  injured  party  in  the  divorce 
case.  Few  expert  students  of  the  alimony  question  approve  the  granting 
of  alimony  to  both  sexes  as  a  solution  of  the  problem.  This  device  is 
simply  a  manifestation  of  the  old  error  that  two  wrongs  can  make  a  right. 

Any  sane  solution  of  the  problem  of  alimony  would  require  that  the 
punitive  aspects  of  alimony  be  completely  wiped  away  and  that  im- 
prisonment for  nonpayment  for  alimony  be  terminated.  The  matter  of 
alimony  awards  should  be  determined  wholly  by  the  needs  of  the  de- 
pendent wife  and  children.  Legitimate  rights  of  both  of  these  should  be 
fully  protected  in  divorce  cases,  though  there  should  never  be  alimony 
payments  that  would  encourage  the  divorced  woman  to  avoid  seeking 
remunerative  work  or  satisfactory  marriage.  Least  of  all,  should  a 
divorced  woman  be  allowed  to  collect  alimony  from  a  former  husband 
after  she  has  remarried.  At  present,  alimony  does  not  automatically 
cease  upon  the  remarriage  of  the  divorced  woman.  There  have  been  cases 
where  married  women  have  collected  alimony  from  two  or  more  former 
husbands  at  the  same  time. 

The   Future  of  the  Family 

Few  social  problems  are  more  solemnly  discussed  than  that  of  the 
future  of  the  human  family.  There  are  many  who  predict  that  it  will 
ultimately  disappear,  but  even  if  this  should  prove  to  be  true  it  will  not 
take  place  for  many  generations  to  come.  One  should  be  clear  just  what 
is  meant  by  the  discussion  of  the  future  of  the  family  and  the  possibility 


634  CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS 

of  its  disappearance.  That  which  is  seriously  threatened  by  contem- 
porary developments  is  the  old  rural  patriarchal  family  and  the  notion 
of  indissoluble  monogamy.  Definite  pairing  arrangements  between 
males  and  females  do  not  appear  to  be  in  the  slightest  jeopardy.  In 
fact,  there  are  more  marriages,  and,  hence  at  least  more  temporary 
families,  than  ever  before  in  history.  This  is  notably  true  of  the  United 
States,  where,  as  we  have  seen,  the  marriage  rate  is  increasing  rapidly. 
If  companionate  marriage  is  introduced,  the  marriage  rate  will  be  even 
more  markedly  increased.  Even  the  radical  developments  in  Soviet 
Russia,  which  represented  as  drastic  a  social  change  as  we  may  expect  in 
the  civilized  world  for  many  years  to  come,  did  not  seem  to  have  lessened 
the  popularity  of  marriage.  Therefore,  while  the  older  type  of  family, 
which  came  down  from  a  pastoral  and  agricultural  economy,  does  seem 
to  be  disintegrating  and  may  disappear  entirely,  there  appears  to  be  no 
reason  whatever  for  predicting  the  end  of  marriage  or  even  any  decline 
in  its  popularity.  Indeed,  if  divorce  becomes  easier,  it  is  likely  that 
many  persons  who  now  recoil  from  the  idea  of  assuming  a  life-long 
responsibility  will  be  encouraged  to  contract  matrimony  and  may  be  so 
entranced  therewith  as  to  be  induced  to  continue  the  arrangement  in- 
definitely. An  interesting  and  amusing  item  in  this  connection  is  the 
announcement  that,  in  1940,  18,913  marriage  licenses  were  issued  in 
Heno,  Nevada,  while  only  2,314  divorce  suits  were  filed  there. 

The  percentage  of  those  married  in  the  United  States  has  increased  in 
the  last  fifty  years.  In  1890,  53.9  per  cent  of  the  male  population  was 
married.  In  1930,  the  figure  stood  at  exactly  60  per  cent.  The  per- 
centage of  married  females  in  1890  was  56.8,  and  in  1930  it  had  risen  to 
61.1  per  cent.  The  marriage  rate  of  11.0  per  1,000  of  the  population  in 
the  United  States  in  1937  was  relatively  high.  The  marriage  rate  in 
Germany  in  1937  was  9.1;  in  England,  8.7;  in  Italy,  8.7;  in  Canada,  7.9; 
and  in  France,  6.6. 

The  possibility  of  the  extinction  of  the  human  family  at  some  distant 
date  in  the  future  is,  therefore,  quite  obviously  a  purely  academic  question. 
But  immediate  future  tendencies  in  the  family  are  a  matter  of  real  prac- 
tical concern.  As  Anderson  and  Lindeman  have  suggested,  the  increased 
prevalence  of  urban  life  and  the  living  conditions  associated  therewith 
are  likely  to  bestow  far  greater  importance  upon  the  mother.  Obviously, 
no  changes  in  our  cultural  and  social  set-up  will  ever  alter  the  biological 
fact  that  women  must  bear  the  children.  Woman's  biological  function 
thus  remains  constant,  whatever  the  degree  or  type  of  social  changes 
affecting  the  family.  On  the  other  hand,  as  we  have  already  noted,  the 
father's  importance  in  the  family  has  been  considerably  lessened  by  recent 
cultural  and  social  changes.  Moreover,  social  workers  have  pointed  out 
that  keeping  the  mother  and  child  together  is  a  far  more  important  matter 
than  keeping  the  father  present  in  the  family. 

It  is  quite  possible  that  the  state  will  step  in  and  take  over  a  good 
many  of  the  father's  responsibilities  in  the  way  of  supporting  mothers  and 
children.  It  is  obvious  that  the  state  and  other  agencies  have  already 


CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS  635 

intruded  markedly  into  former  family  responsibilities  and  services.21 
The  state  now  provides  for  the  education  of  children.  Public  health 
agencies,  nursing  associations,  child  guidance  clinics,  recreational  centers 
and  many  other  child  welfare  bodies  supply  forms  of  aid  to  families  which 
were  formerly  a  purely  domestic  responsibility.  The  increasing  preva- 
lence of  mothers7  pensions  is  another  indication  that  the  state  may  assume 
an  ever  greater  responsibility  for  supporting  mothers  and  dependent 
children.  The  National  Youth  Administration  helps  to  care  for  older 
children,  and  the  Civilian  Conservation  Corps  has  also  done  much  along 
this  line.  The  permanent  family,  under  male  parental  dominion,  owed 
its  cohesiveness  and  enduring  qualities  primarily  to  the  fact  that  there 
were  indispensable  responsibilities  which  only  the  family  could  supply. 
Now  that  this  set  of  conditions  have  been  greatly  modified  we  cannot 
doubt  that  such  changes  will  have  a  marked  effect  upon  the  future  of 
the  family. 

With  the  growing  prevalence  of  Fascism  and  Communism  it  is  perhaps 
relevant  to  inquire  as  to  just  what  influences  these  new  forms  of  political 
and  economic  life  are  likely  to  bring  to  bear  upon  the  human  family. 
In  this  respect,  Fascism  has  produced  many  paradoxes  and  contradic- 
tions. The  chief  marital  policy  of  Fascism  is  to  increase  the  birth  rate, 
so  as  to  provide  more  children  for  future  cannon  fodder.  Hence  Fascism 
tends  to  encourage  marriage  by  taxes  on  bachelors,  the  restriction  of  di- 
vorce, and  so  on.  But  its  zeal  for  a  larger  population  leads  it  to  policies 
which  work  in  the  opposite  direction.  It  encourages  births  out  of  wed- 
lock and  tends  to  eliminate  the  whole  conception  of  bastardy.  Mothers' 
pensions  are  favored  to  support  unmarried  mothers  who  have  borne 
future  soldiers.  Fascism  thus  encourages  the  extremely  radical  notion 
that  procreation  outside  of  wedlock  is  socially  tolerable  if  not  commend- 
able. 

Communism  has  thus  far  favored  free  divorce,  but  marriage  continues 
to  be  popular  in  Soviet  Russia.  As  the  military  emergency  in  Soviet 
Russia  has  become  more  marked,  there  has  been  a  definite  inclination  to 
clamp  down  on  some  of  the  earlier  manifestations  of  sexual  freedom. 
The  government  has,  for  example,  assumed  a  less  tolerant  attitude  toward 
abortions,  and  is  following  the  Fascist  program  in  encouraging  a  high 
birth  rate.  Soviet  Russia  appears  likely  to  encourage  the  continuance 
of  the  family  because  it  feels  that  the  latter  is  indispensable  to  the  desired 
increase  of  population  for  national  defense. 

If  civilization  survives  the  present  world  crisis,  we  may  safely  predict 
that  the  family  will  be  greatly  modified,  but  that  marriage  will  continue 
to  be  as  popular  as  ever,  though  undoubtedly  readjusted  in  terms  of  social 
rationality.  Affection  will  come  to  play  a  larger  role  in  keeping  the  family 
together  than  sheer  economic  pressure.  Hence  those  influences  which  in- 
crease affection,  such  as  children,  mutual  interest,  avoidance  of  excessive 
intimacy,  and  the  like,  will  need  to  be  stressed  and  encouraged.  Super- 


-1  See  below,  pp.  645-648. 


636  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS 

naturalism,  intolerance,  ignorance,  and  dogma  will  have  an  ever  lessening 
authority  and  influence  over  family  life.  The  latter  will  be  reconstructed 
in  harmony  with  scientific  facts  and  a  reconsideration  of  social  welfare. 
Such  a  readjustment  must  certainly  involve  thoroughgoing  sex  education, 
the  sanction  and  encouragement  of  companionate  marriages,  and  the 
imposition  of  greater  restrictions  and  responsibilities  upon  permanent 
unions,  rational  divorce  legislation  and  easier  divorce,  and  the  provision 
of  economic  conditions  which  will  bestow  upon  the  family  the  material 
foundations  for  an  enduring  and  successful  matrimonial  arrangement. 
The  family  of  the  future  will  be  kept  together  because  the  parties  wish  to 
have  their  marriage  endure  and  because  the  family  situation  is  worth 
preserving.  If  we  desire  to  increase  the  number  of  marriages  which  can 
be  both  personally  congenial  and  socially  worth  while,  it  will  impose 
upon  us  the  necessity  of  bringing  about  economic  security  and  other 
general  living  conditions  which  are  reasonably  compatible  with  success- 
ful monogamy  on  the  part  of  the  masses. 

The  future  of  marriage,  like  the  future  of  everything  else  in  American 
life,  is  closely  tied  up  with  the  second  World  War.22  If  Germany  should 
win  the  war  there  would  be  increased  prestige  for  the  marriage  practices 
of  the  Nazis.  These  are  paradoxical.  On  the  one  hand,  we  find  the 
Nazis  praising  the  old-fashioned  virtues  of  the  home,  and  the  mother  as* 
the  docile  parent  of  young  Nazis.  At  the  same  time,  they  welcome  the 
birth  of  children  out  of  wedlock,  in  this  way  undermining  the  conven- 
tional family  morality.  It  is  probable,  however,  that  Nazi  support 
would  be  placed  behind  the  old  patriarchal  family.  The  struggle  for  a 
large  population  is  likely  to  subside  in  Germany  after  the  war  is  over. 

An  Anglo-American-Russian  victory,  or  a  negotiated  peace,  coming 
fairly  quickly,  would  bolster  the  family  ethics  of  the  United  States  and 
Britain  and  give  them  a  greater  opportunity  to  contest  the  future  with 
Nazi  and  Soviet  family  ideas  and  practices. 

Should  an  Anglo-American-Russian  victory  over  Germany  or  a  stale- 
mate throw  the  Old  World  into  the  hands  of  Russia,  there  would  be  great 
gains  for  the  unconventional  family  ideals  and  practices  of  the  Soviet 
Union.  These  are  the  new  sex  ethics,  separated  entirely  from  religious 
control,  namely,  what  we  usually  call  "free  love,"  easy  divorce,  and 
legalized  abortion.  But  there  is  little  reason  to  think  that  the  family 
would  be  abandoned  or  that  marriage  would  be  less  popular.  The  silly 
myth  that  Russia  has  approved  communism  in  women  is  utterly  without 
foundation.  If  a  long  stalemate  and  chaos  come  in  the  wake  of  war, 
we  may  look  forward  to  the  breakdown  of  the  family  and  to  generations 
of  marital  disorder,  rapine,  and  lust. 

Since  there  is  a  considerable  prospect  of  a  long  war,  we  may  profitably 
consider  some  obvious  effects  of  war  on  marriage  and  the  family.  In 
the  first  place,  war  undermines  the  conventional  sex  and  family  morals. 


22  For  authoritative  discussions  of  war  and  the  family,  see  J.  H.  S.  Bossard,  "War 
and  the  Family,"  American  Sociological  Review,  June,  1941,  pp.  330-344;  and 
Willard  Waller,  "War  and  the  Family"  (a  brochure),  Dryden  Press,  1940. 


CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS  637 

All  is  regarded  as  good  which  helps  along  victory.  A  special  wartime 
morality  exists  for  the  soldier  group.  Unconventional  sexual  behavior 
was  justified  in  the  first  World  War  as  an  aid  to  licking  the  Kaiser,  and 
it  may  be  so  justified  in  the  second  World  War  as  an  important  item  in 
aiding  the  triumph  over  Hitler  and  the  Mikado. 

In  the  second  place,  families  are  at  least  temporarily  broken  up  by  war. 
Fathers,  sons,  and  brothers  go  to  war  or  to  work  in  war  industries. 
Women  also  often  leave  homes  to  engage  in  war  work.  Family  income 
may  be  lessened  and  standards  of  living  lowered.  Economic  bonds  of 
the  family  are  loosened.  Divorces  tend  to  increase  and  unconventional 
sex  behavior  is  encouraged. 

In  the  third  place,  more  males  than  females  are  killed  off  in  war  and 
the  sex  ratio  is  upset,  there  tending  to'  be  an  excess  of  females.  The 
death  of  husbands  and  other  male  wage-earners  produces  serious  emo- 
tional and  economic  situations.  Chaotic  economic  conditions  after  war 
and  inability  to  find  husbands  stimulate  prostitution  and  unconventional 
sex  unions. 

In  the  fourth  place,  war,  especially  at  the  outset,  stimulates  hasty 
marriages,  contracted  on  the  spur  of  the  moment  or  in  a  burst  of  idealism. 
These  "marry-and-run"  unions  prove  more  unstable  than  marriages  con- 
tracted in  peace  time.  This  is  another  way  in  which  war  contributes  to 
marital  instability. 

In  the  fifth  place,  wars  have  usually  made  for  a  radical  overhauling 
of  the  sexual  folkways.  This  may  prove  a  gain,  but  it  is  an  expensive 
way  to  liberalize  sexual  ethics.  As  Professor  Willard  Waller  has  sug- 
gested, it  is  like  burning  down  a  house  to  get  roast  pig. 

In  the  sixth  place,  the  killing  off  of  young  men  increases  the  difficulty 
of  women  in  finding  husbands  and  reduces  the  marriage  and  birth  rates. 

Finally,  wars  tend,  at  least  temporarily,  to  elevate  the  economic  and 
social  status  of  women,  and  may  gain  for  them  new  political  rights. 

On  the  whole,  one  may  safely  conclude  that  a  long  war  will  at  least 
temporarily  undermine  conventional  sexual  morality  and  family  life. 
In  such  a  case,  we  cannot  hope  to  escape  from  its  demoralizing  impact 
upon  our  family  life  and  marriage  institutions. 

The  Unmarried  Adult 

Discussions  of  sex  and  marriage  problems  frequently  revolve  solely 
about  the  consideration  of  the  family  and  divorce.  But  a  very  consid- 
erable social  problem  is  involved  in  the  matter  of  the  unmarried  adult. 
There  are,  today,  more  single  persons  than  divorced  or  deserted.  In 
1930,  34.1  per  cent  of  the  males,  15  years  of  age  or  older,  were  single  and 
26.4  per  cent  of  the  females,  15  years  of  age  or  older,  were  unmarried. 
There  were  thus  over  25  millions  in  the  American  population,  past  the 
period  of  puberty,  who  were  unmarried.  In  addition,  there  was  a  con- 
siderable contingent — over  7  million — of  the  widowed,  deserted,  and 
divorced.  It  is  worthy  of  note  that  the  proportion  of  the  unmarried  was 


638  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS 

somewhat  less  in  1930  than  at  any  other  period  since  1890.  The  in- 
creased rate  of  marriage  in  the  United  States  has  naturally  decreased  the 
relative  proportion  of  the  unmarried,  since  marriage  has  grown  more 
rapidly  of  late  than  the  general  increase  of  the  population.  But  a  large 
residual  element  of  unmarried  still  remains  in  the  population. 

A  number  of  reasons  have  been  assigned  for  the  failure  of  so  large  a 
proportion  of  the  population  to  enter  into  what  Malthus  called  "the 
delights  of  domestic  society."  Economic  inadequacy  and  insufficiency 
undoubtedly  accounts  for  a  considerable  amount  of  non-marriage.  There 
may  not  be  sufficient  income  available  to  support  children.  This  is 
particularly  important  today  when  children,  under  conditions  of  city  life, 
have  become  an  almost  unmitigated  financial  liability. 

The  growth  of  economic  and  sexual  freedom  encourages  and  enables 
many  to  obtain  their  sex  satisfactions  outside  of  matrimony.  The  ex- 
tensive entry  of  women  into  industry  and  the  professions  makes  it  un- 
necessary for  an  ever  larger  group  of  women  to  marry  solely  from 
pecuniary  reasons.  The  proportion  of  gainfully  occupied  women,  15 
years  and  older,  who  have  entered  industry  and  professions  has  increased 
very  markedly  in  the  last  50  years  in  the  United  States.  Over  half  of 
these  are  single,  widowed,  or  divorced.  In  1930  there  were  10,632,227 
women  in  all  occupations,  of  whom  5,734,825  were  single  and  1,826,100 
widowed  or  divorced. 

Many  psychological  factors  help  to  explain  the  existence  of  the  un- 
married contingent  of  the  population.  Feelings  of  inferiority  and  other 
neurotic  states  may  hold  one  back  from  seeking  or  securing  matrimonial 
opportunities.  Fixations  on  the  parents  and  faulty  sex  education  may 
effectively  obstruct  normal  sexual  aspirations  and  the  consummation  of 
conjugality.  Serious  disappointments  in  love  may  exert  their  influence, 
as  well  as  entertaining  too  high  ideals  in  the  quest  of  a  partner.  Homo- 
vScxuality  and  other  sexual  abnormalities  very  obviously  stand  in  the  way 
of  normal  marriage  relationships. 

We  may  now  consider  some  of  the  major  results  of  non-marriage.  The 
most  conspicuous  one  is  the  fact  that  a  large  group  of  persons  of  child- 
bearing  age  are  not  contributing  to  population  growth.  While  there  is 
a  'considerable  amount  of  illegitimacy,  procreation  outside  of  wedlock  is 
not  institutionally  accepted  and  non-marriage  certainly  contributes 
markedly  to  a  lower  birth  rate  than  would  exist  if  the  unmarried  had 
entered  into  conjugal  relations.  Whether  this  is  a  disaster  or  a  benefit 
to  society  depends  upon  the  social  philosophy  with  which  one  approaches 
the  population  problem.  But  the  existence  of  any  large  number  of  un- 
married persons  of  high  ability  does  have  its  effect  in  the  way  of  lessening 
the  potential  level  of  population  quality.  If  marriage  be  regarded  as 
conferring  upon  the  married  an  enviable  state  of  mind  and  social  sur- 
roundings, these  advantages  are  obviously  lost  by  the  non-married.  Yet, 
since  many  of  those  who  remain  unmarried  are  psychologically  unfitted 
for  normal  marriage  relations,  their  entry  into  wedlock  might  well  pro- 
duce more  discord  and  unhappiness  than  satisfaction  and  well-being. 


CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS  639 

Certain  authorities  contend  that  various  types  of  evils,  particularly 
neurotic  developments,  arise  from  the  absence  of  normal  sexual  relations 
on  the  part  of  the  unmarried,  but,  as  Dr.  Ira  S.  Wile  and  others  have 
pointed  out,  we  must  not  assume  that  all  the  unmarried  are  celibate  and 
innocent  of  sexual  experience.  Dr.  Ellen  Klatt  studied  a  group  of  un- 
married women  and  found  that  18  per  cent  of  those  under  18  years  of  age, 
and  over  60  per  cent  of  those  between  18  and  22  years  of  age  had  enjoyed 
some  active  form  of  sex  experience.  Dr.  G.  V.  Hamilton  investigated  a 
group  of  professional  men  and  women  and  found  that  59  per  cent  of  the 
men  and  47  per  cent  of  the  women  had  had  sexual  relations  before 
marriage.  In  some  cases,  this  seems  to  have  been  a  result  of  the  fact 
that  marriage  was  anticipated.  Katharine  B.  Davis's  study  of  the  sex 
life  of  1,200  unmarried  college  women  revealed  the  fact  that  61  per  cent 
had  practiced  masturbation,  over  half  beginning  before  the  age  of  15. 
Other  studies  have  confirmed  the  impression  that  a  large  portion  of  the 
unmarried  have  normal  but  noninstitutionalized  sexual  relations,  while 
many  more  practiced  auto-erotic  and  homosexual  relations.  It  is  mainly 
among  those  who  are  both  unmarried  and  celibate  that  we  need  fear  any 
marked  development  of  neurotic  tendencies  on  account  of  the  repression 
of  the  sex  instinct.  Nevertheless,  there  seems  to  be  a  regrettable  number 
of  this  type  in  the  population.  But  it  must  also  be  remembered  that 
there  are  many  who  enter  into  marriage  relations  and  develop  neuroses 
because  of  their  inability  to  initiate  or  sustain  normal  sex  relations. 

When  we  turn  to  the  social  pathology  of  the  unmarried  we  find  that 
the  unmarried  show  a  per  capita  preponderance  among  cases  of  de- 
pendency, mental  instability,  vagrancy,  crime,  and  the  patrons  of  prosti- 
tution. Except  in  the  case  of  the  latter,  we  cannot  assign  the  responsi- 
bility directly  to  the  unmarried  state.  We  would  expect  to  find  a  larger 
number  of  dependents  among  the  unmarried  because  the  economic  in- 
adequacy is  a  major  cause  of  the  failure  to  marry.  Likewise,  many  fail 
to  marry  because  they  have  been  neurotic  types  from  childhood.  We 
cannot  assume  that  all  the  unmarried  neurotics  are  neurotic  because  of 
their  failure  to  marry.  Marriage  responsibilities  would  be  likely  to  make 
such  types  even  more  neurotic.  In  the  same  way,  vagrancy  is  likely  to 
be  an  outgrowth  of  mental  instability  and  economic  insufficiency,  which 
are  more  a  cause  of  failure  to  marry  than  a  direct  result  thereof.  It  is 
only  natural,  however,  to  suppose  that  the  absence  of  family  responsi- 
bilities lessens  the  restraint  upon  vagrant  tendencies.  When  we  come  to 
crime,  it  is  logical  to  believe  that  absence  of  family  restraints  and  re- 
sponsibilities will  remove  some  of  the  elements  which  deter  people  from 
committing  crime.  But  it  is  frequently  true  that  criminality  arises  from 
the  very  conditions  of  mental  instability  and  poverty  which  prevent 
marriage.  In  the  matter  of  vice  and  prostitution  it  may  be  safely 
assumed  that  the  patronage  of  prostitutes  is  notably  increased  by  the 
presence  of  a  large  number  of  unmarried  males  in  the  population.  But 
studies  have  revealed  the  fact  that  prostitutes  have  many  married  cus- 
tomers. Moreover,  with  the  growing  freedom  of  sex  relations,  unmarried 


640  CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS 

males  are  satisfying  their  sex  desires  to  an  ever  greater  degree  through 
relations  with  females  not  in  the  prostitute  group. 

A  number  of  remedies  suggest  themselves  for  failure  to  marry  and  its 
unsound  social  and  personal  results.  Higher  wages  and  salaries  and 
steadier  employment  are  necessary,  if  we  are  going  to  make  it  possible 
for  many  of  those  now  unmarried  to  support  a  family.  So  long  as  they 
are  unable  to  do  so  it  is  better  that  they  should  not  marry  and  beget  a 
number  of  dependent  or  inadequately  reared  children.  Sex  education 
and  mental  hygiene  services  would  help  to  eliminate  many  of  the  neurotic 
conditions  which  stand  in  the  way  of  marriage  today.  Companionate 
marriage  would  offer  a  solution  for  those  who  are  biologically  and  psy- 
chologically fitted  to  marry  but  cannot  or  do  not  wish  to  assume  the 
responsibilities  of  a  permanent  union.  If  we  wish  to  encourage  procrea- 
tion by  the  able  unmarried,  we  shall  have  to  do  away  with  the  various 
social  penalties  imposed  upon  illegitimacy  and  bastardy.  The  further 
development  of  a  rational  scheme  of  sex  relations  and  mental  hygiene 
facilities  will  naturally  take  care  of  a  good  many  causes  and  cases  of 
failure  to  marry.  But  there  will  be  no  permanent  solution  of  the  problem 
until  we  have  a  sufficient  economic  readjustment  to  provide  the  material 
basis  for  successful  conjugality  on  the  part  of  all  able-bodied  and 
mentally  healthy  citizens. 

Widows  and  Deserted  Women 

The  number  of  widows  in  American  society  has  increased  along  with 
the  general  growth  of  population,  but  there  is  probably  no  more  widow- 
hood per  capita  than  at  earlier  periods  in  our  history.  In  1930  there 
were  over  4,700,000  widowed  females  and  over  2,000,000  widowed  males. 
It  is  estimated  that  some  400,000  newly  widowed  females  are  added 
annually  as  a  result  of  deaths  of  husbands  from  various  causes.  The 
preponderance  of  widowed  females  is  easily  explained.  Males  are  more 
numerous  in  industry  and  arfc  otherwise  more  exposed  to  the  dangers  in 
moving  about  in  contemporary  life.  Hence  more  males  are  killed  in 
accidents,  travel,  and  in  ordinary  occupational  activities.  Moreover, 
males  who  have  lost  their  wives  find  it  easier  to  contract  a  second  mar- 
riage, because  age  and  widowhood  seem  to  be  less  of  a  handicap  to  a 
man  than  to  a  woman. 

The  deaths  which  produce  widowhood  result  from  a  few  outstanding 
causes.  About  six  deaths  out  of  every  ten  prior  to  old  age,  which  cost  the 
life  of  the  male  wage-earner,  afe  produced  by  tuberculosis,  influenza- 
pneumonia,  heart  disease  and  high  blood  pressure,  and  accidents.  Cancer 
and  syphilis  also  play  an  important  role  in  this  mortality.  Most  of  the 
recent  progress  in  reducing  the  mortality  which  leads  to  widowhood  has 
taken  place  in  the  successful  attack  upon  pneumonia  and  tuberculosis. 
The  other  leading  causes  of  mortality  still  remain  relatively  constant, 
though  we  may  expect  notable  progress  to  be  made  in  the  next  few  years 
in  reducing  the  number  of  deaths  caused  by  syphilis. 

There  are  a  number  of  deplorable  personal  and  social  effects  of  widow- 


CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS  641 

hood.  The  problem  of  dependency  is  aggravated  as  a  result  of  the  loss 
of  the  earnings  of  the  breadwinner.  But  the  problems  of  a  bereaved 
home  are  more  than  economic.  If  the  mother  has  to  leave  the  home  to 
secure  employment,  or  children  have  to  go  to  work  earlier  than  desirable, 
it  is  difficult  to  provide  for  a  normal  and  desirable  type  of  home  life  and 
education.  The  emotional  difficulties  of  widowhood  are  serious  and 
numerous.  The  sorrow  frequently  brings  a  serious  psychological  shock. 
Family  associations  are  broken  up.  Sex  starvation  frequently  results. 
The  transferring  of  all  affection  from  the  husband  to  the  children  may 
create  important  difficulties  of  a  psychological  nature  for  both  mother 
and  children.  This  is  particularly  the  case  if  there  is  only  one  child. 
Mental  breakdowns  and  sheer  dependency  represent  the  extreme  forms  of 
ravages  created  by  widowhood. 

The  remedies  for  widowhood  naturally  fall  under  the  heading  of  im- 
mediate relief  and  preventive  measures.  Until  recently,  younger  widows 
and  their  children  have  ordinarily  been  taken  care  of  by  a  system  of 
outdoor  relief,  either  by  public  or  private  agencies.  Most  of  the  elderly 
widows  have  been  taken  care  of  in  private  homes  for  the  aged  and  in 
our  almshouses.  Children,  dependent  as  a  result  of  widowhood,  have 
been  cared  for  both  through  outdoor  relief  and  through  being  placed  in 
public  or  private  institutions  for  orphaned  children.  A  more  adequate 
and  civilized  method  of  supporting  widows  and  dependent  children  has 
been  more  recently  provided  by  the  system  of  widows'  pensions.  The 
first  comprehensive  mothers'  pension  law  was  passed  in  Illinois  in  1911. 
By  1930,  all  states  except  Alabama,  Georgia,  South  Carolina,  and  New 
Mexico  had  passed  some  sort  of  mothers'  pension  legislation,  carrying 
with  it  an1  annual  expenditure  of  about  30  million  dollars  as  relief  aid  of 
this  type.  The  Social  Security  Act  of  1935  provided  some  federal  and 
state  aid  to  widows  and  dependent  children.  More  liberal  and  uniform 
workmen's  compensation  laws  will  be  essential  to  provide  an  adequate 
and  immediate  income  for  widows.  Both  personal  and  social  insurance 
will  need  to  be  extended  as  a  method  of  lessening  the  economic  impact  of 
the  death  of  wage-earners.  Savings  and  thrift  should  be  encouraged,  but 
this  should  be  accompanied  by  assuring  the  solvency  and  reliability  of 
banks.  Many  an  American  widow  has  lost  the  family  savings  because 
of  our  scandalous  and  numerous  bank  failures.  Mental  hygiene  clinics 
have  done  something  in  the  way  of  providing  psychological  relief  in  the 
case  of  both  widows  and  children,  but  such  facilities  will  need  to  be 
greatly  extended  before  they  will  be  adequate. 

If  we  are  to  prevent  widowhood,  we  must  make  possible  better  medical 
care  for  the  masses.  There  will  need  to  be  improvements  in  preventive 
medicine  and  in  our  methods  of  dealing  with  certain  fatal  and  hitherto 
unconquered  diseases,  and  more  stringent  regulation  of  occupational  and 
transportation  hazards. 

We  have  already  noted  that  desertion  has  been  called  the  poor  man's 
divorce.  We  do  not  have  the  exact  statistics  with  respect  to  the  number 
of  desertions  which  we  possess  with  respect  to  divorce  and  widowhood. 


642  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS 

But  certain  estimates  enable  us  to  know  that  there  is  a  considerable  vol- 
ume of  desertion.  From  one  third  to  one  half  of  the  divorce  cases  brought 
to  court  list  desertion  as  a  cause  of  action.  Whether  desertion  is  the 
fundamental  cause  of  the  family  discord,  it  is  likely  to  be  a  contributing 
cause  if  so  stated  in  the  divorce  proceeding.  About  20  per  cent  of  all 
expenditures  for  family  relief  go  for  aid  to  deserted  women  and  their 
dependents.  The  most  competent  estimate  that  we  have  places  the 
annual  number  of  desertions  in  the  United  States  at  around  50,000. 

The^causes  of  family  desertion  are  numerous  and  complicated,  as  is 
the  case  with  the  causes  for  divorce.  But  they  boil  down  to  two  basic 
situations,  namely,  that  family  life  is  unattractive,  or  that,  for  one  rea- 
son or  another,  it  cannot  be  successfully  continued.  The  causes  of  the 
latter  situation  arc  primarily  economic  insufficiency,  personal  inadequacy 
to  meet  the  responsibilities  of  family  life,  and  lack  of  proper  technique 
for  making  marriage  relations  successful.  The  great  majority  of  deser- 
tions are  made  by  men.  This  is  due  to  the  fact  that  men  depend  less 
upon  their  wives  for  support  and  are  more  easily  drawn  away  from 
family  situations  in  quest  of  sexual  novelty  and  new  contacts. 

There  are  a  number  of  conditions  which  are  most  frequently  associated 
with  family  desertion,  many  of  which  naturally  grow  out  of  the  fact 
that  it  is  mainly  a  lower-class  phenomena.  Deserters  have  been  found 
who  have  an  inadequate  education  in  many  cases.  They  rate  high  in 
lawlessness,  some  20  per  cent  of  them  having  court  records.  Many  of 
the  desertions  are  associated  with  hasty  youthful  marriages.  Personal 
instability  seems  to  play  its  part,  since  over  50  per  cent  of  male  deserters 
are  repeaters  at  the  process.  Abnormal  alcoholic  indulgence  is  frequently 
associated  with  desertion.  There  is  a  relatively  high  proportion  of 
feeble-minded  and  psychopathic  among  family  deserters.  Desertion  is 
much  more  common  in  city  families  than  in  rural  families,  due  to  the 
fact  that  the  family  renders  less  indispensable  services  in  the  city  than 
in  the  country  and  that  there  are  more  temptations  in  the  city.  Deser- 
tions are  more  likely  to  take  place  in  the  case  of  mixed  marriages,  where 
conflicts  of  race,  religion,  language,  and  the  like  exist,  thus  increasing 
the  problems  of  family  adjustment.  In  an  important  study  of  1,500  rep- 
resentative cases  of  desertion  Joanna  C.  Calcord  found  that  about  76  per 
cent  of  the  cases  arose  from  various  forms  of  sex  difficulties  and  from  the 
use  of  alcohol  and  narcotic  drugs.  Thirty-nine  per  cent  was  attributed 
to  the  former  and  37  per  cent  to  the  latter  cause.  Temperamental  causes 
and  economic  insufficiency  accounted  for  the  majority  of  the  remaining 
cases. 

The  social  problems  arising  out  of  desertion  are  not  markedly  different 
from  those  which  grow  out  of  bereavement  and  widowhood,  except  that 
the  element  of  personal  sorrow  may  be  rather  less.23  Desertion  imposes 
the  same  heavy  burden  upon  relief  agencies  and  legislation  which  take 
care  of  the  destitution  produced  by  desertion.  The  problems  of  the 


23  For  an  excellent  discussion  of  desertion  as  a  social  problem,  see  Charles  Zunser, 
"Family  Desertion,"  in  Social  Service  Review,  June,  1932. 


CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS  643 

broken  home,  in  relation  to  both  mother  and  children,  are  the  same  as 
in  the  case  of  widowhood.  In  some  cases,  where  there  are  no  children, 
desertion  may  turn  out  to  be  a  blessing  rather  than  a  calamity,  since  it 
may  terminate  a  family  relationship  which  involved  more  quarreling  and 
discord  than  cordiality  and  satisfaction. 

In  attempting  to  solve  the  problem  of  desertion  we  must  recognize 
that  it  is  a  field  chiefly  for  economic  reform,  mental  hygiene  work,  and  sex 
education.  As  much  as  possible  should  be  done  to  provide  more  adequate 
sex  instruction,  to  bring  the  psychopathic  types  into  contact  with  guid- 
ance clinics,  and  to  increase  the  scope  of  the  work  of  domestic  relations 
courts.  Legislation  to  prevent  hasty  marriages  and  to  discourage  alto- 
gether the  marriages  of  the  psychopathic  and  the  feeble-minded  is  de- 
sirable. Special  social  work  agencies  to  deal  with  desertion  cases  would 
be  extremely  helpful.  It  is  particularly  essential  that  any  assistance 
intended  for  those  already  married  should  be  brought  to  bear  in  the 
early  years  of  marriage.  There  is  little  prospect  of  effective  aid  after 
the  discord  and  quarreling  have  become  chronic.  More  adequate  income 
would  prevent  a  number  of  cases  of  desertion,  but  this  is  a  matter  which 
lies  beyond  the  reach  of  the  social  worker  or  the  mental  hygiene  adviser. 

Illegitimacy  as  a  Social   Problem 

Illegitimacy  is  a  surprisingly  common  phenomenon  in  modern  countries. 
For  example,  in  1914  the  illegitimate  births  in  Austria  amounted  to  11.9 
per  cent  of  the  total  live  births;  in  Denmark  11.5  per  cent;  in  Bavaria 
12.6  per  cent;  in  Saxony  16  per  cent;  in  Portugal  11  per  cent;  in  Sweden 
15.8  per  cent.  In  certain  of  the  European  cities  the  rate  was  much 
higher.  Over  a  five  year  period  from  1905  to  1909  the  illegitimacy  rate 
in  Budapest  was  26.3,  in  Copenhagen  25.5;  in  Lyons  22.2;  in  Moscow  24; 
in  Munich  27.8;  in  Paris  25.5;  in  Stockholm  33.5;  in  Vienna  30.1. 
These  urban  figures  are  somewhat  inflated  however,  because  a  number  of 
the  illegitimate  births  in  urban  hospitals  represent  deliveries  of  rural 
mothers  who  come  to  the  city  for  delivery,  and  the  illegitimate  birth  is 
therefore  registered  in  the  city  where  the  delivery  takes  place.  Sexual 
freedom  and  the  elimination  of  the  whole  conception  of  bastardy  in  Soviet 
Russia,  and  the  desire  to  breed  ample  cannon  fodder  in  Fascist  countries, 
have  of  late  tended  to  increase  illegitimacy  in  European  countries,  as  has 
also  the  confusion  incident  to  the  second  World  War. 

In  the  United  States,  while  the  illegitimacy  rate  is  growing  fairly  rap- 
idly, it  is  still  far  below  representative  European  rates,  especially  in  the 
case  of  our  white  population.  Among  the  Negroes  the  illegitimacy  rate 
tends  to  equal  that  of  the  European  states  with  the  highest  illegitimacy 
rates.  In  1934,  the  illegitimacy  rate  for  American  Negroes  was  15.15  per 
cent.  Samuel  J.  Holmes  has  completed  the  latest  authoritative  survey 
of  illegitimacy  in  the  United  States,  that  based  upon  1934  figures.  Tak- 
ing into  account  both  the  white  and  the  black  population,  the  illegitimacy 
rate  was  3.9  per  cent.  In  other  words,  out  of  every  thousand  live  births, 
39  of  the  babies  were  born  out  of  wedlock.  There  were  35,000  white 


644  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS 

bastards  and  43,000  black  ones.  But  the  ratio  of  bastardy  was  more 
than  seven  times  higher  among  the  blacks  than  it  was  among  the  whites. 
The  rate  for  whites  was  2.04  per  cent  and  for  blacks  the  15.15  per  cent 
mentioned  above.  Professor  Holmes  indicates  that  illegitimacy  is  defi- 
nitely increasing  in  this  country  and  accounts  for  the  increase  in  the 
following  ways:  (1)  over-confidence  in  the  effectiveness  of  simple  and 
inadequate  birth  control  methods;  (2)  the  economic  effects  of  the  de- 
pression which  have  checked  the  marriage  rate  and  produced  a  certain 
amount  of  sexual  and  family  demoralization;  and  (3)  a  lessening  of  the 
stigma  attached  to  illegitimacy. 

Among  the  direct  causes  of  illegitimacy  are  sexual  ignorance  and  inex- 
perience, inadequate  birth  control  devices  or  incomplete  knowledge  of 
how  to  use  effective  devices,  pathological  carelessness  and  indifference, 
intoxication  and  mental  defect.  There  are  other  more  general  and  indi- 
rect causes  of  illegitimacy.  Such  are  increased  sexual  freedom,  unaccom- 
panied by  adequate  knowledge  of  birth  control,  low  economic  status 
which  is  often  associated  with  ignorance,  bad  living  conditions  which 
make  for  sexual  promiscuity,  mental  instability,  and  so  on. 

The  burdens  of  illegitimacy  fall  most  heavily  upon  the  poor.  With  the 
rich  it  is  chiefly  a  matter  of  personal  inconvenience  or  social  humiliation. 
Many  of  the  evils  associated  with  illegitimacy  are  as  much  due  to  social 
intolerance  and  wrong-headedness  as  to  the  personal  responsibility  of 
the  parties  directly  involved.  The  antipathy  toward  the  mother  and 
illegitimate  child  and  the  tendency  to  make  them  both  outcasts  is  an 
outrageous  social  error  which  should  be  speedily  brought  to  an  end  in 
any  civilized  era.  The  fact  that  illegitimate  children  rank  relatively  high 
among  the  juvenile  delinquents  is  also  due  mainly  to  the  stigma  which 
society  places  upon  the  illegitimate  child  and  the  handicaps  which  are 
thus  imposed  upon  him.  The  fear  of  bearing  an  illegitimate  child  leads 
to  many  abortions,  with  the  unfortunate  physical  results  which  frequently 
come  therefrom.  The  economic  problem,  of  rearing  an  illegitimate  child 
is  also  increased  by  the  psychological  obstacles  which  are  added  through 
social  antipathy.  If  one  eliminates  the  traditional  aspect  of  sin,  it  is  thus 
apparent  that  most  of  the  evils  associated  with  illegitimacy  are  socially 
created  and  all  of  them  are  aggravated  by  the  archaic  social  attitude 
toward  the  problem.  If  this  were  changed  the  most  important  aspect  of 
illegitimacy  would  be  that  of  adequate  economic  support  for  the  mother 
and  child. 

The  remedial  steps  to  be  taken  against  illegitimacy  are  clearly  indi- 
cated by  the  situation.  There  should  be  better  sex  education  and  par- 
ticularly better  instruction  in  the  use  of  birth  control  methods.  Improved 
economic  conditions  might  enable  many  to  marry  who  now  find  them- 
selves unable  to  do  so  and  hence  risk  illegitimacy  through  sex  relations 
outside  of  wedlock.  Wholesale  sterilization  of  the  feeble-minded  would 
prevent  the  large  volume  of  illegitimacy  which  is  associated  with  feeble- 
minded parentage.  Better  education,  especially  instruction  in  sex  mat- 
ters and  birth  control,  as  well  as  the  improvement  of  economic  conditions, 


CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS  645 

would  help  to  reduce  the  especially  notable  volume  of  illegitimacy  among 
the  Negroes  in  this  country.  Pending  the  time  at  which  illegitimacy  may 
be  reduced  in  those  cases  where  it  is  desirable  to  do  so,  the  whole  idea  of 
bastardy,  and  the  mental  complexes  associated  therewith,  should  be  com- 
pletely swept  away,  as  has  already  been  done  in  Fascist  countries  and 
Soviet  Russia.  After  an  illegitimate  child  is  born  it  is  too  late  to  accom- 
plish anything  by  terrorizing  the  mother  or  humiliating  the  child.  The 
child's  future  transcends  any  other  consideration.  His  chances  for  devel- 
opment into  a  useful  citizen  must  not  be  lessened  as  a  result  of  antiquated 
ethical  prejudices  and  mob  psychology. 

Child   Problems  and  Child  Care  Outside  the  Family 

Down  to  modern  times  the  child  contributed  all  of  his  labor  to  the 
family,  and  the  family  gave  the  child  such  attention  as  he  received  in 
the  way  of  food,  clothing  and  shelter,  education,  medical  care,  and  the 
like.  The  family  had  nearly  complete  control  of  the  child  and  received 
all  his  services  in  return.  Now  that  the  old  authoritarian  family  is 
breaking  up  and  the  rural  economy  is  being  superseded  by  an  urban  in- 
dustrial age,  the  family  no  longer  provides  complete  care  for  children, 
does  not  exert  full  authority  over  children,  and  does  not  receive  all  of 
the  services  of  children.  We  may  look  briefly  at  some  ways  in  which 
the  community  and  the  state  have  stepped  in  to  take  over  many  respon- 
sibilities for  the  child  which  once  fell  to  the  family. 

Great  progress  has  been  made  in  protecting  the  health  of  the  child  since 
a  century  ago,  when  the  mother  was  usually  delivered  by  a  midwife  and 
doctored  her  children  through  various  herbs  and  syrups.  The  develop- 
ment of  antiseptic  methods  in  maternity  cases  and  especially  the  recent 
introduction  of  the  drug  sulfanilamide  has  greatly  reduced  the  number  of 
maternity  deaths  at  childbirth  and  saved  many  mothers  to  care  for  their 
children.  The  control  of  communicable  diseases  and  the  epidemic  dis- 
eases of  childhood  have  saved  the  lives  of  many  thousands  of  children 
who  formerly  died  from  diphtheria,  whooping  cough,  scarlet  fever,  and 
the  like.  Improved  knowledge  of  nutritional  science  has  greatly  reduced 
deaths  among  young  children.  The  community  and  the  state  have  given 
special  attention  to  providing  public  medical  care  for  children.  Clinics 
and  state  medicine  in  various  forms  have  usually  been  made  accessible 
to  children  long  before  they  are  generally  extended  to  adults.  Gymna- 
sium work  and  supervised  play  have  also  made  their  contributions  to  the 
improvement  of  the  physical  health  and  resistance  of  children. 

Even  more  solicitous  has  been  the  action  of  the  more  alert  communities 
in  looking  after  the  mental  health  of  children.  This  has  been  due  largely 
to  the  fact  that  psychiatrists  recognize  the  critical  importance  of  child- 
hood in  relation  to  both  mental  health  and  disease.  Psychological  clinics 
for  children  appeared  in  this  country  as  early  as  1896.  But  the  move- 
ment for  mental  health  clinics  for  children,  usually  called  child  guidance 
clinics,  did  not  really  begin  to  get  under  way  until  the  National  Com- 
mittee for  Mental  Hygiene  was  created  in  1909.  Then  the  movement 


646  CONTEMPORARY  FAMILY  PROBLEMS 

grew  rapidly.  By  1914  there  were  a  hundred  such  clinics,  and  by  1930 
there  were  over  500.  A  great  stimulus  to  the  movement  was  given  in 
1921,  when  the  Commonwealth  Fund  provided  money  for  setting  up  a 
large  number  of  demonstration  clinics  in  important  cities  throughout  the 
country.  These  guidance  clinics  have  been  of  great  value  in  curbing 
mental  disease  and  delinquency  and  in  aiding  educators  in  a  more  realistic 
handling  of  problem  children. 

A  hundred  years  ago  very  few  persons  thought  of  limiting  the  labor  of 
children.  The  parents  were  supposed  to  have  full  right  to  get  as  much 
work  out  of  children  as  possible.  If  they  were  employed  outside  of  the 
family,  much  the  same  notions  held  true.  Beginning  in  1842  public 
authority  began  to  be  asserted  in  protecting  children  from  industrial 
exploitation.  In  that  year  the  state  of  Massachusetts  passed  a  law 
limiting  the  work  of  children  under  twelve  to  ten  hours  daily.  But  the 
movement  for  such  protection  developed  very  slowly  and  as  late  as 
1938  only  ten  states  adequately  protected  children  from  excessive  hours 
of  labor.  Federal  child  labor  laws  were  set  aside  by  the  Supreme  Court 
in  1918  and  1922.  An  amendment  to  the  federal  constitution  prohibiting 
child  labor  has  been  before  the  country  since  1924.  Recent  decisions  of 
the  Supreme  Court,  such  as  United  States  vs.  Darby  (1941),  indicate  that 
the  present  bench  would  uphold  federal  legislation  outlawing  child  labor. 

That  much  needs  to  be  done  still  in  protecting  children  from  economic 
exploitation  is  to  be  seen  from  the  fact  that  in  1930  there  were  nearly 
700,000  gainfully  employed  children  under  fifteen  years  of  age.  The 
Wages-and-Hours  Act  of  1938  sharply  restricted  the  labor  of  children  in 
industries  engaged  in  interstate  commerce,  but  there  are  still  a  large 
number  employed  in  intrastate  industries. 

In  addition  to  negative  or  restraining  activities  on  the  part  of  the  gov- 
ernment in  relation  to  the  labor  of  young  children  the  federal  government 
has  in  the  last  decade  taken  positive  steps  to  provide  employment  or 
support  for  unemployed  youth  old  enough  to  be  permitted  to  work.  The 
Civilian  Conservation  Corps  has  provided  employment  for  over  2  million 
and  further  assistance  has  been  rendered  by  the  National  Youth  Adminis- 
tration. 

A  century  ago  orphaned  and  dependent  children  were  taken  care  of 
mainly  in  almshouses  and  through  what  is  known  as  indentures,  that  is, 
placing  the  children  in  families  who  agreed  to  support  them  in  return 
for  their  labor.  Both  of  these  types  of  caring  for  dependent  children 
were  cruel  and  unsatisfactory.  The  almshouses  made  for  demoraliza- 
tion; indenture  invited  exploitation. 

In  the  middle  of  the  last  century  the  Children's  Aid  Society  of  New 
York  began  the  important  movement  to  take  children  out  of  almshouses 
and  put  them  in  foster  homes  without  the  abuse  of  indenture.  In  1868  the 
Massachusetts  Board  of  Charities  introduced  the  practice  of  boarding  out 
children  at  public  expense.  It  is  generally  agreed  that  carefully  selected 
foster  homes  are  a  better  place  for  the  dependent  child  than  even  very 
good  orphanages.  However,  the  latter  are  an  enormous  improvement  over 


CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS  647 

the  old  almshouses  and  their  administration  is  constantly  improving. 
The  census  of  dependent  children  in  1923  showed  that  out  of  the  total  of 
about  400,000  such  children,  204,000  were  in  institutions,  121,000  in  their 
own  homes,  51,000  in  free  foster  homes,  and  22,000  in  boarding  homes. 

Public  care  has  been  extended  not  only  to  dependent  children  but  also  to 
neglected  children.  In  1875  the  Society  for  the  Prevention  of  Cruelty  to 
Children  was  founded  to  protect  neglected  children  in  New  York.  Similar 
societies  sprang  up  in  many  other  important  cities.  They  brought  cases 
of  cruelty  and  exploitation  of  children  to  the  courts,  helped  to  punish  the 
guilty,  and  made  provisions  for  the  welfare  of  the  child.  The  progress 
which  has  been  made  in  protecting  children  from  abuse  can  be  seen  from 
the  fact  that  in  early  days  half  the  cases  related  directly  to  physical 
cruelty.  Today  these  cases  usually  do  not  amount  to  more  than  10  per 
cent  of  the  total  cases.  In  addition  to  protecting  children  from  cruelty, 
the  care  of  neglected  children  extends  to  the  support  of  such  children,  and 
efforts  to  prevent  them  from  falling  into  crime  and  vice. 

In  earlier  days  the  family  supplied  most  of  the  moral  training  and 
discipline  for  children.  But  with  the  decline  of  the  rural  family  and  the 
greater  temptations  of  urban  life,  agencies  had  to  be  set  up  to  keep  chil- 
dren out  of  crime.  Here  the  most  important  agencies  have  been  the  Child 
Guidance  Clinics  mentioned  above  and  the  clinics  for  juvenile  delinquents 
and  juvenile  courts.  The  leading  figure  in  promoting  this  movement  has 
been  Dr.  William  Healy.  He  established  a  juvenile  psychopathic  insti- 
tute in  connection  with  the  juvenile  court  of  Chicago  in  1909.  Later  he 
went  to  Boston  and  continued  his  good  work  with  the  Judge  Baker 
Foundation.  This  juvenile  court  movement  under  psychiatric  guidance 
has  made  considerable  headway  in  the  last  two  decades.  Frederic  M. 
Thrasher  and  Clifford  Shaw  have  aroused  interest  in  preventing  juvenile 
delinquency  through  coping  with  the  gang  problem  of  youth  and  the 
special  dangers  involved  in  rearing  children  in  delinquency  areas. 

Formerly,  the  father  and  mother  provided  much  of  the  education  for 
the  child  (guided  by  the  motto  that  to  spare  the  rod  spoils  the  child). 
Most  of  those  who  got  any  chance  for  an  education  received  it  in  the 
miserably  equipped  rural  schools.  Beginning  back  in  the  eighties  of  the 
last  century,  G.  Stanley  Hall  applied  scientific  psychological  principles 
to  the  education  of  children.  An  effort  was  made  to  free  education  from 
the  barbarous  discipline  of  the  traditional  schools  by  John  Dewey  and 
others  through  what  has  come  to  be  known  as  experimental  schools  and 
progressive  education.  Some  kind  of  an  education  was  made  accessible 
for  all  through  the  extension  of  free  public  instruction  for  children  after 
1837.  The  introduction  of  mental  tests  has  enabled  us  to  classify  chil- 
dren more  effectively  and  to  differentiate  education  in  such  a  fashion  as 
to  make  it  more  satisfactorily  adjusted  to  superior  children,  average 
children,  and  retarded  children.  Vocational  instruction  is  being  provided 
more  adequately  for  the  last  group.  City  schools  early  showed  great 
improvement  over  the  little  red  school  house  of  the  country.  More  re- 
cently the  development  of  consolidated  and  centralized  schools  has  revo- 


648  CONTEMPORARY   FAMILY   PROBLEMS 

lutionized  the  quality  of  instruction  and  the  educational  opportunities  in 
rural  schools. 

Play,  which  used  to  be  limited  to  the  family  groups,  the  neighborhood, 
and  the  rural  school,  has  now  been  developed  as  a  major  community  and 
national  enterprise.  Public  recreational  activities  have  developed  on  a 
vast  scale  and  supervised  play  has  grown  by  leaps  and  bounds.  In  1938 
there  were  about  1,300  communities  carrying  on  public  recreation,  spend- 
ing about  60  million  dollars  therefor.  Over  a  third  of  them  were  aided 
by  federal  funds.  Nevertheless,  our  recreational  facilities  for  children 
are  still  woefully  inadequate.  There  are  about  8  million  urban  children 
who  have  little  facility  for  play  and  few  rural  children  have  much  oppor- 
tunity for  organized  and  supervised  recreation.  The  consolidated  rural 
schools  have  done  something  to  remedy  this  situation,  but  so  far  the  sur- 
face has  only  been  scratched.  There  are  certain  organizations  of  youth 
devoted  to  recreation  and  character  building,  such  as  the  Boy  and  Girl 
Scouts,  Camp  Fire  Girls,  Pioneer  Youth,  and  the  like. 

Child  welfare  activities  and  organizations  are  numerous  and  extensive. 
Various  health  agencies  look  after  the  physical  and  mental  health  of  chil- 
dren. Educators  and  social  workers  are  concerned  with  seeing  to  it  that 
children  get  a  decent  education.  Criminologists  and  psychiatrists  en- 
deavor to  break  up  gangs  and  save  children  from  crime.  Recreation 
organizers  seek  to  provide  a  substitute  for  unhealthy  forms  of  activity 
which  might  lead  to  delinquency  and  degeneracy. 

Among  the  various  associations  which  give  special  attention  to  child 
welfare  are  the  Consumers  League,  the  National  Child  Labor  Commit- 
tee, the  Child  Welfare  League  of  America,  the  National  Child  Welfare 
Association,  and  the  American  Child  Health  Association.  There  are  also 
various  institutes  of  child  welfare  conducted  by  leading  universities.  The 
Federal  Children's  Bureau  is  devoted  to  research  and  education  in  the 
field  of  child  welfare.  Important  national  White  House  conferences  on 
child  welfare  met  in  1909  and  1930. 

The  preceding  pages  indicate  the  remarkable  development  of  social 
organizations  and  agencies  designed  to  supplement  functions  formerly 
assumed  by  the  family.  Their  growth  has  paralleled  the  loosening  of 
family  ties  and  the  decay  of  family  responsibility  on  the  heels  of  indus- 
trialization and  urbanization.  There  is  no  reason  to  believe  that  extra- 
family  activities  and  agencies  will  absorb  all  of  the  former  social  functions 
of  the  family,  but  it  is  already  apparent  that  they  are  extensively  supple- 
menting the  family  in  the  control  of  children.  The  desirable  future 
situation  is  better  family  control  over  those  responsibilities  which  can  best 
be  executed  by  the  family  and  a  more  complete  development  of  those 
policies  and  agencies  which  are  needed  to  supplement  family  activities  in 
our  complex  society. 


CHAPTER  XVI 

The  Disintegration  of  Primary  Groups 
and  Community  Disorganization 

The  Meaning  of  Community  Life 

AN  ANALYSIS  of  community  organization  will  be  vague  unless  some 
underlying  sociological  concepts  are  clarified,  since  all  efforts  to  create  a 
new  condition  of  social  stability  can  succeed  only  after  a  thorough  under- 
standing of  the  causative  factors  involved  in  the  decay  of  the  former 
primary  institutions. 

The  frequent  use  of  the  term  community  in  the  past  few  decades  does 
not  mean  that  a  new  basis  for  human  association  has  been  discovered. 
Group  life  was  characteristic  of  human  society  as  soon  as  a  sufficient 
food  supply  for  man  and  his  herds  would  permit  permanent  settlement. 
The  struggle  to  exist  made  it  necessary  for  primitive  society  to  be  formed 
on  tightly  drawn  lines.  Kinship,  based  on  blood  ties,  represented  the 
most  intimate  of  associations,  but  this  kinship  grouping  was  also  extended 
to  clans  and  tribes  living  in  one  area.  The  vital  interest  of  making  a 
living  was  sufficient  to  unite  the  members  of  one  local  group  and,  so  long 
as  the  common  interest  remained,  the  group  was  cohesive.  Primitive 
society  thus  represented  partly  isolated  groups  of  people  dependent  on 
their  own  members.  Unity  of  purpose  was  so  necessary  to  the  existence 
of  a  group  that,  as  Ross  observes,  "In  the  ancient  village  community, 
every  quarrel  between  individual  members  was  treated  as  a  community 
affair,  even  the  bitter  words  uttered  during  a  quarrel  being  considered  an 
offense  against  the  community.  Every  dispute  was  brought  before 
arbiters,  or  in  the  gravest  cases,  before  the  folk  mote."  *  As  population 
increased,  groups  came  in  contact  with  others.  The  close  bonds  of 
association  were  weakened  by  the  entrance  of  new  interests,  and  kinship 
by  blood  ties  was  no  longer  the  only  social  bond. 

As  the  economic  base  of  society  broadened,  associations  along  the  lines 
of  caste  and  class  were  formed  and,  with  the  increasing  complexity  of  life, 
these  associations  were  expanded.  However  broadened  the  contacts  of 
individuals  may  be  in  a  complex  society,  one  fundamental  fact  is  to  be 
noted,  namely,  no  individual  can  be  independent  of  all  others.  All  indi- 
viduals are  mutually  dependent,  and  our  whole  "social  order  rests  essen- 


E.  A.  Ross,  Principles  of  Sociology,  Revised  Ed.,  Applet on-Century,  1930,  p.  385. 

649 


650          DISINTEGRATION   OF  PRIMARY  GROUPS 

tially  upon  the  interaction  and  interdependency  of  people." 2  In  primi- 
tive society  this  dependence  was  due  to  the  need  for  cooperation  in  the 
struggle  for  existence,  and  involved  intimate  relationships.  In  complex 
modern  society  there  still  is  interdependence  because  specialization  and 
division  of  labor  have  made  it  impossible  for  individuals  to  exist  alone. 
The  combined  efforts  of  all  workers  are  needed  to  produce  the  goods 
that  will  be  used  by  individual  members  of  the  group,  but  the  associations 
have  lost  some  of  their  intimate  characteristics. 

The  word  community  has  been  loosely  used  to  designate  a  group  of 
people  having  a  unity  of  purpose,  or  to  be  more  specific,  a  group  of  people 
having  the  we-feeling  and  living  in  a  common  area.  There  have  been  so 
many  definitions  of  the  term  that  it  is  well  to  give  definite  content  to  the 
word.  The  rural  sociologists  have  given  the  most  painstaking  thought 
to  the  term  and  have  settled  on  the  idea  that  community  represents  the 
smallest  geographical  unit  that  permits  organized  execution  of  the  chief 
human  activities.3 

One  accepted  approach  which  does  not  limit  community  to  a  small 
social  unit  is  recognition  of  a  common  purpose.  This  is  a  vague  and 
philosophical  concept.  The  common  purpose  is  the  real  aim  of  commu- 
nity organization  but  it  must  be  clearly  defined.  Stuart  A.  Queen  gives 
a  practical  definition  when  he  thinks  of  community  as  being  a  group 
which  occupies  a  given  territory  and,  through  the  exchange  of  service  and 
goods,  may  be  regarded  as  a  cooperating  unit.4 

Even  this  definition  is  none  too  good,  because  under  modern  conditions 
no  group  of  people  can  be  self-supporting;  nor  do  communities  stay  the 
same  in  size.  The  more  the  mobility  of  the  population  increases,  through 
extended  communication  and  transportation,  the  less  usual  it  is  for  the 
local  community  to  supply  the  needs  of  the  group.  The  automobile  has 
widened  the  scope  of  interest  until  rural  people  can  shop  in  the  city  and 
not  be  dependent  on  their  own  local  group. 

The   Role  of  Primary  Groups   in  Social    Life 

The  local  community  is  a  primary  group — one  which  emphasizes  the 
we-feeling.  The  concept  of  the  primary  group  is  so  important  to  the 
whole  community  organization  movement  that  a  reference  to  C.  H. 
Cooley's  theory  of  the  primary  group  is  in  order.  The  human  infant  is 
helpless  for  the  first  few  years.  It  is  the  family  which  cares  for  him,  and 
in  the  close  circle  he  learns  his  first  words  and  is  taught  the  things  he 
should  and  should  not  do.  In  other  words,  the  mores  and  customs  of  the 
group  are  transmitted  to  him  through  the  family.  Therefore,  by  virtue 
of  being  born  helpless  into  a  group,  man  from  birth  to  death  is  dependent 
on  others.  As  the  child  grows  older,  he  becomes  part  of  a  play  or  a  small 
neighborhood  group.  Further  association  and  cooperation  here  adjusts 


2  L.  D.  Osburn  and  M.  H.  Neumeyer,  The  Community  and  Society,  American  Book 
Company,  1933,  p.  81. 

3  J.  F.  Steiner,  Community  Organization,  Appleton-Century,  1930,  p.  18. 
*  "What  Is  a  Community?"  Journal  of  Social  Forces,  Vol.  I,  pp.  375-382. 


DISINTEGRATION   OF  PRIMARY  CROUPS         651 

him  to  the  institutional  pattern.  Cooley  in  his  Social  Organization  calls 
these  intimate  associations,  or  face-to-face  relationships  of  man  "the  pri- 
mary groups."  5 

In  these  primary  groups  the  person  acquires  all  the  attributes  which  we 
think  of  as  being  human:  that  is,  love,  forebearance,  sympathy,  tolerance, 
cooperation,  respect  for  others,  and  in  short,  all  that  is  "super-organic," 
to  use  Spencer's  and  Kroeber's  term: 

It  is  in  a  primary  group  that  the  child  attains  its  first  awareness  of  other 
persons  and  subsequently  acquires  self-consciousness.  Here  the  sense  of  belong- 
ing and  having  a  place  and  a  role,  which  is  the  essence  of  personality,  is  first 
derived ;  and  here,  also,  the  child  learns  to  talk  and  acquires  its  habits  of  obedience 
and  self-assertion,  or  their  opposites,  as  well  as  its  moral  judgments.  It  is  in 
the  family,  the  play  group,  the  neighborhood,  and  other  close  relations,  that  the 
standards  and  traditions  of  the  larger  society,  as  well  as  those  typical  of  primary 
groups  are  impressed  most  effectively.0 

The  primary  group  is  characterized  by  "one-ness"  of  purpose  and 
sentiments  of  loyalty.  This  may  also  be  said  of  groups  that  are  not 
permanent,  such  as  the  loyalty  of  the  mob  to  party  or  leader  and  other 
temporary  groupings  that  have  been  formed  in  crises  or  temporary  enthu- 
siasms, but  the  term  is  used  here  to  apply  only  to  those  groups  which  are 
recognized  as  being  permanent  institutions. 

Since  the  primary  groups  have  played  an  outstanding  role  in  the  devel- 
opment of  the  social  process,  they  are  vitally  important  in  the  socializa- 
tion of  the  individual  and  the  integrity  and  preservation  of  all  our  estab- 
lished institutions.  The  economic  and  the  social  changes  of  the  past  150 
years  have  produced  sweeping  changes  in  our  way  of  living  and  the 
machine 'age,  with  its  resultant  transformations  of  life,  has  led  to  the 
partial  breakdown  of  these  fundamental  primary  groups.  This  important 
social  problem  has  recently  been  analyzed  with  thoroughness  by  Ernest  R. 
Mowrer  in  his  Disorganization:  Personal  and  Social. 

The  Disintegration  of   Primary  Groups 

Family  Deterioration.  The  family  has  been  the  primary  institution 
most  resistant  to  social  change,  but  the  events  of  the  past  century  have 
brought  about  such  revolutionary  changes  in  its  composition  and  trends 
that  some  alarmists  predict  that  the  end  of  the  family  is  near.  We  have 
already  discussed  the  changed  conditions  of  women  since  the  Industrial 
Revolution  and  the  growth  of  divorce.  We  shall  here  deal  mainly  with 
symptoms  of  family  instability  as  a  phase  of  the  decay  of  primary  groups. 
The  large  patriarchal  family  of  olden  times,  with  its  close-knit  cohesive- 
ness  and  direct  disciplinary  influence  on  its  members,  has  been  replaced 
by  a  small  individualized  family  group — a  shocking  change  to  the  more 
conservative  students  of  human  relationships.  Willistyne  Goodsell 
points  to  the  complete  disappearance  of  "the  great  family"  from  our 


B  C.  H.  Cooley,  Social  Organization,  pp.  23  ff.    See  above,  pp.  13  ff. 
6E.  T.  Hiller,  Principles  of  Sociology,  Harper,  1933,  p.  22. 


652         DISINTEGRATION  OF  PRIMARY  CROUPS 

modern  picture.7  By  this  is  meant  the  group  of  closely  related  persons 
descended  from  the  same  grandfather  or  great-grandfather  and  residing 
in  the  same  community.  "The  pioneer  spirit,  the  love  of  adventuresome 
change  of  a  pioneer  people,  has  dispersed  the  old  family  stocks  over  the 
face  of  the  American  continent."  She  continues  by  saying  that,  with  the 
dispersion  of  families,  has  come  the  decline,  not  only  of  unity  and  soli- 
darity but  also  of  even  the  honored  meaning  of  the  family:  "Who  in  this 
hurried  individualistic  age  of  self-aggrandisement  and  self-expressions, 
holds  up  before  youth  the  ideals  and  achievements  of  their  ancestors,  the 
honored  place  they  carved  out  in  social  and  political  life,  as  did  the 
Romans  of  old?" 

The  early  American  family  represented  the  cohesive  power  of  a  primary 
institution.  It  rested  on  three  bases:  First,  there  was  the  economic 
and  social  importance  of  the  home.  Second,  one  notes  the  patriarchal 
authority  of  the  husband  and  father,  given  to  him  by  custom  and  law. 
Since  public  opinion  and  the  conditions  of  life  added  to  the  force  of  law 
for  the  male's  authority,  it  is  small  wonder  that  divorces  were  relatively 
unknown.  Third,  the  dependence  of  all  individuals  on  the  united  family 
was  a  prime  factor  in  family  stability,  for  no  individual  had  status  unless 
he  was  a  member  of  a  family  group.  Girls  were  expected  to  marry  young 
and  raise  large  families  and  a  spinster's  usual  lot  in  life  was  to  take  care 
of  the  children  of  some  more  fortunate  sister.  Women,  except  in  their 
family  function,  were  almost  helpless.  This  point  must  be  stressed  be- 
cause of  its  importance  to  the  whole  discussion  of  the  current  lessening  of 
family  bonds.  Women  were  subordinate  to  males  in  the  domestic  econ- 
omy before  the  Industrial  Revolution  to  the  point  where  few  women  had 
economic,  occupational,  or  legal  freedom.  To  summarize  the  social  influ- 
ence of  the  American  family: 

The  American  family  was  many  things  to  its  individual  members.  There  was 
not  only  its  economic  importance,  but  other  institutional  functions  of  the  family 
were  at  the  same  time  strongly  developed.  It  furnished  protection  to  its  mem* 
bers,  with  less  aid  from  the  community  than  is  expected  today;  it  might  even, 
as  in  the  case  of  feuds,  carry  on  private  wars.  The  authority  of  the  father 
and  husband  was  sufficient  to  settle  within  the  family  many  of  the  problems  of 
cbnduct.  Religious  instruction  and  ritual  were  a  part  of  family  life.  For  a  suc- 
cessful marriage  it  was  considered  important  that  couples  should  have  the  same 
faith.  In  general,  the  home  was  the  gathering  place  for  play  activities,  though 
there  were  some  community  festivities.  Educationally,  the  farm  and  home  duties 
constituted  a  larger  part  of  learning  than  did  formal  instruction  in  schools.  Farm 
life  furnished  what  we  now  call  manual  training,  physical  education,  domestic 
science  instruction  and  vocational  guidance.  The  individual  spent  much  of  the 
daily  cycle  in  the  family  setting,  occupied  in  ways  set  by  the  family  pattern.8 

Today  an  impressive  number  of  forces  are  at  work  to  reduce  the  sanc- 
tity of  the  hearth  fire  to  an  interesting  antique  while  the  individual 


*  Goodsell,  Problems  of  the  Family,  Appleton-Century,  1936,  Revised  Ed.,  p.  122. 
8  J.  H.  S.  Bossard,  Social  Change  and  Social  Problems,  Harper,  1938,  p.  597,  quoted 
from  W.  F.  Ogburn,  Recent  Social  Trends,  McGraw-Hill,  1930,  Vol.  I,  p.  662. 


DISINTEGRATION   OF  PRIMARY   CROUPS         653 

family  members  scatter  to  search  congenial  associates  and  new  ways  to 
pass  the  time. 

The  divorce  rate  is  one  of  the  most  convincing  evidences  of  the  break- 
down of  the  patriarchal  form  of  family  life.  All  countries  of  the  western 
world  and  particularly  the  United  States  have  had,  as  we  have  seen,  an 
alarming  increase  in  the  divorce  rate  in  the  past  fifty  years.  The  fre- 
quency of  divorce  has  increased  by  more  than  threefold  since  1890.  In 
this  year  there  were  53  divorces  per  100,000  of  the  population,  while 
in  1935  there  were  171.  In  the  latter  year  there  was  one  divorce  to  every 
six  marriages.9  Miss  Goodsell  further  continues  with  the  statistical  evi- 
dence by  comparing  the  ratio  of  unbroken  marriages  to  the  population 
in  1912  and  1932.  In  that  interval  the  number  of  unbroken  marriages 
per  thousand  of  the  population  fell  from  9.57  to  6.59.10 

J.  P.  Lichtenberger  has  shown  how  the  increase  in  divorce  rate,  as  early 
as  the  period  1870-1905,  far  outstripped  the  rate  of  population  increase.11 
Analysis  of  the  divorce  statistics  shows  a  steady  increase  in  the  number 
of  divorces  granted  as  petitions  by  the  wife,  indicating  a  growing  refusal 
on  the  part  of  femininity  to  submit  to  situations  which  were  once  tolerated 
because  of  the  force  of  the  folkways  and  mores.  We  can  glean  few  im- 
portant sociological  truths  from  scanning  the  formal  legal  causes  of 
divorce.  As  has  been  observed,  cruelty,  one  of  the  most  frequent  causes 
listed  in  petitions  for  divorce,  is  a  blanket  term  which  may  extend  all 
the  way  from  lack  of  understanding  to  the  actual  infliction  of  physical 
blows. 

Other  analyses  that  have  been  made  by  the  U.  S.  Bureau  of  Census  on 
the  salient  features  of  divorces  show  that  in  1932,  3.9%  of  divorces  were 
granted  to  couples  whose  marriage  had  lasted  under  one  year  and  that, 
of  the  total  divorces,  35%  were  granted  to  persons  whose  marriages  had 
lasted  less  than  five  years.  And  then,  again,  the  same  year,  1932,  shows 
that  55%  of  all  divorces  were  granted  to  couples  who  had  no  children. 
In  other  words,  the  decreasing  desire  for  children  and,  consequently,  the 
shrunken  family  makes  the  family  influence  decidedly  less  permanent.12 

One  more  observation  on  divorce  statistics  is  necessary  for  future  refer- 
ence. Available  data  show  that  the  percentage  of  divorce  in  urban  com- 
munities outstrips  the  rate  in  rural  districts.  We  shall  deal  with  this  in 
detail  later,  but  at  this  point,  we  can  see  that  the  social  and  economic 
conditions  of  the  city,  with  its  hurry,  competition,  and  nervous  strain 
coupled  with  the  breakdown  of  moral  standards  and  the  indifference  of 
the  public  in  the  matter  of  the  individual's  affairs,  have  been  largely  re- 
sponsible for  the  increase  in  divorce  and  the  threatened  disappearance  of 
American  family  life.13  First  place  in  the  reasons  for  divorce  must  be 


°See  above,  pp.  622  ff. 

10  Goodsell,  op.  cit.,  p.  123. 

11  Divorce:  A  Social  Interpretation,  p.  143. 

12  Goodsell,  op.  cit.,  p.  394  ff. 

13  See  Ernest  Groves  and  W.  F.  Ogburn,  American  Marriage  and  Family  Rela- 
tionship, Holt,  1928,  p.  356. 


654         DISINTEGRATION  OF  PRIMARY  CROUPS 

assigned  to  the  rapid  urbanization  of  modern  life,  recent  economic  changes 
and  the  growing  economic  independence  of  woman,  sexual  ignorance  and 
incompatibility  on  the  part  of  the  husband,  wife,  or  both,  and  the  current 
ease  of  contracting  marriage.14 

Added  to  the  foregoing  statistical  evidence  of  the  broken  marital 
ties  may  be  mentioned  desertion.  Though  desertion  has  often  been 
described  as  "the  poor  man's  divorce,"  some  students  insist  that  it  would 
be  more  correct  to  speak  of  desertion  as  the  "poor  man's  vacation/'  since 
the  deserting  man  does  not  as  a  rule  consider  his  absences  from  home  as 
anything  so  final  and  definite  as  divorce.15 

Social  workers  give  us  our  best  information  concerning  the  large  num- 
ber of  men  who,  finding  the  economic  burden  at  home  too  heavy,  shake  it 
off  on  the  shoulders  of  welfare  agencies  and  depart.  Desertions  have  be- 
come more  numerous  since  the  depression  days  of  1929,  as  governmental 
agencies  have  marshaled  their  forces  to  take  over  the  responsibilities  of 
the  individual  heads  of  families.  Some  recent  commentators  have  called 
attention  to  the  increasing  proportion  of  cases  where  the  wife  and  mother 
deserts  the  family.  This  is  probably  a  result  of  the  newer  freedom  of 
women  and  the  recent  expansion  of  the  occupational  opportunities. 

Laws  passed  to  bring  the  erring  husband  back  to  compel  his  support 
of  his  wife  and  children  have  been  of  little  effect.  With  no  job,  there 
can  be  no  support,  or  if  he  is  fortunate  enough  to  secure  a  job,  he  may 
refuse  to  support  his  family.  The  only  alternative  is  a  jail  sentence 
which  removes  both  job  and  husband  and  places  the  family  back  on 
relief. 

The  weakened  influence  of  the  primary  relationship  may  be  seen  fur- 
ther in  the  increase  of  juvenile  delinquency.  More  than  200,000  children 
each  year  pass  through  our  juvenile  courts,  representing  1%  of  children 
of  juvenile  court  age.16 

The  breakdown  of  the  family  may  be  further  traced  to  the  economic 
changes  following  the  Industrial  Revolution.  The  center  of  production 
shifted  from  the  home,  which  ceased  to  be  of  primary  economic  impor- 
tance. The  change  went  further  than  that.  The  growing  of  foodstuffs, 
canning,  breadmaking,  the  fashioning  of  clothing,  the  concocting  of  home 
medicines — all  of  the  cooperative  enterprises  which  made  for  family  self- 
sufficiency  and  the  resulting  cohesion — were  removed  from  the  family. 
Electricity  for  home  use  has  made  possible  thousands  of  labor-saving 
devices  that  provide  more  leisure. 

The  urban  impact,  which  is  responsible  for  the  change  in  size  of  homes, 
will  be  considered  in  detail  later.  The  employment  of  women  outside 
the  home,  as  a  logical  result  of  the  reduced  economic  role  of  women  within 
the  home  and  because  of  the  increased  cost  of  living,  will  be  discussed 
later  and  need  only  be  mentioned  in  this  connection  as  a  reason  why  the 

14  Cf.  Lichtenberger,  Divorce,  Part  II. 

15  Bossard,  Social  Change  and  Social  Problems,  p.  629,  cited  from  Joanna  Colcord, 
Broken  Homes,  Russell  Sage  Foundation,  1919,  p.  7. 

16  Bossard,  op.  cit.,  p.  663,  quoted  from  Joanna  Colcord,  op.  cit.t  p.  7, 


DISINTEGRATION  OF  PRIMARY  CROUPS         655 

home  has  lost  in  cohesiveness  and  influence.  To  cite  Bossard,  the  social 
cohesion  of  the  earlier  form  of  family,  cemented  by  joint  participation  in 
community  enterprises  is  passing:  "As  a  result  its  individual  members 
have  been  liberated  to  pursue  first,  his  or  her  own  work  and  subsequently 
and  increasingly,  other  aspects  of  their  individual  lives." 1T  In  summary, 
"the  members  of  the  family  are  torn  asunder  by  different  tasks,  interests, 
contacts,  and  circles  of  friends.  So  far  as  the  family  holds  the  loyalty  of 
its  members,  it  does  so  in  spite  of  their  diversity  of  work."  18  In  other 
words,  the  home  of  today  is  maintained  not  as  a  necessity  but  because 
we  have  found  no  other  substitute  for  women  as  mothers,  and  no  other 
place  where,  "we  may  act  like  we  feel  and  when  we  feel  like  it."  But  the 
influence  of  the  family  as  a  basic  social  unit  is  fading  away. 

Breakdown  of  the  Neighborhood.  The  second  of  the  primary  relation- 
ships that  have  been  weakened  as  a  result  of  the  changes  of  the  past  150 
years  is  that  of  the  neighborhood.  The  decay  of  the  neighborhood  has 
been  closely  associated  with  the  increasing  importance  of  city  life.  In 
the  city,  "identity  of  interests  and  a  concern  for  the  conditions  of  the 
neighborhood,  except  as  they  clearly  affect  personal,  economic,  and  social 
affairs,  tend  to  disappear.  Modern  methods  of  communication  and  trans- 
portation make  possible  a  wide  psycho-social  and  territorial  range.  The 
person's  activities  are  not  necessarily  located  in  his  home  community  nor 
are  the  participants  of  these  activities,  his  neighbors.  Locus  becomes 
significant  as  a  place  of  retirement  from  the  varied  stimuli  of  social 
activity,  and  neighboring  tends  to  be  redefined  as  unwarranted  interest." 19 

The  neighborhood  spirit  of  a  small  isolated  group  was  only  an  exten- 
sion of  the  intimate  characteristics  of  family  association.  A  real  neigh- 
bor was  concerned  with  the  affairs  of  others.  Helping  hands  were  given 
in  time  of  trouble  and  distress.  A  family  joy  over  the  birth  of  a  new 
baby,  an  engagement,  wedding,  or  some  good  luck,  was  a  signal  for  neigh- 
borhood rejoicing.  Farmers  exchanged  work  during  harvest  time.  In 
a  typical  rural  community  where  the  wheat  was  ripe  and  ready  for  thresh- 
ing, the  news  went  forth  to  all  the  farmers  and  their  wives  for  miles 
around,  who  gathered  to  help  with  the  threshing.  Wagons  and  teams 
of  the  neighborhood  were  all  at  the  disposal  of  the  threshing  farmers. 
All  hands  went  to  work  with  a  will.  The  threshing  scene  was  one  of 
frenzied,  cheerful  activity.  Wagons  hauling  water  plied  back  and  forth, 
small  boys  of  all  ages  and  sizes  darted  around  getting  in  the  way  but 
helping  in  their  own  fashion.  On  a  single  farm,  there  might  be  25  or  30 
farmers  with  as  many  teams  all  engaged  in  threshing,  sacking,  and  loading 
grain,  and  stacking  straw  and  carrying  it  to  the  barns. 

But  it  was  at  noon  time  that  the  real  community  spirit  was  most 
evident.  Since  early  morning  the  women  of  the  neighborhood  had  been 
on  hand  to  prepare  the  food  for  the  noon  day  meal.  They  had  come 


™  Op.  cit.,  p.  600. 

18  E.  A.  Ross,  op.  cit.,  p.  606. 

19  Bessie  A.  McClenahan,  The  Changing  Urban  Neighborhood,  Univ.  of  California, 
Studies  #  1,  1930,  quoted  from  E,  A,  Ross,  Principles  of  Sociology,  p.  U5, 


656          DISINTEGRATION   OF  PRIMARY  CROUPS 

armed  with  pans,  kettles,  tableclothes,  and  provisions.  The  tables  were 
set  on  trestles  under  the  trees  and  it  was  the  job  of  the  small  girls  to  wave 
green  branches  to  keep  the  flies  away  from  the  crowd,  who  gathered  hot 
and  goodnatured  for  the  noon  meal.  Each  farm  woman  vied  with  the 
others  to  supply  a  good  meal  for  the  threshers.  The  choicest  of  vege- 
tables, jellies  and  preserves  were  opened;  dozens  of  frying  chickens  and 
stacks  of  pies  and  cakes  were  absolute  necessities  for  the  threshing  dinner. 
The  work  was  cheerfully  done,  but  the  helpers  expected  a  good  meal  and 
one  thresher's  helper  was  heard  to  remark,  "I  ain't  never  going  to  help 
there  agin.  The  apple  pie  was  so  tough  you  couldn't  cut  it  and  there 
warn't  enough  sweetening  in  it  for  a  cup  of  coffee."  During  the  threshing 
season  these  gatherings  were  repeated  until  all  the  neighborhood  wheat 
was  in  the  barn  or  at  the  mill. 

The  coming  of  the  mechanized  machinery  made  it  unnecessary  for  the 
neighborhood  to  cooperate  in  the  threshing  on  each  farm  and  put  an  end 
to  this  particular  expression  of  neighborliness.  One  by  one,  the  other 
neighborhood  bonds  have  been  loosened.  Quilting  parties,  ice  cream  so- 
cials, the  camp  meeting,  the  corn  bee — all  have  been  made  unnecessary  in 
the  farmer's  life  by  the  automobile  and  the  radio  and  the  other  numerous 
mechanizations.  Some  remnants  of  neighborliness  may  still  be  found  in 
the  more  remote  communities,  where  modern  interests  and  smooth  high- 
ways have  not  as  yet  penetrated  so  completely.  The  stronger  the  urban 
and  mechanical  influence,  the  more  complete  the  disappearance  of  the 
primary  influence  of  neighborhood.  In  the  place  of  the  neighborhood,  we 
find  small  interest-groups  which  have  only  the  localized  interests  of  their 
occupations  or  recreations  to  hold  them  together. 

The  community  neighborliness,  with  its  concern  with  the  affairs  of  all, 
has  been  criticized  because  of  its  insistence  on  the  observance  of  a  rigid 
code  of  behavior.  The  nonconformist  who  refused  to  hold  to  this  code 
found  himself  quickly  ostracized.  It  was  because  of  the  old  type  neigh- 
borhood and  its  one-ness  of  mind  on  moral  codes  that  the  divorce  rate 
in  the  United  States  remained  low  until  urbanization  occurred.  No 
woman  dared  incur  the  disapproval  of  the  community  by  divorcing  her 
husband,  even  if  she  had  ample  justification  for  doing  so.  The  home 
was  a  sacred  institution  and  the  neighborhood  saw  to  it  that  the  family, 
to  all  outward  appearances,  remained  intact.  The  efforts  of  the  past 
20  years  to  revive  the  old  neighborhood  spirit  by  clubs,  poultry  associa- 
tions, home-makers  clubs,  farm  clubs,  and  other  substitutes  for  the 
primary  group  are  the  surest  proof  that  the  influence  of  the  primary  group 
was  a  strong  force  for  the  good  of  the  community. 

The  Decay  of  the  Rural  Play  Group.  As  is  to  be  expected,  with  the 
decline  of  the  neighborhood  the  traditional  play  group  was  doomed.  The 
old  rural  play  group  has  been  wiped  out  even  more  thoroughly  than  the 
rural  family,  which  still  continues  to  exist,  though  with  much  less  co- 
hesiveness  than  formerly.  The  rural  play  group  was  made  up  of  the 
boys  and  girls  in  one  family  or  in  several  neighboring  families,  or  of  those 
who  attended  the  local  district  school.  Theirs  represented  a  simple  and 


DISINTEGRATION   OF  PRIMARY  CROUPS         657 

direct  type  of  games  and  recreation,  in  which  all  participated  on  a  rela- 
tively equal  plane.  This  play  group  not  only  supplied  most  of  the 
recreation  enjoyed  by  rural  youngsters  but  also  exercised  a  remarkable 
socializing  influence.  The  games  tended  to  inculcate  a  spirit  of  fair  play, 
of  healthy  competition,  and  of  well-earned  exultation. 

The  simple  rural  play  group  has  now  all  but  disappeared.  There  are 
fewer  children  in  both  the  family  and  the  rural  neighborhood.  A  smaller 
number  of  children  attend  district  schools  where  those  still  persist.  How- 
ever, there  has  been  a  marked  tendency  in  the  more  progressive  states  to 
do  away  with  district  schools  altogether  and  send  the  children  to  new  and 
improved  centralized  schools.  In  the  centralized  schools  there  is  super- 
vised play  and  better  playground  equipment  and  athletic  paraphernalia. 
But  the  small  play  group  has  disintegrated.  In  the  prescribed  classroom 
gymnastics  there  is  little  element  of  play.  In  much  of  the  real  play  most 
of  the  pupils  are  merely  spectators  who  look  on  while  the  members  of  two 
ball  teams,  for  example,  contest  their  skill.  Moreover,  many  neighbor- 
hoods are  brought  together  in  these  centralized  playgrounds  and  different 
cultures  intermingle.  Most  of  the  children  are  originally  strangers  to 
each  other.  There  remains  little  of  the  old  psychic  unity  and  spontaneity 
which  prevailed  in  the  small  rural  playground  associations.20 

The  desire  for  play  is  not  only  neglected  but  often  suppressed  in  the 
city.  Space  is  at  a  premium  and  the  dangers  of  playing  on  crowded  city 
streets  are  all  too  much  in  evidence.  Accordingly,  youngsters  are  prone 
to  gather  on  the  street  corners  and  get  into  mischief  in  their  leisure  hours, 
It  was  not  until  late  in  the  nineteenth  century  that  the  socializing  value  of 
play  was  realized  and  the  Play  Movement  proper  really  began.21 

This  breakdown  of  the  primary  relationships — the  family,  the  neigh- 
borhood, and  the  rural  play  group — thus  began  with  urbanization  and 
the  mechanization  of  life.  Since  urbanization  is  the  chief  cause  of  the 
disappearance,  in  our  modern  life,  of  the  relationships  which  make  for 
fundamental  stability  and  which  have  been,  as  Cooley  says,  "the  cradle 
of  human  nature,"  let  us  further  examine  the  effects  of  this  urban  impact. 

The   Impact  of  Urban   Life  on  Social    Institutions 

The  power  of  the  city  to  disrupt  all  former  social  organization  is  largely 
inherent  in  the  causes  of  city  growth.  Any  sound  interpretation  of  the 
city  will  recognize  the  Industrial  Revolution  and  its  counterpart — the 
Agrarian  Revolutions — as  causal  facts. 

The  mechanical  devices  of  the  nineteenth  century  substituted  machines 
for  hand  work  and  differentiated  manufacturing  from  agriculture,  thereby 
producing  a  cleavage  which  has  influenced  all  social  institutions.  The 
cultural  lag  which  exists  today  in  our  social  institutions  is  a  result  of  the 
failure  of  man's  institutions  to  keep  pace  with  his  material  progress.  The 


20  Cf.,  J.  F.  Steiner,  America  at  Play,  McGraw-Hill,  1933. 

21  See  below,  pp.  831  ff. 


658          DISINTEGRATION   OF  PRIMARY  CROUPS 

factory  system  made  necessary  concentration  of  man  power  and,  con- 
sequently, the  unprecedented  growth  of  urban  population.  However, 
concentration  of  population  would  have  been  impossible  without  improve- 
ments in  communication  and  transportation,  and  without  the  agricultural 
revolution  to  furnish  food  and  raw  materials  for  the  workers  in  the  city 
factories.  In  other  words,  it  would  not  be  inaccurate  to  say  that  ma- 
chines and  factories  made  the  industrial  city  necessary,  while  improved 
agriculture,  transportation  and  trade  have  made  it  possible  for  large 
cities  to  exist  with  unparalleled  frequency.22 

The  agricultural  improvements  made  it  possible  to  grow  a  larger 
amount  of  food  than  ever  before.  As  farming  became  more  efficient, 
fewer  hands  were  needed  and  young  men  and  women  might  go  to  seek 
employment  in  the  cities.  This  shift  began  before  1914,  and  for  20  years 
thereafter  there  was  a  steady  decline  in  the  number  of  those  engaged  in 
agriculture. 

It  was  not  only  an  economic  change  that  aided  the  growth  of  the  city. 
Thut  the  cause  of  the  city's  growth  was  basically  economic,  there  is  no 
doubt,  but  the  psychological  and  cultural  lure  of  the  city  .is  one  of  the 
most  important  reasons  for  a  steady  migration.  The  city  has  been 
called  "a  state  of  mind."  It  is  the  place  where  life  moves  swiftly,  with 
kaleidoscopic  changes,  exciting  hazards,  the  lure  of  large  rewards — offer- 
ing a  glamorous  change  to  the  monotony  that  characterized  rural  life  be- 
fore the  coming  of  the  automobile  and  the  hard-surfaced  road,  and  the 
radio.  It  was  youth  that  was  particularly  dazzled  by  the  city.  Here 
ambition  could  have  full  scope;  the  desire  for  self-expression  and  recog- 
nition— in  fact,  all  the  fundamental  desires  of  the  individual,  it  seemed 
— might  be  realized  in  the  city.  Here  competition  is  at  its  keenest,  offer- 
ing a  challenge  to  those  with  energy.  Rural  life  soon  came  to  carry  a 
stigma  of  the  "hay-seed"  and  the  "country  bumpkin."  It  was  only  in 
the  city  that  life  might  be  lived  to  its  fullest.  The  lag  in  rural  culture 
has  also  been  a  cause  of  rural  migration.  Education,  recreation,  better 
conveniences,  better  churches  are  among  the  varied  causes  of  cityward 
migration. 

While  all  social  types  are  thrown  together  within  the  urban  community, 
social  differentiations  and  barriers  are  found  as  great  as  those  existing  in 
feudal  society.  In  the  city,  persons  live  massed  together  within  close 
proximity,  yet  find  themselves  separated  by  a  "social  distance"  such  as 
exists  nowhere  else: 

In  the  village  and  the  open  country,  where  there  are  few  distinctions  based 
on  social  or  economic  status,  the  social  distance  between  persons  is  usually  not 
pronounced  except  perhaps  in  cases  of  significant  racial  or  cultural  differences. 
But  in  the  city  with  its  varied  cultures,  its  multiplicity  of  behaviour  patterns,  its 
racial  barriers  and  class  distinctions,  its  extremes  of  poverty  and  wealth,  social 
distance  has  widened  even  though  spatial  distance  has  narrowed.23 


22  C/.,  W.  S.  Thompson,  Population  Problems,  McGraw-Hill,  1930,  Chap.  XVI. 

23  N.  P.  Gist  and  L.  A.  Halbert,  Urban  Society,  Crowell,  1935,  p.  266. 


DISINTEGRATION   OF  PRIMARY  CROUPS         659 

The  impersonal  relationships  of  the  city  have  been  cited  as  the  cause 
of  many  of  the  major  social  problems  prevailing  in  the  family,  industry, 
and  education.  But  impersonal  relations  are  inherent  in  the  city  itself. 
It  is  impossible  to  continue  in  urban  life  the  intimate  personal  relation- 
ships of  the  small  community.  Diversified  national  groups,  with  different 
cultural  patterns,  mobility  of  groups,  and  congestion  have  all  definitely 
prevented  the  extension  of  the  spirit  of  neighborliness  in  the  city,  as  in  the 
local  community: 

As  Burgess  has  put  it,  mobility  becomes  "the  pulse  of  the  community"  the  best 
index  of  the  state  of  metabolism  of  the  city.  Always  does  the  rate  of  mobility 
affect  social  relationships  within  the  community.  Excessive  mobility  "with  its 
increase  in  the  number  and  intensity  of  stimulations,  tends  inevitably  to  confuse 
and  to  demoralize  the  person."  It  is  conducive,  in  its  extreme  forms,  to  patho- 
logical behaviour  and  social  disorganization;  it  hinders  the  functioning  of  the 
traditional  forms  of  social  control;  it  is  disastrous  to  the  development  of  com- 
munity consciousness ;  it  frequently  means  the  pulverization  of  social  relationship 
with  the  concomitant  individualizations  of  behaviour  patterns.  In  a  word,  it  is 
inextricably  linked  with  the  social  problems  of  the  city,  and  the  urban  area  that 
present  these  problems  in  an  aggravated  form  are  invariably  areas  of  excessive 
mobility.  But  in  its  modified  forms  mobility  means  growth,  integration,  intellec- 
tual development.  It  is  for  this  reason  that  mobility  in  the  city  may  be  either 
normal  or  pathological ;  may  mean  either  integration  or  disintegration,  depending 
on  the  number  and  kind  of  psychic  stimulations  and  the  state  of  mutability  of 
the  person  who  responds  to  these  stimulations.24 

The  entire  social  basis  of  urban  life  is,  of  necessity,  based  primarily  on 
a  money  economy.  Life  must  be  based  on  superficial  social  relationships, 
for  there  is  neither  time  nor  opportunity  for  intimate  personal  acquaint- 
ance. The  city  stereotype  has  been  formed  around  the  idea  of  not  what 
the  individual  is,  but  what  he  can  show.  Accordingly,  persons  are  placed 
in  definite  categories  according  to  the  role  they  play  in  the  city — as 
intellectual,  agitator,  banker,  society  woman,  man  about  town,  and  so 
on.25 

But  it  is  an  impulse  of  human  nature  to  wish  to  associate  and,  although 
primary  groups  have  been  broken  down,  especially  in  cities,  many  func- 
tional groups,  service  clubs,  and  fraternal  organizations  have  arisen  to 
satisfy,  so  far  as  possible,  the  desire  for  intimate  social  contact.  The 
altruistic  impulses  and  social  consciousness  which  formerly  functioned 
within  the  neighborhood  structure  of  agrarian  society  now  find  their 
outlet  in  various  urban  organizations  designed  to  promote  some  form  of 
social  uplift.  In  New  York  City  alone  there  are  over  twelve  hundred  of 
these  organizations  which  aim  to  serve  others  without  remuneration.  As 
the  home  has  become  less  important  in  city  civilization,  these  functional 
groups  and  civil  centers  have  gained  in  relative  influence.  We  have  such 
functional  organizations  as  chambers  of  commerce,  labor  union  centrals, 
and  the  like.  Service  clubs  of  numerous  types  abound,  and  fraternal 


.,  op.  cit.,p.  269. 

25  See    Nels   Anderson   and    E.    C.    Lindeman,    Urban   Sociology,    Knopf,    1928, 
Chap.  XII,  for  further  characterization  of  these  types. 


660         DISINTEGRATION  OF  PRIMARY  CROUPS 

organizations  tend  to  thrive  as  a  mode  of  providing  social  contacts  for 
urban  dwellers.26 

Occupations  in  the  city  are  many  and  varied,  and  the  activities  in- 
volved in  earning  a  living  are  sufficient  to  condition  individuals  to  the 
point  where  habits  are  formed  that  color  their  thoughts,  their  reactions, 
and  their  leisure  time: 

It  is  more  than  a  myth  that  the  preacher,  the  teacher,  the  salesman,  the  poli- 
tician, the  farmer,  and  the  entrepreneur  conform  to  a  type.  Each  reveals  a 
mental  slant  having  its  genesis  in  the  task  of  earning  a  livelihood.  Since  the 
prevailing  occupation  in  the  rural  community  is  agriculture,  it  is  not  difficult  to 
sec  where  the  diverse  interests  of  the  city  dweller  have  led  to  a  diversity  of  ideas 
which  make  community  spirit  difficult  to  form.27 

Gist  and  Halbert  properly  emphasize  the  fact  that  it  is  difficult  to 
develop  a  vigorous  and  unified  community  sentiment  under  such  cir- 
cumstances: 

It  is  obvious  that  with  such  diversity  of  social  status,  economic  interest  and 
cultural  background,  it  is  extremely  difficult  to  bring  about  any  community 
of  interest  or  unity  of  attitude  in  urban  public  affairs.  In  rural  communities, 
those  who  associated  in  schools,  business,  and  the  like,  were  drawn  from  a  common 
cultural  heritage,  which  their  association  perpetuated.  In  our  cities,  the  popu- 
lation is  either  drawn  from  different  parts  of  the  same  countries  or  from  many 
different  countries,  or  drawn  from  both.  All  have  different  types  of  mores, 
traditions  and  social  habits.  There  is  no  continuity  of  tradition  to  perpetuate, 
or  any  common  community  standards  to  conform  and  apply.28 

The  competitive  basis  on  which  a  money  economy  is  planned  is  inimical 
to  the  spirit  of  neighborliness.  The  struggle  in  the  city  is  one  to  reach 
a  goal.  With  some,  it  is  to  pay  the  rent,  light  bills,  and  grocery  bills; 
with  others,  it  is  to  scale  the  social  ladder  of  success.  The  average  city 
person  develops  an  attitude  of  aggressiveness  and  self-assertion  as  a  pro- 
tective device  to  keep  him  from  being  imposed  on  by  others  and  to -main- 
tain his  "rights."  The  result  of  this  aggressiveness  and  forced  impersonal 
attitude  is  to  widen  further  the  gulf  or  social  distance  between  city 
dwellers.  This  makes  the  organization  of  a  benevolent  or  community 
spirit  difficult. 

•  When  we  speak  of  "the  family,"  we  usually  mean  the  traditional  rural 
family,  composed  of  parents,  a  large  number  of  children,  and  a  fixed  abode. 
These  units  rested  on  a  definite  social  and  economic  foundation.  A  father 
and  husband  were  necessary  to  furnish  a  living  and  to  be  the  head  of  the 
family.  Women  accepted  their  role  as  mothers  and  their  dependence  on 
their  husbands.  Children  were  an  asset  economically  and  were,  there- 
fore, welcome.  These  fundamental  bases  of  the  family  have  been  de- 
stroyed by  the  city. 

No  longer  is  the  family  the  economic,  educational,  protective,  recrea- 
tional, and  affectional  unit.  Recreation  and  education,  in  large  part, 
have  gone  from  the  home.  The  city  family  has  become  a  consuming,  not 

26  Cf.,  Anderson  and  Lindeman,  op.  cit.,  Part  III. 

27  Gist  and  Halbert,  op.  cit.,  p.  314. 
**Ibid.,p.  315. 


DISINTEGRATION   OF  PRIMARY  CROUPS         661 

a  producing  agency.  The  shifting  of  productive  and  recreational 
interest  outside  the  home  has  reduced  the  dependence  of  the  members  on 
each  other  and  has  weakened  the  bond  which  held  the  family  together  in 
a  cohesive  social  unit.  The  father  is  becoming  less  important  as  a  neces- 
sary wage  earner.  The  emancipation  of  women  and  their  entrance  into 
industry  has  made  urban  women  unwilling  to  assume  the  responsibilities 
that  the  rural  mother  did  in  raising  a  large  family.  The  day  nursery, 
maintained  by  relief  agencies,  churches,  and  benevolent  societies  as  a 
place  for  working  women  to  leave  their  children,  has  become  a  part  of  the 
city  pattern.  It  represents  an  attempt  to  substitute  for  a  mother's  care. 
In  short,  children  in  the  city  have  become  a  definite  economic  liability. 
Since  few  city  dwellers  can  afford  a  home  of  even  moderate  size,  they 
must  be  content  with  apartments  or  flats.  Those  of  the  poorer  classes 
who  have  children  urge  them  to  find  employment  as  soon  as  they  are  old 
enough,  while  the  children  of  the  well-to-do  are  turned  over  to  maids  or 
nurses  or  sent  away  to  boarding-schools.  There  are  too  many  distrac- 
tions in  the  city  and  people  are  too  busy  to  permit,  even  when  apartments 
are  large  enough,  the  impromptu  gatherings  of  the  family  and  friends 
which  provide  the  chief  recreation  of  the  rural  family.  To  visit  a  friend 
in  the  city  without  first  telephoning  is  considered  a  breach  of  good  man- 
ners. 

Individualism  in  the  family  is  thus  intensified  by  both  the  economic 
and  the  social  pattern  set  by  the  city.  This  individualism  is,  in  part, 
responsible  for  the  changing  attitude  toward  marriage.  With  woman's 
entrance  into  industry  and  her  new  legal  freedom,  plus  the  loss  of  the 
economic  and  social  necessity  of  the  home  as  a  production  unit,  the  atti- 
tude toward  divorce  has  undergone  a  change.  As  we  have  seen,  in  the 
old  rural  community  the  attitude  of  the  neighborhood  was  all  important. 
To  the  neighborhood,  a  stable  and  well-integrated  family  was  of  vital 
importance.  The  wife  who  attempted  or  even  desired  to  break  her  mar- 
riage ties  or  failed  in  her  duty  to  her  husband  or  her  children  was  an 
object  of  public  scorn.  So  powerful  was  the  conventional  code  of  the 
neighborhood  that  few  women  dared  to  brave  its  thundering  disapproval. 

In  the  modern  city,  however,  the  neighborhood  spirit  and  censorship 
has  all  but  disappeared.  No  longer  is  the  neighborhood  concerned  with 
the  individual  families.  Life  is  so  intense,  so  hurried,  the  pull  up  the 
social  and  economic  ladder  is  so  urgent  and  time  so  short  that  there  is 
little  energy  left  to  concern  oneself  with  the  affairs  of  the  neighbors.  The 
rate  of  mobility  is  such  that  scenes  and  social  settings  are  constantly  shift- 
ing. The  neighborhood  consciousness  of  its  duty  as  the  social  mentor  is 
naturally  weakened.  Only  when  the  neighborhood  remains  a  stable,  un- 
changing unit  is  it  a  power  in  the  shaping  and  molding  of  tradition. 

The  breakdown  of  the  family,  as  a  result  of  the  urban  impact,  and  the 
disappearance  of  the  neighborhood  have  produced  community  disorgani- 
zation and  demoralization.  The  high  rate  of  divorce  and  the  large  num- 
ber of  desertions  are  direct  results  of  this  breakdown.  Juvenile  court 
judges  in  our  cities  and  investigators  of  crime  assign  a  large  proportion  of 


662         DISINTEGRATION  OF  PRIMARY  CROUPS 

the  blame  for  increased  juvenile  delinquency  to  the  defective  training  of 
the  young  by  parents.  With  the  increase  in  individualization  and  of 
working  parents,  the  children  receive  little  of  the  disciplinary  training  of 
former  days.  This  lack  of  training,  accompanied  by  a  lack  of  respect  for 
parents  and  social  obligations,  makes  them  easy  converts  to  anti-social 
practices.  Unless  they  have  a  congenial  home  to  play  in,  to  live  in,  and 
something  with  which  to  occupy  their  leisure  time,  they  are  likely  to  drift 
into  anti-social  behavior  from  association  with  the  gang  on  the  street 
corners.  Our  reformatories  and  our  penitentiaries  arc  evidences  of  the 
lack  of  provision  for  the  youth  of  our  cities. 

The  disintegration  of  the  urban  family  has  been  the  result  of  its  in- 
ability to  adjust  itself  to  the  rapidly  changing  material  world.  Where 
there  is  a  lag  between  an  institutional  pattern  and  social  reality,  disorgan- 
ization will  result.  The  family  is  in  a  period  of  transition  and,  while  still 
monogamic  in  form,  it  is  in  confusion  and  chaos,  as  a  result  of  the  break- 
down of  the  primary  contacts  so  necessary  to  its  cohesiveness. 

How  the  Impact  of  City  Life  on  the  Country  Has 
Affected  Rural   Life  Patterns 

We  mentioned  in  an  earlier  section  the  Agrarian  Revolution  and  its 
effect  on  the  growth  of  the  modern  city.  The  farm  and  rural  life  once 
occupied  a  dominant  place  in  society.  The  chief  social  institutions  of 
modern  times  have  been  deeply  influenced  by  rural  life.  When  we  talk 
of  the  family  in  a  sociological  sense  we  still  mean  essentially  the  rural 
family.  Contemporary  discussion  of  the  weakening  or  downfall  of  the 
family  refers,  in  reality,  to  changes  in  what  has  been  the  traditional  rural 
kinship  group.  The  rural  population  has  provided  the  major  support  of 
the  Christian  church,  especially  of  the  Protestant  church.  The  latter  was 
the  center  of  social  life  in  the  rural  community.  Country  dwellers  long 
remained  immune  to  the  discoveries  in  scholarship  which  undermined 
traditional  views  of  the  Bible  and  religion.  Hence  they  have  been  a 
bulwark  of  Christian  orthodoxy.29 

In  the  last  half-century,  more  and  more  of  the  rural  population  has 
been  drawn  to  our  urban  centers.  But  improvements  in  communication 
and  transportation  have  tended  to  urbanize  the  remaining  rural  elements. 
On  the  farm,  machinery  has  supplanted,  to  a  great  extent,  the  need  of 
hand  labor.  Therefore,  fewer  children  are  needed  and  the  farm  family  of 
today,  while  larger  than  the  urban  family,  has  also  felt  the  urban  influ- 
ence. Women  are  less  dependent  on  men  today.  They  can  leave  for  the 
city,  get  jobs,  and  support  themselves  better  than  most  farm  wives  and 
mothers.  Then,  too,  country  women  are  no  longer  needed  in  the  same  way 
as  they  were  in  the  old  rural  family,  where  most  of  the  production  was  in 
the  home  and  women's  labor  was  sorely  needed.  Divorce,  while  still  not 


2*  C/.,  H.  B.  Hawthorn,  The  Sociology  of  Rural  Life,  Century,  1926,  Chaps.  I-III, 


DISINTEGRATION   OF  PRIMARY  GROUPS         663 

so  common  in  rural  areas  as  in  cities,  is  beginning  to  be  accepted  to  the 
extent  that  a  divorcee  is  not  considered  a  pariah. 

The  automobile  has  brought  changes  in  life  that  have  taken  recreation 
from  the  rural  home  and  placed  it  on  an  urban  basis.  Young  folks  can 
now  drive  into  cities  or  small  towns  and  go  to  the  movies  or  a  dance,  and 
the  community  sing  or  husking-bee  has  lost  most  of  its  former  lure.  The 
radio  brings  the  latest  in  news,  music,  drama  and  programs  of  every 
variety  to  the  farm  living-room.  Up-to-date  farm  journals  and  metro- 
politan dailies  bring  the  farmer  in  close  contact  with  the  city.  The 
women  no  longer  have  to  depend  on  Sears-Roebuck  or  Montgomery  Ward 
catalogs  for  their  glimpse  into  city  fashions,  but  can  go  shopping  to 
near-by  cities  by  automobile,  listen  to  the  fashion  hints  over  the  radio, 
or  get  a  breathless  presentation  from  the  newest  moving  picture. 

The  rural  church,  once  a  center  of  social  life,  has  suffered  severely  from 
this  urbanization.  Revivals  and  Sunday  services  in  the  old  days  pro- 
vided a  meeting-place  for  the  exchange  of  bits  of  gossip,  and  the  swapping 
of  ideas  on  the  weather,  crops,  or  politics.  Many  a  romance  was  begun 
on  the  way  home  from  a  church  meeting.  Poor  young  preachers  advocat- 
ing cither  the  Fundamentalist  doctrine  of  fire  and  brimstone  or  Modernist 
social  ideals  are  hardly  able  to  distract  the  younger  generation  from  the 
secular  attractions  of  the  city. 

The  rural  neighborhood  is  disappearing  rapidly.  Mechanization  of 
labor  has  made  socialibility  and  mutual  aid  unnecessary.  There  is  less 
need  for  cooperative  help  when  the  days  of  the  tractor-combine  have 
come.  The  rural  community  attempts  to  form  clubs  and  cliques  in 
imitation  of  city  ways.  The  prevailing  rural  attitude  is  that  of  aping  the 
city,  and,  as  a  result,  the  community  has  lost  its  cohesiveness  and  social 
unity,  since  it  no  longer  lives  with  and  for  itself. 

Rural  education,  which  was  formerly  limited  to  what  the  district  school 
could  give,  has  been  transformed.  There  are  better  buildings  on  a  con- 
solidated school  plan,  better  trained  teachers,  who  draw  larger  salaries  and 
have  the  use  of  modern  equipment.  Buses  carry  the  children  to  and 
from  school ;  and  no  longer  do  farmers  feel  that  it  is  necessary  to  keep  their 
children  home  from  school  for  needed  labor  or  because  it  is  too  far  for 
them  to  walk  or  go  on  horseback.  The  practical  side  of  education  is 
beginning  to  be  stressed.  Manual  training  courses  in  farm-husbandry 
and  domestic  science  are  coming  to  be  a  part  of  the  rural  curriculum. 

The  rural  press  has  also  undergone  a  remarkable  transformation.  The 
old  country  newspaper  with  its  week-old  national  news  and  provincial 
outlook  has  been  replaced  by  the  up-to-date  metropolitan  daily.  Good 
roads  have  made  excellent  rural  news  coverage  possible.  Farm  journals 
are  now  of  superior  quality  carrying  the  latest  information  concerning 
crops,  livestock,  and  new  methods  of  agriculture. 

The  radio  is  everywhere  and,  more  than  any  one  other  single  item,  it 
has  been  responsible  for  the  "urbanization"  of  country  life.  Amos  and 
Andy,  Rudy  Vallee,  Easy  Aces,  and  the  like,  are  as  well  known  to  the 
rural  dweller  as  to  his  city  neighbor.  The  cultural  side  of  the  radio  has 


664          DISINTEGRATION   OF  PRIMARY  CROUPS 

made  possible  the  familiarization  of  the  farm  family  with  the  best — as 
well  as  the  worst — in  music. 

The  provincial  attitude  of  the  typical  rural  family,  then,  is  being  broken 
down  by  the  same  agencies  that  have  made  for  the  shallow  superficiality 
of  the  city.  The  new  rural  personality  stereotype  is  not  clearly  defined  as 
is  the  urban  personality  type,  because  the  urbanizing  influences  have  not 
been  operating  so  long  or  deeply  on  the  rural  life  pattern,  but  their  effects 
are  clearly  seen  already.  Some  of  the  best  of  our  rural  youth  have  mi- 
grated to  the  city.  Many  of  the  superior  men  and  women  in  American 
cities  have  had  rural  backgrounds.  This  means  that  the  rural  community 
now  finds  a  paucity  of  leaders.  The  mentality  of  the  average  young  man 
and  woman  in  the  rural  community  has  been  compared  to  that  of  a 
second-generation  immigrant.  They  are  in  a  disorganized  state,  pulled 
between  two  conflicting  cultures. 

We  see,  then,  that  the  old  rural  strongholds — the  home,  the  neighbor- 
hoods and  the  play  group — have  been  undermined  as  a  result  of 
mechanization  both  in  industry  and  agriculture.  The  farm  family  still 
exists  and  is  a  more  stable  unit  than  the  urban  family,  but  many  of  its 
former  functions  of  discipline,  domestic  economy,  recreation,  and  affec- 
tion have  been  weakened  and  it  has  lost  most  of  its  cohesiveness  as  a 
stabilizing  unit.  The  neighborhood,  as  a  socializing  agency,  has  been 
broken  down  by  the  automobile,  good  roads,  mechanization,  and  the 
radio.  These  same  forces  have  dissipated  the  play  groups  of  the  rural 
community,  since  there  is  less  desire  to  play  ball  on  the  corner  lot  if  a 
gangster  movie  is  showing  at  the  village  or  in  the  town  10  miles  down  the 
road.  Therefore,  the  impact  of  urbanism  has  been  sufficiently  strong  to 
undermine  the  primary  institutions  of  both  country  and  city. 

It  is  a  well-known  truism  that  when  one  thing  is  removed  and  a  gap 
left,  there  will  be  a  replacement  of  some  kind  to  fill  up  the  vacuum.  This 
is  true  in  natural  science.  The  principle  also  applies  in  the  social  sci- 
ences. Invasion  and  succession,  according  to  Gist  and  Halbert,  have 
their  counterparts  in  human  society: 

In  a  social  organization  where  there  is  a  relatively  high  rate  of  mobility  and 
where  competition  is  not  only  economic  but  cultural  as  well,  groups  of  varying 
economic  and  cultural  levels  tend  to  displace  each  other,  to  change  their 
ecological  position  as  a  result  of  the  competitive  process.80 

Community  Organization  Supplants  Primary  Groups 

Community  organization  has  moved  in  to  substitute  for  the  gap  left  in 
the  breakdown  of  the  primary  institutions.  C.  E.  Rainwater,  in  discuss- 
ing the  rise  of  the  play  movement  in  the  United  States,  says  that  the 
nineteenth  century  saw  the  complete  deterioration  of  the  neighborhood, 
but  the  twentieth  is  to  see  its  reconstruction.  It  is  through  the  medium 
of  the  organization  of  community  forces  in  all  phases  that  this  recon- 


80  Gist  and  Halbcrt,  op.  cit.,  p.  167. 


DISINTEGRATION   OF  PRIMARY  CROUPS         665 

struction  is  to  be  accomplished.81  Most  of  the  processes  of  urbanization 
have  been  hostile  to  such  a  reconstruction  of  community  life.  High 
population  density,  low  rate  of  permanent  residence,  and  the  mixed  na- 
tional and  cultural  groups  have  all  made  for  secondary  groups  and 
relationships  which  break  down  the  primary  units  and  are  inimical  to 
their  rebuilding. 

The  extension  of  community  organization  into  the  field  of  the  primary 
relationships  has  come  about  as  a  result  of  the  gradual  growth  of  group 
consciousness.  As  soon  as  the  Industrial  Revolution  made  changes  in 
industry  that  concentrated  a  large  number  of  workers  in  one  place  and 
produced  division  of  labor  and  mass  production,  the  role  of  the  individual 
was  minimized,  because,  in  the  world  of  machinery,  no  isolated  individual 
could  maintain  himself  successfully.  This  is  the  reason  for  the  rise  of 
corporations,  syndicates,  and  mergers  in  the  business  world.  In  other 
words,  the  Industrial  Revolution  drove  the  first  wedge  into  the  fortress 
of  the  primary  institutions  but  at  the  same  time  furnished  a  new  tech- 
nique to  provide  a  substitute  process. 

The  growing  trend  toward  group  solidarity  is  to  be  seen  in  the  entrance 
of  the  government  into  what  have  hitherto  been  private  affairs.  Social 
legislation  has  advanced  in  a  remarkable  fashion  to  cover  fields  of  ac- 
tivity that  heretofore  would  have  been  considered  a  violation  by  govern- 
ment of  the  inalienable  rights  of  an  individual.  Laws  relating  to 
housing,  tenant  regulation  and  supervision,  child  labor,  child  welfare, 
municipal  parks,  playgrounds  and  other  public  welfare  measures  are 
examples  of  the  recognition  of  the  new  approach  to  the  field  of  group 
responsibility. 

The  significance  of  the  group  approach  in  community  life  may  be  seen 
from  the  attitude  assumed  by  education.  Education  is  no  longer  a  purely 
individual  matter.  It  is  now  conceived  to  be  a  community  responsibility 
for  definite  standards  to  be  upheld  so  that  education  for  the  masses  can 
be  made  effective.  The  modern  emphasis  is  on  fitting  the  child  into  the 
community  rather  than  mere  training  of  the  individual.  Vocational 
guidance,  manual  training,  domestic  science,  and  the  social  studies  are 
examples  of  this  group  approach.  The  force  of  the  group  in  the  commu- 
nity is  nowhere  better  demonstrated  than  in  the  field  of  public  welfare. 
Unless  the  entire  community  functions  fairly  well  as  a  group  in  the 
matter  of  alleviating  poverty  or  righting  maladjustments,  the  entire  pro- 
gram is  doomed  and  the  community  as  a  whole  suffers. 

The  group  approach  to  the  whole  field  of  social  work  is  a  new  em- 
phasis. Gone  is  the  old  idea  that  the  individual  is  wholly  responsible 
if  he  fails  to  make  a  living  or  if  he  drifts  into  anti-social  conduct.  The 
new  theory  is  that  society,  in  its  malfunctioning,  is  partly  responsible. 
Social  agencies  have  employed  this  philosophy  in  their  approach  to  the 
giving  of  aid.  A  complete  picture  of  the  personal  background,  environ- 


81  The  Play  Movement  in  the  United  States,  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1922, 
p.  522. 


666          DISINTEGRATION   OF  PRIMARY  CROUPS 

ment,  employment,  friends,  clubs,  lodges,  and  use  of  leisure  time  is  ob- 
tained before  any  help  is  given.  In  other  words,  the  individual  is  placed 
against  his  group  or  community  picture  rather  than  viewed  as  an 
entity.  The  application  of  group  responsibility  may  be  seen  in  the  field 
of  crime  and  juvenile  delinquency.  The  entire  procedure  of  the  juvenile 
court  revolves  around  placing  the  child  in  the  right  sort  of  group  relation- 
ships,32 

All  these  community  activities  need  not  imply  that  the  idea  is  now 
prevalent  that  the  individual  has  no  responsibility  for  his  actions.  They 
simply  mean  that  there  is  a  growing  realization  that  the  environment 
exercises  a  definite  effect  on  the  individual.  Illness,  unemployment,  and 
delinquent  conduct  are  no  longer  considered  as  unrelated  factors  in  the 
individual's  life,  but  are  to  be  regarded  as  group  or  community  problems, 
as  well.  So  long  as  men  lived  under  a  system  of  domestic  economy  where 
each  family  or  gild  was  a  separate  unity  and  not  dependent  on  other 
units,  or  so  long  as  the  welfare  of  the  whole  was  not  at  stake,  group  ac- 
tions on  social  matters  were  all  but  unheard  of.  But  as  soon  as  modern 
industry  produced  a  situation  of  fine  balance  between  all  social  units, 
it  was  to  the  interest  of  the  whole  that  the  welfare  of  individuals  be  made 
a  concern  of  the  group.  People  living  in  cities  have  found  it  to  their 
advantage  to  combine  their  mutual  strength  and  assets  and  work  to- 
gether on  some  common  needs.  Community  of  interest  is  found  in  the 
provisions  made  to  protect  the  group  from  fire  and  theft  through  the  fire 
and  police  departments.  Municipally  owned  public  utilities  are  a  rec- 
ognition of  this  group  approach.  In  other  words,  concentration  of 
population,  changes  of  economy,  and  the  rise  of  cities  made  the  group 
approach  to  social  problems  necessary. 

The  existence  of  the  social  worker  offers  the  best  evidence  of  the 
substitution  of  community  emphasis  for  primary  relationships.  So  long 
as  men  lived  in  small  groups  and  moved  in  more  or  less  isolated  units, 
the  spirit  of  mutual  aid  and  neighborliness  operated.  There  was  less  need 
for  formal  organization  to  aid  distress.  But  with  the  growing  detach- 
ment of  individuals  from  their  primary  groups,  the  neighborhoods  and 
the  family,  came  the  need  for  group  social  work. 

'  The  creed  of  the  social  worker,  working  in  the  new  community  perspec- 
tive, is  to  be  found  in  the  philosophy  of  Karl  de  Schweinitz,  in  his  Art 
of  Helping  People  Out  of  Trouble: 88  that  all  persons  have  one  problem 
in  life — adjustment  to  environment.  This  problem  is  solved  only  if  a 
working  relationship  and  correlation  are  achieved  between  the  things  that 
are  the  self  of  the  individual,  and  the  experiences,  opportunities,  and 
material  elements,  which  are  the  environment.  It  is  then  the  job  of  the 
social  worker  to  make  it  possible  for  the  individual  to  integrate  his  per- 
sonality, so  that  he  will  be  able  to  fit  naturally  into  his  social  environ- 
ment. This  also  means  that  the  social  workers  must  understand  the  com- 
munity and  its  possibilities,  in  order  to  be  of  service  to  those  who  are 
dependent  upon  them  for  adjustment  to  the  new  life-patterns. 

32  Steiner,  Community  Organization,  p.  8. 
33Houghton  Miffllin,  1924. 


PART  VI 
Institutions  Promoting  Richer  Living 


CHAPTER  XVII 
The  Contemporary  Crisis  in  Religion  and  Morals 

Some  Phases  of  the  Development  of  Religion 

The  Nature  and  Social  Importance  of  Religion.  Before  proceeding  to 
discuss  the  origins  of  religion,  we  should  submit  at  least  a  few  preliminary 
definitions.  We  must  not  accept  the  various  modern  sophisticated  atti- 
tudes toward  religion  as  an  interpretation  of  what  religion  has  meant 
down  the  ages.  Who,  for  example,  could  have  any  quarrel  with  religion, 
when  viewed  as  Edward  Scribner  Ames  defines  it  in  his  Religion  (1929), 
namely,  as  th&  search  for,  and  realization  of,  the  highest  conceivable 
social  values?  If  one  identifies  religion  with  all  social  decency  and 
justice,  one  creates  a  conception  of  religion  that  is  necessarily  highly 
attractive.  But  such  a  definition  is  not  accurate  as  a  historical  picture 
of  the  nature  and  practices  of  religion,  nor  is  it  a  reliable  description  of 
organized  religion,  even  today. 

Whatever  religion  may  become  in  the  future,  it  has  always  embraced, 
in  the  past,  man's  interpretation  of  the  nature  of  the  hypothetical  super- 
natural world.  It  includes  the  resulting  efforts  man  has  made  to  avail 
himself  of  the  supposedly  beneficent  intervention  of  the  friendly  super- 
natural powers  and  to  ward  off  the  assumed  malevolent  influences  of  evil 
supernatural  beings.  In  other  words,  religion  has,  thus  far,  been  man's 
effort  to  adjust  himself  to  the  supernatural  world  in  such  a  manner  as  to 
secure  the  maximum  benefits  and  the  minimum  disasters  therefrom. 

Religion  has  also  exerted  a  tremendous  influence  upon  other  institu- 
tions. Religion  and  morals  have  always  been  closely  intertwined.  In- 
deed, morals  have,  so  far,  literally  been  applied  religion.  Moral  conduct 
has  been  designed  to  please  the  gods  rather  than  to  serve  man  directly 
and  efficiently.  For  many  thousands  of  years  religion  exerted  a  large 
influence  over  economic  life.  Man  believed  that  he  had  to  placate  the 
gods  to  be  successful  in  his  economic  efforts.  The  gods  were  supposed 
to  provide  good  hunting  and  fishing  grounds,  to  increase  the  supply  of 
fish  and  game,  to  insure  fertility  for  vegetation  and  animals,  and  to  ward 
off  evil  spirits  which  might  do  harm  to  flocks  and  crops.  Economic 
institutions  and  practices  were  believed  to  be  revealed  and  favored  by 
the  gods.  Religious  dogmas  have  stimulated  and  controlled  economic 
activities  and  systems  from  primitive  times  to  our  own.  Property  has 
often  been  believed  to  have  divine  sanction,  and  attempts  to  control  it  in 
the  interest  of  society  have  been  branded  as  wijpked  and  sinful. 

Politics  and  government  were  long  based  upon  religion.  The  priest- 

669 


670         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

hood  blessed  and  approved  existing  forms  of  government.  Early  kings 
were  regarded  as  ruling  through  the  will  of  gods.  They  were  themselves 
regarded  as  semi-divine.  In  the  Middle  Ages,  the  Church  sought  to 
control  government  in  matters  relating  to  religion  and  morals.  Even  in 
early  modern  times,  absolute  monarchs  asserted  that  they  ruled  by 
divine  right.  In  our  own  day,  we  confer  a  sort  of  divine  sanction  upon 
our  constitutions.  Divine  blessing  is  still  invoked  in  behalf  of  our  gov- 
ernmental agents.  Revolution,  political  radicalism,  and  social  change 
have  usually  been  cursed  by  the  custodians  of  religion. 

For  many  thousands  of  years,  education  was  little  more  than  the 
transmission  of  religious  beliefs  and  sacred  usages  under  priestly  auspices. 
In  pagan  times,  the  priesthood  exerted  a  considerable  influence  over  many 
phases  of  education.  During  the  Middle  Ages  education  was  primarily 
in  the  hands  of  the  Church.  Even  in  our  day,  there  are  a  great  many 
church  schools,  and  religious  education  is  still  a  prominent  item  in 
modern  instruction.  Art  originated  as  a  phase  of  religious  mythology, 
and  until  recent  times  art  was  used  primarily  to  glorify  the  gods,  to 
teach  religious  lessons,  and  to  portray  religious  figures  and  scenes. 
Ecclesiastical  structures  have  always  constituted  an  important  element 
in  architecture.  Our  conception  of  the  gods  and  important  religious 
personages  have  grown  primarily  out  of  their  portrayal  in  art.  Early 
literature  was  chiefly  religious.  The  most  widely-read  books  of  all 
history  have  been  the  sacred  literature  of  the  great  religious  systems. 
Even  much  of  secular  literature  has  revolved  around  religious  themes. 
Religion  has  given  color  to  all  of  the  great  stages  of  cultural  evolution. 

The  Potency  of  Religion.  It  is  almost  impossible  to  exaggerate  the 
extensive  role  that  religion  played  in  the  life  of  primitive  man.  His 
conception  of  the  universe  rested  almost  entirely  upon  the  assumption 
of  supernatural  forces  and  powers.  To  him,  knowledge  and  religion 
were  almost  identical.  Few  of  the  important  daily  activities,  whether 
economic  or  recreational,  were  carried  on  except  under  proper  religious 
auspices.  Primitive  industry  was  almost  literally  applied  religion.  For 
instance,  among  the  primitive  Todas  in  India  today,  religion  centers 
Ground  their  herds  of  buffalo  and  dairy  activities.  Their  whole  dairy 
industry  is  controlled  by  religion  and  magical  rites. 

Much  time  and  effort  were  devoted  by  primitive  men  and  early  historic 
peoples  to  propitiating  the  gods  associated  with  agriculture  and  industry. 
For  example,  early  Roman  agriculture  became  a  round  of  religious  rituals; 
there  were  forty-five  holy  days  each  year  devoted  to  placating  or  venerat- 
ing agrarian  deities.  Among  the  Jews,  Yahweh  was  originally  a  pastoral 
god  who  protected  their  flocks.  The  most  important  gods  of  early  peoples 
were  those  who  were  believed  to  preside  over  the  fertility  of  flocks,  and 
to  provide  good  crops.  Religion  and  industry  went  hand  in  hand  among 
both  the  aborigines  and  ancient  peoples.  So  did  politics,  warfare,  and 
most  social  activities.  Social  customs  were  supposed  to  have  been  re- 
vealed by  the  gods.  Primitive  education  was  scarcely  more  than  initia- 
tion into  supernatural  mysteries. 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         671 

In  brief,  the  life  of  a  savage  is  cradled  in  mystery,  and  matured  in  the 
supernatural.  The  gods  attend  his  birth,  safeguard  his  youth,  preside 
at  every  milestone  of  his  existence — adolescence,  initiation  into  man- 
hood, marriage,  sickness,  and  death.  They  shower  him  with  their  favors 
or  crush  him  with  their  malice.  Everything  in  primitive  life  is  wrapped 
in  supernaturalism.  The  sun  Is  a  god — later,  the  Greeks  called  him 
Phoebus  Apollo,  and  he  was  drawn  around  the  heavens  in  a  magnificent 
chariot.  The  moon  is  a  goddess — the  Greeks,  in  their  time,  called  her 
Artemis  (Roman,  Diana) .  The  rivers,  forests,  winds,  waves,  flowers  are 
invested  with  human  attributes.  The  earth  and  all  its  phenomena  have 
indwelling  secret  spirits,  invisible,  palpable,  kind,  ferocious,  beneficent, 
malignant.  The  primitive  mind  invests  these  spirits  with  romance  and 
drama,  with  comedy  and  tragedy.  A  mythology  accumulates.  The 
popular  mythology  of  Greece — perhaps  one  of  the  most  beautiful  and 
attractive — is  paralleled  in  part  among  even  primitive  tribes. 

So  powerful  is  the  mystical  or  religious  aspect  of  the  uneducated  mind 
that,  in  many  respects,  civilization  advances  only  in  the  degree  to  which 
man  frees  himself  from  the  spell  of  the  supernatural,  puts  away  his 
animism,  taboos,  fetishes,  totems — as  a  growing  child  puts  away  its 
toys — and  relies  upon  his  intellect  and  observations  to  interpret  the 
varying  manifestations  of  nature  and  the  activities  of  his  own  psyche. 

Development  of  Religion  in  Primitive  Society.  How  did  the  super- 
natural first  enter  man's  mental  world?  The  daily  routine  of  primitive 
existence  left  many  desires  unfulfilled,  many  questions  unanswered  about 
nature  and  the  human  psyche.  The  supernatural  hypothesis  stepped  in, 
made  man  feel  more  at  home  with  nature,  provided  him  with  an  answer 
to  such  simple  and  yet  such  difficult  questions  as:  Why  does  the  wind 
blow?  Why  does  the  sun  race  around  the  heavens?  What  makes  light- 
ning strike?  What  causes  shadows,  images,  dreams?  What  brings  on 
strong  bodily  sensations,  particularly  those  associated  with  hunger  and 
sex? 

Modern  man,  equipped  with  some  knowledge  of  the  sciences,  is  able  to 
give  a  convincing  naturalistic  explanation  of  almost  everything  which 
puzzled  primitive  man.  We  know  why  water  flows,  why  rocks  are  dis- 
lodged from  their  natural  foundations  and  crash  down  hillsides,  why  the 
wind  blows,  what  sends  the  rain  down  into  the  ground  and  stimulates  the 
growth  of  foliage,  why  the  rivers  become  rag-ing  torrents,  what  causes 
bodily  changes,  and  what  produces  stirring  and  pleasant  sensations  when 
one  comes  in  contact  with  an  attractive  person  of  the  opposite  sex. 
Primitive  man  had  to  have  recourse  to  the  supernatural  hypothesis  to 
find  plausible  explanations  of  these,  and  many  other  questions. 

Alexander  Goldenweiser  divides  religious  experience  into  three  major 
phases:  (1)  the  emotional  thrill  which  comes  from  communion  with  the 
supernatural  world  and  from  contact  with  its  occult  powers;  (2)  the 
emotional  satisfactions  which  come  from  participation  in  religious  ritual, 
chiefly  through  worship  and  the  invocation  of  magic;  and  (3)  the  in- 
tellectual convictions  derived  from  theology,  viewed  as  the  conceptional 


672         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

side  of  religion — the  "reasoning  out"  of  the  mysteries  of  supernaturalism. 
There  are,  then,  three  main  aspects  of  religion :  the  emotional,  which  gives 
driving  force  to  religion;  the  activational,  which  expresses  itself  in  re- 
ligious rites  and  worship;  and  the  conceptual,  which  rationalizes  the 
preceding  and  ultimately  develops  into  theology. 

Primitive  man,  thus  being  unable  to  defect,  as  we  can,  the  secret  work- 
ings of  nature,  and  also  unable  to  unravel  nature's  laws,  faced  nature 
with  a  question  mark.  This  question  mark  was  an  endless  source  of 
thrill-producing  mysteries  in  the  form  of  supernatural  fictions. 

Out  of  the  basic  hypothesis  of  a  potent  mysterious  force  which  creates, 
controls,  and  replenishes  the  world  arose  ghost  worship,  animal  worship, 
phallic  worship,  and  the  worship  of  nearly  all  the  commonplace  phe- 
nomena of  nature.  At  the  outset,  the  mysterious  force,  which  was  be- 
lieved to  .guide  the  world,  was  not  personified.  It  was  looked  upon  as  an 
impersonal  supernatural  power  which  accounted  for  the  activities  of  the 
sun,  moon,  stars,  waters,  winds,  men,  plants,  and  animals.  It  was  be- 
lieved responsible  for  a  wide  range  of  experiences  in  savage  life.  The 
name  now  given  to  this  impersonal  supernatural  power  is  mana — the 
term  applied  to  it  by  the  natives  of  Melanesia.  Other  primitive  tribes 
recognize  this  vague  but  awesome  power  under  the  name  of  manitou 
(Algonquin  Indians),  orenda  (Iroquois  Indians),  wakan  (Sioux  Indians), 
and  so  on.  The  gradual  emergence  of  a  belief  in  spirits  from  the  concept 
of  mana  is  exemplified  by  the  theory  of  the  Algonquins.  Their  manitou  is 
capable  of  either  a  personal  or  an  impersonal  interpretation.  Religion 
in  this  first  period  of  impersonal  supernaturalism  has  been  called 
animatism  by  R.  R,  Marett. 

Primitive  man  in  due  time  visualized  this  supernatural  power  in  terms 
of  his  own  daily  life  and  human  relationships — where  personalities  pre- 
vail. Once  man  took  this  step,  he  was  well  on  his  way  to  the  creation  of 
the  personnel  and  machinery  of  religion — spirits,  gods,  devils,  and  or- 
ganized cults.  This  second  stage  of  religious  development,  that  in  which 
people  came  to  believe  in  individualized  or  personified  spirits,  was  called 
animism  by  the  famous  English  anthropologist  Sir  E.  B.  Tylor.  Once 
man  had  invented  the  world  of  personified  spirits,  the  basic  framework 
of  religion  was  well  laid  down.  It  was  a  logical  step  to  assume  that  most 
pleasant  and  beneficial  things  come  through  the  aid  of  good  spirits,  and 
disasters  from  evil  spirits.  In  this  way,  the  supernatural  world  was 
divided  into  the  two  contending  camps  of  benevolent  and  wicked  spirits. 

Early  historic  man  was  familiar  with  established  social  ranks.  Certain 
classes  were  servile,  others  aristocratic.  Some  were  generous  and  noble, 
others  mean  and  wicked.  These  categories  were  projected  into  the  in- 
terpretation of  the  gods.  Hence  there  arose  a  hierarchy  of  spirits.  Some 
of  the  early  historic  races  imagined  that  the  supernatural  world  is  con- 
trolled by  a  supreme  benevolent  spirit — God.  He  is  continually  assailed 
by  a  supreme  evil  spirit — Satan.  Each  has  a  host  of  underlings  (angels 
or  devils)  fighting  for  his  cause  and  obeying  him  as  servants  obey  their 
master. 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         673 

Religious  thought  has  rarely,  if  ever,  gone  beyond  this  conception  of  a 
hierarchy  of  good  and^vil  spirits.  No  great  religious  system  ever  de- 
veloped into  a  literally  pure  monotheism.  None  has  ever  gone  so  far  as 
to  imagine  a  supreme  God,  absolutely  isolated,  without  angels  and  under- 
lings, alone  controlling  this  vast  universe. 

Out  of  polytheism  there  came  an  elaborate  primitive  mythology.  Since 
he  was  not  hampered  by  considerations  of  exact  scientific  knowledge  or 
formal  logic,  primitive  man  could  ramble  on  from  one  absurd  fancy  to 
another. 

The  elevation  of  the  notion  of  a  hierarchy  of  good  and  evil  spirits  into 
a  grand  cosmological  philosophy,  representing  the  universe  as  an  arena 
in  which  the  principles  of  good  and  evil  fight  it  out  until  good  finally 
prevails,  was  the  product  of  Persian  theology,  a  matter  which  we  shall 
deal  with  later. 

Along  with  the  hypothesis  of  a  dynamic,  creative,  and  all-pervading 
supernaturalism,  primitive  man  brought  into  being  our  ideas  of  a  human 
soul  and  human  immortality.  The  primitive  belief  in  animism  implied 
that  all  nature,  including  man,  is  animate,  that  is,  possesses  a  spirit  or 
soul.  There  seemed  to  be  special  evidence  to  support  the  idea  of  a 
second  self  or  human  soul.  Man  could  see  his  image  in  a  pool  of  water. 
He  might  hear  the  echo  of  his  voice.  He  had  dreams  in  which  his  body 
seemed  to  undergo  definite  experiences  and  to  move  from  the  spot.  Yet, 
on  awakening,  the  body  appeared  not  to  have  moved.  Indeed,  some 
primitive  peoples  have  exceeded  the  Christians  in  the  matter  of  postulat- 
ing a  human  soul,  for  they  have  believed  in  a  plurality  of  souls. 

Closely  related  to  this  notion  of  a  soul  or  spiritual  self  has  been  the 
belief  in  immortality,  of  which  we  have  plenty  of  evidence  among  primi- 
tive peoples — not  only  among  existing  primitives  but  in  the  burial  prac- 
tices of  extinct  preliterate  peoples.  But  they  rarely  believed  in  a  purely 
spiritual  immortality.  They  shared  the  orthodox  Christian  notion  of  a 
bodily  resurrection.  The  grounds  for  the  primitive  belief  in  immortality 
were  such  things  as  the  notion  of  a  spiritual  self  which  might  survive 
death,  the  imagery  and  philosophy  growing  out  of  dream  experiences, 
and  the  rationalized  will  to  eternal  existence,  whether  of  the  individual 
or  of  his  relatives  and  friends. 

The  notion  of  rewards  and  punishments  after  death  was  a  natural  out- 
growth of  primitive  moral  codes,  with  their  ideas  of  compensation,  and 
of  the  hypothesis  of  good  and  evil  spirits  controlling  life  after  death,  a& 
well  as  life  on  this  earth.  This  idea  was  elaborated  gradually.  The 
historical  philosophies  associated  with  the  complex  conceptions  of  heaven 
and  hell  maintained  by  Christians  and  Muslims  were,  however,  mainly 
a  Persian  contribution. 

The  activational  side  of  primitive  religious  experience  falls  into  two 
categories,  namely,  magic  and  worship.  A  number  of  the  older  anthro- 
pologists, particularly  Sir  J.  G.  Frazer,  were  inclined  to  distinguish  magic 
from  religion  and  to  represent  magic  as  primitive  science.  No  reputable 
anthropologist  any  longer  entertains  this  view  of  the  matter. 


674         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

Magic  is  that  phase  of  primitive  religious  behavior  which  is  devoted 
chiefly  to  the  immediate  realization  of  certain  desired  ends  or  objects. 
Primitive  man  imagined  that  he  could  gain  his  ends  by  coercing  the  gods 
according  to  a  definite  ritualistic  contract  that  the  gods  had  supposedly 
revealed  arid  to  which  they  had  voluntarily  agreed.  If  these  occult 
formulas  were  accurately  complied  with,  then  the  gods,  according  to  the 
theory  of  magic,  would  hand  over  the  desired  results  to  the  group.  It 
was  even  believed  by  some  primitive  peoples  that  these  wished-for 
results  might  be  obtained,  even  without  the  participation  of  the  gods, 
by  virtue  of  the  very  potency  of  the  magic  rites  themselves. 

Worship,  as  distinguished  from  magic,  is  the  ritualistic  and  ceremonial 
expression  of  man's  attitude  of  awe,  reverence,  humility,  and  gratitude 
with  respect  to  the  supernatural  world  and  its  dominating  powers.  In 
both  early  and  modern  religious  behavior,  magic  and  worship  have 
usually  been  extensively  intertwined,  rather  than  sharply  differentiated. 
However,  it  is  probably  going  too  far  to  describe  magic  as  the  technique 
of  primitive  religion,  as  certain  writers  have  done. 

Some  writers,  especially  the  eminent  French  anthropologists  Hubert 
and  MaiiRg,  have  insisted  that  the  chief  difference  between  magic  and 
worship  is  that  magic  is  regarded  as  the  bad,  or  socially  disapproved, 
aspect  of  religious  practices,  while  worship  includes  the  socially  proper 
manifestations. 

Such  a  distinction  can  scarcely  be  maintained.  Magic,  by  its  very 
nature,  had  to  be  more  occult,  private,  and  technical  than  worship;  but 
this  does  not  mean  that  it  was  always  socially  tabooed.  Certain  pagan 
magical  practices  brought  over  into  Christianity  frequently  had  to  be 
executed  under  cover,  but  these  were  very  special  cases.  The  notion, 
therefore,  that  magic  is  bad,  or  "black,"  is  a  late  historical  view,  deeply 
colored  by  Christian  prejudices  against  pagan  magic,  witchcraft,  sorcery, 
and  the  like.  This  conception  rarely  prevailed  in  primitive  society; 
there,  magic  was  distinguished  from  worship  primarily  by  its  more 
practical  and  coercive  character. 

The  Rise  of  Gods.  The  traditional  notion  represents  man  as  made  by 
God  in  His  image.  History,  however,  shows  man  making  gods  to  con- 
form to  his  own  physical  image,  as  well  as  to  his  mental  imagery.  As 
with  religion  in  general,  so  with  the  deities  in  particular,  early  man 
accounted  for  the  mysteries  of  earth  by  inventing  a  supernatural  realm 
and  its  spirits.  The  gods  were  no  more  than  glorified  spirits.  The  whole 
supernaturalistic  structure — the  gods,  their  life  and  their  doings — became 
simply  a  reflex  of  the  real  world — topographically,  occupationally,  tech- 
nologically, and  so  forth.  J.  H.  Dietrich  summarizes  the  evolution  of 
gods  out  of  earlier  animistic  beliefs  in  this  way: 

The  recognition  of  the  importance  of  some  spirits  over  others,  in  connection 
with  the  gradual  understanding  of  certain  natural  processes,  led  men  to  depart- 
mentalize and  organize  their  deities,  instead  of  ascribing  a  spirit  to  each  and 
every  object.  Things  are  grouped  together,  and  one  god  is  thought  to  preside 
over  a  whole  group.  For  example,  they  no  longer  think  of  a  spirit  in  each  tree, 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         675 

but  of  a  spirit  presiding  over  all  trees — the  god  of  the  forest;  there  is  no  longer 
a  spirit  in  each  stream  but  a  god  of  streams;  no  longer  a  god  of  each  sea,  but  a 
god  of  the  seas.  This  stage  of  thought  is  best  exemplified  in  the  religion  of  the 
Greeks  and  the  Romans. 

By  this  time,  man  had  developed  a  highly  organized  family  and  social  life 
and  this  was  carried  over  into  the  realm  of  the  gods;  so  that  the  gods  were 
related,  and  special  functions  and  responsibilities  assigned  to  each,  and  the 
importance  of  the  god  or  goddess  determined  by  the  importance  of  the  function. 
Man  had  also  by  now  attained  a  much  higher  degree  of  culture  and  there  came 
to  be  gods  of  the  thought  and  emotional  world,  such  as  the  goddess  of  wisdom 
and  the  goddess  of  love.  Thus  arose  twelve  major  deities  and  the  countless 
minor  divinities  of  the  pagan  world,  forming  a  well-organized  pantheon  of  gods 
and  goddesses.1 

Man  has  shown  a  tendency  to  create  gods  to  preside  over  all  experiences 
of  vital  importance  to  the  individual  and  the  group.  Consequently,  the 
number  and  character  of  the  gods  devised  by  any  people  depend  upon 
the  emotional  experiences  of  the  members  of  that  group.  Some  experi- 
ences are  universal,  such  as  fertility,  hunger,  and  life  and  death.  There- 
fore, we  find  certain  universal  deities  that  appear  among  the  gods  of  every 
people.  Many  experiences,  however,  are  peculiar  to  a  people  because  of 
the  differences  in  living  conditions  brought  about  by  the  specific  divergen- 
cies in  geographical  environment.  Thus  there  arise  wide  variations  in 
the  nature  and  functions  of  regional  deities. 

All  we  can  say  in  the  way  of  a  sweeping  generalization  is  that  wherever, 
in  early  civilization,  there  was  an  emotional  experience  of  great  im- 
portance to  the  race,  man  had  the  raw  material  out  of  which  a  god  might 
be — and  usually  was — created. 

We  may  consider  first  those  gods  who  owe  their  existence  to  experiences 
common  to  all  men.  One  such  body  of  experience  grows  out  of  the  re- 
productive instinct.  The  sexual  urge  is  responsible  for  a  great  number 
of  deities  in  all  pantheons.  Household  gods  are  numerous,  and  have  their 
assigned  functions.  But  reproduction  is  something  which  goes  far  beyond 
the  perpetuation  and  increase  of  the  human  race.  It  involves  all  nature. 
Therefore,  man  created  potent  gods  of  fertility,  of  life  and  death,  and 
rebirth.  Noticing  that  the  female  seems  to  be  the  all-important  factor 
in  human  reproduction,  man  frequently  created  female  deities  or  god- 
desses to  embody  the  generalized  concept  of  fertility  and  reproduction. 
Because  of  the  vital  importance  of  the  growth  of  vegetation  and  the 
increase  of  domestic  animals,  the  fertility  goddesses  loomed  large  in  the 
religion  and  mythology  of  early  peoples.  Such  were  Isthar  (Astarte)  of 
the  Babylonians,  Kubaba  of  the  Hittites  (later  known  as  Cybele),  Deme- 
ter  of  the  Greeks,  and  Tellus  of  the  Romans. 

For  each  of  the  important  crises  in  life,  such  as  birth,  puberty,  mar- 
riage, sickness,  and  death,  a  god  was  usually  provided  for  man's  protec- 
tion. There  are  also  natural  occurrences,  such  as  seasonal  changes  and 
the  passage  of  day  into  night  and  night  into  day,  which  all  men  observe. 


*How  the  Gods  Were  Made,  privately  printed,  1926,  p.  10;  c/.  Joseph  McCabe, 
How  Man  Made  God,  Haldeman-Julius,  1931. 


676         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

Accordingly,  every  pantheon  has  deities  for  seasons  and  for  light  and 
darkness.  Further,  strong  drink  and  drugs  produce  strange  and  powerful 
reactions.  Consequently,  we  find  among  the  Greeks  Dionysus,  the  vine 
god,  arid  in  India  a  god  for  Soma,  a  powerful  liquor  made  from  leaves  of 
a  mountain  plant. 

As  a  result  of  special  geographic  circumstances,  gods  of  the  mountains, 
plains,  desert,  forest,  or  the  sea  are  given  varying  degrees  of  importance, 
according  to  the  habitat  of  the  different  peoples.  Each  occupation 
and  industry  is  usually  presided  over  by  a  god.  Hunters,  shepherds,  and 
agricultural  peoples  have  always  invented  deities  appropriate  to  their 
several  occupations.  Moreover,  the  shepherd  especially  depends  on 
animal  fertility,  the  farmer  on  weather,  the  fisherman  on  the  sea.  Gods 
are  provided  to  look  after  each  of  these  needs.  There  is  also  a  tendency 
to  deify  animals — those  upon  which,  for  any  reason,  man  depends,  as 
well  as  those  he  especially  fears. 

The  multiplicity  of  gods  in  early  civilizations  is  difficult  for  us  to 
understand  today.  Take,  for  instance,  Roman  household  gods.  First 
there  was  Vesta,  the  goddess  of  the  hearth,  the  center  of  family  worship. 
Next  came  the  di  penates,  or  gods  of  the  family  storeroom.  Then  there 
was  the  god  of  the  paterfamilias,  the  procreative  power  which  continued 
the  family 's  existence — a  sort  of  symbol  of  the  germ  plasm;  the  god  of 
the  door  or  threshold,  called  Janus;  and  finally,  the  lar  familiaris,  or  the 
spirit  of  the  boundaries  of  the  family  domain.  Added  to  these,  of  course, 
was  the  great  number  of  Roman  public  gods. 

Man  deifies  man  as  well  as  nature.  Most  consciously  he  tends  to  give 
ancestors  and  the  heroes  of  the  past  divine  attributes,  much  as  we  glorify 
George  Washington  and  the  founders  of  our  country.  The  political  head 
of  society  was  often  deified  in  early  civilization;  so  were  military  heroes. 

Not  only  does  man  create  gods  and  assign  them  certain  functions,  he 
even  invests  them  with  moral  attributes.  In  this  process,  too,  the  facts 
are  exactly  the  opposite  of  what  is  usually  believed.  It  is  generally 
assumed  that  God  created  and  revealed  our  moral  codes.  The  Deca- 
logue was  handed  to  Moses  on  Mount  Sinai,  right  and  wrong  are  decided 
upon  in  heaven,  and  so  on.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  man  has  always  pro- 
jected his  own  moral  beliefs  on  the  gods.  He  has  attributed  to  the  gods 
the  origin  of  the  folkways  that  were  gradually  worked  out  by  each  social 
group  in  the  course  of  its  life  experiences. 

This  is  admirably  illustrated  by  the  Old  Testament  God,  Yahweh,  who 
first  appeared  as  a  crude  supernatural  power  symbolized  by  upright 
stones — a  phallic  symbol.  He  then  developed  into  a  ruthless  tribal 
divinity  of  desert  nomads,  bidding  his  followers  savagely  to  destroy  these 
enemies  who  worshiped  gods  other  than  Yahweh.  Ultimately,  Yahweh 
became  a  universal  providence,  directing  the  affairs  of  nature  and  man 
and  controlling  the  course  of  history. 

In  preliterary  times,  the  gods  were  the  product  of  man's  unrestrained 
imagination.  As  culture  developed  and  man  learned  to  write,  his  deities 
were  given  more  precise  and  permanent  attributes.  We  shall  have  occa- 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         677 

sion  to  illustrate  this  trend  as  we  describe  the  pantheons  of  historical 
peoples. 

Fundamental  Religious  Concepts  and  Practices.  First  and  foremost 
in  primitive  religious  thought  is  the  realm  of  things  sacred,  those  things 
which  are  charged  with  the  mystical  mana,  the  vague  but  potent  source 
of  supernatural  power.  Usually,  sacred  things  can  be  handled  safely 
only  by  specialists  in  mystery,  priests  or  medicine  men  (shamans). 
Nearly  all  individual,  social,  and  industrial  activities  were  under  the 
spell  of  the  supernatural,  and  so  the  shaman,  or  medicine  man,  was  very 
powerful  in  primeval  society. 

Closely  allied  to  the  concept  of  sacredness  are  the  notions  of  clean  and 
unclean.  In  most  cases,  these  terms  have  no  relation  to  considerations 
of  hygiene  or  aesthetics,  but  are  connected  with  ideas  of  safety  and 
danger.  A  "clean"  thing  is  free  of  the  supernatural  or  of  danger  there- 
from. It  is  safe.  Contact  with  it  does  not  expose  one  to  mysterious 
risks  and  possible  disasters.  The  unclean  is  steeped  in  mystery.  Evil 
forces  play  around  it.  Contamination  with  it  may  bring  tragedy.  Only 
proper  religious  rites,  administered  by  "authorized"  persons,  may,  at 
times,  make  the  unclean  become  clean  and  safe. 

Next  we  may  look  at  the  concept  of  sacrifice,  a  highly  important  rite, 
combining  both  magic  and  worship.  The  purposes  of  sacrifice  are  varied. 
It  may  be  a  way  of  offering  thanks  to  the  gods — one  gives  them  a  share 
of  his  crops,  or  cattle.  At  other  times,  sacrifice  serves  to  bring  gods  and 
votaries  together,  thereby  cementing  the  bond  between  them  and  renew- 
ing the  covenant.  Sacrifice  may  also  be  used  to  increase  the  volume  of 
mana  or  spiritual  grace  in  the  community  or  to  bring  the  social  group  into 
contact  with  its  mysterious  operations. 

Sacrifice  takes  on  varied  forms.  In  "theophagy"  a  worshiper  may  eat 
the  symbol  of  the  god,  or  the  god's  representative,  man  or  animal,  thereby 
imbibing  the  mana  residing  in  that  which  is  consumed.  On  the  whole, 
sacrifice  usually  expresses  gratitude  and  loyalty  to  the  gods,  or  it  is 
indulged  in  for  the  sake  of  securing  supernatural  aid  in  times  of  stress. 

Taboo  is  the  fundamental  primitive  means  of  executing  social  control. 
It  aims  to  make  human  life  safe.  The  gods  are  supposed  to  indicate 
what  types  of  conduct  they  approve,  and  what  they  disapprove.  Dis- 
approved acts  are  taboo — forbidden.  If  one  never  violates  taboos,  he 
is  likely  to  remain  in  the  favor  of  the  gods,  thus  receiving  and  retaining 
spiritual  grace.  There  may  be  taboos  against  marrying  certain  people, 
eating  certain  animals  (consider  the  Jewish  dietary  laws),  working  on 
certain  days  (the  Christian  Sunday,  for  instance,  or  Jewish  Sabbath), 
coming  into  contact  with  strangers  (Jewish  dislike  of  Gentiles) ,  and  so 
on.  In  a  word,  taboos  are  the  "don'ts" — the  red  lights — of  primitive 
society. 

Fetishism  pervades  primitive  religion.  It  is  the  worship  of  objects 
which  are  believed  to  harbor  spirits  and  therefore  bring  good  luck.  In 
a  few  instances,  however,  fetishism  does  not  involve  the  residence  of  a 
spirit  in  an  object.  In  western  Africa,  for  example,  the  magical  power 


678         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

in  the  object  is  looked  upon  as  impersonal  and  no  indwelling  spirit  is 
implied. 

Primitive  religion  abounds  with  ritual,  particularly  for  handling  safely 
those  crises  which  are  supposed  to  be  specifically  charged  with  mana, 
and  hence  especially  dangerous.  To  ward  off  potential  evils  during  these 
crucial  periods  of  existence,  one  must  indulge  in  specified  types  of  rites, 
thereby  propitiating  the  proper  deities.  Hence,  nearly  all  primitive 
tribes  invest  birth,  adolescence,  initiation  into  manhood  and  womanhood, 
marriage,  sickness,  and  death  with  a  distinct  sense  of  the  sacred  and 
mysterious,  and  provide  specific  religious  rites  to  handle  them  safely. 
These,  as  Professor  Marett  and  others  have  made  clear,  are  the  primitive 
origins  of  the  famous  sacramental  system  of  the  Roman  Catholic  church, 
to  which  we  shall  later  pay  attention. 

An  important  concept  of  primitive  religion  and  social  relations  is 
toteinism.  Commonly,  a  group  regards  itself  as  descended  from  or  aided 
by  some  plant,  animal,  or  object,  towards  which  it  observes  an  attitude 
of  veneration.  Totemism  is  important  as  furnishing  the  basis  for 
marriage  taboos — fellow  totemites  usually  may  not  marry — and  in  stimu- 
lating ceremonial  activities. 

Finally,  we  must  say  a  little  more  about  primitive  "clergy,"  medicine 
men,  or  shamans.  They  are  exalted,  ineffable  beings,  holding  special 
communion  with  the  gods.  They  alone  can  deal  safely  with  the  super- 
natural powers  and  competently  handle  the  sacred,  since  they  themselves 
are  filled  with  mana. 

Two  types  of  shamans  are  found  in  primitive  society — those  especially 
adept  in  administering  rituals  and  performing  ceremonies,  and  those  of  a 
more  saintly  cast,  who  dwell  mentally  in  peculiarly  mystical  regions. 
The  latter  are  the  "holy  men."  They  live  apart.  Tribesmen  come  to 
them  for  counsel,  revelation,  and  regeneration.  In  later  religions,  they 
became  the  prophets.  The  ceremonial  shaman  became  the  priest. 

Primitive  chieftains  and  kings  frequently  are  supposed  to  be  endowed 
with  mana.  On  this  account  they  are  entitled  to  high  position  and  great 
respect.  Their  special  reserve  of  mana  enables  them  to  contact  the 
sacred  powers.  Hence  it  is  not  uncommon  to  find  priest-kings  among 
frarbarians.  The  medieval  and  modern  doctrine  of  the  divine  right  of 
kings  is  little  more  than  a  sophisticated  vestige  of  this  picturesque  bit  of 
primitive  speculation. 

The  Christian  Synthesis.  We  have  now  discussed  briefly  the  origins 
and  leading  traits  of  religion.  Little  progress  in  fundamentals  has  been 
made  by  any  great  world  religion  beyond  the  beliefs  and  practices  which 
we  have  outlined.  We  do  not  have  the  space  here  to  describe  the  re- 
ligions of  the  Ancient  East,  which  represent  a  slightly  more  sophisticated 
expression  of  the  foregoing  primitive  dogmas  and  rites.  We  must  pass 
on  to  a  survey  of  the  nature  of  the  Christian  religion,  which  has  dominated 
the  Western  world  for  two  millenniums. 

Christianity  is  frequently  believed  to  have  appeared  suddenly,  as  a 
new  and  fully-fashioned  religion,  some  two  thousand  years  ago.  But 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         679 

the  historian  of  religion  recognizes  that  Christianity  drew  heavily  upon 
earlier  strains  in  religious  belief  and  practice  and  combined  many  of  the 
most  popular  and  potent  trends  in  the  religions  of  all  the  peoples  around 
the  Mediterranean  basin.  Indeed,  its  very  comprehensiveness  was  one 
of  the  chief  sources  of  the  strength  of  Christianity.  It  had  many  dogmas 
and  rites,  some  one  of  which  would  appeal  very  strongly  to  a  given  group 
of  potential  converts.  It  had  some  form  of  strong  appeal  to  Jew  and 
Gentile,  Greek  and  barbarian,  rich  and  poor,  the  mighty  and  the  meek. 
We  may  now  turn  our  attention  to  the  manner  in  which  Christianity  com- 
bined portions  of  the  religions  of  the  antique  world  and  built  up  an 
imposing  religious  synthesis. 

The  fundamental  doctrines  in  Christianity  were  common  to  all  re- 
ligions. Primitive  man  had  provided  the  basic  beliefs  essential  for  deal- 
ing effectively  with  the  supernatural  world.  Primitive  man  had  intro- 
duced the  doctrine  of  supernatural  power,  and  had  classified  its  agents 
into  good  and  evil  spirits.  He  had  introduced  various  rituals — worship, 
magic,  sacrifice,  baptism,  birth,  death,  initiation,  and  purification  rites — 
all  of  which  expressed  man's  fear  and  gratitude  with  respect  to  the  super- 
natural powers  who  were  believed  to  control  the  world.  These  were  at 
the  root  of  Judaism  and  other  eastern  prototypes  of  Christianity,  and 
most  of  them  still  persist  in  orthodox  Catholicism  and  Protestantism. 

The  religion  of  the  Jews,  developed  over  hundreds  of  years,  made  many 
obvious  contributions  to  Christianity.  Christians  measured  historical 
time  by  means  of  the  Jewish  chronology,  which  ran  back  to  the  Creation. 
Jewish  history  provided  the  framework  of  the  Christian  historical  per- 
spective and  the  heroes  of  the  Christian  past — Moses,  Joshua,  Samson, 
David,  Solomon,  and  the  like.  Even  Enoch  and  Lot  crowded  out  Pericles. 
The  Christian  cosmology — the  theory  of  the  origin  and  development  of 
the  universe,  the  earth,  and  its  inhabitants — was  derived  primarily  from 
Genesis. 

The  Jews  also  gave  the  Christians  their  particular  deity.  Their  tribal 
God,  Yahweh,  became  the  Christian  God.  Jewish  scriptures  supplied  the 
basis  for  the  expected  coming  of  Christ — namely,  the  so-called  Messianic 
hope.  Finally,  the  Jews  contributed  Jesus,  whom  they  later  disowned. 

Much  of  early  Christian  morality  was  also  obtained  from  the  Old 
Testament.  God's  revelations  in  respect  to  good  conduct,  and  his  mani- 
fest will  in  such  matters,  as  illustrated  by  Old  Testament  examples,  were 
accepted  by  Christian  converts. 

Pre-Christian  asceticism  was  found  in  certain  Jewish  cults  which 
echoed  the  denunciation  of  human  vanity  and  futility  to  be  found  in  the 
literature  attributed  to  Solomon,  and  urged  withdrawal  from  the  world. 
John  the  Baptist  presumably  belonged  to  such  a  sect,  the  Essenes. 

Other  sacred  books  of  the  Jews  in  addition  to  the  Bible,  such  as  the 
Talmud,  and  later  the  Cabala,  similarly  exerted  a  deep  influence  on 
Christianity,  These  were  worked  into  Christianity  by  scholarly  Jewish 
converts. 

Some  Jewish  lore  which  the  Christians  took  over,  such  as  the  legends 


680         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

relative  to  the  Creation  and  the  Deluge,  originally  came  from  Babylonian 
sources,  while  it  was  believed  by  the  late  James  H.  Breasted,  and  others, 
that  the  Messianic  hope  of  the  Jews  originated  in  Egyptian  social  phi- 
losophy, whence  the  Jews  borrowed  it. 

From  the  Persians  came  what  was  perhaps  the  most  influential  of  all 
the  elements  that  entered  into  Christianity — namely,  the  notion  of  the 
overwhelming  importance  of  the  life  to  come.  The  Persians  were  the 
first  to  provide  elaborate  and  dogmatic  answers  to  the  eternal  question: 
Why  did  the  universe  and  man  come  into  existence?  They  believed  that 
God  had  created  the  universe  as  an  arena  where  the  principles  of  good 
and  evil  could  engage  in  decisive  combat,  and  where  the  triumph  of  good 
over  evil  might  be  overwhelmingly  demonstrated.  Those  who  had  be- 
lieved in  the  principle  of  good,  represented  by  Ormuzd,  the  Persian  God, 
would  be  rewarded  by  a  life  of  immortal  happiness  in  the  world  to  come. 
Those  who  had  been  foolish  enough  to  pin  their  hopes  on  the  forces  of 
evil,  championed  by  Ahriman,  the  Persian  devil,  would  be  thrown  into 
a  lake  of  fire  and  brimstone. 

The  Persians  were  probably  the  first  people  to  whom  the  future  life 
was  a  mutter  of  all-absorbing  interest.  There  was  little  thought  of 
future  punishment  in  early  Jewish  theology.  Sheol  was  regarded  as  a 
vague  place  of  the  dead,  retribution  having  already  taken  place  in  this 
world.  Not  until  the  Jews  were  influenced  by  the  Persians,  as  reflected 
in  the  apocryphal  Book  of  Enoch,  did  they  develop  the  idea  of  future 
torment.  The  Greeks  and  Romans  believed  in  a  sort  of  drab  and  in- 
different afterlife  in  Hades,  where  men  were  neither  sad  nor  glad,  though 
certain  specially  hideous  criminals  might  receive  appropriate  punishment. 

The  Persian  eschatology  made  the  next  world  a  challenge  to  conduct 
in  this  world.  Indifference  to  the  future  life  was  no  longer  possible,  since 
the  good  would  be  forever  blessed  and  the  wicked  eternally  punished. 

Christianity  derived  its  idea  of  immortality  from  Persia  partly  through 
direct  contact  with  competing  Persian  religions  like  Mithraism  and 
Manichaeism,  and  partly  from  the  Jews  of  pre-Christian  days.  These 
Jews  had  taken  over  the  Persian  beliefs,  as  is  particularly  evident  in  the 
Book  of  Enoch  and  other  late  Jewish  literature. 

The  Persians,  through  Mithraism,  contributed,  in  addition,  the  famous 
light-and-darkness  symbolism,  associating  light  with  good,  and  darkness 
with  evil.  Incidentally,  they  supplied  the  particular  date  chosen  for 
Christmas.  The  twenty-fifth  day  of  December  was  the  day  of  the  great 
Mithraic  feast  celebrating  the  returning  strength  of  their  sun  god  after 
the  winter  solstice.  From  Mithraism  also,  rather  than  from  the  tradi- 
tional Jewish  Sabbath,  was  derived  Sunday,  with  its  taboo  on  work. 
Many  Christian  rites,  such  as  the  use  of  bells,  candles,  and  the  like,  were 
imitated  from  Mithraic  usage ;  whence  likewise  came  the  blood  symbolism 
in  baptism. 

Into  Christianity  were  also  drafted  elements  of  Manichaeism,  a  strange 
compound  of  Persian,  Babylonian,  and  Buddhist  religions,  founded  by 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         681 

Manes  of  Ctesiphon  (A.D.  215-272).  It  laid  special  stress  on  renuncia- 
tion of  the  flesh,  the  vividness  of  heaven  and  hell,  and  the  symbolism  of 
light  and  darkness.  Manichaeism,  we  may  noter  persisted  down  to  late 
medieval  times  among  the  Cathari  of  Italy,  the  Albigenses  of  southern 
France,  and  certain  Bulgarian  sects,  such  as  the  Bogomiles.  The  phi- 
losopher Pierre  Bayle  (1647-1706)  thought  well  of  it  in  modern  times. 

The  Greeks  left  innumerable  impressions  on  Christianity.  Scholarly 
Greeks  converted  to  Christianity  could  not  rest  satisfied  with  the  real 
Jesus,  portrayed  as  an  unlettered  village  workman,  whose  intimates  and 
disciples  were  fishermen.  They  had  to  exalt  him  to  high  metaphysical 
rank,  where  he  could  rival  the  Platonic  logos,  the  source  of  all  truth. 
Hence  Christian  theology  became  essentially  Greek  metaphysics,  restated 
and  revalued  in  relation  to  the  person  and  mission  of  Jesus.  In  Gnosti- 
cism, a  logical  but  extreme  development  of  this  metaphysical  interpreta- 
tion, Jesus  all  but  ceased  to  be  a  person  and  became  an  abstract  philo- 
sophical principle,  an  illuminating  and  redeeming  revelation  of  religious 
truth  and  prophecy.  Most  of  the  great  heresies  of  the  early  church  were 
little  more  than  unofficial  Hellenized  views  of  Jesus'  nature  and  mission. 

The  moral  austerity  of  Christianity  drew  heavily  upon  the  Stoic  eulogy 
of  moral  earnestness.  The  Stoics  also  contributed  their  cosmopolitan 
outlook,  and  their  attitude  of  mental  resignation  before  the  all-pervading 
will  of  God,  as  expressed  in  nature  and  the  life  experiences  of  man. 
Neoplatonism  provided  Christianity  with  its  underlying  mental  atmos- 
phere— the  contention  that  an  attitude  of  faith  and  credulity  most  befit 
a  religious  person  and  that  they  are  the  means  of  attaining  contact  with 
the  Infinite.  It  thus  stimulated  Christian  mysticism.  Finally,  when 
Aristotle  was  rediscovered  by  the  Middle  Ages  and  approved  by  the 
church,  Hellenic  logic  laid  the  foundations  for  the  mature  body  of 
Catholic  doctrine — Scholasticism. 

Christian  ritual  was  borrowed  in  part  from  the  Greek  mysteries.  The 
holiest  of  Christian  rites,  the  Eucharist,  was  invented  by  Paul  as  an 
imitation  of  the  sacred  meal  of  the  Eleusinian  mysteries.  Baptism  and 
the  brilliant  Christian  liturgy  and  ritual  were  drawn  primarily  from 
Hellenistic  orientalism.  Greek  rhetoric  furnished  the  models  for  Chris- 
tian preaching,  and  the  original  name  of  a  Christian  church — ecclesia — 
was  of  Greek  origin. 

Rome  brought  to  Christianity  its  genius  for  organization  and  adminis- 
tration. Roman  law,  adapted  to  religious  cases,  became  the  famous 
Canon  Law  of  the  medieval  church.  When  the  Christian  church  spread 
around  the  Mediterranean  world  it  took  over  the  system  of  administration 
used  by  the  Roman  emperors.  It  even  adopted  many  of  the  administra- 
tive districts  and  titles.  The  title  of  bishop,  for  example,  had  been  that 
of  the  leading  civil  officer  of  the  Roman  municipalities  in  the  East — the 
ancient  equivalent  of  a  mayor. 

The  Romans  also  made  important  contributions  to  Christian  ritual. 
Roman  rites  dealing  with  birth,  puberty,  marriage,  and  death — milestones 


682         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

of  life  especially  safeguarded  in  Roman  religion — passed  over  into  Chris- 
tian baptism,  confirmation,  the  sacramental  wedding,  and  the  ecclesiasti- 
cal funeral.  Roman  notions  of  religio,  embracing  attitudes  of  awe, 
anxiety,  and  piety,  and  the  conception  of  the  sacred  as  something  given 
over  to  God,  also  exerted  a  real  influence  on  Christian  doctrine. 

Finally,  when  Christianity  was  accepted  by  the  barbarians  of  northern 
Europe,  the  primitive  beliefs,  rites,  and  festivals  of  these  backward 
peoples  were  carried  over  into  their  new  religion  and  a  fusion  between 
the  two  resulted.  The  antique  primitivism  in  Christianity,  which  had 
survived  from  the  preliterary  period,  was  thus  merged  with  the  currently 
primitive  culture  of  the  barbarian  converts. 

The  foregoing  does  not  exhaust  the  accretions  to  Christianity  drawn 
from  many  sources.  But  it  does  show  how  the  composite  character  of 
the  new  religion  gave  it  a  potential  appeal  to  many  areas,  cultures,  sects, 
and  linguistic  stocks.  It  was  the  most  syncretic,  and  therefore  the  most 
attractive,  of  all  the  cults  which  competed  for  favor  in  the  later  Roman 
Empire. 

At  first,  there  was  a  tendency  to  regard  Christianity  as  a  religion  for 
the  Jews  only.  A  special  vision  was  required  to  convert  Peter  to  the  idea 
that  Christianity  should  be  spread  over  the  whole  pagan  world.  This 
attitude  is  mirrored  in  the  Gospel  according  to  Matthew  and  the  conflict 
it  engendered  is  shown  in  the  Book  of  Acts.  Paul  proclaimed  the  uni- 
versal purpose  of  Christianity  once  and  forever,  and  it  appears  in  the 
Acts,  the  Pauline  Epistles,  and  the  Gospel  according  to  Luke,  which  was 
written  under  Pauline  influence. 

The  Christians  made  the  most  of  their  missionary  opportunities.  One 
of  the  great  advantages  of  conversion  to  Christianity  in  the  early  days 
was  that  it  offered  a  chance  to  live  one's  daily  life  in  a  pagan  society  and, 
at  the  same  time,  claim  communion  in  the  kingdom  of  God  and  look 
forward  to  salvation  in  the  world  to  come.  The  idea  that  all  Christians 
in  the  first  and  second  centuries  lived  like  terror-stricken  refugees  is  quite 
false.  Only  during  periods  of  persecution  were  they  driven  underground 
— and  then  only  in  certain  places. 

No  torture  Rome  could  devise,  and  the  Latins  have  been  past  masters 
in  the  art,  could  halt  the  flow  of  converts.  By  A.D.  300  there  were  so 
many  Christians  that  persecution  seemed  pointless.  Christianity  had 
become  an  organized  defiance  of  imperial  law.  In  311,  the  Emperor 
Galerius  revoked  the  edict  of  persecution  of  303  and  introduced  an  era  of 
tolerance.  In  313,  Constantine  the  Great  issued  the  famous  Edict  of 
Milan,  which  legalized  Christianity.  In  325  he  called  the  great  Council 
Nicea,  which  adjusted  for  a  time  the  doctrinal  dispute  between  the  Arians 
and  the  Athanasians  by  deciding  in  favor  of  the  latter  and  settling  the 
problem  of  the  Trinity. 

After  Constantine's  death,  paganism  was  practically  doomed.  Chris- 
tians were  favored  over  pagans.  By  the  time  of  the  famous  code  of 
Theodosius  II  (438)  Christianity  had  become  a  religious  monopoly  de- 
fended by  the  state,  The  worship  of  heathen  gods  was  forbidden,  The 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         683 

Christians  turned  the  tables  on  their  enemies  and  soon  more  than  evened 
the  score  through  vigorous  persecution  of  the  pagans. 

Far  and  away  the  most  important  medieval  institution  was  the  Catholic 
Church,  which  became  thoroughly  enmeshed  in  the  feudal  system.  Some 
of  the  most  powerful  feudal  lords  were  abbots,  bishops,  and  archbishops. 
The  Roman  Catholic  Church  has  been  usually  and  quite  rightly  regarded 
as  a  spiritual  agency  designed  to  procure  salvation.  But  assuring  salva- 
tion for  its  millions  of  communicants  necessitated  an  elaborate  adminis- 
trative and  financial  organization.  At  its  height,  there  were  over  500,000 
clergy  in  the  church: 

The  Church  was  essentially  an  organized  state,  thoroughly  centralized,  with 
one  supreme  head  and  a  complete  gradation  of  officials;  with  a  comprehensive 
system  of  law  courts  for  trying  cases,  with  penalties  covering  all  crimes,  and 
with  prisons  for  punishing  offenders.  It  demanded  an  allegiance  from  all  its 
members  somewhat  like  that  existing  today  between  subjects  and  a  state.  It 
developed  one  official  language,  the  Latin,  which  was  used  to  conduct  its  business 
everywhere.  Thus  all  western  Europe  was  one  great  religious  association  from 
which  it  was  treason  to  revolt.  Canon  law  punished  such  a  crime  with  death, 
public  opinion  sanctioned  it,  and  the  secular  arm  executed  the  sentence.2 

It  is  clear,  then,  that,  in  addition  to  its  spiritual  prestige  and  preroga- 
tives, the  Catholic  church  of  the  Middle  Ages  was  a  vast  international 
state  of  greater  territorial  extent  and  financial  resources  than  any  secular 
power  of  the  period.  From  parish  to  provinces,  all  united  under  the 
jurisdiction  of  the  Holy  See,  it  not  only  embraced  much  the  larger  part 
of  Europe  but  also  boasted  colonies  of  converts  in  Africa  and  Asia. 

The  foregoing  view  of  the  medieval  church  helps  us  to  understand  the 
nature  pf  the  Protestant  revolution.  It  was  not  simply  an  attempt  to 
modify  the  doctrine  of  the  Church.  It  was  far  more  truly  a  political 
and  economic  secession  from  the  great  international  ecclesiastical  state, 
motivated  principally  by  the  desire  to  be  free  from  its  financial  exactions. 

Protestantism  and  Rationalism.  It  is  commonly  supposed  by  both 
devout  Protestants  and  Catholics  that  the  Protestant  Reformation 
brought  into  existence  a  type  of  Christianity  profoundly  different  from 
Roman  Catholicism.  We  may  appropriately  investigate  this  conviction, 
first  briefly  looking  into  the  actual  changes  introduced.3 

In  the  first  place,  the  Protestants  stamped  out  what  they  regarded  as 
the  leading  aspects  of  ecclesiastical  corruption.  They  suppressed  com- 
pletely the  sale  of  indulgences.  They  strove  for  a  simpler  and  more 
direct  form  of  worship.  They  particularly  attacked  those  phases  of 
Catholic  worship  and  ritual  which  were  based  on  the  doctrine  of  salvation 
by  good  works.  They  abolished  the  veneration  of  relics,  the  adoration  of 
images,  and  the  practice  of  making  pilgrimages  to  holy  places.  They 
profoundly  modified  the  central  Catholic  doctrine  of  transubstantiation 


2  A.  C.  Flick,  The  Rise  of  the  Medieval  Church,  Putnam,  1909,  pp.  603-304. 
8  For  a  sympathetic   interpretation,  see   Burris  Jenkins,   The   World's  Debt  to 
Protestantism,  Stratford,  1930. 


684         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

in  the  sacrament  of  the  Mass  by  denying  the  miraculous  transformation 
of  the  bread  and  wine  into  the  actual  body  and  blood  of  Jesus.  The 
Lutherans,  however,  accepted  "consubstantiation"  or  the  "corporeal 
presence."  The  Bible,  rather  than  the  dogmas  of  the  Church  fathers 
and  Catholic  theologians,  became  the  guide  of  the  Protestant  Christian 
in  his  religious  devotions.  The  Protestants  denied  the  necessity  of  a 
mediating  priesthood  to  bring  the  believer  into  contact  with  God.  The 
Protestants  contended  that  a  Christian  could  secure  God's  attention  di- 
rectly through  personal  worship  and  prayer.  Thus,  they  put  special 
emphasis  on  the  importance  of  the  individual  conscience  in  matters  re- 
ligious. 

The  degree  to  which  Protestantism  differed,  even  in  matters  religious, 
from  the  parent  Catholic  church  greatly  depended  upon  the  particular 
Protestant  sect.  With  the  early  Lutherans  and  Angelicans  the  divergence 
from  Catholicism  in  worship  was  relatively  slight — in  spite  of  doctrinal 
differences.  On  the  other  hand,  the  more  radical  religious  groups,  such 
as  the  Anabaptists  and  the  later  evangelical  sects,  almost  completely 
abandoned  the  old  Catholic  rites  and  practices. 

Nevertheless,  as  the  able  German  church  historian  Ernst  Troeltsch 
has  made  very  clear,  the  fundamental  religious  differences  between  the 
Catholics  and  even  the  radical  Protestants  were  not  extensive.  This 
fact  was  commonly  overlooked  in  the  fierce  partisanship  which  charac- 
terized the  controversies  between  Catholics  and  Protestants.  Both 
Catholics  and  orthodox  Protestants  fully  accepted  the  whole  Christian 
Epic,  as  outlined  in  the  Old  and  New  Testaments.  The  Bible  was  the 
central  sacred  book  of  their  religion.  Catholics  and  Protestants  alike 
were  primarily  concerned  with  making  a  proper  adjustment  to  the  super- 
natural world  and  with  securing  the  salvation  of  the  individual  soul  in 
the  world  to  come.  The  medieval  doctrines  of  heaven  and  hell  were 
adopted  with  no  marked  change  by  all  Protestants.  To  Luther  in  par- 
ticular, the  devil  and  his  hosts  became  more  real  and  fearful  beings. 
Evangelical  divines  of  the  eighteenth  and  nineteenth  centuries  tended  to 
lay  far  more  stress  upon  the  horrors  of  hell  and  the  dangers  of  damnation 
than  Catholic  theologians  of  pre-Reformation  days.  Moreover,  the 
Protestants  were  just  as  alert  and  severe  as  Catholics  in  their  denuncia- 
tion of  sceptics  and  freethinkers.  It  is  no  exaggeration  to  say  that,  upon 
at  least  95  per  cent  of  all  matters  of  strictly  religious  import,  Catholics 
and  Protestants  were  in  agreement.  They  were  also  about  equally  an- 
tagonistic to  the  inroads  of  theological  liberalism  and  secular  scepticism. 

Protestants  have  taken  great  pride  in  having  discarded  many  allegedly 
idolatrous  Catholic  practices.  But  they  weakened  the  emotional  power 
of  their  churches  by  depriving  them  of  the  most  potent  appeal  of  the 
Catholic  church:  its  visual  and  auricular  imagery.  The  rich  emotion- 
bearing  ritual  and  liturgy  of  the  Catholic  church  were  far  better  cal- 
culated to  attract  and  hold  a  mass  of  faithful  believers  than  the 
metaphysical  dogmatism  of  Calvin  or  the  vocal  emotionalism  of  other 
Protestant  cults.  This  is  even  more  apparent  today  than  it  was  in  the 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         685 

sixteenth  century.  The  intellectual  classes,  to  whom  the  Calvinistic 
metaphysics  and  doctrinal  sermons  appealed,  have  now  generally  dis- 
carded all  types  of  orthodoxy  and  found  other  forms  of  intellectual 
interest.  In  its  non-religious  aspects,  Protestantism  was  notable  for  the 
impetus  it  gave  to  nationalism,  capitalism,  and  the  spirit  of  business 
enterprise. 

During  the  seventeenth  and  eighteenth  centuries,  certain  intellectual 
leaders  in  Europe  and  America  brought  into  being  a  somewhat  different 
attitude  toward  religion  than  had  prevailed  in  either  the  Protestant  or 
the  Catholic  camp.  The  philosopher  John  Locke  (1632-1704)  insisted 
that  religion  should  be  a  matter  of  reason  rather  than  emotion  and  blind 
faith.  But  he  remained  loyal  to  Protestant  Christianity.  More  ad- 
vanced were  the  so-called  Deists,  a  group  of  religious  liberals,  extending 
in  their  influence  from  Lord  Herbert  of  Cherbury  (1583-1645)  to  Thomas 
Paine  and  Thomas  Jefferson,  who  lived  nearly  two  centuries  later.  Other 
important  writers  in  this  group  were  Anthony  Collins,  Thomas  Woolston, 
and  Matthew  Tindal.  The  Christians  had  believed  in  the  uniqueness 
and  arbitrariness  of  their  religion,  but  the  Deists  held  that  the  true  reli- 
gion must  be  universal  and  reasonable.  The  Deists  were  greatly  influ- 
enced by  the  new  natural  science  and  tended  to  identify  nature  with  God 
and  such  natural  laws  as  that  of  gravitation  with  divine  laws.  Essen- 
tially, the  Deistic  religious  beliefs  were  the  following:  (1)  God  exists; 
(2)  it  is  desirable  to  worship  God;  (3)  the  chief  end  of  worship  is  to 
promote  better  living;  (4)  this  implies  and  requires  repentance  of  sins; 
and  (5)  there  is  a  future  life,  in  which  man  will  be  dealt  with  according 
to  his  conduct  here  on  earth.  It  will  thus  be  apparent  that  the  Deists 
were  devout  believers  in  God,  the  divinity  of  Jesus,  and  the  future  life. 
But  they  rejected  both  Catholic  and  Protestant  Christianity,  which  they 
regarded  as  a  departure  from  the  true  teachings  of  Jesus. 

Some  philosophers  of  this  period,  such  as  the  Frenchman  Pierre  Bayle, 
and  the  Englishman  David  Hume,  went  further  than  the  Deists  and 
raised  serious  doubts  as  to  the  validity  of  religion,  the  existence  of  God, 
and  the  future  life.  But  they  did  not  dogmatically  deny  God's  existence. 
They  roughly  resembled  the  Agnostics  of  our  day.  Some  other  thinkers, 
such  as  Baron  d'Holbach,  went  the  whole  way  to  overt  atheism  and 
frankly  denied  the  existence  of  God.  It  was  at  this  time  also  that 
Hobbes,  Spinoza,  Simon,  Astruc,  and  others  began  the  criticism  of  the 
Bible,  which  was  ultimately  to  give  us  an  accurate  historical  notion  of 
the  origin  and  nature  of  this  work.  These  developments  are  interesting 
mainly  as  a  phase  of  the  history  of  human  thought.  The  great  mass  of 
the  people  remained  steadfast  in  the  orthodox  Catholic  or  Protestant 
faith. 

In  the  century  following  1750,  there  was  a  reaction  against  the  liberal 
religious  views  we  have  just  described  briefly.  Romanticism,  led  by 
Herder,  Fichte,  Schelling,  Schleiermacher  and  others,  represented  a  philo- 
sophical onslaught  against  rationalism.  It  laid  great  stress  on  man's 
emotional  life  and  on  the  all-important  nature  of  deep  religious  feeling 


686         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

and  vivid  personal  religious  experience.  The  Christian  Evidences  move- 
ment, dating  from  William  Paley  and  others  in  the  latter  part  of  the 
eighteenth  century,  assaulted  Deism  and  scepticism  and  appealed  to 
nature,  as  God's  handiwork,  to  vindicate  the  existence  and  creative 
activity  of  a  personal  God.  The  Oxford  movement  in  England  was 
designed  to  revive  spirituality  in  the  Angelican  church.  By  the  middle 
of  the  nineteenth  century  the  religious  temper  of  Europe  was  far  more 
devout  than  it  had  been  in  the  days  of  Voltaire. 

At  the  same  time,  the  foundations  were  being  laid  for  a  new  revolt 
against  orthodox  religion  more  serious  and  comprehensive  than  any  which 
had  ever  taken  place  in  the  previous  history  of  man.  This  was  founded 
upon  the  new  natural  science,  including  the  doctrine  of  evolution,  scepti- 
cal philosophy,  biblical  scholarship,  anthropology,  and  cultural  history. 
Some  alert  writers  have  compared  the  present  period  with  the  first  cen- 
turies of  the  Roman  Empire,  which  was  an  age  of  dissolution  of  ancient 
faiths  and  the  development  of  new  forms  of  religious  doctrines.  This 
comparison  does  not  seem  to  hold  in  any  comprehensive  fashion,  since 
the  present  era  presents  a  challenge  to  religion  far  more  sweeping  and 
serious  than  anything  which  transpired  in  the  classical  age.  The  religious 
situation  which  arose  in  the  Mediterranean  world  at  the  close  of  the 
Roman  republic  represented  merely  a  challenge  to  some  of  the  existing 
religions  and  attested  the  decay  of  certain  older  faiths.  That  revolu- 
tion was  not  in  any  sense  whatever  a  challenge  to  supernatural  religion 
itself,  for  the  dying  religions  were  replaced  by  others  as  pregnant  with 
superstition  and  supernaturalism  as  were  the  religions  of  ancient  Greece 
or  of  early  agricultural  Rome.  Even  bitter  critics  of  religion,  such  as 
Lucretius,  believed  firmly  in  the  existence  of  gods,  but  held  that  the 
latter  had  no  interest  in  mankind. 

Today,  the  situation  is  far  different.  We  are  now  in  possession  of  a 
body  of  knowledge  and  a  resulting  set  of  intellectual  and  social  attitudes 
which  offer  a  challenge  not  merely  to  orthodox  Catholicism  and  Funda- 
mentalist Protestantism  but  to  supernatural  religions  of  any  sort  what- 
soever. There  has  never  been  a  religious  crisis  of  this  kind  before, 
#nd  any  attempt  to  make  precise  comparisons  with  the  past  are  here 
bound  to  be  misleading  and  distorting.  Even  the  extreme  classical 
assailants  of  pagan  religions,  like  Lucretius,  had  no  such  basis  for  the 
critical  attitude  as  have  the  contemporary  sceptics.  The  bitter  attack 
of  Lucretius  upon  supernatural  religion  was  based  mainly  upon  assump- 
tions and  intuitions  as  incapable  of  proof  at  the  time  as  were  the  most 
extreme  pietistic  views  of  his  age. 

Contemporary  science,  especially  astrophysics,  renders  the  whole  set 
of  assumptions  underlying  the  anthropomorphic  and  geocentric  super- 
naturalism  of  the  past  archaic  and  unsupportable.  Our  scientific  and 
historical  knowledge  has  undermined  the  holy  books  of  all  peoples.  The 
development  of  biblical  criticism  has  discredited  the  dogma  of  the  direct 
revelation  and  unique  nature  of  the  Hebrew  Bible.  Textual  scholarship 
has  been  equally  devastating  to  the  sacred  scriptures  which  form  the 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         687 

literary  basis  of  the  other  world  religions.  Most  devastating  of  all  has 
been  the  removal  by  psychology  of  all  mystery  from  religious  experience. 
It  avails  one  nothing  to  deny  these  things,  for  they  are  literally  un- 
deniable. We  must  face  the  implied  intellectual  revolution  honestly 
and  see  what  is  to  be  done  about  it.  Nor  does  it  suffice  to  get  angry  at  a 
writer  who  brings  forward  these  truths,  so  unpleasant  to  many  of  a  pious 
turn  of  mind.  No  individual  writer  is  to  blame  for  these  changes.  If 
one  becomes  indignant  over  the  intellectual  progress  of  the  last  century 
he  must  logically  direct  his  anger  comprehensively  against  the  combined 
results  of  the  researches  of  the  natural  scientists,  cultural  historians, 
textual  critics,  and  social  scientists  of  the  era. 

Outstanding   Religious  Groups   in  the 
Twentieth  Century 

We  have  briefly  surveyed  the  origins  and  development  of  religious 
thought  and  attitudes  to  the  opening  of  the  twentieth  century.  We  may 
now  take  a  brief  inventory  of  the  prevailing  types  of  religious  attitudes. 
The  marked  divergencies  in  the  beliefs  of  the  major  religious  groups  of 
our  day  are  explained  by  the  wide  differences  in  the  degree  to  which 
members  of  the  community  have  entered  into  the  intellectual  currents  of 
modern  times.  Some  have  been  profoundly  influenced  by  science  and 
critical  philosophy,  while  others  have  remained  essentially  oblivious  to 
them.  Others  fall  between  these  two  extremes. 

In  western  Christendom  today  we  find  essentially  the  following  group- 
ings: thfe  completely  orthodox,  the  Devout  Modernists,  and  the  Advanced 
Modernists.  The  completely  orthodox  believe  in  a  personal  God,  accept 
the  Bible  as  the  literal  word  of  God,  proclaim  the  complete  divinity  of 
Jesus,  and  believe  in  the  personal  immortality  of  the  human  soul.  This 
group  is  still  numerous,  particularly  among  the  agricultural  groups  and 
among  the  lower  middle  class  in  urban  populations,  who  accept  without 
question  the  whole  Christian  Epic:  the  biblical  God,  the  theory  of  a 
special  creation  about  six  thousand  years  ago,  the  deluge,  the  theory  of 
the  chosen  race,  the  Messianic  hope,  the  vicarious  sacrifice  and  messiah- 
ship  of  Jesus,  the  divinity  of  Jesus,  a  literal  future  life,  and  the  reality 
of  heaven  and  hell.  These  ideas  are  shared  by  orthodox  Catholics  and 
Protestants  alike.  They  have  modified  but  slightly  the  general  complex 
of  religious  faith  held  by  St.  Paul,  Augustine,  or  Luther. 

Among  the  Protestants  in  the  United  States,  a  large  group  of  these 
orthodox  believers  founded  a  movement  which  is  known  as  Fundamen- 
talism. There  was  an  inevitable  tendency  for  teachings  of  an  unsettling 
character  finally  to  seep  down  to  the  masses.  Alarmed,  the  latter  organ- 
ized to  repel  scepticism  and  unbelief.  Consequently,  during  and  follow- 
ing the  first  World  War,  ultra-orthodox  organizations  began  to  spring 
up — the  Christian  Fundamentals  League,  the  League  of  Evangelical  Stu- 
dents, various  Bible  institutes,  and  many  anti-scientific  societies.  But 


688         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

the  most  comprehensive  organization  was  the  World's  Christian  Funda- 
mentals Association,  founded  in  1918  by  the  Rev.  William  B.  Riley  of 
Minneapolis,  the  leader  of  American  Fundamentalism.  The  aggressive 
clerical  leaders  of  American  Fundamentalism  have  been  Riley,  Curtis 
L.  Laws,  J.  C.  Massee,  R.  A.  Torrey,  John  Roach  Straton,  Mark  A.  Mat- 
thews, J,  Gresham  Machen,  and  J.  Frank  Norris. 

The  Fundamentalist  platform  embodies  the  following  five  "minimum 
basic  doctrines":  "(1)  the  inerrancy  and  infallibility  of  the  Bible;  (2)  the 
virgin  birth  and  the  complete  deity  of  Christ  Jesus;  (3)  the  resurrection  of 
the  same  body  of  Jesus  which  was  three  days  buried;  (4)  the  substitution- 
ary  atonement  of  Jesus  for  the  sins  of  the  world;  (5)  the  second  coining 
of  Jesus  in  bodily  form,  according  to  the  Scriptures."  Mr.  Riley  insisted 
upon  adding  to  the  above  a  firm  belief  in  a  literal  heaven  and  hell.  He 
was  joined  by  Mr.  Straton. 

The  Fundamentalists  organized  a  number  of  anti-scientific  societies 
and  warred  against  those  scientific  teachings  which  seemed  to  threaten 
orthodoxy.  They  succeeded  in  placing  anti-evolution  laws  on  the  statute 
books  of  three  American  states  and  narrowly  missed  success  in  a  number 
of  others.  The  most  dramatic  episode  in  the  history  of  American  Funda- 
mentalism was  the  Scopes  trial  in  Tennessee  in  the  summer  of  1925,  in 
which  William  Jennings  Bryan  joined  in  a  legal  duel  with  the  great 
agnostic,  Clarence  Darrow.  Tennessee  had  passed  a  law  forbidding  the 
teaching  of  evolution  in  the  schools.  The  Fundamentalists  arrested  a 
young  high  school  teacher  named  J.  T.  Scopes  on  the  charge  of  teaching 
evolution.  His  trial  attracted  great  interest.  Mr.  Bryan,  who  led  the 
prosecution,  died  of  excessive  heat  and  overeating  during  the  closing  days 
of  the  trial,  and  American  Fundamentalism  lost  its  most  powerful  and 
colorful  champion.  During  the  trial  Bryan  expounded  the  fundamental- 
ist conviction  that  it  is  not  what  science  proves  to  be  the  truth,  but  rather 
what  the  majority  of  the  people  want  to  believe  which  should  dominate 
in  a  democracy.  The  fundamentalist  attitude  toward  modern  science 
is  illustrated  by  the  following  pronouncement  of  Edward  Y.  Clarke,  former 
Imperial  Wizard  of  the  Ku  Klux  Klan,  and  one  of  the  leaders  in  the 
battle  against  evolution:  "In  another  two  years,  from  Maine  to  California 
and  from  the  Great  Lakes  to  the  Gulf,  there  will  be  lighted  in  this  country 
countless  bonfires,  devouring  these  damnable  and  detestable  books  on 
evolution." 

The  Fundamentalists  and  other  orthodox  groups  have  one  undoubted 
source  of  strength  which  cannot  be  claimed  by  the  more  liberal  Christians. 
This  is  the  clarity  and  logic  of  their  position,  once  we  grant  their 
assumptions.  This  consideration  has  been  ably  stated  by  John  Herman 
Randall: 

Orthodoxy  has,  moreover,  an  intellectual  power  that  liberalism  has  so  far 
lacked.  In  the  face  of  uncertainty  and  confusion,  the  muddled  thinking  and 
mingling  of  contradictory  ideas,  that  so  abound  in  modernist  circles,  its  theological 
tenets  stand  out  with  clarity  and  precision.  In  accepting  them  there  is  no  vague 
hoping  to  eat  one's  cake  and  still  have  it.  The  orthodox  know  just  where  they 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         689 

stand.  Particularly  is  this  true  of  the  refined  and  elaborate  thought  of  Catholic 
philosophy.  The  Church  has  never  countenanced  what  it  calls  fkleism,  reliance 
on  sentiment  and  emotion  alone.  It  has  recognized  that  a  great  body  of  men  can 
be  united  only  by  a  faith  that  is  clear-cut  and  objective.  It  has  always  stood  for 
rationalism,  and  today  its  rationalistic  philosophy  has  a  great  appeal  for  those 
disheartened  by  the  irritationalism  and  voluntarism  of  modern  thought.  To  be 
sure,  it  has  always  dictated  the  authoritative  premises ;  but  that  in  itself  has  much 
to  recommend  it  over  mere  personal  prejudice  and  bias. 

So  markedly  does  the  clarity  of  orthodoxy  contrast  with  the  confusion  and  more 
or  less  unconscious  hypocrisy  of  liberalism,  that  more  radical  minds  who  have 
broken  with  traditional  religion  completely  are  apt  to  respect  the  orthodox  be- 
liever more  highly  than  the  muddled  modernist.  They  do  not  speak  his  lan- 
guage; but  they  can  understand  what  he  means,  and  appreciate  the  power  of  the 
experience  he  expresses.  Nothing  is  more  difficult  for  the  outsider  to  sympathize 
with,  than  the  attempt  to  combine  two  loyalties;  nothing  harder  to  understand 
than  the  man  who  remains  within  the  church  without  believing,  who  recites  the 
creed  with  mental  denial.4 

The  Devout  Modernists  represent  a  group  within  Christendom  which 
has  mad«  an  effort  to  come  to  terms  with  science  and  scholarship,  espe- 
cially the  science  and  scholarship  of  the  nineteenth  century.  They  at 
least  formally  accept  the  doctrine  of  evolution  and  the  conclusions  of 
historical  and  textual  criticism  with  respect  to  the  nature  of  the  Bible, 
which  they  frankly  admit  is  a  wrork  written  by  man.  But  they  regard 
the  Bible  as  a  unique  work  on  religion.  Most  of  them  believe  firmly  in 
God,  interpreted  in  a  paternal  pattern,  and  regard  Jesus  as  a  unique 
and  divinely  inspired  religious  leader.  They  still  maintain  a  respectful 
attitude  toward  the  immortality  of  the  soul,  though  many  of  them  no 
longer  believe  in  a  literal  heaven  and  hell.  They  tend  to  regard  the  ex- 
perience of  religious  conversion  as  a  proof  of  the  divine  character  of 
religion  and  as  something  close  to  the  miraculous.  They  have  been  drawn 
almost  entirely  from  the  ranks  of  the  Protestants,  all  devout  Catholics 
still  adhering  resolutely  to  the  tenets  of  orthodoxy. 

The  most  complete  and  authoritative  revelation  of  the  nature  of  the 
beliefs  of  the  devout  modernist  element  in  American  Christianity  is  con- 
tained in  the  very  important  work  of  George  Herbert  Betts,  The  Beliefs 
of  Seven  Hundred  Ministers.5  A  systematic  questionnaire  was  submitted 
to  500  liberal  ministers  and  200  students  in  theological  seminaries.  Of 
the  500  ministers,  100  per  cent  believed  that  God  exists;  98  per  cent 
believed  that  the  relation  of  God  to  man  is  best  expressed  by  the  word 
"Father";  95  per  cent  believed  that  God  is  a  being  with  personal  attri- 
butes, complete  and  perfect  in  all  moral  qualities;  71  per  cent  believed 
that  Jesus  was  born  of  a  virgin  without  a  human  father;  82  per  cent 
believed  that  while  on  earth  Jesus  possessed  and  used  his  powers  to  restore 
the  dead  to  life.  Some  84  per  cent  believed  that  after  Jesus  was  dead 
and  buried  he  actually  rose  from  the  dead,  leaving  the  tomb  empty ;  92 


4  J.  H.  Randall,  Religion  and  the  Modern  World,  Henry  Holt,  1929,  p.  145. 

5  Abington  Press,  1929. 


690         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

per  cent  believed  that  there  is  a  continuance  of  life  after  death;  62  per 
cent  believed  in  the  literal  resurrection  of  the  body;  61  per  cent  believed 
that  a  considerable  part  of  the  human  race  will  suffer  eternal  punishment 
because  of  their  rejection  of  Christ;  66  per  cent  believed  that  Jesus  will 
come  again  to  judge  all  mankind,  both  living  and  dead;  60  per  cent 
believed  that  death  and  suffering  were  brought  into  the  world  by  the 
disobedience  of  Adam  and  Eve  and  that  man  was  originally  in  a  state 
of  complete  moral  perfection,  which  he  lost  by  his  disobedience  and  fall; 
64  per  cent  believed  that  prayer  has  the  power  to  change  conditions  in 
nature,  such  as  drought;  83  per  cent  believed  that  prayer  for  others 
directly  affects  their  lives  whether  or  not  they  know  that  such  prayer  is 
being  offered;  94  per  cent  believed  that  God  now  acts  upon  or  operates 
in  human  lives  through  the  agency  and  person  of  the  Holy  Spirit;  47  per 
cent  believed  that  the  creation  of  the  world  occurred  in  the  manner  and 
time  recorded  in  Genesis;  57  per  cent  believed  that  heaven  exists  as  an 
actual  place  or  location.  These  answers  clearly  show  that,  when  they 
are  pinned  down  to  specific  points,  most  of  the  devout  modernist  minis- 
ters stick  pretty  close  to  orthodox  notions  of  Christian  essentials  and 
prove  that  essential  orthodoxy  is  by  110  means  "a  man  of  straw"  in  the 
United  States,  as  is  so  frequently  asserted  by  liberal  ministers  when 
orthodox  beliefs  are  being  challenged  or  attacked. 

The  replies  received  from  the  theological  students  revealed  a  consider- 
ably greater  departure  from  orthodoxy.  For  example,  whereas  60  per 
cent  of  the  ministers  declared  for  the  belief  in  the  Devil  as  an  actual 
person,  only  9  per  cent  of  the  theological  students  took  this  view. 
Whereas  56  per  cent  of  the  ministers  held  that,  in  biblical  times,  God 
exhibited  himself  to  persons  in  a  manner  which  no  longer  occurs,  only 
13  per  cent  of  the  theological  students  accepted  such  a  statement. 
Whereas  55  per  cent  of  the  ministers  held  that  the  Bible  was  written  by 
men  chosen  and  supernaturally  endowed  by  God  for  that  purpose  and 
by  Him  given  the  exact  message  they  were  to  write,  only  8  per  cent  of 
the  theological  students  concurred  in  this  position.  Whereas  38  per 
cent  of  the  ministers  held  that  the  Bible  is  wholly  free  from  legend  or 
myth,  only  4  per  cent  of  the  theological  students  shared  this  viewpoint. 
Whereas  over  50  per  cent  of  the  ministers  believed  that  heaven  and  hell 
exist  as  actual  locations,  only  11  per  cent  of  the  theological  students  so 
believed.  Whereas  62  per  cent  of  the  ministers  believed  in  the  resurrec- 
tion of  the  body,  only  18  per  cent  of  the  theological  students  retained  this 
belief.  Whereas  53  per  cent  of  the  ministers  believed  that  all  men,  being 
sons  of  Adam,  are  born  with  natures  wholly  perverse,  sinful,  and  de- 
praved, only  13  per  cent  of  the  theological  students  supported  this  atti- 
tude. Whereas  46  per  cent  of  the  ministers  held  that  in  order  to  be  a 
Christian  it  is  necessary  and  essential  to  believe  in  the  virgin  birth  of 
Jesus,  only  3  per  cent  of  the  theological  students  gave  their  assent  to  this 
viewpoint. 

However,  in  regard  to  11  crucial  items  out  of  the  56  in  the  question- 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         691 

naire,  more  than  three  quarters  of  both  the  ministers  and  theological 
students  definitely  concurred.  We  print  below  these  11  items,  with  the 
percentage  of  those  who  gave  an  affirmative  to  the  propositions  advanced: 

1.  There  is  a  supreme  being;  God  exists.     (100%) 

3.  God  is  omnipotent.     (80%) 

4.  God's  relation  to  man  is  that  of  Father.     (98%) 

8.  God  controls  the  universe  through  his  personal  presence  and  power.     (82%) 
13.  God  is  a  being  with  personal  attributes,  complete  and  perfect  in  all  moral 
qualities.     (90%) 

27.  Jesus  while  on  earth  Was  subject  to  temptation  as  arc  other  men.     (97%) 

28.  Jesus  met  his  problems  and  difficulties  using  only  those  powers  and  resources 

available  to  all  men.     (76%) 

29.  Jesus  lived  a  life  on  earth  without  sin.     (87%) 
39.  Life  continues  after  death.     (95%) 

48.  Forgiveness  of  sin  is  essential  to  a  right  relationship  with  God.     (96%) 
52.  God  operates  on  human  lives  through  the  agency  and  person  of  the  Holy 
Spirit.     (91%) 

The  Advanced  Modernists  represent  a  thorough  departure  from  ortho- 
dox beliefs.  The  more  conservative  members  of  this  group,  while  com- 
pletely rejecting  the  notion  of  any  divine  inspiration  of  the  Bible  and  the 
divinity  of  Jesus,  still  retain  a  shadowy  loyalty  to  Christianity  and  a 
formal  belief  in  the  existence  of  God.  Such  are  the  radical  wing  among 
the  Congregationalists  and  the  more  conservative  Unitarians  and  Univer- 
salists. 

Any  formal  connection  with  Christianity  was  repudiated  by  the  Ethical 
Culture  Society  founded  in  1876  by  Felix  Adler.  The  organization  did, 
however,  maintain  a  respectful  attitude  toward  theism  and  the  teachings 
of  Jesus.  In  the  vanguard  of  the  Advanced  Modernists  we  find  the  group 
who  call  themselves  Humanists,  because  they  base  their  doctrines  upon 
the  service  of  man  rather  than  the  worship  of  God.  Most  of  their 
adherents  have  come  from  Unitarian  and  Universalist  circles.  They  take 
an  agnostic  position,  neither  denying  nor  affirming  the  existence  of  God. 
They  accept  without  question  even  the  most  disconcerting  revelations  of 
science  and  scholarship.  They  view  the  Bible  as  surely  one  of  the  great 
historic  works  on  religion,  but  one  having  no  greater  claim  to  divine 
authorship  than  the  Koran.  They  not  only  reject  the  divinity  of  Jesus 
but  accord  him  no  special  uniqueness  as  a  human  religious  teacher.  They 
have  built  up  a  religion  solely  around  man  himself,  with  the  aim  of  utiliz- 
ing religion  as  a  means  of  promoting  human  well-being  here  and  now. 
They  frankly  reject  the  idea  of  personal  immortality  and  any  hope  or 
fear  of  the  future  life.  The  leaders  of  this  movement  have  been  John  H. 
Dietrich,  A.  Eustace  Haydon,  Charles  Francis  Potter,  Curtis  W.  Reese, 
A.  C.  Dieffenbach,  John  Haynes  Holmes,  E.  B.  Backus,  T.  C.  Abell,  Ed- 
win H.  Wilson,  and  A.  W.  Slaten.  The  Humanist  position  has  been  sup- 
ported by  able  philosophers,  such  as  John  Dewey,  James  H.  Tufts,  J.  H, 
Leuba,  Roy  W.  Sellers,  0.  L.  Reiser,  Max  C.  Otto,  John  Herman  Randall, 
Durant  Drake,  and  Corliss  Lament.  Dr.  Charles  Francis  Potter  has  pro- 


692         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 


vided  us  with  a  ten-point  contrast  between  the  views  of  orthodox  Chris- 
tianity and  those  espoused  by  Humanism : 


CHRISTIANITY 


God  created  thn  world  and  man. 

Hell  is  a  place  of  eternal  torment  for 
the  wicked. 

Heaven  is  the  place  where  good  people 
go  when  they  die. 

The  chief  end  of  man  is  to  glorify  God. 


Religion  has  to  do  with  the  supernatu- 
ral. 


Man  is  inherently  evil  and  a  worm  of 
the  dust. 

Man  should  submit  to  the  will  of  God. 


Salvation  comes  from  outside  of  man. 


The  ideas  of  sin,  salvation,  redemption, 
prayer,  and  worship  are  important. 

The  truth  is  to  be  found  in  one  religion 
only. 


HUMANISM 


The  world  and  man  evolved. 

Suffering  is  the  natural  result 
ing  the  laws  of  right  living. 


Doing  right  brings  its  own  satisfaction. 

The  chief  end  of  man  is  to  improve 
himself,  both  as  an  individual  and  as  a 
race. 

Religion  has  to  do  with  the  natural. 
The  so-called  supernatural  is  only  the 
not-yct-undcrstood  natural. 

Man  is  inherently  good  and  has  infinite 
possibilities. 

Man  should  not  submit  to  injustice  or 
suffering  without  protest  and  should 
endeavor  to  remove  its  causes. 

Improvement  comes  from  within.  No 
man  or  god  can  savo  another  man. 

These  ideas  are  unimportant  in  re- 
ligion.  

There  are  truths  in  all  religions  and 
outside  of  religion. 


The  most  extreme  deviation  from  orthodox  Christianity  is  to  be  found 
among  the  Atheists.  They  vehemently  deny  the  existence  of  God  and 
take  a  hostile  attitude  toward  all  forms  of  supernatural  religion.  They 
are  not,  however,  necessarily  opposed  to  the  effort  of  the  Humanists  to 
create  a  social  religion  devoted  to  improving  the  welfare  of  man  here 
pn  earth.  The  leaders  of  American  Atheism  have  been  Joseph  Lewis  and 
his  Free  Thinkers  Society,  and  Charles  B.  Smith  and  his  American  Asso- 
ciated for  the  Advancement  of  Atheism.  The  Atheists  have  few  actual 
and  enthusiastic  followers.  The  many  who  have  become  sceptical  of  all 
the  tenets  of  orthodoxy  are  usually  completely  indifferent  to  religion. 
They  seldom  become  affiliated  with  any  organizations  attacking  religion. 
They  take  little  interest  in  either  pro-religious  or  anti-religious  activities 
and  organizations. 

There  have  been  certain  special  religious  developments  in  the  United 
States  in  the  last  century  or  so,  such  as  the  Mormon  church,  the  Salvation 
Army,  Christian  Science,  the  New  Oxford  Movement,  and  the  like.  The 
first  three  of  these  groups  mentioned  above  are  essentially  orthodox  in 
their  religious  concepts,  the  Salvation  Army  sharing  the  views  of  other 
Christian  Fundamentalists.  The  New  Oxford  Movement,  which  has  de- 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         693 

veloped  mainly  since  the  World  War  under  the  leadership  of  the  Rev. 
Frank  N.  D.  Buchman,  represents  a  sort  of  neo-romanticism,  laying  stress 
upon  the  emotions  and  the  highly  personal  element  in  religion  and  making 
an  adroit  use  of  the  erotic  element  in  religious  conversion  and  religious 
association.  The  social  tendencies  of  the  movement  are  conservative,  if 
not  reactionary. 

Approximately  one  half  of  all  Americans  above  the  age  of  13  are  not 
affiliated  with  any  form  of  religious  organization. 

The  Conflict  of  Religion  with  Modern  Science 

Much  has  been  written  about  the  conflict  between  religion  and  science. 
Andrew  D.  White  wrote  a  very  popular  and  thoughtful  work  dealing 
comprehensively  with  the  history  of  this  important  subject.6  There  can 
be  no  intelligent  discussion  of  the  relation  of  religion  to  science  unless  we 
differentiate  between  the  attitudes  of  the  various  religious  groups  dis- 
cussed. A  complete  conflict  exists  between  fundamentalist  religion  and 
modern  science,  and  no  conflict  whatever  between  the  latter  and  Human- 
ism. 

It  is  obvious  that  many  doctrines  of  Fundamentalism  and  other  forms 
of  Christian  orthodoxy  are  contradictory  to  the  teachings  of  natural  and 
social  science.  The  orthodox  dogmas  with  respect  to  the  certainty  and 
personal  nature  of  God,  the  geocentric  theory  of  the  universe,  the  doc- 
trine of  a  special  and  recent  creation  of  the  universe  and  everything 
therein,  the  notion  that  human  life  exists  primarily  to  secure  forgiveness 
from  sin  and  a  blessed  immortality,  the  certainty  of  a  literal  and  personal 
immortality,  and  the  assurance  of  a  specific  heaven  and  hell  are  all  incom- 
patible'with  the  rudiments  of  modern  science.  It  is  true  that  orthodoxy 
does  not  forbid  activity  in  certain  fields  of  science,  such  as  geography, 
comparative  anatomy,  botany,  and  nature  study,  but  it  does  vigorously 
oppose  those  forms  of  scientific  activity  which  in  any  way  threaten  the 
integrity  of  the  Christian  epic.  For  the  most  part,  the  orthodox  are 
entirely  ignorant  of  the  more  unsettling  aspects  of  contemporary  science, 
such  as  astro-physics,  relativity,  and  psychiatry.  Hence  they  have  not 
actively  opposed  these  developments.  They  have  centered  their  attack 
chiefly  upon  Biblical  scholarship  and  the  doctrine  of  evolution.  Even 
these  are  very  incompletely  understood  by  the  orthodox. 

The  tenets  of  the  Devout  Modernists  indicate  that  even  this  group  is 
fundamentally  aligned  with  beliefs  which  are  incompatible  with  scientific 
discoveries.  The  more  enlightened  of  the  Devout  Modernists  have  made 
their  peace  with  certain  general  phases  of  nineteenth-century  science,  but 
they  have  failed  to  come  to  grips  with  the  even  more  unsettling  scientific 
revelations  of  the  twentieth.  For  example,  they  accept  the  general  theory 
of  evolution,  but  they  have  not  digested  the  implications  of  contemporary 
astro-physics.  A  book  like  Harlow  Shapley's  Flights  from  Chaos  offers 


6  A  History  of  the  Warfare  of  Science  with  Theology  in  Christendom,  2  vols., 
Appleton-Century,  1896. 


694         THE  CRISIS   IN    RELIGION   AND  MORALS 

a  more  sweeping  challenge  to  Christianity  than  did  Darwin's  Origin  of 
Species.  Other  phases  of  modern  science  of  which  the  Devout  Modernists 
have  not  taken  proper  account  are  the  new  quantum  physics  and  rela- 
tivity, the  naturalistic  explanation  of  human  conduct  provided  by  scien- 
tific psychology,  the  wholly  secular  explanation  of  religious  conversion 
provided  by  modern  psychiatry,  and  the  sociological  interpretation  of  the 
origin  and  nature  of  social  institutions,  moral  codes,  and  human  conduct. 
In  any  showdown,  the  Devout  Modernists  tend  to  line  up  with  the  Funda- 
mentalists and  orthodox  against  the  Advanced  Modernists.  As  recently 
as  1929,  a  very  liberal  and  intelligent  Devout  Modernist,  President  Henry 
Slone  Coffin  of  Union  Theological  Seminary,  called  upon  all  the  faithful 
to  rally  and  smite  Humanism  as  "the  scourge  of  Christendom."  The 
comprehensive  conflict  between  Devout  Modernism  and  the  attitudes  and 
revelations  of  twentieth-century  science  have  been  well  stated  by  John 
Herman  Randall: 

In  the  light  of  the  present  situation,  we  can  see  that  -the  19th  century  philoso* 
phies  and  liberal  theologies  made  no  real  adjustment  to  the  spirit  of  science. 
They  were  rebelling,  with  the  idealistic  thinkers  of  the  Romantic  era,  against  the 
narrowness  and  dogmatism  of  Newtonian  science;  they  naturally  sought  further 
truth  in  another  realm  by  another  method.  Even  when  they  welcomed  evolu- 
tion, they  never  saw  the  real  implications  of  its  insistence  on  man's  biological 
setting  in  a  natural  environment;  they  made  of  it  another  Romantic  faith,  with 
no  comprehension  of  what  it  ultimately  meant.  They  never  really  absorbed  the 
spirit  of  science. 

This  whole  intellectual  attitude  and  apparatus  of  liberal  religious  thinking,  still 
dominant,  with  few  exceptions,  in  modernist  circles,  is  irrelevant  today.  It  is 
irrelevant  intellectually,  because  contemporary  philosophical  thinking  has  passed 
beyond  idealism,  has  passed  beyond  creative  evolution,  has  passed  beyond  the  will 
to  believe.  Thinkers  today  are  no  longer  escaping  from  Newtonian  science;  they 
have  transformed  the  harsh  mechanism  of  the  19tn  century  into  a  scientific  world 
that  has  a  place  for  ah1  the  levels  of  human  experience,  and  concepts  for  dealing 
with  them  intellectually.  Philosophers  are  today  exploring  the  implications  of 
man's  biological  experience,  of  the  new  physics,  of  the  new  sciences  of  man.  The 
present  generation  has  seen  new  philosophies  that  base  themselves  frankly  on  an 
acceptance  of  the  scientific  spirit  and  method,  supersede  the  older  idealism  and 
evolutionary  faiths.  For  the  most  part,  liberal  religious  leaders  are  still  offering 
to  men  whose  intellectual  techniques  have  thus  changed,  a  religious  attitude  and 
a  philosophical  interpretation  of  the  religious  life  a  hundred  years  out  of  date. 

This  attitude  is  still  suspicious  of  science.  It  endeavors  to  limit  its  scope,  to 
set  bounds  to  the  realm  where  its  methods  will  apply.  There  must  be  truths 
beyond  science,  approaches  to  reality  that  will  discover,  not  only  values  and 
meanings,  but  facts  and  descriptions,  where  scientific  verification  is  impotent. 
Liberals  have  pared  away  their  faith  in  a  supernatural  governance  of  the  world 
until  less  and  less  is  left;  like  the  young  woman  who  produced  a  baby  with  no 
apparent  father,  they  apologize  that  it  is  after  all  a  very  little  baby.  They  are 
still  afraid  to  accept  the  modern  scientific  philosophies  that  frankly  acknowledge 
the  implications  of  biology,  psychology,  anthropology,  and  physics,  that  above  all 
welcome  the  tentative  and  investigating  spirit  of  scientific  thinking.  Philosophers 
have  worked  out  a  naturalistic  interpretation  of  experience  that  gives  full  scope 
to  all  the  verifiable  needs  of  the  moral  and  spiritual  life.  Religious  leaders  are 
still  ignorant  of  what  has  been  accomplished,  or  are  afraid  to  follow. 

Moreover,  the  moral  optimism  of  religious  liberalism,  its  individualism,  its 
reliance  on  the  divinity  of  man  and  nature,  is  a  weak  weapon  with  which  to  face 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         695 

the  ethical  demands  of  modern  society.  It  insists  on  the  comfortable  reality  of 
God  and  Heaven,  but  it  shrinks  from  the  harder  facts  of  the  Devil  and  Hell.  It 
is  apt  to  assume  complacently  that  all  is  right  with  the  world,  and  to  gloss  over 
the  disagreeable  call  to  make  it  better.  It  lends  itself  far  more  easily  to  the 
smug  middle-class  worship  of  prosperity  than  to  the  vital  religious  impulses  at 
the  basis  of  our  humanitarian  and  social  faiths.  .  . 

Judged,  therefore,  in  the  light  of  present  intellectual  and  social  needs,  it  can 
hardly  be  said  that  the  mediating  compromise  of  liberal  religion  in  recent  times 
has  been  as  successful  as  the  great  historic  reconstructions  of  the  past.  Most 
modernist  leaders  are  still  thinking  in  terms  that  are  irrelevant  to  the  serious 
thought  of  today;  they  are  merely  acquiescing  in  the  passing  social  and  moral 
ideals  of  the  day,  with  little  attempt  at  illuminating  criticism.  It  is  apparent  to 
the  sympathetic  observer  that  such  religious  thought  and  life  is  still  serving  well 
those  who  have  in  their  own  lives  broken  from  rigid  orthodoxy.  But  it  is  equally 
apparent  that  present-day  modernism  must  undergo  great  transformations  before 
it  can  hope  to  satisfy  the  religious  needs  of  our  civilization.7 

Many  friends  of  conventional  religion  have  taken  heart  of  late  because 
certain  eminent  scientists  have  assumed  the  role  of  liberal  theologians. 
Among  the  best  known  have  been  the  English  mathematician,  Alfred  N. 
Whitehcad,  the  able  English  astro-physicist,  Arthur  S.  Eddington,  the 
eminent  British  biologist,  the  late  J.  Arthur  Thomson,  the  brilliant  Ameri- 
can physicists,  Robert  A.  Millikan  and  the  late  Michael  I.  Pupin,  the 
prominent  zoologist,  the  late  Henry  Fairfield  Osborn,  and  the  Harvard 
geologist,  Kirtley  F.  Mather.  These  men,  and  many  others  of  their  kind, 
have  valiantly  proclaimed  that  there  is  no  conflict  between  science  and 
religion.  A  particularly  confident  expression  of  this  point  of  view  was 
set  forth  by  the  late  Professor  M.  I.  Pupin: 

Science  is  making  us  better  Christians. 

Science  teaches  us  that  the  Universe  is  guided  by  an  intelligent  Divinity. 

Science  is  teaching  men  how  to  cooperate  intelligently  with  God;  it  is  teaching 
men  what  his  laws  are  and  how  to  obey  them. 

Science  is  proving  that  the  human  soul  is  the  greatest  thing  in  the  Universe;  the 
supreme  purpose  of  the  Creator. 

Science  is  leading  us  closer  and  closer  to  God. 

Science  has  made  us  better  homes  and  is  teaching  us  how  to  make  a  better  de- 
mocracy and  a  better  social  life ;  it  is  thus  preparing  us  for  the  greatest  spiritual, 
artistic  and  intellectual  life  that  men  have  ever  known. 

Science  does  not  contradict  belief  in  the  immortality  of  the  human  soul. 

Science  is  revealing  God  in  greater  and  greater  glory,  and  teaches  us  that  in 
time  we  may  possibly  even  see  Him  face  to  face  .  .  . 

President  Nicholas  Murray  Butler,  of  Columbia  University,  is  reported  to  have 
said  recently  that,  while  talking  with  Dr.  Pupin,  he  felt  that  he  was  witnessing  the 
curtain  being  lifted  upon  a  new  and  brighter  world :  "I  believe  he  would  make  you 
feel  the  same  way,  and  I  should  like  to  convey  that  feeling  to  you  through  his  own 
words."  8 

It  is  usually  assumed  that  these  scientists  speak  with  as  much  authority 
upon  religion  as  they  do  upon  science.  But  James  Harvey  Robinson  has 
suggested  that  their  views  on  religion  are  nothing  more  than  a  hangover 


7  Randall,  op.  cit.,  pp.  124-126. 

8  Cited  by  A.  E.  Wjgga,m,  Exploring  Your  Mind  with  the  Psychologists,  Bobbs 
Merrill,  1930,  pp.  38^-386. 


696         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

of  their  youthful  impressions,  which  they  share  with  William  Jennings 
Bryan  and  Billy  Sunday: 

Bryan  exhibited  through  his  life  no  more  knowledge  of  religious  matters  than 
he  could  have  easily  acquired  at  ten  years  of  age.  Sermons  of  the  commoner  sort 
contain  only  what  both  preacher  and  audience  accepted  before  they  were  grown 
up.  Religion  does  not  tend  to  mature  in  most  cases.  It  is  what  we  learned  at 
our  mother's  knee.  In  later  life  we  are  preoccupied  with  business  and  amuse- 
ment, and  there  is  no  time  to  keep  up  with  the  course  of  religious  investigation, 
even  if  we  had  the  slightest  disposition  to  do  so.  Billy  Sunday  talks  as  a  big 
husky  boy  to  other  boys  and  girls.  Even  distinguished  scientific  men  solemnly 
diHCMiss  the  relation  of  religion  to  science,  when,  if  they  but  stopped  to  think,  they 
would  find  that  they  were  assuming  that  they  know  all  about  religion,  without 
having  given  it  much  thought  since  childhood;  although  they  would  readily 
admit  that  after  a  lifetime's  work  they  knew  very  little  about  science.9 

The  essential  innocence  of  these  apologetic  scientists  with  respect  to  the 
bearing  of  scientific  discoveries  upon  religion  has  been  forcefully  stated  by 
John  Herman  Randall,  Jr.: 

It  is  true  that  many  physicists  have  recently  blossomed  forth  as  liberal  theo- 
logians. Aware  that  modern  physics  has  abandoned  doctrines  that  were  once 
hostile  to  religious  claims,  they  imagine  that  there  is  no  further  conflict  between 
religion  and  science.  But  they  are  abysmally  ignorant  of  all  that  anthropology 
and  psychology  have  discovered  about  the  nature  of  religion  itself.  They  are 
ignorant  of  the  serious  philosophies  that  have  built  upon  such  ^  data.  They  do 
not  realize  that  the  present  conflict  of  religious  faith  with  science  is  no  longer  with 
a  scientific  explanation  of  the  world,  but  with  a  scientific  explanation  of  religion. 
The  really  revolutionary  effect  of  the  scientific  faith  on  religion  today  is  not  its 
new  view  of  the  universe,  but  its  .new  view  of  religion.  Reinterpretations  of 
religious  belief  have  been  unimportant  compared  with  reinterpreta^ions  of  religion 
itself.  For  those  who  share  them,  it  has  become  impossible  to  view  religion  as  a 
divine  revelation  entrusted  to  man.  It  has  even  become  impossible  to  see  it  as 
a  relation  between  man  and  a  cosmic  deity.  Religion  has  rather  appeared  a 
human  enterprise,  an  organization  of  human  life,  an  experience,  a  social  bond  and 
an  aspiration.10 

Moreover,  when  one  of  these  scientific  reconcilers  gives  thoughtful 
attention  to  religion,  it  is  usually  found  that  he  does  not  have  in  mind 
orthodoxy  but  some  abstruse  form  of  philosophical  contemplation.  A.  N. 
Whitehead  has  frequently  been  held  up  as  one  of  the  eminent  scientists 
who  support  contemporary  religion.  But  we  actually  find  that  few 
Atheists  have  been  more  severe  in  their  judgment  of  orthodoxy  than  has 
Professor  Whitehead.  This  will  appear  from  his  characterization  of  the 
religions  of  the  past,  including  historical  Christianity: 

History,  down  to  the  present  day,  is  a  melancholy  record  of  the  horrors  which 
can  attend  religion:  human  sacrifice,  and  in  particular  the  slaughter  of  children, 
cannibalism,  sensual  orgies,  abject  superstition,  hatred  as  between  races,  the 
maintenance  of  degrading  customs,  hysteria,  bigotry,  can  all  be  laid  at  its  charge. 
Religion  is  the  last  refuge  of  human  savagery.11 


»  The  Human  Comedy,  Harper,  1937,'  pp.  318-319. 

1°  J.  H.  Randall,  Jr.,  in  Current  History,  June,  1929,  p.  360. 

11  Religion  in  the  Making,  Macmillan,  1926. 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         697 

The  fundamental  incompatibility  between  all  forms  of  conventional 
religion  and  the  methods  and  attitudes  of  natural  science  has  been  effec- 
tively stated  by  Clifford  Kirkpatrick: 

It  should  be  noted  that  it  is  rather  the  method  and  philosophy  of  science  than 
science  itself  which  is  incompatible  with  religion,  although  the  facts  of  science 
certainly  contradict  the  belief  phase  of  most  religions,  especially  the  Hebrew- 
Babylonian  account  of  creation  and  cosmology.  Science  rests  upon  certain  prac- 
tical and  useful  philosophical  assumptions  and  as  a  rule  develops  through  the 
efforts  of  men  using  certain  methods  and  entertaining  certain  attitudes.  These 
assumptions,  methods,  and  attitudes  are  so  closely  associated  with  the  conceptual 
system  of  science  itself  that  the  whole  sociologically,  if  not  logically,  constitutes  a 
single  culture  pattern.  Let  us  examine  some  of  the  contrasts  between  religion 
and  this  culture  pattern  formed  by  the  union  of  naturalistic  philosophy,  the 
scientific  method,  and  the  body  of  science. 

( 1 )  Science  is  nourished  by  the  active  use  of  the  scientific  method  involving 
observation,  experimentation,  induction,  deduction,  and  verification.    Religion 
rests  upon  passive  faith. 

(2)  Science  is  based  upon  the  principle  of  induction  which  is  the  assumption 
that  a  repetition  of  events  implies  a  further  repetition  of  these  events.    Further- 
more, in  spite  of  the  scepticism  of  Hume  and  his  follower,  Pearson,  scientists 
usually  assume  an  external  reality  organized  in  an  orderly  manner.    In  brief, 
science  is  associated  with  a  philosophy  of  determinism,  the  assumption  that  there 
are  no  uncaused  phenomena,  that  given  a  certain  set  of  conditions  a  certain 
result  must  inevitably  follow.    Religion,  on  the  other  hand,  commonly  if  not 
invariably  implies  the  existence  of  powers  which  interfere  by  miracle  and  revela- 
tion with  the  laws  of  the  universe. 

(3)  Science  recognizes  no  personal  powers  in  the  universe  responsive  to  the 
prayers  and  needs  of  men.    Belief  in  mysterious  powers  which  constitutes,  ac- 
cording to  our  definition,  the  conceptual  aspect  of  religion  is  usually  an  animistic 
belief  in  personal  powers.    Science  in  effect  denies  the  existence  of  spiritual  beings 
which  religion  affirms. 

(4)  Science  is  critical  and  agnostic  while  religion  is  credulous.    The  scientist 
accepts  nothing  save  proven  existential  facts  of  fruitful  hypotheses,  while  for  the 
conventionally  religious  person  faith  is  a  virtue  and  doubt  a  vice. 

(5)  Science  is  based  upon  disciplined  thought  which  demands  exact  definitions 
and  precise  terms  as  well  as  a  logical  manipulation  of  concepts.    Religion  makes 
use  of  vague  symbolism  and  of  terms  which  are  suffused  with  emotion  and  serve 
as  a  means  of  communicating  feeling  rather  than  an  intellectual  currency. 

(6)  Science  deals  only  with  observations,  that  is  to  say,  existential  facts  and 
their  relationships  rather  than  with  judgments  or  values.    Religion,  on  the  other 
hand,  in  common  with  philosophy,  deals  with  values.    Dean  Inge  would  deny  this 
point,  claiming  that  the  attributes  of  ultimate  reality  are  values  and  that  even 
science  is  based  on  such  values  as  coherence,  uniformity  and  commensurability. 
As  has  been  previously  pointed  out,  culture  patterns  such  as  that  of  religion 
merge  into  one  another  and  yet  there  is  a  difference  of  no  small  degree  between 
science  and  religion  in  this  respect. 

(7)  Science  represses  rationalization,  wishful  thinking  and  the  various  forms 
of  bias,  while  religion  gives  expression  to  such  attitudes  and  modes  of  thought. 

(8)  The  thought  content  of  science  is  dynamic,  ever  changing  in  the  direction 
of  new  harmonies.    Religious  belief  tends  to  harden  into  dogma  and  to  remain 
static  even  in  the  face  of  changing  conditions. 

(9)  In  its  emotional  aspects  likewise,  the  naturalistic-scientific  culture  pattern 
stands  contrasted  to  that  of  religion.    With  scientific  achievement  there  comes 
an  expansion  of  the  ego,  a  sense  of  triumph  at  having  wrested  from  nature  some 
of  her  cherished  secrets.    It  is  true  that  Newton  pictured  himself  as  a  child  pick- 
ing up  the  brighter  pebbles  along  the  shores  of  the  vast  ocean  of  truth,  and 


698         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

scientists  of  a  mystical  turn  of  mind  have  entered  into  humble  communion  with 
nature.  Nevertheless,  in  religion  there  tends  to  be  a  greater  contraction  of  the 
ego  and  reverence  passes  readily  to  awe,  self-abasement,  a  feeling  of  loss  of  person- 
ality and  of  absolute  dependence.  One  might  venture  a  guess  that  scientists  tend 
to  the  extrovert,  and  the  religiously-minded  to  the  introvert  type,  but  this  is  mere 
speculation  with  vague  terms. 

(10)  The  scientist  while  aware  of  the  wondrous  in  the  universe  is  inclined  to 
deny  the  existence  of  mystery  and  seeks  to  remove  it  in  so  far  as  possible  by 
research.    Religion  on  the  other  hand  is  bathed  in  mystery  which  it  often 
cherishes  for  its  own  sake. 

(11)  In  regard  to  overt  behavior  as  well  as  thought  and  feeling,  science  stands 
in  contrast  to  religion.    The  scientist  moving  calmly  among  the  instruments  of  his 
laboratory  hardly  reminds  one  of  a  participant  in  a  Saturnalian  orgy  or  even  of 
the  priest  presiding  over  the  miracle  of  transubstaritiation.    Ritual,  on  the  other 
hand,  deals  with  objects  arid  processes  stooped  in  emotional  value.    Even  if  the 
ritual  be  lifeless  and  devoid  of  its  original  emotional  appeal  it  still  stands  con- 
trasted to  scientific  procedure  in  that  it  is  stereotyped  and  formal,  while  experi- 
mental methods  are  ever  changing  in  response  to  the  new  problems  on  the  fron- 
tier of  knowledge. 

If  it  be  objected  that  those  contrasts  do  not  mean  incompatibility,  since  science 
and  religion  huve  coexisted  and  scientists  have  boon  religious,  it  is  necessary  to 
define  the  term  incompatibility  more  closely.  Within  the  individual  personality 
two  patterns  of  thought,  feeling  and  overt  behavior  are  incompatible  when  there 
is  mental  conflict  and  reciprocal  modification  of  the  systems  under  conditions  in 
which  the  patterns  are  not  dissociated  or  compartmentalized  one  from  another. 
If  the  biologist  who  is  an  evolutionist,  a  mechanist  and  a  thoroughgoing  deter- 
minist  in  his  laboratory  is,  while  in  church,  a  believer  in  special  creation,  the 
Virgin  Birth,  miracles  and  bodily  resurrection  of  the  dead,  it  is  only  because  two 
aspects  of  his  personality  arc  separated.  If  brought  into  contact  in  the  course  of 
discussion  or  during  preparation  of  a  statement  of  his  views,  a  reorganization 
would  be  necessary.12 

There  is  little  possibility  for  conflict  between  Advanced  Modernism 
and  science,  particularly  between  Humanism  and  science,  because  Hu- 
manists frankly  base  their  religion  upon  the  findings  of  contemporary  sci- 
ence, especially  those  phases  of  science  which  deal  most  directly  with 
man.  Occasionally,  an  Advanced  Modernist  exhibits  a  certain  yearning 
for  the  doctrine  of  free  will,  but,  in  general,  this  group  has  brought  its 
thought  thoroughly  into  keeping  with  scientific  attitudes  and  discoveries. 
However,  the  Advanced  Modernists  are  numerically  only  the  merest  drop 
in  the  bucket  when  compared  with  the  more  than  54  millions  listed  as  re- 
ligious believers  and  church  communicants  in  the  United  States.  There 
are,  for  example,  only  a  little  over  60,000  Unitarians  in  the  country. 
There  are  about  55,000  Universalists,  so  that  it  is  probable  that  there 
are  not  more  than  150,000  church-going  Advanced  Modernists  in  the 
country  as  a  whole,  to  make  a  very  liberal  estimate. 

Therefore,  it  is  apparent  that  there  is  a  marked  conflict  between  science 
and  the  religious  beliefs  of  the  overwhelming  majority  of  religious  com- 
municants in  the  United  States  today.  Except  in  the  case  of  the  militant 
Fundamentalists  and  certain  of  the  more  aggressive  of  the  Catholic  group, 


12  Reprinted  by  permission  from  Religion  in  Human  Affairs,  by  C.  Kirkpatrick, 
published  by  John  Wiley  &  Sons,  Inc.,  1929,  pp.  469-472. 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         699 

however,  this  conflict  between  religion  and  science  does  not  normally 
take  the  form  of  vigorous  practical  opposition  to  scientific  activities. 
Scientists  are  rarely  openly  persecuted  for  their  beliefs  today.  Herein 
lies  the  great  difference  between  our  age  and  the  previous  millennium  or 
more.  However,  the  scholars  who  attempt  to  popularize  modern  scien- 
tific notions  or  to  show  their  implications  for  religion  and  ethics  are  in 
danger  of  dismissal  from  many  institutions  of  learning  and  of  exclusion 
from  many  others.  The  promulgation  of  scientific  views  in  the  public 
schools  is  still  highly  precarious  when  they  touch  upon  human  and  social 
problems.  Exposition  of  the  implications  of  the  biological,  psychologi- 
cal, and  social  sciences  is  far  more  hazardous  than  the  teaching  of  the 
physical  sciences.  The  latter  are  almost  immune  from  religious  interfer- 
ence in  the  United  States  today. 

A  common  rationalization  by  the  timid  and  evasive  among  both  re- 
ligionists and  scientists  is  the  assertion  that  there  is  no  real  conflict 
between  science  and  religion ;  whatever  conflict  there  is  lies  between  sci- 
ence and  theology.  This  is  akin  to  saying  that  while  there  is  no  conflict 
between  religion  and  medicine,  there  may  be  a  conflict  between  religion 
and  surgery.  As  we  have  made  clear  earlier  in  this  chapter,  one  cannot 
separate  religion  from  theology.  Theology  is  the  conceptual  or  intellec- 
tual side  of  religion,  that  which  formulates  the  ideas  underlying  and 
rationalizing  religious  practices.  It  is  obvious  that  science,  as  a  body 
of  intellectual  concepts,  is  most  likely  to  contact,  and  come  into  conflict 
with  religion  through  the  field  of  theology.  Any  conflict  between  science 
and  theology  is  necessarily  a  conflict  between  science  and  religion. 

The  Humanizing  of  Religion 

One  of  the  most  commendable  religious  developments  in  recent  times 
has  been  the  growing  concern  of  religion  with  the  well-being  of  man  here 
on  earth.  As  we  have  noted,  the  Humanists  are  solely  interested  in  this 
phase  of  religious  activity.  But  those  groups  primarily  concerned  with 
the  soul  of  man  and  his  destiny  in  the  future  life  are  also  showing  an 
increasing  interest  in  the  improvement  of  human  conditions  here  on  earth. 
An  epoch-making  event  in  the  history  of  Catholic  policy  came  in  1891 
when  Pope  Leo  XIII  issued  his  famous  encyclical,  Rcrum  Novarum, 
expressing  solicitude  for  the  welfare  of  labor.  The  Catholic  Social  Wel- 
fare Council,  led  by  Father  John  A.  Ryan,  has  taken  an  active  part  in 
supporting  progressive  social  legislation  in  the  United  States.  Certain 
Catholic  leaders  have,  however,  placed  religious  strategy  ahead  of  human 
welfare  as  is  evidenced  by  the  opposition  of  powerful  members  of  the 
Catholic  hierarchy  to  the  pending  child  labor  amendment.  Indeed,  even 
Father  Ryan  has  made  it  clear  that  when  the  dogmas  of  the  Church  con- 
flict with  social  reform  movements  as,  for  instance,  with  birth-control,  the 
former  take  precedence. 

Among  the  Protestants,  the  Methodist  denomination  has,  of  late,  shown 
a  special  concern  with  the  relief  of  poverty  and  such  changes  in  the  eco- 
nomic order  as  are  necessary  to  increase  the  income  of  the  masses  and  to 


700         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

lessen  unemployment.  Bishop  Francis  J.  McConnell  has  been  an  out- 
standing leader  in  this  movement.  He  was  the  chief  bulwark  standing 
behind  the  famous  Report  on  the  Steel  Strike  of  1919  y  made  by  the  Inter- 
church  World  Movement.  But  the  power  of  reactionary  economic  forces 
over  American  religion  was  made  evident  through  the  fact  that,  after  this 
report  was  made,  the  Inter-church  World  Movement  was  broken  up. 

A  number  of  leaders  in  social  reform  have  concluded  that  organized 
Christianity  is  fundamentally  opposed  to  social  change  and  social  better- 
ment. Hence  they  propose  to  appeal  over  the  head  of  organized  Chris- 
tianity to  what  they  believe  to  be  the  revolutionary  teachings  of  Jesus. 
The  leaders  of  this  group  are  such  men  as  Kirby  Page,  Sherwood  Eddy, 
Harry  Ward,  Jerome  Davis,  Charles  Ellwood,  S.  Ralph  Harlow  and 
David  D.  Vaughan.  The  most  aggressive  figure  in  this  movement  is 
Sherwood  Eddy,  who  thus  summarizes  his  program: 

Believing  in  Jesus'  way  of  life  and  in  his  all-inclusive  principle  of  love  as  the  full 
sharing  of  life,  I  therefore  determine  to  apply  this  principle  in  all  the  relationships 
of  life: 

(1)  To  live  simply  and  sacrificially,  avoiding  waste  and  luxury.    To  make  the 
purpose  of  my  life  the  making  of  men  rather  than  the  making  of  money.    Not 
to  grow  rich  in  a  poor  world  by  laying  up  treasures  for  myself  but  to  share  all 
with  my  fellow  men.    To  apply  the  golden  rule  in  all  my  relationships. 

(2)  To  practice  brotherhood  toward  all.    To  remember  that  every  human 
being  is  a  person  of  infinite  worth,  deserving  the  fullest  opportunity  for  self- 
development.    To  participate  in  no  secret  order  or  fraternity  if  it  tends  to  exclu- 
siveness,  prejudice  or  strife.    To  seek  justice  for  every  man  without  distinction 
of  caste  or  color. 

(3)  To  make  peace  where  there  is  strife;  to  seek  to  outlaw  war,  "the  world's 
chief  collective  sin/'  as  piracy  and  slavery  have  already  been  outlawed,  substitut- 
ing a  positive  program  of  international  justice  and  good  will. 

(4)  To  redeem  the  social  order;  to  test  its  evils  by  the  principle  of  love  and 
fearlessly  to  challenge  them  as  Jesus  challenged  the  money-changers  in  the  tem- 
ple.   To  endeavor  to  replace  them  by  the  constructive  building  of  a  new  social 
order,  the  Kingdom  of  God  on  earth.    If  a  student,  to  apply  this  purpose  im- 
mediately to  the  problems  of  our  campus;  to  seek  education  as  training  for  service 
rather  than  the  mere  enjoyment  of  privilege,  the  attainment  of  grades  or  the 
achievement  of  cheap  "success";  to  tolerate  no  dishonest  practices  in  classroom, 
athletics  or  college  elections;  to  maintain  no  relationships  with  my  fellows,  men 
or  women,  which  violate  absolute  purity  or  debase  the  divine  value  of  personality. 
Since  I  realize  my  inability  to  achieve  this  way  of  life  unaided : 

(5)  To  seek  a  new  discovery  of  God  which  will  release  within  my  life  new 
springs  of  power  such  as  men  in  the  past  have  experienced  when  they  rediscov- 
ered the  religion  of  Jesus. 

A  still  more  liberal  view  of  religion  heartily  approves  such  a  program 
of  social  betterment,  but  criticizes  its  sponsors  for  insisting  that  it  must 
be  inspired  by  the  teachings  of  Jesus.  This  point  was  made  very  effec- 
tively by  Paul  Blanshard,  in  commenting  upon  the  attitude  of  Harry  F. 
Ward: 

What  I  object  to  in  his  treatment  is  the  constant  dragging  in  of  "the  ethic 
of  Jesus."  Is  it  necessary  for  a  professor  in  a  theological  seminary  to  pretend 
that  a  sound  economic  morality  must  come  from  Jesus?  Anyone  who  reads  the 
Gospels  with  an  impartial  eye  will  discover  that  Jesus's  teaching  concerning  eco- 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         701 

nomic  values  was  confused,  fragmentary,  and  quite  inapplicable  to  a  world  of 
tickers,  billionaires,  and  communists.  What  Mr.  Ward  really  means  by  the 
"ethic  of  Jesus"  is  the  ethic  of  Harry  F.  Ward,  and  I  don't  see  why  he  should 
be  so  modest  about  saying  so.13 

The  Humanists  go  the  whole  way  in  humanizing  religion  and  declare 
it  unnecessary  to  appeal  to  Jesus  to  justify  a  program  of  social  reform, 
designed  to  improve  the  earthly  well-being  of  man.  They  believe  in  the 
supreme  worth  of  man,  and  hold  that  better  social  conditions  are  justified 
by  the  beneficent  effect  upon  man  himself.  This  attitude  of  Humanism 
has  been  summarized  by  John  H.  Dietrich: 

1.  Humanism  believes  in  the  supreme  worth  of  human  life,  and  that  man  there- 
fore must  be  treated  as  an  end,  not  as  a  means  to  some  other  end.    Man  is  the 
highest  product  of  the  creative  process  which  conies  within  our  knowledge,  and 
therefore  Humanism  recognizes  nothing  which  commands  a  higher  allegiance.  .  .  . 

2.  Humanism  is  the  effort  to  understand  human  experience  by  means  of  human 
inquiry.    This  stands  in  direct  contrast  to  the  method  of  the  older  religions,  which 
is  known  as  revelation.  .  .  . 

3.  Humanism  is  the  effort  to  enrich  human  experience  to  the  utmost  capacity 
of  man  and  of  his  environment;  that  is,  the  primary  concern  of  Humanism  is 
human  development.    It  has  no  blind  faith  in  the  perfectibility  of  man,  but  it 
believes  that  his  present  condition  can  be  immeasurably  improved.  .  .  . 

4.  Humanism  accepts  the  responsibility  for  the  conditions  of  human  life  and 
relies  entirely  upon  human  effort  for  their  improvement.    The  Humanist  makes 
no  attempt  to  shove  the  responsibility  for  the  present  miserable  conditions  of 
human  life  onto  some  God  or  some  cosmic  order.    He  fully  realizes  that  the  situ- 
ation is  in  our  own  hands,  and  that  practically  all  the  evils  of  the  world  have  been 
brought  upon  men  by  themselves.  .  .  . 

5.  He  frankly  assumes  the  responsibility  for  the  way  in  which  our  social  life 
is  regulated,  and  knows  that  if  such  flagrant  and  horrible  miscarriages  of  justice 
as  we  have  recently  witnessed  are  to  be  avoided,  man  himself  must  create  the 
machinery.14 

The  Humanists  courageously  advocate  specific  measures  which  they 
believe  are  essential  to  the  creation  of  a  civilized  social  order.  As  good 
a  statement  of  these  as  any  is  set  forth  by  Charles  Francis  Potter: 

1.  The  cultivation  of  international  and  inter-racial  amity. 

2.  The  legalizing  of  birth  control. 

3.  The  improvement  and  extension  of  education. 

4.  The  raising  of  cultural  standards. 

5. 'The  correlation  of  cultural  agencies. 

6.  The  defense  of  freedom  of  speech. 

7.  The  encouragement  of  art,  music,  drama,  the  dance,  and  all  other  means  of 
self-expression. 

8.  The  elevation  of  the  ethical  standards  of  moving  pictures. 

9.  The  promotion  of  public  health. 

10.  The  checking  of  standardization  ia  cases  where  it  injures  the  individual. 

11.  The  improvement  of  methods  of  dealing  with  criminals. 

12.  The  improvement  of  means  of  communication. 

13.  The  abolition  of  religious  subsidies. 

14.  The  improvement  of  industrial  conditions. 

15.  The  extension  of  social  insurance. 


"  The  Nation,  July  10,  1929. 

14  "The  Advance  of  Humanism,"  Sermon,  privately  printed,  October,  1927. 


702         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

16.  The  establishment  of  full  sex  equality. 

17.  The  extension  of  child  welfare  measures. 

18.  The  purification  of  politics. 

19.  The  abolition  of  special  privilege. 

20.  The  conservation  of  natural  resources  for  the  people. 

21.  The  substitution  of  temperance  for  prohibition.15 

Religion  has  never  been  primarily  interested  in  the  welfare  of  man. 
It  has  relied  almost  exclusively  upon  supernatural  power,  and,  since  the 
rise  of  Christianity,  it  has  been  chiefly  concerned  with  the  future  life. 
Humanism  repudiates  the  slightest  thought  of  supernatural  assistance  and 
is  entirely  concerned  with  bettering  human  conditions  here  and  now.  It 
is,  however,  a  real  question  whether  so  rational  a  religion,  divorced  from 
the  supernatural,  can  sufficiently  grip  the  imagination  of  man  to  gain 
many  followers. 

Some  students  of  religion  believe  that,  if  we  ever  have  any  popular 
secular  religions  in  the  future,  they  will  take  the  form  of  Fascism  and 
Communism,  which  are  organized  for  mass  emotional  appeal.  Fascism 
and  Communism  have  shown  many  similarities  to  the  older  religions. 
Communism  has  its  Trinity — with  Marx,  the  Father;  Lenin,  the  Son;  and 
Stalin,  the  Holy  Ghost — its  sacred  places,  its  saints  and  especially  sanc- 
tified groups  or  classes,  and  a  dogmatic  (Marxian)  philosophy  of  history 
comparable  to  the  Christian  Epic.  The  Nazis  have  deified  Hitler,  made 
saints  of  the  men  killed  in  the  party's  struggle  for  power,  and  revived  the 
ancient  Aryan  mythology,  in  conjunction  with  their  secular  program  and 
propaganda. 

The  Role  of  Religion  and  the  Church  in 
Modern   Life 

It  follows,  as  a  matter  of  course,  that  the  great  changes  brought  about 
in  the  intellectual  status  of  orthodox  religion  and  Devout  Modernism  by 
science  and  critical  thought  make  it  desirable  to  reexamine  the  place  of 
religion  and  the  function  of  the  church  in  contemporary  society. 

In  the  first  place,  it  is  evident  that  the  clergyman  can  no  longer  pre- 
'tend  to  be  a  competent  expert  in  the  way  of  discovering  the  nature,  will, 
and  operations  of  any  possible  cosmic  God.  The  theologian,  at  best,  can 
be  only  a  competent  second-  or  third-hand  interpreter  of  the  facts  and 
implications  about  the  cosmos  and  its  laws  gathered  by  specialists  in 
science  and  philosophy.  In  the  old  days,  when  it  was  thought  that  God 
might  be  reached  and  understood  through  prayer,  sacrifice,  or  revelation, 
the  clergyman  or  theologian  was  indeed  the  "man  of  God"  who  could 
make  clear  the  will  of  the  Deity  to  believers.  But  now,  when  God  must 
be  sought  in  terms  of  the  findings  of  the  test-tube,  the  compound  micro- 
scope, the  interferometer,  the  radium  tube,  and  Einstein's  equations,  the 
average  clergyman  is  hopelessly  out  of  place  in  the  search.  Therefore, 


15  Humanism,  a  New  Religion,  Simon  and  Schuster,  1930,  pp.  124-125. 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         703 

the  intelligent  and  educated  theologians  must  surrender  their  age-long 
pretension  to  special,  if  not  unique,  competence  in  clearing  up  the  problem 
of  the  nature  of  God  and  His  laws.  They  can,  at  best,  be  little  more  than 
ringside  spectators  of  the  observatory  and  the  laboratory. 

We  may  concede  the  contention  that  theology  is  a  very  important  phase 
of  religion,  but  we  can  scarcely  admit  that  there  is  today  any  function 
for  the  independent  and  sovereign  theologian.  The  presentation  of  "or- 
derly and  systematic  ideas  about  religion"  must  now  be  looked  upon  as 
the  province  of  the  social  scientist  and  social  philosopher. 

Next  to  the  revelation  of  the  nature  of  God  and  His  ways,  the  most 
honored  function  of  the  minister  has  been  to  unravel  God's  will  with 
respect  to  human  conduct.  He  then  could  indicate  the  absolute  principles 
which  should  guide  personal  morality,  in  order  that  the  soul  of  the  indi- 
vidual might  be  assured  of  an  ultimate  refuge  in  the  New  Jerusalem. 
This  was  a  perfectly  rational  and  logical  function  for  religion  when  it  was 
commonly  assumed:  (l)'that  the  purpose  of  moral  conduct  is  to  insure 
the  salvation  of  the  soul,  and  (2)  that  the  supreme  and  complete  guide  to 
moral  living  is  to  be  discovered  in  Holy  Scriptures. 

There  seems  to  be  no  ground  whatever  for  the  orthodox  views  of  a 
bodily  or  spiritual  immortality  and  the  imminence  of  a  literal  heaven  and 
hell.  Hence  the  basic  objective  of  right  living  can  no  longer  be  regarded 
as  the  assurance  of  spiritual  salvation.  On  the  contrary,  the  scientists' 
discoveries  have  shown  that  the  fundamental  purpose  of  the  good  life  is 
to  secure  the  maximum  amount  of  happiness  for  the  greatest  possible 
number  here  upon  this  earth. 

Extensive  research  has  shown  the  Bible  to  be  not  a  series  of  divine  reve- 
lations but  a  historical  record  of  an  evolving  culture.  It  is  plain,  there- 
fore, that  accurate  guidance  to  the  good  life  in  our  complex  society  cannot 
be  sought  in  the  Scriptures  or  provided  by  specialists  in  Holy  Writ.  The 
moral  code  of  the  future  must  be  supplied  by  the  specialists  in  mundane 
happiness,  namely,  biologists,  physiologists,  psychiatrists,  educators,  so- 
cial scientists,  and  the  students  and  practitioners  of  esthetics. 

Some  who  frankly  admit  the  incompetence  of  the  clergyman  and  the 
theologian  in  the  way  of  providing  original  and  conclusive  guidance  to  the 
best  conduct  for  a  happy  life  on  earth  contend,  nevertheless,  that  religion 
can  exercise  a  very  valuable  service  in  interpreting  and  popularizing 
the  findings  of  scientific  specialists.  This  may  be  true,  to  a  certain  ex- 
tent, but  many  qualifications  would  have  to  be  noted.  Many  phases  of 
guidance  to  complete  human  happiness  would  necessarily  be  a  highly 
technical  and  individual  matter,  to  be  handled  by  medical  and  other  ex- 
perts in  relation  to  individual  cases  and  problems,  and  would  scarcely  be 
adapted  to  comprehensive  general  interpretation  or  exhortation. 

A  case  can  be  made  for  the  service  which  may  be  rendered  by  religion 
in  inculcating  an  interest  in,  and  respect  for,  such  broad  and  scarcely 
debatable  moral  conceptions  as  justice,  honesty,  pacifism,  cooperation, 
kindliness,  and  beauty.  Kirsopp  Lake  has  stated  the  case  for  the  desira- 
bility of  having  religion  relinquish  interest  in  sumptuary  moral  control 


704         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

and  assume  responsibility  for  the  advancement  of  more  profound  and  gen- 
eral moral  principles: 

One  man  may  find  much  comfort  in  tobacco,  while  another  may  injure  himself 
by  smoking;  one  may  err  by  playing  too  much,  and  another  by  never  playing  at 
all.  I  doubt  whether  the  men  of  tomorrow  will  try  to  interfere  with  each  other 
on  these  points,  knowing  that  the  thing  which  matters  is  ability  to  do  good  work, 
and  that  one  man  can  do  his  best  work  in  one  way,  another  otherwise.  Many  of 
the  things  Puritans  condemn  are  strictly  indifferent.  The  religion  of  tomorrow 
will  recognize  this,  it  will  give  good  advice  to  individuals,  but  not  lay  down  general 
rules  for  universal  observance. 

On  the  other  hand,  it  may  have  a  sterner  standard  in  business,  industry  and 
finance.  It  may  insist  more  loudly  that  honesty  applies  to  the  spirit  of  business, 
not  merely  to  its  letter.  It  may  even  demand  that  men  must  be  as  trustworthy 
in  advertisements,  business  announcements  and  journalistic  reporting  as  they  are 
in  private  affairs.  For  those  are  the  questions  of  morals  which  are  the  issues 
of  life  and  death  for  the  future.  They  are  not  covered  by  the  teaching  of  Jesus 
or  of  historic  Christianity,  for  neither  ever  discussed  problems  which  did  not  exist 
in  their  time.  Some  of  the  principles  which  have  been  laid  down  by  them  will 
play  a  part  in  the  solution  of  these  problems  but  probably  others  will  also  be 
needed,  certainly  the  actual  solutions  will  contain  new  elements,  and  the  religion 
of  tomorrow  will  have  to  look  for  them.18 

However,  it  can  scarcely  be  expected  that  the  custodians  of  the  modern 
order,  who  provide  the  chief  pecuniary  support  for  our  religious  institu- 
tions and  organizations,  will  contribute  with  enthusiasm  to  a  movement 
designed  to  cut  at  the  root  of  many  business  principles  and  practices 
which  they  hold  indispensablQ  for  the  creation  of  wealth  and  power.  Be- 
fore religion  could  achieve  much,  it  would  be  necessary  to  carry  on  a  very 
positive  program  of  education  in  the  principles  of  social  ethics,  broadly 
conceived.  Thus  far,  however,  few  clergymen  so  motivated  have  been 
able  to  maintain  their  ecclesiastical  position  long  enough  to  make  much 
headway.  So  far  as  the  writer  is  aware,  there  has  been  no  organized  effort 
to  draft  the  services  of  such  men  as  Sherwood  Eddy,  Norman  Thomas, 
Kirby  Page,  Bouck  White,  Jerome  Davis,  Ralph  Harlow,  Harry  Ward, 
or  David  D.  Vaughan  and  to  induct  them  into  the  pastorates  of  great 
metropolitan  churches. 

The  supervision  of  religion  over  recreation,  which  has,  in  the  past,  been 
exercised  chiefly  in  making  arbitrary  decisions  as  to  what  are  immoral 
and  what  are  moral  forms  of  recreation,  and  in  closely  scrutinizing  and 
controlling  the  activities  of  individuals  in  these  fields,  must  now  be  chal- 
lenged. The  orthodox  religious  criteria  as  to  moral  and  immoral  forms 
of  recreation  were  not  based  upon  physiological,  psychological,  or  social 
grounds,  but  upon  theological  considerations  which  have  little  or  no  valid- 
ity in  the  light  of  modern  knowledge.  Religion,  having  no  direct  compe- 
tence in  the  matter  of  determining  the  nature  of  moral  and  immoral 
conduct  in  the  light  of  modern  secularism,  obviously  cannot  apply  its 
decisions  in  this  field  to  the  realm  of  recreation.  Recreation,  like  moral- 
ity, with  which  it  has  been  so  closely  associated  in  the  past,  is  a  field  for 


16  The  Religion  of  Yesterday  and  Tomorrow,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1925,  p.  173. 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         705 

the  secular  expert  and  must  be  handed  over  to  biologists,  medical  experts, 
psychologists,  social  scientists  and  esthetes.  Religion,  at  most,  could 
scarcely  go  further  than  to  proclaim  the  general  desirability  of  healthy 
and  adequate  exercise  and  the  exhibition  of  a  proper  spirit  of  good  sports- 
manship. 

Another  function  of  religion  in  the  past  which  has  received  much  sup- 
port relates  to  its  esthetic  services.  It  is  held  that  the  ritual,  pageantry, 
and  liturgy  of  the  church  provide  a  relatively  economical  and  highly  valu- 
able esthetic  service  to  the  community.  This  is,  of  course,  an  argument 
which  can  be  far  better  justified  from  the  Catholic  standpoint  than  from 
the  Protestant,  as  the  Protestant  churches  have  given  up  most  of  the 
splendor  of  the  Catholic  service.  This  argument  boils  down  to  the  allega- 
tion that  the  church  is  in  a  position  to  "put  on  a  better  show"  for  the  price 
than  any  comparable  secular  organization.  While  there  was  much  to  be 
said  in  support  of  this  view  in  regard  to  the  services  of  the  church  in 
earlier  periods,  this  function  may  be,  and  indeed  is,  achieved  more  ade- 
quately by  various  secular  enterprises,  such  as  the  opera,  the  theatre,  the 
movies,  the  art  museums,  various  types  of  public  pageantry,  and  com- 
munity art  activities.  Further,  many  contend  that  the  attitude  of  fear, 
awe,  and  solemnity  generated  by  religious  ritual  and  pageantry  produces 
a  fundamentally  unhealthy  state  of  mind  which,  to  a  large  degree,  offsets 
the  esthetic  service  contributed  thereby. 

An  interesting  interpretation  of  the  function  of  religion  has  been  set 
forth  by  John  Cowper  Powys.  He  believes  that  religion  enables  the 
sceptic  to  attain  a  poetic  contemplation  of  the  great  illusions  of  humanity. 
This  certainly  constitutes  a  noble  and  dignified  statement  of  the  case  for 
religion,  'and  there  are  doubtless  many  who  find  that  religion,  thus  con- 
ceived, gives  life  a  deeper  and  richer  content.  Yet  one  can  scarcely  im- 
agine that  this  view  of  religion  will  give  satisfaction  to  any  large  number 
of  individuals.  Not  one  person  in  a  thousand  who  approach  religion 
from  a  sentimental  viewpoint  can  attain  Mr.  Powys'  scepticism.  On  the 
other  hand,  few  who  are  as  sceptical  as  Mr.  Powys  are  capable  of  a  senti- 
mental attitude  toward  religion.  Further,  if  one  believes  that  religion 
should  be  the  dynamic  basis  of  effective  social  reform,  Mr.  Powys'  nega- 
tivistic  conception  of  religion  is  completely  unadapted  to  fulfilling  this 
function. 

It  would  seem  definitely  established  that  the  conventional  functions  of 
traditional  religion  have  nearly  evaporated  in  the  light  of  contemporary 
knowledge  and  intellectual  attitudes.  The  theologian  is  no  longer  needed 
to  chart  out  and  control  the  supernatural  world  and  supernatural  powers, 
inasmuch  as  the  existence  of  such  entities  can  scarcely  be  established. 
Further,  the  theologian  cannot  by  himself  locate,  describe,  or  interpret 
the  new  cosmic  God  believed  to  be  implied  in  the  discoveries  of  modern 
science.  Neither  can  the  theologian  supply  detailed  moral  guidance  in 
indicating  how  man  must  live  to  achieve  maximum  happiness  here  on 
earth.  Nor  can  the  church  support  its  ancient  pretensions  to  guiding  and 
controlling  recreation  or  in  supplying  popular  pageantry.  This  raises  the 


706         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

important  question  as  to  what  religion  can  legitimately  engage  upon,  in 
harmony  with  the  tenets  of  an  open-minded  and  contemporaneous  secular 
attitude. 

The  most  reasonable  field  for  the  operation  of  religion  in  contemporary 
society  seems  to  lie  in  providing  for  the  mass  organization  of  the  group 
sentiment  of  mankind  in  support  of  the  larger  principles  of  kindliness, 
sympathy,  right,  justice,  honesty,  decency  and  beauty.  Just  what  con- 
stitute the  essentials  of  right,  justice,  and  so  on,  would  have  to  be  deter- 
mined by  the  appropriate  scientific  and  esthetic  experts.  These  experts, 
however,  have  little  potency  or  opportunity  in  arousing  ardent  popular 
support  for  their  findings.  Religion  has,  thus  far,  been  the  most  powerful 
agency  in  stirring  and  directing  the  collective  will  of  mankind.  There- 
fore, we  may  probably  contend  with  safety  that  the  function  of  a  liberal- 
ized religion,  divested  of  its  archaic  supernaturalism,  would  be  to  serve 
as  the  public  propaganda  adjunct  of  social  science  and  esthetics.  The 
social  sciences  and  esthetics  would  supply  specific  guidance  as  to  what 
ought  to  be  done;  religion  would  produce  the  emotional  motive  power 
essential  to  the  translation  of  abstract  theory  into  practical  action. 
There  would,  however,  be  ever  present  the  problem  of  restraining  this 
educational  propaganda  to  keep  it  in  thorough  conformity  with  the  recom- 
mendations of  science  and  art.  The  function  of  religion,  then,  would  be 
to  organize  the  mass  mind  and  group  activities  in  such  a  fashion  as  to 
benefit  secular  society  and  not  to  please  God  as  he  has  been  understood 
and  expounded  in  the  orthodox  religions  of  the  past. 

To  the  author  the  problem  is  whether  religion  can  successfully  carry  out 
the  foregoing  social  service.  The  issue  is  primarily  one  of  whether  an 
organization  hitherto  almost  exclusively  devoted  to  the  understanding, 
control,  and  exploitation  of  the  supernatural  world  can  be  completely 
transformed  into  an  institution  devoted  entirely  to  the  task  of  increasing 
the  secular  happiness  of  mankind  here  on  earth.  Such  a  transformation 
would  imply  a  complete  revolution  in  the  premises  and  activities  of 
religion.  The  question  is,  fundamentally,  whether  religion  organized  on  a 
large  scale  can  exist  without  a  sense  of  mystery  and  a  fear  of  the  unknown. 
The  thrill  of  the  mysterious  has  been  the  core  of  all  organized  religions 
in  the  past.  We  have  nothing  to  give  us  any  convincing  assurance  that 
religion  can  persist  without  this  dominating  element  of  mystery  and  fear. 
Confucianism  is  often  listed  as  an  exception  to  this  rule,  but  Confucianism 
is  really  a  sublime  ethical  philosophy,  not  an  emotional  mass  religion. 

Certain  writers  contend  that  there  will  always  remain  a  certain  fringe 
of  mystery  in  the  way  of  unsolved  problems,  as  well  as  the  general  mys- 
tery inherent  in  the  riddle  of  the  universe.  Yet,  as  Professor  Shotwell  has 
well  indicated  in  his  Religious  Revolution  of  Today,  the  mysteries  of 
modern  science  are  quite  different  in  their  premises,  manifestations,  and 
psychic  effects  from  the  conventional  religious  mystery,  based  upon  an 
emotional  reaction  to  a  hypothetical  supernatural  world.  The  reaction  to 
the  mysteries  of  science  does  not  promote  that  group-forming  tendency 
which  Lester  F.  Ward,  Hankins,  Durkheim,  and  others  have  shown  to  be 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         707 

so  characteristic  an  effect  of  supernatural  religion.  Abstruse  scientific 
perplexities  and  the  riddle  of  the  universe  may  promote  complex  forms  of 
cerebral  effort,  but  they  are  not  likely  to  evoke  a  sentimental  thrill  or  to 
generate  a  crusading  passion  in  human  assemblages. 

Indeed,  some  leading_social  scientists  contend  that  the  divergence  be- 
tween the  old  supernaturalism  and  the  new  secular  program  is  so  great 
that  no  real  common  ground  jpanjbe^ found.  Hence  they  argue  that  wei 
should  not  contaminate  the  new  secular  type  of  ethical  enterprise  by 
calling  it  religion.  This  is  certainly  a  consideration  entitled  to  receive 
serious  thought.  The  chief  defense  for  the  application  of  the  term  reli- 
gion to  the  secular  program  is  that  it  will  soften  the  shock  of  the  transition 
if  we  preserve  the  older  terminology.  Whether  or  not  this  justifies  the 
retention  of  the  term  religion  for  a  conception  different  from  its  usual 
connotation,  the  writer  will  not  assume  to  say.  Another  argument  for 
preserving  the  religious  terminology  is  that  we  should  thereby  be  able  to 
make  use  of  existing  ecclesiastical  organization  and  equipment.  How- 
ever, existing  religious  institutions  may  be  so  attached  to  outworn  con- 
ceptions and  practices  as  to  make  them  more  of  a  liability  than  an  asset 
to  religious  reconstruction.  Those  who  have  surrendered  traditional 
notions  of  religion  and  yet  are  unwilling  to  admit  that  religion  must 
become  the  inspirational  basis  of  social  ethics  generally  display  confused 
thinking.  They  tend  to  flounder  hopelessly  in  search  of  a  hypothetical 
area  for  religious  activity,  intermediate  between  adjustment  to  the  super- 
natural world  and  the  betterment  of  human  society.  Such  confusion  has 
particularly  been  the  bane  of  the  more  radical  wing  of  the  Devout  Mod- 
ernists. The  recent  writings  of  Reinhold  Niebuhr  are  probably  the  most 
conspicuous  example  of  this  confusion  and  logical  contradiction  in  Devout 
Modernist  theology. 

Many  believe  that  religion,  of  whatever  variety,  is  bound  to  pass  away 
and  that  its  place  will  be  taken  by  various  secular  cults  organized  about 
some  particular  social  and  economic  program;  in  short,  that  religion  will 
be  supplanted  by  devotion  to  the  ideals  of  capitalism  (through  Rotary, 
Kiwanis,  and  other  Service  Clubs),  Fascism,  Communism,  Socialism, 
Anarchism,  and  so  on.  These  secular  programs  may  have  the  power  to 
enlist  that  group-forming  tendency  and  to  invoke  those  group  loyalties 
which  Hankins,  Ward,  Durkheim,  and  others  look  upon  as  the  essential 
core  of  religion.  Many  of  the  Russians,  for  example,  seem  to  have  found 
as  much  satisfaction  in  devotion  to  the  Bolshevist  principles  as  they 
formerly  did  in  subservience  to  the  dogmas  of  the  Greek  Catholic  church. 
We  can  only  say,  in  this  regard,  that  time  alone  will  tell  whether  socio- 
economic  dogmas  and  cults  will  usurp  the  position  formerly  occupied  by 
religion. 

In  his  extremely  interesting  work  on  Religion  Coming  of  Age,  Roy  W. 
Sellars  adopts  a  thoroughly  secular  and  critical  point  of  view,  which  will 
commend  his  book  to  all  emancipated  intellects.  He  concludes,  however, 
that  we  must  stand  with  the  existing  churches  and  attempt  to  achieve 
religious  reconstruction,  moral  reform,  and  social  progress  through  these 


708         THE  CRISIS    IN    RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

present-day  ecclesiastical  organizations  and  institutions.  Though  he 
does  not  attempt  to  defend  the  existing  creeds  and  sectarian  divisions  of 
the  Christian  Church,  his  theory  raises  the  very  interesting  question  as  to 
whether  a  truly  contemporaneously-minded  person  can  stand  by  the 
churches  even  if  he  desires  to  do  so.  We  may  admit  the  potential  value 
of  exploiting  the  existing  resources  in  the  way  of  ecclesiastical  equipment 
and  running  machinery,  but  it  is  a  moot  question  as  to  whether  we  can 
win  over  such  resources  to  the  cause  and  service  of  the  new  rational 
religion.  Adjustments  of  this  sort,  at  any  rate,  call  for  a  degree  of  com- 
promise that  is  usually  destructive  to  intellectual  integrity  and  the  con- 
sistent maintenance  of  a  thoroughly  up-to-date  attitude.  Some  of  our 
greatest  Modernist  preachers  are  compelled  to  stultify  their  theology  and 
repress  their  innate  liberalism,  in  order  to  make  a  working  success  of  their 
church  and  pastoral  duties. 

In  the  former  agrarian  age,  the  church  was  the  center  of  community 
life  and  of  much  social  recreation.  It  could  rely  not  only  upon  the  fear 
of  the  unknown  but  also  upon  man's  craving  for  sociability.  The  rise 
of  urban  life  has  substituted  other  forms  of  social  outlet  for  those  the 
church  formerly  supplied.  As  a  result,  instead  of  being  indispensable  to 
the  social  life  of  man,  the  church  has  become  today  very  largely  an  irk- 
some distraction  from  his  other  social  obligations  and  recreational  inter- 
ests. This  matter  has  been  handled  very  intelligently  and  lucidly  in 
Walter  Lippmann's  notable  book,  A  Preface  to  Morals.*7  There  is  little 
doubt  that  the  automobile  and  radio  have,  in  various  ways,  been  more 
effective  in  undermining  the  old  religious  morality  than  all  the  preachings 
and  writings  of  sceptics  and  Modernists.  The  disintegrating  influence  of 
these  new  secular  interests  is  especially  deadly  and  effective  because  of 
its  indirect  nature.  John  Herman  Randall,  Jr.,  in  Current  History  has 
given  us  an  illuminating  summary  of  the  effect  of  these  new  secular 
interests  upon  the  old  religion: 

Yet  industrialism  and  city  life  have  been  far  more  subversive  than  all  the  scien- 
tific theories  put  together.  We  are  all  too  familiar  with  theological  difficulties. 
We  are  apt  to  overlook  the  real  religious  revolution  of  the  past  forty  years,  the 
crowding  of  religion  into  a  minor  place  by  the  host  of  secular  faiths  and  interests. 
For  every  man  alienated  from  the  Church  by  scientific  ideas,  there  are  dozens 
dissatisfied  with  its  social  attitudes,  and  hundreds  who,  with  no  intellectual 
doubts,  have  found  their  lives  fully  occupied  with  the  other  interests  and  diver- 
sions of  the  machine  age.  What  does  it  matter  that  earnest  men  have  found  a 
way  to  combine  older  beliefs  with  the  spirit  of  science,  if  those  beliefs  have  ceased 
to  express  anything  vital  in  men's  experience,  if  the  older  religious  faith  is 
irrelevant  to  all  they  really  care  for?  A  truly  intelligent  Fundamentalist,  indeed, 
would  leave  biology  alone  as  of  little  influence.  He  would  instead  try  to  abolish 
the  automobiles  and  movies  and  Sunday  papers  and  golf  links  that  are  emptying 
our  churches.  Even  when  the  Church  embraces  the  new  interests,  it  seems  to 
be  playing  a  losing  game.  There  is  little  of  specifically  religious  significance  in 
the  manifold  activities  of  the  modern  institutional  church;  a  dance  for  the  build- 
ing fund  is  less  of  a  religious  experience  than  a  festival  in  honor  of  the  patron 
saint.  And  any  minister  knows  that  his  "social  activities"  spring  less  from  real 


Macmillan,  1929. 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         709 

need  than  from  the  fervent  desire  to  attract  and  hold  members.  The  church 
itself  has  been  secularized.  Its  very  members  continue  a  half-hearted  support, 
from  motives  of  traditional  attachment,  of  personal  loyalty  to  the  minister,  of 
social  prestige,  because  they  do  not  want  to  live  in  a  churchless  community.18 

Unquestionably,  another  important  cause  of  the  lessening  of  the  prestige 
and  influence  of  the  church  is  to  be  discerned  in  the  decline  of  the  in- 
tellectual caliber  of  the  clergy.  There  was  a  time  in  America  when  the 
clergy  constituted  the  real  intellectual  aristocracy  of  the  country.  Today, 
no  such  claim  can  be  advanced  for  the  contemporary  American  clergy, 
as  a  group,  though  the  church  does  continue  to  bring  some  powerful  in- 
tellects into  her  service. 

The  church  must  further  face  the  rivalry  of  new  techniques  for  the 
dissemination  of  religious  and  ethical  doctrines.  The  pulpit  once  pos- 
sessed something  like  a  monopoly  of  the  discussion  of  religious  and  other 
moral  and  public  issues.  Today,  we  have  an  extensive  development  of 
the  public  lecture  forum,  university  extension  courses,  and  institutions 
for  adult  education,  to  say  nothing  of  the  press,  which,  as  a  strong  social 
factor,  is  primarily  a  product  of  the  last  half  century.  Many  believe  that 
if  religion  is  to  be  secularized  and  devoted  to  the  cause  of  social  better- 
ment, the  lecture  platform  and  the  public  forum  are  better  suited  than 
the  church  as  a  medium  for  disseminating  ethical  doctrines.  Then  there 
are  not  a  few  progressive  experts  in  religious  education  who  contend  that, 
if  the  public  schools  were  properly  conducted,  they  would  perform  the 
function  of  character  education,  for  the  instruction  in  which  we  have 
hitherto  formally  relied  primarily  upon  the  church. 

The  publicity  given  to  religion  and  the  churches  by  radio  services  is 
partly  offset  by  the  fact  that  many  people  who  feel  the  need  of  religious 
guidance  may  stay  in  their  homes  and  listen  to  the  radio  instead  of  attend- 
ing, and  contributing  to,  the  local  places  of  worship.  Formerly,  a  man  of 
religious  inclinations  was  dependent  upon  the  local  parson.  However 
intolerable  the  homiletic  exercises  of  this  local  man  of  God,  there  was  no 
feasible  escape.  Today,  the  same  person  may  turn  on  his  radio  and 
listen  to  one  of  the  ablest  and  most  distinguished  preachers  in  the  country. 
Further,  the  radio  offers  him  greater  economies  of  time  and  effort.  He 
may  sit  down  comfortably  in  an  easy  chair,  light  his  pipe,  and  turn  on 
the  radio  only  at  the  moment  when  the  preacher  begins  his  discourse. 
The  appeal  of  the  radio  is,  of  course,  rendered  the  more  effective  today 
since,  as  we  have  seen  above,  there  is  no  significant  social  incentive  to 
church  attendance  as  there  was  in  the  days  of  the  old  rural  neighborhood. 

The  radio  services  are  likely  to  have  the  most  serious  effect  upon  the 
attendance  and  financial  support  of  the  Protestant  churches.  The 
Protestant  cults  have  tended  to  concentrate  worship  primarily  in  the 
preaching  service,  which  is  peculiarly  well-adapted  to  broadcasting.  On 
the  other  hand,  the  elaborate  ritual  and  liturgy  of  the  Catholic  church 
can  scarcely  be  reproduced  with  full  effect  over  the  radio.  But  television 
may  solve  even  this  problem. 


i*Loc,  cit.,  June,  1929. 


710         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

Even  friendly  observers  are  impressed  with  the  degree  to  which  the 
church  devotes  itself  primarily  to  the  perpetuation  of  its  organization 
and  the  preservation  of  its  status  rather  than  to  the  improvement  of 
human  well-being  and  the  spiritual  uplift  of  its  communicants.  A  repre- 
sentative exposition  of  this  point  of  view  was  contained  in  an  article  by 
Rollo  Walter  Brown  on  "An  Observer  Warns  the  Church"  in  Harper's.™ 

In  the  first  place,  Professor  Brown  contends  that  the  church  is  closely 
geared  to  the  economic  interests  of  its  parishioners.  He  says  that  he  has 
found  through  long  experience  and  careful  checking  that  he  can  predict 
the  nature  of  the  sermons  which  will  be  preached  in  any  given  church  by 
the  length  of  the  wheel-base  of  the  automobiles  parked  in  front  of  it: 

A  long-wheel-base  church  still  means  much  preaching  about  "the  manifold 
blessings  of  life,"  the  rewards  of  honest  thrift,  the  beauty  of  Christian  fellowship 
— only  nine  people  are  there — the  glory  of  giving  something  out  of  our  abundance, 
the  sanctity  of  the  faith  of  our  saintly  fathers  and  mothers,  and  much  reading 
of  inspirational  poetry. 

A  middle-wheel-base  church  means  strong  words  for  tolerance,  plenty  of  ad- 
monitions thai  we  must  not  be  too  hurtful  with  our  Convictions,  reminders  that 
compromise  is  the  law  of  the  practical  world,  and  informing  lecture-sermons  on 
non-controversial  subjects. 

And  a  short-wheel-base  church  means  indignation,  demands  for  a  shifting  of  the 
burden  of  life,  many  examples  of  the  sins  of  the  greedy,  and  the  reading  of  for- 
gotten radical  quotations  from  Abraham  Lincoln  or  some  other  known  champion 
of  the  people. 

To  believe  that  any  one  of  these  wheel-bases  expresses  the  way  of  life  of  Jesus 
would  be  difficult  enough.  But  how  could  anybody,  by  any  possible  stretch 
of  the  imagination,  believe  they  all  do?  Somewhere  along  the  way  the  church 
has  experienced  a  disintegration  of  all  singleness  of  purpose.20 

Attention  is  also  called  to  the  pomp  and  ceremony.  "Just  what  would 
Jesus  think  of  the  spectacle  of  a  military  memorial  mass  in  the  Harvard 
football  stadium,  with  photographs  flashed  over  the  country  that  look 
like  nothing  so  much  as  a  Hitler  review,  and  with  reports  dramatically 
telling  how  the  quiet  of  the  Sunday  morning  air  was  rent  by  the  roar  of 
cannon  announcing  consecration?" 

While  Jesus  himself  was  a  reformer,  Professor  Brown  contends  that 
tjie  church  is  not  only  opposed  to  reform  but  attempts  to  wipe  out  re- 
formers, as  the  vested  interests  attempted  to  wipe  out  Jesus  in  his  day: 

If  a  newspaper  editor  who  writes  on  Spain  sees  some  good  in  the  People's  Front, 
then  the  thing  to  do  is  to  have  representatives  of  the  church  see  if  he  cannot 
quietly  be  removed  to  a  position  where  he  cannot  be  heard.  Or  if  a  college  presi- 
dent in  all  honesty  comes  out  for  social  changes  that  would  possibly  affect  the 
pocketbooks  of  men  in  the  denomination  that  supports  the  college,  then  the 
trustees  hire  somebody  to  pray  over  the  matter  for  them,  and  for  some  reason — 
any  reason  but  the  real  one — decide  that  the  president  has  special  abilities  better 
suited  to  a  less  influential  post.  That  saves  all  the  trouble  of  having  the  facts 
examined. 


19  October,  1937. 

20  Brown,  loc.  cit. 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION   AND  MORALS         71T 

Professor  Brown  maintains  that  the  church  is  even  afraid  of  its  own 
liberal  spokesmen,  that  it  is  afraid  of  the  masses,  the  very  type  to  which 
Jesus  ministered,  and  is  afraid  of  youth,  and  the  spirit  of  youth.  He 
warns  it  to  wake  up  and  preach  a  vital  message  before  it  is  too  late: 

There  may  yet  be  time.  But  if  the  church  uses  up  its  energy  in  the  business 
of  making  itself  solid,  if  it  occupies  itself  with  wars  of  one  kind  or  another,  if 
nobody  rises  up  to  give  the  philosophy  of  Jesus  a  fair  chance  in  the  church  and 
through  its  representatives,  the  church  may  well  face  a  more  tragic  eclipse  than 
any  that  it  has  imagined  for  itself  at  the  hands  of  external  enemies. 

In  spite  of  the  serious  and  diversified  effects  of  contemporary  life  upon 
religion  and  the  churches,  the  American  churches  were  able  to  keep  up 
with  the  social  procession,  so  far  as  formal  membership  and  the  value  of 
church  property  were  concerned,  down  to  1926.  Except  for  the  Roman 
Catholic  Church,  the  figures  for  the  1936  religious  census  indicated  a 
decline  in  the  fortunes  of  the  church.  Membership  grew  slightly,  but 
almost  wholly  among  the  Catholics  and  not  anywhere  near  in  proportion 
to  the  increase  of  population.  The  value  of  church  property  declined 
and  there  was  an  alarming  falling  off  in  church  expenditures  and  in  the 
number  of  churches. 

In  1936,  there  were  199,302  churches  and  synagogues  in  the  country, 
as  against  232,154  in  1926.  The  total  membership  of  all  churches  was 
55,807,366,  as  compared  with  54,807,366  in  1926.  In  1926,  the  member- 
ship listed  as  being  of  age  13  and  over  was  approximately  37  millions  or 
about  55  per  cent  of  the  total  population  of  that  age.  The  proportion  of 
church  membership  in  this  age  group  was  somewhat  lower  in  1936  than 
in  1906,  1916,  and  1926.  Far  and  away  the  largest  single  group  in  the 
church  rnembership  population  were  the  Catholics,  who  numbered 
19,914,937,  as  compared  with  18,600,000  in  1926.  The  total  value  of 
church  property  in  1936  was  $3,411,875,000,  as  against  $3,839,500,000  in 
1926.  Church  expenditures  in  1936  were  $518,953,000,  a  marked  drop 
from  the  figure  of  $817,214,000  in  1926.  That  the  hold  of  the  church 
upon  youth  may  be  slipping  is  suggested  by  the  fact  that  Sunday  School 
membership  has  fallen  off  when  compared  with  the  growth  of  population. 
The  Protestants  still  far  outnumber  the  Catholics,  but  the  latter  are  hold- 
ing their  ground  better.  As  Boyd  Barrett  has  pointed  out  in  his  im- 
portant book,  Rome  Stoops  to  Conquer,21  the  Catholic  church  is  today 
concentrating  upon  the  United  States  as  its  great  hope  for  future  expan- 
sion. 

Though  the  clergymen  are  losing  their  relative  prestige  in  American 
intellectual  life,  they  are  better  trained  than  at  any  time  in  the  past. 
Yet,  in  1926,  only  5  out  of  8  ministers  in  white  denominations  claimed  to 
be  graduates  of  either  a  college  or  a  seminary.  Only  one  out  of  4  Negro 
ministers  was  thus  educated. 

Perhaps  the  most  notable  recent  developments  in  the  history  of  the 
church  are  those  associated  with  social  activity  and  philanthropy.  Socio- 


;  1935, 


712         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

religious  organizations,  such  as  the  Y.M.C.A.  (2,493,756  members),  the 
Y.M.H.A.  (450,000  members),  and  the  Knights  of  Columbus  (409,393 
members),  have  grown  markedly  in  membership,  in  financial  resources, 
and  in  expenditures  since  1900.  The  churches  are  spending  more  money 
than  ever  before  in  maintaining  schools,  orphanages,  hospitals,  and  other 
forms  of  charitable  enterprise. 

The  Protestants  have  recognized  the  weaknesses  growing  out  of  dis- 
unity and  a  number  of  movements  have  been  established  to  promote 
mergers  of  various  sects.  The  Interchurch  World  Movement  sought  to 
unite  Protestants  in  various  forms  of  cooperative  endeavor,  but  the  con- 
troversy over  the  steel  strike  of  1919  and  other  types  of  friction  led  to  its 
collapse  in  1920.  In  rural  communities,  economic  pressure  has  forced 
the  abandonment  of  many  churches  and  the  creation  of  federated  and 
community  churches — a  healthy  development.  We  have  already  men- 
tioned the  rise  of  the  radio  and  its  relation  to  the  local  attendance  and 
support  of  churches. 

The  strongest  organization  of  the  Protestant  groups  in  this  country 
today  is  the  Federal  Council  of  the  Churches  of  Christ  in  America, 
founded  in  1908,  with  a  formal  membership  of  24  million.  It  has  not 
eliminated  sectarianism  but  it  has  been  able  to  bring  about  some  unified 
activity  in  behalf  of  peace  and  social  justice.  While  the  Catholic  church 
can  probably  depend  upon  its  organization  and  discipline  to  maintain  its 
prestige  for  some  time  to  come,  the  power  and  influence  of  the  Protestant 
churches  will  probably  depend  upon  the  degree  to  which  they  take  an 
active  and  constructive  part  in  public  affairs. 

Religion,  Morals,  and  Crime 

One  of  the  most  persistent  arguments  in  behalf  of  religion,  especially 
orthodox  religion,  is  that  the  latter  acts  as  a  collective  policeman.  With- 
out the  coercive  influence  of  religion,  it  is  said,  society  would  soon  dis- 
integrate into  anarchy,  violence,  and  rapine.  Cardinal  O'Connell  of 
Boston  has  well  expressed  this  position:  "The  only  thing  that  keeps  the 
human  race  in  some  sort  of  plausible  order  is  the  overpowering  content 
qf  God  upon  the  minds  of  man.  .  .  .  When  religion  goes,  only  one  thing 
can  follow  logically — the  bayonet."  The  moralizing  influence  of  orthodox 
religion,  which  we  usually  take  for  granted,  is,  however,  by  no  means  a 
demonstrated  fact.  The  unreliability  and  selfishness  of  most  ostenta- 
tiously pious  persons  is  notorious  and  readily  explained  by  the  psycholo- 
gist. However,  only  recently  have  thoroughgoing  studies  of  the  actual 
effect  of  religion  upon  conduct  been  made.  The  information  gathered 
by  scientists  seems  to  discredit  the  conventional  notion  that  orthodoxy 
powerfully  promotes  such  desirable  moral  traits  as  honesty,  reliability, 
and  unselfishness.  J.  H.  Leuba  showed  that  the  majority  of  prominent 
American  academicians  and  men  of  science  had  discarded  orthodoxy  but 
it  will  be  conceded,  even  by  those  most  critical  of  the  intelligentsia,  that 
the  professorial  class  is  distinguished  for  its  docile  and  law-abiding  be- 
havior. 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         713 

It  is  obvious  that  the  only  way  to  arrive  at  any  finality  of  judgment  is 
to  carry  on  a  prolonged  series  of  psychological  investigations  into  the 
actual  processes  of  character  formation,  in  order  thus  to  ascertain  the 
relative  influence  of  religion  therein.  Such  a  project  was  carried  out 
under  the  auspices  of  the  Institute  of  Social  and  Religious  Research  in 
New  York  City.  The  investigation  was  directed  by  Hugh  H^rtshorne 
of  Columbia  University  and  Mark  A.  May  of  Yale.  The  first  volume, 
Studies  in  Deceit,  indicated  that  orthodox  religious  training,  either  Chris- 
tian or  Jewish,  did  not  promote  honesty  and  reliability.  To  the  contrary, 
children  who  had  been  exposed  to  progressive  educational  methods,  based 
upon  secular  premises  and  the  exploitation  of  modern  psychology,  ap- 
peared to  have  a  far  better  record  as  to  honesty  and  dependability. 

In  reporting  the  results  of  an  elaborate  test  of  more  than  three  thousand 
children,  at  a  meeting  of  the  International  Congress  of  Psychology,  P.  R. 
Hightower  showed  definitely  that  the  tendency  of  the  children  tested  to 
lie,  cheat,  and  the  like,  was  in  direct  proportion — not  in  inverse  ratio — to 
their  knowledge  of  the  Bible  and  scriptural  precepts.  He  concluded  that: 
"mere  knowledge  of  the  Bible  of  itself  is  not  sufficient  to  insure  proper 
character  attitudes."  At  the  same  meeting,  T.  H.  Howells  reported  that 
religiously  orthodox  college  students  seemed  less  capable  of  dealing  with 
problems  of  conduct  than  the  liberal  and  sophisticated  students,  and 
were  much  more  susceptible  to  irrational  suggestion.  It  does  not  appear, 
therefore,  that  religion  and  religious  education  exert  any  notable  influ- 
ence in  promoting  better  moral  conduct  of  even  a  conventional  sort. 

It  is  commonly  believed  that  no  man  would  be  safe  on  the  broad  streets 
at  high  noon,  were  it  not  for  the  shadow  of  the  church  spire  and  the  in- 
fluence of  religion  in  keeping  alive  a  fear  of  the  hereafter  and  helping  to 
build  character.  However,  a  considerable  amount  of  factual  information 
fails  to  substantiate  this  belief.22  In  his  Religion  and  Roguery,  Frank 
Steiner  analyzed  recent  statistics  of  convicts  in  the  penitentiaries  of  the 
United  States.  He  found  that  84  per  cent  claimed  Christian  affiliation. 
Out  of  85,000  convicts,  5,389  were  of  the  Jewish  faith.  There  were  only 
8,000  "unchurched,"  and  150  avowed  infidels. 

The  distinguished  Dutch  sociologist  and  criminologist,  W.  A.  Bonger, 
made  a  careful  statistical  study  of  the  relation  between  religious  affiliation 
and  criminality  in  the  Netherlands.  He  found  that  the  Roman  Catholics 
came  first  in  the  ratio  of  criminality,  the  Protestants  second,  the  Jews 
third,  and  the  free-thinkers  lowest  of  all.  Carl  Murchison  examined  the 
religious  state  of  the  inmates  of  the  Maryland  penitentiary.  He  found 
that  there  was  a  far  larger  proportion  of  church  members  in  the  prison 
than  in  the  general  population  of  the  state.  In  his  work  on  'The  Church 
and  Crime  in  the  United  States,"  Dr.  C.  V.  Dunn  investigated  the  religious 
connections  of  inmates  of  27  penitentiaries  and  19  reform  schools.  He 


22  John  R.  Miner,  "Do  Churches  Prevent  Crime,"  The  American  Mercury,  Janu- 
ary, 1932.    See  also  Swancara,  The  Obstruction  of  Justice  by  Religion,  Chaps.  VII- 

vin.    • 


714         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

found  that  71.8  per  cent  of  the  prisoners  were  members  of  Catholic  or 
Protestant  churches.  Yet  only  46.6  per  cent  of  the  total  population  of 
the  United  States  are  members  of  any  religious  body.2-a 

This  great  apparent  preponderance  of  the  allegedly  religious  persons  in 
penitentiary  populations  may  be  due  in  some  degree  to  false  statements 
on  the  purt  of  inmates.  Convicts  may,  in  some  cases,  fake  religious 
connections  in  the  hope  of  making  a  more  favorable  impression  on  the 
authorities.  But  this  consideration  is  not  adequate  to  upset  the  obvious 
fact  that  a  decisive  majority  of  our  criminals  are  persons  who  have  been 
brought  up  in  orthodox  religious  surroundings. 

Another  way  of  approaching  the  problem  is  to  try  to  find  the  correla- 
tion, if  any,  between  the  amount  of  criminality  in  any  region  and  the 
proportion  of  church  membership  therein.  This  is  possible  to  compute 
on  the  basis  of  the  information  published  by  the  Bureau  of  the  Census. 
Such  an  investigation  was  made  and  published  in  Human  Biology.23  On 
the  whole,  it  was  found  that  there  was  little  relationship  between  the 
proportion  of  church  members  in  any  given  state  and  the  volume  of  crime. 
Likewise,  a  high  percentage  of  membership  in  any  particular  religious 
denomination  seemed  to  have  little  bearing  on  the  amount  of  existing 
crime.  However,  there  was  an  apparent  correlation  between  certain 
types  of  religion  and  homicide.  In  states  with  a  high  percentage  of 
Roman  Catholics  there  are  few  homicides.  In  those  where  Methodists 
and  Baptists  predominate  we  find  a  high  proportion  of  homicides.  How- 
ever, general  social  conditions  may  have  as  much  to  do  with  the  homicide 
situation  as  the  religious  set-up.  If  so,  this  would  in  itself  prove  that 
religion  has  little  unique  power  to  enforce  the  "thou  shalt  not  kill"  clause 
of  the  Scriptures. 

Summing  up,  then,  prison  populations  show  an  overwhelming  majority 
of  those  who  claim  religious  affiliations.  In  the  population  at  large,  a 
high  percentage  of  church  membership  has  no  apparent  influence  in  sup- 
pressing criminality  in  the  community.  Therefore,  pending  further 
study,  we  may  accept  Dr.  Miner's  conclusion  that  "there  is  little  evidence 
that  the  churches  play  any  major  part  in  the  prevention  of  crime." 

Historical  Attitudes  Toward  Ethics  and  Conduct 

As  we  have  suggested  earlier  in  the  chapter,  religion  has  been  closely 
associated  in  the  past  with  the  problems  and  practices  of  morality.  We 
may  appropriately  conclude  this  chapter  by  a  discussion  of  the  develop- 
ment of  ethical  theory  and  its  impending  reconstruction  in  the  light  of 
science  and  critical  philosophy. 

In  primitive  society  there  was  no  true  ethical  theory  beyond  the  uni- 
versal assumption  of  the  divine  origin  of  all  folkways  and  customs.  The 


22a  Annals  of  the  American  Academy,  1926,  pp.  200-228. 
28  September,  1931. 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         715 

prevailing  doctrine  was  that  custom  is  sacred  and  must  be  blindly  and 
unthinkingly  obeyed.  The  very  idea  of  a  critical  theory  of  ethics  would 
be  repugnant  to  primitive  people.24 

Nor  did  sceptical  theorizing  about  conduct  in  the  ancient  Near  East 
become  a  matter  of  practical  import,  even  though  an  occasional  sage  or 
prophet  produced,  from  time  to  time,  incisive  observations  on  the  subject. 
Such  were  the  Egyptian  social  critics  about  2000  B.C.,  and  the  Hebrew 
prophets.  The  accepted  view  was  that  "what  is,  is  right."  Right  was 
embodied  in  customs  handed  down  from  an  earlier  day  by  sumptuary 
legislation  and  royal  proclamations.  The  "why"  or  the  justice  of  a 
precept  was  a  subject  which  the  discreet  person  never  investigated  too 
closely.  Indeed,  it  was  assumed,  as  in  primitive  society,  that  the  existing 
codes  constituted  the  will  of  the  gods,  and  violation  invited  national  as 
well  as  personal  disaster. 

With  the  Attic  Greeks  the  animistic  and  theological  explanations  of 
conduct  were  in  part  abandoned  by  intellectuals  in  favor  of  a  metaphysi- 
cal approach  to  the  problem.  Socrates  and  Plato  contended  that  there 
were  certain  transcendental,  permanent,  and  immutable  norms  of  right 
and  justice — metaphysical  realities  which  existed  anterior  to  man  and 
independent  of  any  particular  time  or  place.  These  eternal  verities 
might  be  discovered  and  defined  by  careful  philosophical  study.  Aristotle 
introduced  a  much  more  rational  and  secular  theory  of  ethics.  He  main- 
tained that  the  chief  human  good  and  the  true  end  of  life  is  happiness. 
The  best  life  is  a  well-rounded  existence,  guided  by  reason  and  virtue. 
He  advocated  intellectual  restraint  which  would  guide  the  individual  into 
a  happy  mean  between  irrational  indulgence  and  ascetic  self-denial.  The 
speculative  life  of  wisdom  was  regarded  by  Aristotle  as  the  most  perfect 
and  divine,  but  he  thought  that  it  should  be  tempered  by  a  discreet  culti- 
vation of  the  social  graces  and  the  satisfaction  of  normal  human  desires. 
The  Stoics  combined  metaphysics  and  revelation.  The  wisdom  of  God, 
in  the  form  of  the  logos,  was  believed  to  permeate  the  cosmos.  Man 
might  appropriate  some  small  portion  of  this  divine  wisdom  through  his 
rational  powers,  thus  learning  the  divine  wishes  as  to  the  intricacies  of 
personal  conduct.  This  metaphysical  mode  of  approach  to  the  problems 
of  conduct  has  persisted  to  our  own  day,  though  the  progressive  philoso- 
phers like  James,  Dewey,  James  H.  Tufts,  Durant  Drake,  and  Bertrand 
Russell  have  severely  challenged  it.  The  most  striking  and  original  step 
in  ethical  theory  taken  by  the  Greek  thinkers  appeared  in  the  wrritings  of 
the  Sophists  and  Epicureans,  who  recognized  the  relativity  of  our  ideas 
of  what  is  right  and  wrong,  how  they  are  derived  from  custom,  and  their 
service  in  promoting  social  discipline. 

While  the  Christians  retained  much  of  the  Hellenic  metaphysics  in 
their  ultimate  theology,  their  ethical  doctrines  resembled  the  primitive 
and  oriental  attitude,  namely,  the  belief  in  the  specific  revelation  of  codes 


24  See  above,  pp.  17  ff.,  29  ff. 


716         THE  CRISIS   IN  RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

of  conduct,  based  upon  infallible  religious  texts.  The  orthodox  early 
Christian  did  not  arrive  at  his  conclusions  in  regard  to  ethical  theory 
through  careful,  analytical  reasoning.  He  felt  it  necessary  only  to  read 
the  Mosaic  Code  and  certain  New  Testament  writings,  especially  the 
ethical  precepts  of  the  Pauline  Epistles.  To  these  were  later  added  the 
commentaries  of  the  Church  Fathers.  But,  in  any  case,  the  source  of 
guidance  was  explicit  revelation  and  authoritative  command.  The  meta- 
physical and  logical  approach  to  religion,  which  became  rather  more  im- 
portant in  the  medieval  Scholastic  period,  influenced  theology  far  more 
than  it  did  the  theories  and  practices  in  regard  to  conduct.  What  were 
believed  to  be  the  commands  or  wishes  of  God  in  any  matter  of  behavior 
have  remained  to  this  day  the  universal  source  of  formal  guidance  to 
orthodox  Christians  in  the  field  of  conduct.  The  Protestants,  however, 
laid  more  stress  upon  the  severe  and  austere  teachings  of  the  Old  Testa- 
ment as  the  source  of  moral  guidance.  The  Puritans  put  special  em- 
phasis upon  rigorous  personal  morality,  as  an  overcompensation  for  their 
somewhat  dubious  economic  and  commercial  ventures  in  piracy,  the  slave 
trade,  the  rum  trade,  kidnapping  and  the  like. 

The  period  of  Rationalism,  in  early  modern  times,  was  characterized 
by  the  growth  of  an  empirical  and  pragmatic  attitude  towards  the  sources 
of  ethical  guidance  and  the  validity  of  codes  of  conduct — a  position  re- 
sembling the  Sophistic  and  Epicurean  approach.  There  also  developed 
among  the  Deists  a  new  type  of  metaphysic,  drawn  from  the  Newtonian 
natural  science  and  celestial  mechanics.  This  view  contended  that  proper 
human  conduct,  like  the  motion  and  paths  of  the  planets  and  all  other 
processes  and  manifestations  of  nature,  was  based  upon  a  universal 
natural  norm,  order,  or  law,  which  was  of  divine  origin. 

While  the  Deists  believed  that  conduct  should  be  based  upon  the  laws 
of  nature,  they  identified  God  with  nature,  thus  retaining  an  essentially 
theistic  view  of  morality.  David  Hume,  who  founded  what  is  known  as 
Hedonism  in  ethics,  and  laid  the  basis  for  utilitarianism,  more  than  any 
other  writer  between  the  Greek  period  and  his  own  age,  was  responsible 
for  the  divorce  of  ethics  from  theology.  He  held  that  the  only  test  of 
true  morality  is  its  contribution  to  the  increase  of  human  happiness 
here  and  now.  He  suggested  an  empirical  and  experimental  attitude 
towards  morality  by  holding  that  we  must  study  the  effects  of  different 
forms  of  conduct  upon  human  happiness. 

There  were  also  certain  important  anticipations  of  the  purely  esthetic 
approach  to  moral  problems  in  the  writings  of  Montaigne,  the  third 
Earl  of  Shaftesbury,  and  others.  They  regarded  moral  conduct  as  an 
expression  of  good  taste  and  an  appreciation  of  the  true  and  the  beautiful. 
In  the  works  of  Voltaire,  Montesquieu  and  Adam  Ferguson,  we  find  a 
foreshadowing  of  the  ethnographic  approach  to  problems  of  conduct  and 
ethical  codes,  exemplified  in  our  own  era  by  Spencer,  Ratzel,  Sumner, 
Frazer,  Westermarck,  Briffault,  and  others.  According  to  this  view  of 
ethics,  whatever  is  done  in  any  area  is  believed  to  be  right  by  the  in- 
habitants. Right  is  relative  to  time  and  place,  rather  than  anything 


THE  CRISIS  IN  RELIGION  AND  MORALS        717 

absolute.25  In  Adam  Smith's  Theory  of  Moral  Sentiments  there  appeared 
the  first  systematic  effort  to  construct  an  ethical  theory  upon  psycho- 
logical premises.  Smith  explained  morality  on  the  basis  of  reflective 
sympathy.  An  observer  tends  to  project  himself  into  the  situation  of 
another  and  to  imagine  how  he  would  feel  under  the  same  circumstances. 
Hence  we  are  naturally  impelled  to  do  those  things  which  will  promote 
happiness  and  avert  sorrow.  His  ideas  can  be  described  as  an  extension 
of  the  Golden  Rule. 

The  Romanticist  and  Idealist  philosophers,  who  flourished  in  the  cen- 
tury following  1750,  revived  the  religious  sanctions  of  morality.  The 
most  famous  of  these  ethical  doctrines  was  expressed  by  Immanuel  Kant. 
He  denied  that  morality  should  be  judged  by  its  social  effects  or  social 
utility.  Instead,  he  promulgated  the  concept  of  the  "categorical  im- 
perative," or  the  theory  of  unconditioned  and  obligatory  morality.  We 
should  not  be  guided  in  our  behavior  by  the  expectation  of  immediate 
benefits  or  penalties.  Rather,  we  must  live  in  such  a  manner  that  our 
lives  may  seem,  in  our  small  way,  an  imitation  of  the  moral  law  of  the 
universe.  This  was  a  veritable  deification  of  the  abstract  sense  of  duty. 
Others,  like  Schleiermacher,  went  even  further,  and  contended  that  the 
only  true  guide  to  moral  life  was  to  be  found  in  the  study  and  imitation 
of  the  life  of  Jesus. 

The  most  important  advance  in  ethical  theory  in  the  half  century 
following  Kant  was  the  development  of  Utilitarianism  by  Jeremy 
Bentham  and  his  disciples.  This  notion  was  founded  upon  a  definite 
psychological  basis — the  famous  felicific  calculus.  Man  was  represented 
as  a  consciously  calculating  animal,  carefully  and  discriminatingly  hesi- 
tating before  every  choice.  He  was  believed  to  weigh  the  relative  possi- 
bilities of  pleasurable  satisfaction  or  pain,  likely  to  result  from  each  and 
every  act.  Socially  considered,  this  form  of  ethics  tested  the  ethical 
justification  of  any  act  by  its  prospect  of  contributing  to  the  "greatest 
happiness  for  the  greatest  number."  When  interpreted  in  harmony  with 
the  discoveries  of  differential  biology  and  psychology,  such  an  ethical 
standard  may  be  regarded  as  perhaps  the  best  genelfcl  statement  yet 
made  for  sound  moral  behavior.  But  its  specific  psychological  founda- 
tion— the  felicific  calculus — has  been  proved  by  Graham  Wallas  and 
others  to  be  quite  obviously  fallacious.26  Further,  it  provided  no  ade- 
quate technique  for  actually  discovering  the  precise  nature  of  the 
"greatest  happiness." 

Closely  related  to  the  ethics  of  the  utilitarian  school  was  the  sociological 
theory  of  conduct,  which  took  form  in  the  writings  of  Comte,  Post,  Spen- 
cer, Bagehot,  and  Ward  around  the  middle  third  of  the  nineteenth  century. 
They  accepted,  either  tacitly  or  explicitly,  the  utilitarian  "greatest  happi- 
ness" criterion  as  to  the  validity  of  forms  of  conduct.  But  they  sought 


25  See  above,  pp.  29  ff. 

26  Wallas,  Human  Nature  in   Politics,  Knopf,   1921.    See  also,   W.   C.   Mitchell, 
"Bentham's  Felicific  Calculus/'  in  Political  Science  Quarterly,  June,  1918. 


718        THE  CRISIS  IN  RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

the  origins  of  such  conduct  in  social  evolution,  natural  selection,  and  the 
survival  value  of  institutions.  The  evolutionary  process,  they  held,  tends 
to  favor  socially  desirable  forms  of  conduct,  and  to  eliminate  the  un- 
desirable and  detrimental.  This  evolutionary  trend  in  sociological  ethics, 
together  with  Darwinian  evolutionary  biology,  gave  rise  to  a  naturalistic 
school  of  evolutionary  ethical  theory,  represented  by  such  men  as  Lecky, 
Stephen,  Fiske,  Hobhouse,  Westermarck,  Sumner,  and  others.  Biology 
replaced  theology  as  the  guide  to,  and  appraiser  of,  human  conduct. 

Many  of  these  later  trends  in  the  study  of  codes  of  conduct  laid  the 
foundations  for  a  real  science  of  conduct.  But  no  one  of  these  approaches 
provided  any  real  mode  of  finding  out  just  what  forms  of  conduct  produce 
the  greatest  happiness  for  the  greatest  number.  The  means  for  such  a 
discovery  were  laid  by  sciences  such  as  biology,  chemistry,  psychology, 
medicine,  and  psychiatry,  and  by  esthetics. 

Sociologists  should  quickly  have  exploited  this  opportunity,  but  most  of 
them  were  extremely  tardy  in  so  doing,  preferring  to  build  up  semimeta- 
physical  systems  of  sociology  or  to  construct  elaborate  rationalized  de- 
fenses of  their  own  orthodox  ethical  beliefs.  Socially-minded  psychia- 
trists and  educators  were  the  first  to  provide,  through  mental  hygiene,, 
a  concerted  and  well-organized  effort  to  get  at  the  facts  essential  to  the 
formulation  of  any  valid  code  for  individual  and  social  conduct.  Slowly 
and  very  recently,  some  of  the  more  progressive  sociologists  have  taken 
cognizance  of  these  developments,  as  has  been  demonstrated  by  the  works 
of  Thomas,  Ogburn,  Groves,  Bernard,  and  Young.  When,  and  only  when, 
the  proper  liaison  has  been  established  between  esthetics,  mental  hygiene, 
and  sociology,  will  there  at  last  be  provided,  after  several  generations  of 
cooperative  study,  a  real  science  of  conduct. 

The  Genesis  of  Moral  Codes 

One  of  the  best  modern  statements  of  the  conventional  supernatural 
and  metaphysical  theory  of  ethics  and  the  nature  of  moral  codes  is  con- 
tained in  Louis  T.  Morc's  The  Dogma  of  Evolution: 27 

As  for  the  facts  and  laws  of  morality,  it  is  conceded  that  they  have  been 
known  for  thousands  of  years.  .  .  .  Thus  moral  progress  is  not  coincident  with 
scientific  achievement  or  even  causally  related  to  it.  If  morals  were  merely  an 
adaptation  to  our  environment,  or  if  they  were  conventions  of  society,  then  they 
should  rise  and  fall  with  the  rhythm  of  rational  and  scientific  progress.  Instead 
of  such  variation,  the  standards  of  morality  remain  fixed  and  eternal  truths. 

The  manner  in  which  moral  codes  actually  develop  has  been  admirably 
described,  among  others,  by  Wilfred  Trotter  and  William  Graham  Sum- 
ner.28 In  the  process  of  social  evolution,  one  of  the  chief  requirements  of 
survival  has  been  group  cohesion  and  discipline.  It  has  been  secured  at, 
the  price  of  individual  conformity  to  the  commands  of  the  group.  The 
group,  or  herd,  has  always  been  swift  and  severe  in  its  punishment  of  the 

27  Princeton  University  Press,  1925. 

28  See  above,  Chaps.  I-IL 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         719 

nonconformist.  Primitive  man  regards  his  institutions  and  their  support- 
ing superstitions  as  the  product  of  a  special  divine  revelation.  As  Simmer 
puts  it:  "The  folkways  are  habits  of  the  individual  and  customs  of  the 
society  which  arise  from  efforts  to  satisfy  needs;  they  are  intertwined 
with  goblinism  and  demonism  and  primitive  notions  of  luck,  and  so  they 
win  traditional  authority.  They  become  regulative  for  succeeding 
generations  and  take  on  the  character  of  a  social  force.  ...  At  every 
turn  we  find  evidence  that  the  mores  can  make  anything  right  and  pre- 
vent the  condemnation  of  anything."  29 

We  may  be  sure  that  much  of  the  potential  originality  and  inventive- 
ness of  the  human  race  has  been  eliminated  through  the  extinction  of  the 
more  daring  and  independent  members  of  the  group.  The  codes  of  con- 
duct which  the  herd  has  enforced  with  rigor  and  savagery  have  never 
been  carefully  thought  out  or  experimentally  tested  modes  of  behavior. 
They  were,  rather,  the  crude  products  of  superstition  and  the  trial-and- 
error  methods,  whereby  man  has  been  able  to  effect  some  kind  of  working 
adjustment  to  his  environment  and  to  the  perpetuation  of  his  kind. 
This  origin  of  the  manners  and  customs  of  humanity  is  amply  demon- 
strated by  innumerable  ethnographic  studies  which  reveal  the  great 
diversity  of  human  practices  in  every  range  of  conduct  and  type  of 
behavior. 

In  this  manner  arose  those  standards  of  conduct  which  the  average 
person  designates  as  "the  old,  sturdy  virtues  of  manhood  and  woman- 
hood," "the  tried  wisdom  of  the  ages,"  "the  sanctity  of  the  fathers,"  "the 
enduring  and  permanent  foundations  of  our  institutions,"  and  other 
rhetorical  elaborations.  Only  the  historical  and  sociological  approach 
to  the  study  of  ethical  codes  can  make  completely  clear  the  misleading 
character  of  such  convictions. 

At  the  same  time,  it  docs  not  follow,  as  some  would  seem  to  believe, 
that  all  customs  thus  acquired  are  necessarily  wholly  unscientific  or 
harmful.  The  evolutionary  and  selective  processes  have  tended,  in  a 
rough  general  manner,  to  eliminate  those  groups  which  have  the  least 
efficient  codes  and  institutions.  The  fact  that  most  earlier  civilizations 
have  disintegrated  may  legitimately  lead  to  the  suspicion  that  the  evolu- 
tionary process  has  proved  that  earlier  mores,  considered  collectively, 
were  inadequate  and  led  ultimately  to  the  downfall  of  the  cultures  with 
which  they  were  associated.  However,  certain  specific  customs  within 
the  general  cultural  complex  may  accidentally  have  been  sound  and 
conducive  to  social  strength  and  cohesion. 

Directly  connected  with  the  metaphysical  and  supernatural  conception 
in  regard  to  the  derivation  and  nature  of  moral  codes  is  the  prevailing 
notion  as  to  how  man  becomes  conscious  of  right  and  wrong,  and  is  able  to 
seek  the  former  and  avoid  the  latter.  The  orthodox  and  popular  view  is 
that  there  is  some  metaphysical  entity,  called  the  "conscience,"  implanted 
in  every  human  breast.  Its.  "still,  small  voice"  reveals  to  man,  God's. 


20  Sec  above,  pp.  29  ff. 


720         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

uniform,  invariable,  and  immutable  will  on  all  questions,  from  throwing 
dice  to  casting  a  vote  for  president  of  the  United  States.  It  was  always 
difficult  to  harmonize  this  conception  with  the  observed  fact  that,  in 
certain  areas,  this  inner  conviction  led  some  to  prepare  for  a  respectable 
career  by  head-hunting  and  others,  in  a  different  part  of  the  globe,  by 
committing  to  memory  the  catechism  of  the  Roman  Catholic  church. 
Nor  was  it  easily  possible  to  explain  why  God  allowed  the  "still,  small 
voice"  to  speak  in  many  and  diverse  ways  to  individuals  in  the  same 
cultural  group.  Any  divergence  of  conduct  from  that  approved  by  the 
majority  of  the  herd  was  explained  by  the  hypothesis  of  the  devil  and  his 
influence. 

This  older  view  of  a  mysterious  conscience  has  been  replaced  in  modern 
dynamic  psychology  by  the  concept  of  the  censor  and  the  conditioned- 
reflex.  From  earliest  infancy,  the  contact  of  the  child  with  parents,  rela- 
tives, friends,  and  associates  brings  a  varied  but  potent  body  of  informa- 
tion. These  experiences  inculcate  ideas,  concepts,  and  attitudes  which 
determine  his  notions  of  what  is  right  and  wrong.  In  this  way,  the  ideas 
and  practices  of  the  great  and  little  herds,  with  which  the  individual 
comes  into  contact,  are  translated  into  individual  belief  and  action. 
There  is  little  probability  that  our  convictions  as  to  right  and  wrong,  thus 
derived,  bear  any  close  relation  to  the  scientific  facts  in  the  circumstances. 
Herd  opinion  and  activities  have  never  yet  been  founded  upon  scientific 
investigation  or  statistical  verification.  But  they  do  represent  what  our 
herds  believe  to  be  right,  and,  hence,  they  constitute  a  practical  guide  to 
life  in  a  given  community.  The  "still,  small  voice,"  then,  appears,  upon 
adequate  investigation,  not  to  be  the  voice  of  God,  but,  as  Professor  James 
Harvey  Robinson  once  facetiously  expressed  it,  "the  still,  small  voice  of 
the  herd." 

The  Essentials  of  a   Rational   Moral  Code 

The  supernatural  and  irrational  nature  of  our  conventional  ethical 
codes  and  their  rationalized  defense  can  probably  best  be  made  clear  by 
contrasting  with  them  our  attitudes  towards  matters  which  have  already 
been  brought  within  the  range  of  scientific  analysis  and  control.  If  we 
are  ill  in  any  manner  or  degree,  suffer  from  toothache,  have  a  leak  in  the 
plumbing,  need  a  garage  erected,  require  some  overhauling  of  the  motor 
in  our  car,  or  desire  a  radio  set  installed,  we  are  at  once  impressed  with 
the  reasonableness  and  necessity  of  conferring  with  a  trained  specialist  in 
the  field — a  physician,  dentist,  plumber,  mechanic,  or  electrician.  Yet, 
we  are  willing  to  accept  as  valid  judgments  upon  the  extremely  complex 
problems  of  conduct  the  standards  enunciated,  approved,  and  enforced  by 
persons  utterly  lacking  in  scientific  training. 

This  inconsistency  is  even  worse  than  it  might  seem  at  first  sight,  since 
the  foregoing  problems  for  the  solution  of  which  we  would  normally  have 
recourse  to  a  scientist  or  technician,  are  extremely  simple,  when  compared 
with  the  matter  of  solving  scientifically  the  problems  of  conduct.  The 
wholehearted  cooperation  of  a  large  number  of  scientific  experts  would 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         721 

be  essential  to  arrive  at  any  reliable  verdict  on  any  ethical  problem.  To 
formulate  even  the  most  tentative  body  of  ethical  doctrine,  which  could 
be  expected  to  possess  any  scientific  validity  and  command  the  respect 
of  a  critical  and  sceptical  intellect,  we  would  require  the  collaboration  of 
highly  intelligent  and  thoroughly  trained  respresentatives  of  chemistry, 
biology,  physiology,  medicine,  psychiatry,  psychology,  sociology,  eco- 
nomics, esthetics,  and  history.  To  deal  with  the  further  problem  of  the 
application  and  enforcement  of  a  code  of  conduct  we  would  need  the  aid 
of  the  political  scientists  and  the  students  of  jurisprudence,  education, 
and  journalism. 

Two  things,  then,  are  perhaps  the  most  conspicuous  about  the  sources 
of  guidance  for  the  "good  life"  in  terms  of  a  contemporaneous  view  of 
things:  (1)  the  multiplicity  of  those  secular  sciences  and  fields  of  endeavor 
which  must  be  drawn  upon,  and  (2)  the  essential  exclusion  of  the  theolo- 
gian in  this  process.  The  theologian,  in  the  modern  scheme  of  things,  has 
no  more  propriety  in  morals  and  esthetics  than  in  engineering  or  physical 
chemistry.  The  Bible,  as  such,  need  not  be  approached  with  any  more 
reverential  awe  respecting  its  injunctions  with  regard  to  human  conduct 
than  we  might  bring  to  it  when  studying  the  history  of  medicine  or  cos- 
mology. If  the  Ten  Commandments  are  to  be  obeyed  today,  it  is  only 
because  their  precepts  and  advice  may  be  proved  to  square  with  the  best 
natural  and  social  science  of  the  present  time.  They  must  be  subjected 
to  the  same  objective  scientific  scrutiny  as  that  which  we  would  apply  to 
the  cosmology  of  Genesis  or  the  medical  views  in  Leviticus. 

The  new  cosmic  perspective  and  biblical  criticism,  indeed,  rule  out  of 
civilized  nomenclature  one  of  the  basic  categories  of  all  religious  and 
metaphysical  morality,  namely,  sin.  One  may  admit  the  existence  of 
immorality  and  crime,  but  scarcely  sin,  which  is,  by  technical  definition, 
a  willful  and  direct  affront  to  God — a  violation  of  the  explicitly  revealed 
will  of  God.  Modern  science  has  shown  it  to  be  difficult  to  prove  the  very 
existence  of  God,  and  even  more  of  a  problem  to  show  any  direct  solicitude 
of  God  for  our  petty  and  ephemeral  planet.  Biblical  criticism,  the 
history  of  religion,  and  cultural  history  have  revealed  the  fact  that  we 
can,  in  no  direct  and  literal  sense,  look  upon  the  Bible  or  any  other  exist- 
ing holy  book  as  curely  embodying  the  revealed  will  of  God.  Conse- 
quently, if  we  do  not  and  cannot  know  the  nature  of  the  will  of  God  in 
regard  to  human  behavior,  we  cannot  very  well  know  when  we  are 
violating  it.  In  other  words,  sin  is  scientifically  indefinable  and  un- 
knowable. Hence,  sin  goes  into  the  limbo  along  with  such  ancient 
superstitions  as  witchcraft  and  sacrifice. 

It  is,  of  course,  true  that  many  acts  hitherto  branded  as  sinful  may  be 
socially  harmful,  but  such  action  should  be  scientifically  rechristened  as 
immoral  or  criminal,  and  we  should,  as  rapidly  as  possible,  dispense  with 
such  an  anachronistic  term  as  "sin,"  even  in  popular  phraseology.  In 
this  way  only  will  sin  "vanish  from  the  world!" 

It  can  be  conceded  that  the  sense  of  sin  is  a  genuine  human  experience 
with  many  persons,  and,  hence,  it  exists  as  a  psychological  reality.  The 


722         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS 

psychoanalysts  have,  however,  shown  that  the  "sense  of  sin"  is  a  psycho- 
physical  attribute  of  adolescent  mental  development. 

In  attempting  to  formulate  tentatively  the  essentials  of  an  efficient  and 
sound  ethical  system  it  would  be  necessary  first  to  consider  man  as  an 
animal,  and  to  catalogue  the  various  drives,  instincts,  impulses,  and 
motives  which  dominate  him  as  a  member  of  the  biological  world.  It 
would  then  be  essential  to  investigate  how  far,  with  regard  to  man  purely 
as  an  individual,  the  direct  and  immediate  expression  of  these  drives  and 
impulses,  with  the  satisfactions  thus  produced,  is  desirable  and  beneficial, 
and  to  what  degree  it  is  detrimental  and  should  be  repressed,  diverted,  or 
sublimated.  But  man  cannot  be  considered  solely  as  an  isolated  animal, 
existing  in  a  primitive  or  pre-cultural  age.  He  must  be  viewed  as  a 
member  of  an  advanced  and  cultivated  society,  with  intimate  and  com- 
plicated social  relationships,  obligations,  and  responsibilities. 

The  decision  as  to  what  is  best  for  him,  as  an  isolated  animal,  must, 
then,  be  modified  in  the  light  of  his  social  environment.  However,  any 
lessening  of  man's  organic  efficiency  and  quality  must  necessarily  ulti- 
mately weaken  and  undermine  his  social  institutions.  A  proper  balance 
must  be  struck  between  those  forms  of  conduct  which  secure  the  greatest 
amount  of  physical  vigor  and  psychic  efficiency  and  those  which  will 
produce  the  most  notable  cultural  achievements.  That  there  may  be 
some  clash  and  necessity  for  compromise  here  need  not  be  doubted,  but 
it  is  highly  probable  that  there  is  actually  far  less  divergence  than  is 
usually  assumed  between  those  forms  of  conduct  which  advance  the 
physical  well-being  of  a  nation  and  those  which  impel  it  to  higher  ranges 
of  cultural  progress. 

Our  notions  of  efficiency  in  the  determination  of  ethical  conduct  must 
be  broad  enough  to  include  a  consideration  of  esthetics  and  the  dictates 
of  "the  true  and  beautiful."  Indeed,  there  is  much  ground  upon  which  to 
support  the  contention  of  the  Earl  of  Shaftesbury  in  the  early  eighteenth 
century  that  virtue  and  morals  are  a  fine  art,  and  that  the  esthetic  criteria 
of  conduct  are  perhaps  the  most  valid  of  all.30  In  fact,  it  might  be  de- 
sirable to  give  up  entirely  the  old  category  of  morals  or  morality,  and 
substitute  a  term  more  accurately  descriptive  of  the  new  objective, 
namely,  morale.  As  the  late  G.  Stanley  Hall  has  put  it: 

If  there  is  any  chief  end  of  man,  any  goal  or  destiny  supreme  over  all  others 
...  it  is  simply  this — to  keep  ourselves,  body  and  soul,  and  pur  environment, 
physical,  social,  industrial,  etc.,  always  at  the  tip-top  of  condition.  This  super- 
hygiene  is  best  designated  as  morale.  ...  It  is  the  only  truly  divine  power  that 
ever  was  or  will  be.  Hence  it  follows  that  morale  thus  conceived  is  the  one  and 
only  true  religion  of  the  present  and  the  future,  and  its  doctrines  are  the  only 
true  theology.  Every  individual  situation  and  institution,  every  race,  nation, 
class,  or  group  is  best  graded  as  ascendent  or  decadent  by  its  morale.31 


80  See  below,  pp.  838  ff. 

81  Morale,  the  Supreme  Standard  of  Life  and  Conduct,  Appleton-Century,  1919, 
pp.  1-2. 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         723 

The  body  of  such  moral  practice,  or  the  foundations  of  morale,  would 
be  far  more  comprehensive  than  anything  now  prevailing.  It  would  not 
be  limited  to  formal  correctness  with  respect  to  an  archaic  attitude  to- 
wards sex,  but  would  promote  the  principles  of  honesty,  justice,  sym- 
pathy, and  kindliness  in  all  aspects  of  life.  Probably  more  would  also 
be  made  of  the  distinction  between  the  conventionally  "moral"  man  and 
"the  man  of  honor,"  with  the  latter  as  the  preferable  ideal.  H.  L. 
Mencken  has  well  distinguished  between  these  two  types  by  his  definition 
of  the  man  of  honor  as  a  person  who  sincerely  regrets  having  committed  a 
disreputable  act,  even  if  he  has  not  been  detected  in  it. 

The  difficultly  of  working  out  such  an  approximately  perfect  system  of 
conduct,  particularly  in  its  applicability  to  individual  guidance,  is  indi- 
cated by  the  great  differences  in  ability,  taste,  and  pliability  of  man. 
We  have,  more  or  less,  assumed  in  the  above  discussion  the  uniformity  of 
the  population  in  ability  and  native  endowment,  and  have  implied  that 
some  valid  code  of  conduct  can  be  worked  out  which  will  be  equally 
applicable  to  all  persons.  All  men  have  been  represented  in  pietistic 
tradition  as  equal  before  God.  But,  as  Aristotle  intuitively  perceived, 
and  Galton,  Pearson,  Terman,  and  their  associates  and  disciples  have 
proved,  this  is  one  of  the  most  obvious  fallacies  of  popular  social,  politi- 
cal, and  ethical  thought.  Wide  variations  in  capacity  and  personal 
control  appear  to  be  the  most  important  single  fact  about  the  human 
race,  thus  showing  that  mankind  conforms  to  the  general  implications  of 
the  normal  frequency  curve,  descriptive  of  the  variations  generally  ob- 
servable throughout  the  whole  realm  of  nature.  Therefore,  certain  kinds 
of  conduct  which  will  not  be  harmful  for  the  abler  members  of  society; 
which,  indeed,  may  be  positively  desirable  and  beneficial  for  them,  may 
be  dangerous  for  their  less  capable  fellow-citizens,  relatively  lacking  in 
poise,  self-control,  and  intellectual  discrimination.  There  are  vast  differ- 
ences among  men  and  women  in  physical  size,  strength,  endurance,  tastes, 
and  needs.  It  is  obviously  as  silly  to  prescribe  for  universal  observance 
a  meticulously  precise  and  uniform  code  of  conduct  as  it  would  be  to 
decree  that  every  man  must  wear  the  same  size  of  hat  and  every  woman 
the  same  size  of  shoe.  Some  general  uniformities  may  wisely  be  laid 
down,  provided  they  square  with  sound  science  and  esthetics,  but  mod- 
ern science  emphasizes  the  folly  of  demanding  identical  conduct  on  the 
part  of  all  mankind. 

Pluralism,  as  Montaigne  suggested  centuries  ago,  thus  becomes  a  prob- 
lem for  advanced  ethical  theory  quite  as  much  as  for  political  theory.  It 
raises  the  problem  of  man's  being  his  "brother's  keeper"  with  different 
implications.  Hitherto,  it  has  been  assumed  that  a  genius  should  repress 
his  desires,  cramp  and  paralyze  his  personality,  and  destroy  much  of  his 
power  for  creative  work,  so  that  a  dozen  morons  may  possibly  obtain  a 
hypothetical  harp  in  a  suppositions  New  Jerusalem.  In  the  light  of  the 
fact  that  all  human  progress  has  been  due  primarily  to  the  work  of  the 
able  few,  the  modern  student  of  ethical  theory  will  probably  assert  that 
it  is  better  to  sacrifice  a  thousand  morons  rather  than  seriously  to  handi- 


724         THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION   AND  MORALS 

cap  a  single  genius.  But  whether  or  not  one  accepts  this  generalization, 
the  problem  remains  one  of  adjusting  any  scientific  moral  code  to  the 
extensive  variations  in  human  capacity. 

And  again,  no  scientifically-oriented  person  would  expect  that  anything 
more  than  an  approximation  to  an  intelligent  system  of  ethics  could  be 
worked  out  by  pure  analysis,  even  by  the  most  competent  group  of 
cooperating  scientists  in  all  the  relevant  fields.  We  would  need  to  survey 
history,  to  discover,  so  far  as  possible,  the  effect  of  various  forms  of  con- 
duct in  the  past.  Above  all,  we  would  require  an  experimental  study  of 
the  effects  of  our  new  code  when  applied,  with  the  end  in  view  of  constant 
revision  as  experience  dictates  the  necessity  for  alterations. 

The  tenets  of  such  a  program  could  not  be  more  revolutionary  than 
the  very  assumptions  of  the  program — the  notion  of  a  tentative  and  exper- 
imental attitude  in  regard  to  conduct.  The  view  that  conduct  is  not 
divinely  inspired,  but  socially  determined,  and  should  be  frequently  re- 
vised and  adapted  to  changing  social  and  cultural  conditions  is  diametri- 
cally opposed  to  all  orthodox  views  of  ethical  theory  and  practice.  And 
the  proposal  embraced  in  the  above  discussion  regarding  the  possibility 
of  actually  bringing  together  an  adequate  group  of  scientists  to  construct 
a  scientific  body  of  ethical  doctrine,  and  then  getting  it  accepted  by  the 
mass  of  mankind,  may  be  fanciful  and  Utopian.  Progress  in  the  direction 
of  a  scientific,  esthetic  and  experimental  attitude  toward  conduct  will, 
in  all  probability,  be  achieved  only  very  slowly,  unconsciously,  and  in  a 
highly  piecemeal  fashion. 

The  aim  of  the  writer  will  have  been  executed  if  he  has:  (1)  made  clear 
the  extremely  complicated  and  technical  nature  of  the  quest  for  a  sound 
ethical  code;  and  (2)  shown  how  grotesque  it  is  for  us  to  approve  the 
views  on  ethics  held  by  the  average  metaphysician,  clergyman,  vice- 
crusader,  housewife,  or  Main  Street  gossip.  Yet  such  notions  are  today 
the  sovereign  guides  of  conduct  for  the  majority  of  mankind,  and  it  is 
difficult  for  even  the  ablest  of  the  race  to  disregard  them  with  impunity 
Even  otherwise  highly  emancipated  and  cultivated  persons  like  James 
Truslow  Adams  urge  their  continued  dominion  over  man.32 
i  The  whole  problem  of  ethical  reconstruction  is,  however,  something  of 
more  than  academic  or  curious  import.  Nothing  could  be  more  erroneous 
than  the  assumption  that,  with  the  growing  complexity  of  human  society 
and  the  decline  of  supernaturalism,  we  can  dispense  with  a  serious  con- 
sideration of  the  problems  of  conduct.  There  can  be  no  question  that 
we  are  today  in  far  greater  need  of  a  sound  body  of  morality  and  an 
ample  morale  than  at  any  earlier  time  in  history.  An  unscientific  and 
inefficient  standard  of  conduct  was  far  less  dangerous  in  a  static,  simple, 
agrarian  society  than  it  is  in  the  complex,  dynamic  urban  age  of  today. 
And  it  will  probably  be  necessary  to  enforce  the  desirable  new  standards 
rather  more  rigidly  than  previously. 


32  See  his  chapter  in  Living  Philosophies,  Simon  and  Schuster,  1932,  pp.  153  ff.,  on 
"Why  Be  Good?" 


THE  CRISIS   IN   RELIGION  AND  MORALS         725 

Before  we  go  far  in  this  direction,  however,  we  shall  need  to  discover 
by  scientific  means  the  nature  of  a  valid  code  of  conduct  and  make  sure 
that  we  are  not  trying  to  enforce  a  system  which  would  be  socially  dis- 
astrous. It  will  further  be  necessary  to  understand  that  to  enforce 
standards  of  conduct  may  be  futile  unless  preceded  by  an  adequate  cam- 
paign of  public  education.  If  man  fails  to  meet  the  responsibility,  the 
wreck  of  our  civilization  will  doubtless  be  the  penalty  which  we  shall  pay 
for  the  lack  of  a  sound  moral  code,  as  our  predecessors  have  invariably 
paid  it  in  previous  ages. 

The  foregoing  discussion  should  certainly  make  apparent  how  danger- 
ous and  inaccurate  it  is  to  maintain  a  distinction  between  "character"  and 
intelligence.  There  are,  to  be  sure,  many  examples  of  men  of  high  intelli- 
gence who  are  utterly  lacking  in  a  sense  of  honor  or  decency,  or  in  funda- 
mental honesty  and  fairness,  in  exactly  the  same  way  that  there  are  many 
arrogant  scoundrels  among  the  clergy  of  the  United  States  and  among 
foreign  missionaries.  But  to  assume  that  this  constitutes  any  basis  for 
divorcing  intelligence  from  morality  is  as  absurd  as  it  would  be  to  con- 
clude that  no  clergyman  or  missionary  could  be  moral. 

While  there  may  be  intelligent  men  who  are  not  moral,  there  can  cer- 
tainly be  no  truly  moral  men  who  are  not  intelligent,  unless  one  means 
by  morality  unreasoning  obedience  to  the  dictates  of  the  herd.  If  one 
accepts  this  latter  as  the  criterion  of  moral  conduct,  then  many  animals 
and  most  insects  are  far  more  highly  moral  than  any  man.  Indeed,  one 
can  probably  say  that  there  is  no  completely  intelligent  person  who  is  not, 
at  the  same  time,  moral  in  the  scientific  sense  of  that  term.  Any  devia- 
tion from  sound  morality  would  constitute,  to  that  degree,  evidence  of 
shortqornings  in  his  intelligence. 


CHAPTER  XVIII 
Education  in  the  Social  Crisis 

The  Vital    Importance  of  Education  Today 

WE  HAVE  already  suggested  that  mankind  is  now  in  one  of  the  great 
transitional  periods  of  human  history,  comparable  to  the  dawn  of  history, 
to  the  breakup  of  classical  civilization  with  the  decline  of  the  Roman 
Empire,  or  to  the  disintegration  of  medieval  society  with  the  rise  of  mod- 
ern times  between  1500  and  1800.  In  this  transitional  age  the  most 
striking  thing  about  our  culture  is  the  vast  gulf  which  exists  between  the 
mechanical  era  in  which  we  live  and  the  outworn  institutions  by  which 
we  attempt  to  control  our  new  empire  of  machines.1  We  are  proud  of 
our  material  equipment  in  proportion  to  its  being  thoroughly  up  to  the 
minute  in  model  and  performance;  but  we  almost  seem  to  take  pride  in 
our  thinking  and  institutions  in  the  degree  to  which  they  are  out  of  date 
and  inadequate  to  meet  the  emergencies  of  the  present.  Only  when  we 
have  become  as  ashamed  of  an  out-of-date  idea  or  institution  as  we  are 
of  an  out-moded  bathtub  or  radio  will  there  be  much  prospect  of  our 
taking  steps  to  build  a  civilized  social  order. 

We  even  encourage  this  already  serious  discrepancy  between  our  ma- 
terial life  and  our  social  thinking.  We  give  every  conceivable  reward 
and  encouragement  to  those  who  seek  to  invent  new  machines.  On  the 
other  hand  we  persecute,  threaten,  or  even  cast  into  jail  those  who  would 
invent  the  new  social  machinery  that  we  must  have  if  civilization  is  to 
be  maintained.  We  honor  our  Edisons  but  laugh  to  scorn  our  "brain 
trusts"  in  government  and  economics. 

All  our  contemporary  problems  are  secondary  manifestations  of  this 
gulf  between  the  two  aspects  of  our  civilization.  Because  we  have  failed 
to  improve  our  political  institutions,  in  keeping  with  the  changes  in  the 
last  century,  we  now  find  ourselves  faced  by  the  desperate  situation  aris- 
ing out  of  the  bellicosity  of  great  national  states  and  the  inadequacies  of 
democracy  and  capitalism  in  meeting  the  complicated  problems  of  our 
industrial  age.  The  answer  to  this  is  "crisis  government,"  which  means 
some  form  of  dictatorship.  In  the  economic  field,  the  failure  of  capital- 
ism to  insure  productive  efficiency,  to,,provide  for  a  fair  distribution  of 
the  social  income,  and  to  check  the  speculative  manipulations  of  finance, 
has  already  so  undermined  the  capitalistic  system  as  to  call  for  the 
intervention  of  force  and  Fascism  in  most  of  the  important  states  of  the 


1  See  above,  Chap.  III. 

726 


EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  727 

world.  In  the  economic  realm,  Fascism  is  the  answer  to  the  crisis  in 
capitalism,  as,  in  its  political  expression,  it  is  the  answer  to  the  crisis  in 
democracy.  It  is  often  asserted  that  the  only  sound  solution  of  our  social 
problems  is  to  be  found  in  education.  This  is  probably  true,  but  it  will 
require  a  different  system  of  education  from  that  which  is  now  in  opera- 
tion. 

The  men  who  made  the  first  World  War,  those  who  threw  us  into  it, 
those  responsible  for  the  great  depression  of  1929,  and  those  who  brought 
on  and  extended  the  second  World  War  were  literally  the  best  that  our 
educational  system  could  produce;  and  their  works  are  as  much  as  we 
can  reasonably  expect  from  this  type  of  education. 

The  world  finds  itself  today  in  a  serious  social,  economic,  and  political 
crisis.  We  must  go  ahead  or  backward.  All  sane  persons  want  civiliza- 
tion to  move  ahead  rather  than  collapse.  Education  can  provide  the 
only  safe  and  assured  leadership  toward  progress  and  prosperity. 

If  we  are  going  to  move  ahead  we  have  a  clear  choice — and  only  this 
choice — between  orderly  progress,  under  intelligent  guidance,  or  revolu- 
tion, violence,  and  a  gambling  chance  with  the  future.  If  we  choose 
orderly  social  advance,  we  must  rely  more  and  more  upon  the  educational 
direction  of  the  social  process.  The  problems  of  today  have  become  so 
complicated  and  technical  that  only  well-educated  public  servants  can 
hope  to  deal  with  them  effectively. 

If  education  is  going  to  assume  a  more  important  role  in  public  affairs, 
it  must  setjis  own  house  in  order  and  prepare  itself  for  realistic  instruc- 
tion in  terms  of  contemporary  facts.  The  present  system  of  education  is 
inadequate  to  supply  the  type  of  leadership  which  is  necessary  in  the 
current  world  crisis.  It  failed  to  live  up  to  the  responsibilities  of  the  last 
generation.  It  did  not  save  the  world  from  war  or  depression. 

We  must  eliminate  useless  antiquities  from  the  curriculum,  stress  the 
realities  of  the  twentieth  century,  and  offer  protection  to  members  of  the 
teaching  profession  who  expound  courageously  and  honestly  the  facts  as 
they  see  them. 

The  social  studies  present  the  only  cogent  information  that  can  enable 
us  to  bridge  the  gulf  between  machines  and  institutions.  More  time 
should  be  given  to  the  social  studies;  also,  their  content  must  be  made 
more  vital  and  be  linked  up  with  the  immediate  problems  of  our  day. 
We  must  provide  security  for  the  teachers  of  the  social  studies,  for  it  is 
here  that  most  of  the  heresy-hunts  are  waged.  No  teacher  is  in  much 
danger  analyzing  the  binomial  theorem,  but  the  teacher  who  resolutely 
describes  our  economic  and  political  system  is  constantly  flirting  with 
dismissal. 

Education  is  our  best  safeguard — almost  our  only  safeguard — against 
Fascism  and  Communism,  and  the  foremost  bulwark  of  democracy. 
The  more  courageous  and  realistic  it  is,  the  better  will  it  serve  such  pur- 
poses. If  it  is  cowardly,  evasive,  and  time-serving,  it  cannot  aspire  to 
vigorous  leadership.  Indeed,  it  will  only  contribute  to  the  inevitability 
of  general  misery  and  chaos.  If  the  latter  comes,  education  will  share 
in  it  to  a  particularly  disastrous  degree.  In  an  era  of  social  decline  and 


728  EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

barbarism,  there  is  little  place  for  education.  Let  those  who  are  scepti- 
cal about  this  statement  study  the  history  of  the  Dark  Ages.  And  let 
those  who  are  sceptical  about  the  return  of  another  Dark  Age  study  world 
events  of  the  last  fifteen  years. 

Some  Landmarks  in  the  History  of  Education 

With  our  present  great  educational  plant  and  our  compulsory  education 
for  all  children,  it  is  difficult  for  us  to  realize  that  it  has  been  only  about 
100  years  since  we  began  to  provide  schools  for  all  children,  even  in  the 
most  highly  civilized  countries.  Free  public  education  for  youth  has  been 
a  product  of  contemporary  civilization. 

Yet  education,  even  though  it  was  not  provided  in  schools,  has  existed 
since  prehistoric  times  and  cave-man  culture.  The  social  customs,  be- 
liefs, and  manual  arts  which  prevailed  in  any  primitive  group  were  taught 
to  the  children  from  an  early  age.  At  certain  special  times  there  were 
also  formal  ceremonies  devoted  to  giving  information  about  religious 
and  moral  folkways.  These  were  the  famous  initiation  rites  of  primitive 
society.  The  general  purpose  of  primitive  education  was  to  inculcate  the 
wisdom  of  the  elders,  and  great  respect  was  developed  therefor.  It  was 
from  primitive  society  that  we  derived  our  paralyzing  respect  for  the 
knowledge  of  the  past,  or,  what  has  been  called  by  Herbert  Spencer,  "the 
dead  hand." 

In  afccient  oriental  times  the  "wisdom"  of  the  past  was  handed  down 
by  the  ^priesthood,  in  conjunction  with  the  family  education.  Instruction 
in  the  mechanical  arts  came  chiefly  from  skilled  workmen  in  homes  and 
shops.  It  is  in  this  age  that  we  discover  the  origins  of  natural  and  ap- 
plied science.  This  arose  chiefly  in  association  with  practical  activities, 
such  as  surveying  and  the  study  of  the  rise  and  fall  of  water  levels.  Even 
medicine  and  surgery  were  regarded  chiefly  as  skilled  crafts.  Since  the 
great  mass  of  the  people  could  neither  read  nor  write,  such  education  as 
they  received  in  matters  of  folkways,  religion,  and  morals  was  imparted 
by  word  of  mouth.  However,  some  great  libraries  were  collected,  and 
educational  centers  were  established  where  scholars  could  gather  and  dis- 
pense the  information  they  possessed. 

Among  the  ancient  Greeks  we  find  the  origins  of  formal  education, 
though  this  was  limited  to  the  children  of  citizens.  The  youth  among 
the  slaves  and  foreigners  picked  up  such  education  as  was  given  them  in 
a  purely  informal  manner.  In  Sparta,  we  find  the  origins  of  rigorous 
discipline  in  education  and  the  stressing  of  military  training  and  loyalty 
to  the  state.  The  boys  were  thrown  into  barracks  at  an  early  age,  given 
severe  physical  training,  and  taught  the  arts  of  war.  There  was  little 
literary  education  beyond  chanting  ancient  laws  and  passages  from 
Homer.  Bravery,  brutality,  and  loyalty  to  the  state  were  the  essentials 
of  Spartan  education. 

In  ancient  Athens,  a  broader  conception  prevailed.  Physical  educa- 
tion, music,  reading,  and  writing  were  the  main  subjects  prescribed  for 


EDUCATION    IN  THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS  729 

the  Athenian  boys.  The  copying  and  memorizing  of  passages  from  the 
Greek  classics  constituted  the  chief  literary  education.  At  the  age  of  18, 
the  boys  were  placed  in  the  army  and  given  two  years  of  military  train- 
ing. Those  who  were  trained  for  public  life  were  given  more  extended 
instruction  in  rhetoric,  literature,  and  logic.  The  ability  to  make  a  florid 
speech  and  to  carry  on  oral  argument  was  regarded  as  indispensable  to  a 
successful  life  in  politics.  It  was  from  the  Greeks  that  we  derived  the 
educational  dogma  that  rhetorical  talent  and  literary  flourishes  are  the 
chief  marks  of  an  educated  man.  Universities  first  appeared  among  the 
Greeks  at  Athens,  Alexandria,  and  Rhodes.  Here  scholars  gathered  and 
produced  those  contributions  to  philosophy  and  natural  science  for  which 
the  Greeks  were  justly  famous.  The  Sophists  earnestly  tried  to  bring 
Greek  education  down  to  earth  and  to  give  it  a  practical  cast.  But  they 
met  the  same  opposition  from  conservative  pedants  that  comparable  edu- 
cational reformers  have  encountered  in  our  day. 

The  Romans  were  influenced  in  their  educational  ideals  by  the  Greeks, 
as  they  were  in  all  other  phases  of  their  intellectual  life.  Elementary  and 
secondary  education  were  mainly  designed  to  prepare  one  for  a  study  of 
rhetoric,  and  instruction  in  the  latter  remained  the  basic  preparation  for 
successful  public  life.  Toward  the  end  of  the  Roman  Empire,  a  precise 
and  stereotyped  curriculum  was  provided  for  general  literary  education, 
the  so-called  seven  liberal  arts:  namely  grammar,  rhetoric,  and  logic 
(the  trivium),  and  arithmetic,  geometry,  astronomy,  and  music  (the 
quadrivium).  While  it  had  been  in  practical  use  for  a  long  time,  this 
curriculum  was  first  formally  outlined  by  Martinus  Capella,  a  pedantic 
scholar  who  is  thought  to  have  lived  in  the  fourth  century  A.D.  With 
certain  modifications  and  elaborations,  this  curriculum  has  remained  the 
basis  of  formal  education  from  Roman  times  to  our  own  day.  Our 
Bachelor  of  Arts  degree  in  the  colleges  is  derived  from  it  directly. 

In  the  Middle  Ages  there  were  remarkable  changes  in  education,  as 
compared  with  the  situation  in  Greece  and  Rome.  A  great  part  of  the 
learning  of  classical  antiquity  was  lost,  as  a  result  of  the  general  decline  of 
culture  in  the  later  Roman  period  and  the  early  Middle  Ages.  Education 
was  far  more  limited  than  it  had  been  under  the  Greeks  and  Romans,  and 
its  content  was  far  less  reliable.  Moreover,  education  was  primarily  de- 
voted to  the  promotion  of  religion  and  the  salvation  of  the  soul  rather 
than  to  training  for  public  life.  The  greater  part  of  education  for  public 
life  was  provided  in  the  castle  society  of  the  feudal  system,  where  the 
young  nobles  were  trained  for  future  knights  and  lords.  The  schools 
did,  however,  offer  some  instruction  which  was  useful  in  public  life, 
particularly  training  as  scribes  and  secretaries.  Most  of  the  learned  men 
were  churchmen,  especially  the  monks;  for  a  long  time  the  schools  were 
almost  exclusively  in  the  hands  of  the  church.  Even  after  universities 
were  established,  the  churchmen  usually  retained  a  dominant  control  over 
their  organization  and  activities. 

Education  was  chiefly  devoted  to  instruction  in  the  trivium.  The  text- 
books were  incredibly  brief  and  dull,  usually  the  merest  compilations 


730  EDUCATION    IN  THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS 

which  medieval  monks  had  condensed  from  the  works  of  Greek  and 
Roman  scholars.  In  addition  to  these  were  the  textbooks  in  theology 
which  had  been  supplied  by  the  church  fathers  and  medieval  theologians. 
Most  of  the  teachers  in  the  schools  and  universities  were  monks.  In 
short,  the  great  mass  of  the  people  in  the  Middle  Ages  were  illiterate  and 
had  no  literary  education  whatsoever,  except  when  rarely  provided  in  a 
crude  form  of  family  instruction.  The  formal  schools  were  devoted 
chiefly  to  training  clergymen  for  religious  practices.  Even  the  training 
of  lawyers  and  doctors  in  the  medieval  universities  was  based  on  abstract 
logic  and  authority  rather  than  upon  a  scientific  study  of  cases. 

One  of  the  most  interesting  developments  in  medieval  education  was 
that  associated  with  the  rise  of  universities  in  the  twelfth  and  thirteenth 
centuries.  A  French  monk,  Peter  Abelard  (1074-1142),  showed  that  an 
understanding  of  logic  was  absolutely  indispensable  to  a  proper  mastery 
of  theology.  Since  the  latter  was  looked  upon  as  the  queen  of  the  sci- 
ences, it  was  necessary  to  leave  no  stone  unturned  to  improve  its  content. 
Consequently,  the  earlier  universities  were  devoted  primarily  to  training 
in  logic  and  its  accessories,  such  as  grammar  and  rhetoric.  The  general 
spirit  of  medieval  education  is  well  expressed  in  the  phrase  to  the  effect 
that  "the  sword  of  God's  words  is  forged  by  grammer,  sharpened  by 
logic,  and  burnished  by  rhetoric,  but  only  theology  can  use  it."  Only  a 
few  courses,  devoted  to  training  in  the  art  of  writing  letters,  executing 
legal  forms,  drawing  up  proclamations,  making  out  bills,  and  the  like, 
offered  much  practical  and  secular  education  during  the  medieval  period 
in  undergraduate  courses.  Graduate  instruction  in  law  and  medicine 
represented  a  secular  element  in  the  educational  system,  but  even  these 
were  usually  taught  by  the  same  logical  method  that  dominated  the- 
ology. 

The  universities  were  based  upon  the  form  of  organization  already  pro- 
vided by  the  medieval  industrial  corporations  or  guilds.  Indeed,  the 
very  words  college  and  university  came  from  the  titles  of  these  medieval 
guilds:  namely,  universitas  and  collegium.  The  Bachelor  of  Arts  degree 
was  given  for  proficiency  in  the  seven  liberal  arts,  particularly  the  trivium. 
Contrary  to  the  general  impression,  it  was  not  related  to  any  mastery  of 
the  Greek  and  Latin  languages  and  literatures.  Even  instruction  in  law 
and  medicine  was  given  according  to  the  same  canons  and  doctrines  of 
logic  that  were  employed  in  theology.  A  great  deal  of  the  formal  bag- 
gage of  education — such  as  the  official  titles  of  professors,  deans,  rectors, 
and  the  like;  periodic  examinations,  academic  degrees,  academic  regalia 
and  ritual;  and  the  severe  and  solemn  conceptions  of  academic  dignity 
and  good  taste — has  all  been  a  heritage  from  the  medieval  university. 

From  medieval  times  is  derived  the  traditional  importance  of  religion 
in  education  and  the  religious  ends  of  education.  Moreover,  churchmen 
often  remained  in  charge  of  schools  down  to  the  present  century.  In 
Catholic  schools  and  universities,  the  clergy,  monks,  and  nuns  are  in 
charge  of  instruction.  Only  recently  has  theology  been  dislodged  by 
natural  and  social  science  from  its  position  as  the  queen  of  the  sciences. 


EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  731 

From  the  later  Middle  Ages  and  early  modern  times  we  derived  the 
traditional  respect  for  classical  languages  and  literature  which  dominated 
educational  philosophy  and  procedure  right  down  into  the  twentieth  cen- 
tury. The  first  step  toward  reviving  the  study  of  Greek  and  Roman 
literature  came  in  the  early  fifteenth  century,  as  a  healthy  revolt  against 
the  sterility  and  other-worldliness  of  medieval  education.  Educational 
pioneers  like  Vittorino  da  Feltre  (1378-1446)  revived  the  broad  educa- 
tional interests  of  Greece  and  Rome  under  the  label  of  the  so-called  "hu- 
manities." The  latter  were  supposed  to  involve  the  information  necessary 
to  produce  a  cultivated  man  of  the  world,  including  physical  training. 
The  classical  languages  and  literatures  were  regarded  as  a  central  feature 
in  this  type  of  education.  They  were  at  first  merely  the  means  to  a  laud- 
able end,  but  in  due  time  they  became  an  end  in  themselves.  Cicero 
cast  a  tremendous  spell  over  the  school  teachers  of  the  early  modern  age, 
and  it  was  not  long  before  the  humanities  degenerated  into  a  slavish 
linguistic  enterprise  devoted  to  a  mastery  of  the  involved  Latin  language 
of  Cicero.  Perhaps  the  most  influential  leader  in  this  degradation  of  the 
classics  was  Johannes  Sturm  (1507-1589),  principal  of  the  famous  classi- 
cal school  at  Strassburg.  This  trend  was  followed  all  over  western 
Europe  and  the  study  of  the  classics  became  little  more  than  a  pedantic 
excursion  into  intellectual  slavery,  in  which  the  beauties  of  the  classical 
literatures  and  culture  were  lost  sight  of  amidst  the  punitive  mazes  of 
classical  syntax. 

The  educational  philosophy  that  accompanied  this  sterile  instruction 
was  entirely  compatible  with  it:  namely,  the  theory  that  the  will  should 
be  developed  through  gloom  in  the  schoolroom,  accompanied  by  plenty  of 
physical  punishment.  One  highly  successful  teacher,  for  example, 
proudly  computed  that  during  his  career  he  had  given  911,527  strokes 
with  a  stick,  124,000  lashes  with  a  whip,  136,715  slaps  with  the  hand, 
and  1,115,800  boxes  on  the  ear. 

In  the  seventeenth  and  eighteenth  centuries,  a  number  of  educational 
doctrines  of  great  importance  for  the  later  progress  of  a  realistic  and 
socialized  education  were  enunciated.  The  first  outstanding  educational 
theorist  of  modern  times  was  Johann  Amos  Comenius  (1592-1670), 
author  of  a  famous  book  known  as  The  Great  Didactic.  He  protested 
against  the  tyranny  of  logic  and  of  classical  syntax  alike.  He  believed 
that  the  subject  matter  of  education  should  be  adapted  to  the  mental  age 
of  the  child,  holding  that  instruction  should  be  both  natural  and  pleasant. 
He  was  one  of  the  first  to  demand  universal  education  for  both  boys  and 
girls.  It  was  not  until  the  late  nineteenth  century  that  these  ideals  were 
rather  thoroughly  adopted  in  educational  procedure.  The  eminent  phi- 
losopher John  Locke  laid  great  stress  upon  rational  education  as  a  means 
of  developing  a  well-trained  mind,  and  suggested  the  value  of  manual 
training  for  the  children  of  the  poor.  Voltaire  assailed  both  classical 
syntax  and  religious  instruction.  In  the  middle  of  the  eighteenth  century, 
the  French  reformer  Claude  Helvetius  anticipated  the  democratic  educa- 
tors of  the  nineteenth  century  by  defending  the  right  of  the  masses  to  a 


732  EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

thorough  education.  He  was  one  of  the  first  to  believe  that  the  lower 
classes  were  mentally  just  as  capable  as  the  upper  classes. 

One  of  the  most  influential  books  ever  written  in  the  history  of  educa- 
tion was  Rousseau's  Smile  (1762),  a  devastating  criticism  of  the  sterility 
and  artificiality  of  the  conventional  schools  of  his  day.  He  believed  that 
rational  education  is  chiefly  a  matter  of  giving  a  wise  direction  to  the 
natural  curiosity  of  the  child.  He  advocated  adaption  of  educational 
practice  to  human  nature  and  stressed  universal  education.  Rousseau's 
ideas  exerted  a  great  influence  on  educational  reforms  in  the  nineteenth 
century.  They  were  introduced  into  formal  pedagogy  by  Basedow,  Pes- 
talozzi,  Herbart,  and  Froebel.  The  education  of  women  found  its  first 
loyal  advocate  in  the  French  reformer  Condorcet  (1743-1794).  The 
revolt  against  the  worship  of  the  classics  in  the  universities  was  aided  by 
Christian  Thomasius,  a  Leipzig  professor  of  the  early  eighteenth  century. 
A  tendency  toward  realism  and  utility  in  education  appeared  when 
technical  schools  began  to  be  founded,  around  the  middle  of  the  eight- 
eenth century.  Though  most  of  these  advanced  theories  were  not  gener- 
ally accepted  until  the  nineteenth  and  twentieth  cnturies,  many  of  our 
more  important  educational  philosophies  date  back  to  the  period  between 
Comenius  and  Rousseau. 

The  nineteenth  century  was  a  period  of  remarkable  educational  fer- 
ment and  revolution.  The  power  of  the  church  over  education  was 
broken.  Public  education  under  state  auspices  became  more  usual. 
Frederick  the  Great  established  a  public  school  system  for  Prussia,  and 
in  1794  a  law  was  passed  establishing  free  compulsory  education  in  that 
country.  France  flirted  with  public  education  throughout  the  nineteenth 
century  and  finally  established  free  compulsory  education  in  1882.  Eng- 
land lagged  behind,  and  it  was  not  until  1918  that  an  adequate  public 
school  system  was  provided  there. 

The  leaders  of  the  struggle  for  free  public  education  in  the  United 
States  were  James  Gordon  Carter,  Horace  Mann,  and  Henry  Barnard. 
They  were  thorough  democrats  and  believed  that  democracy  could  not 
be  successfully  operated  without  free  public  instruction.  Aided  by 
Carter's  legislative  efforts,  Mann  was  able  to  set  up  the  first  department 
of  public  instruction  in  Massachusetts  in  1837.  This  departure  was 
widely  imitated  after  the  Civil  War. 

But  these  early  reformers,  who  led  in  making  education  available  to 
the  masses,  committed  one  tragic  sin  of  omission.  They  failed  to  give 
due  consideration  to  the  content  of  the  education  needed  to  fit  the  masses 
to  operate  a  democracy.  Instead  of  devising  a  curriculum  suitable  to 
democratic  objectives  and  experiences,  they  permitted  teachers  to  con- 
tinue a  type  of  instruction  which  had  been  worked  out  by  educators  of 
the  fifteenth  century  for  the  purpose  of  instructing  the  children  of  the 
decadent  feudal  nobility  and  the  rising  urban  bourgeoisie.  Hence  we 
failed  for  a  century  to  train  American  children  for  life  in  a  democracy, 
and,  by  the  time  we  realized  the  mistake,  it  was  all  but  too  late  to  correct 
the  error.  Fascism  was  just  around  the  corner. 


EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  733 

Teachers  were,  however,  better  trained,  and  were  enabled  to  develop  a 
more  intelligent  attitude  toward  the  mentality  of  the  child.  Friedrich 
Froebel  (1782-1852),  a  disciple  of  Rousseau,  first  established  the 
kindergarten  for  the  training  of  very  young  children.  Scientific  child 
study,  based  upon  the  new  psychology,  was  introduced  by  educators  sucli 
as  G.  Stanley  Hall.  Normal  schools  and  teachers>  colleges  arose  to 
provide  formal  instruction  in  pedagogical  science.  Sociology  showed  the 
relation  of  schools  and  education  to  a  better  understanding  of  human 
society  and  suggested  ways  of  guiding  social  change  in  an  efficient  and 
non-violent  manner. 

Some  headway  was  made  in  uprooting  the  stereotyped  curriculum 
which  we  had  inherited  from  the  Middle  Ages  and  the  Humanists.  The 
vernacular  languages  and  literatures  challenged  the  dominion  of  the 
classics.  Natural  science  gradually  forced  its  way  into  the  universities 
and  ultimately  into  the  schools.  In  the  latter  part  of  the  nineteenth  cen- 
tury the  social  sciences  also  gained  considerable  respect  in  the  colleges 
and  universities,  though  they  were  generally  neglected  in  the  schools. 
Greater  flexibility  and  rationality  in  education  were  provided  by  the  elec- 
tive system,  first  introduced  in  a  limited  way  by  President  Charles  W. 
Eliot  at  Harvard  University  in  1869.  This  allowed  students  to  have 
some  freedom  in  selecting  the  subjects  they  proposed  to  study. 

The  twentieth  century  has  brought  many  interesting  innovations  in 
education.  The  public  support  of  education  has  enabled  us  to  build  a 
physical  plant  devoted  to  the  instruction  of  youth.  The  average  high 
school  building  in  a  small  American  city  is  a  very  impressive  structure 
compared  to  the  greatest  of  medieval  universities.  We  have  developed 
educational  machinery  which  has  enabled  us  to  carry  on  mass  education 
in  an  ever  more  smooth  and  convenient  fashion.  Millions  of  children 
now  attend  school,  in  the  place  of  the  few  thousands  who  were  lucky 
enough  to  get  an  education  in  earlier  centuries. 

It  is  doubtful,  however,  that  mass  education  is  well  adapted  for  the 
more  capable  or  the  more  retarded  children.  Indeed,  it  is  contended 
that  mass  education  even  restricts  and  limits  the  natural  impulses  and 
capabilities  of  the  average  pupil.  Hence,  we  have  had  experimental 
schools  devoted  both  to  instruction  and  to  a  study  of  the  mind  of  the  child. 
Leaders  in  this  movement  have  been  Francis  Parker  and  John  Dewey. 
An  Italian  educator,  Maria  Montessori,  went  far  beyond  Froebel  in  her 
study  of  the  child  mind  and  her  reforms  of  the  kindergarten  system. 
Even  more  sweeping  was  the  development  of  what  is  known  as  the 
Progressive  Education  Movement,  a  revolt  against  the  formalities  and 
artificialities  of  mass  education  and  ordinary  school  administration. 
Progressive  education  aims  to  combine  sane  and  realistic  instruction 
with  the  provision  of  an  educational  experience  so  pleasant  that  children 
will  enjoy  attending  school.  An  extreme  example  of  this  reaction  is  the 
Dalton  system  of  instruction,  where  pupils  study  those  subjects  they 
wish,  when  and  as  they  desire  to  do  so.  The  mental  hygiene  movement 
and  the  scientific  study  of  feeble-mindedness  have  provided  better  in- 


734  EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

struction  for  retarded  children.  Mentally  defective  children  can  make 
commendable  progress  in  the  manual  arts.  A  revolution  has  taken  place 
in  higher  education.  In  the  nineteenth  century  it  was  a  rare  person  who 
had  a  chance  to  attend  a  college  or  university.  Today,  there  are  1,350,- 
000  students  in  our  colleges  and  universities,  about  190,000  being  grad- 
uated each  year. 

While  far  too  much  of  the  old  stereotyped  "liberal"  curriculum  remains, 
there  have  been  important  changes  in  the  scope  of  education  in  the  twen- 
tieth century.  The  social  sciences  have  become  more  popular  in  colleges 
and  universities  and  are  also  now  being  widely  introduced  into  schools. 
The  evidences  of  the  possible  downfall  of  capitalism  and  democracy  have 
led  thoughtful  persons  to  consider  how  far  an  inadequate  educational 
system  has  been  responsible  therefor.  Hence  more  stress  has  been  laid 
upon  realistic  social  science  as  a  means  of  appraising  existing  institutions 
and  of  guiding  us  more  safely  along  the  path  of  social  change.  But  the 
social  sciences  have  not  progressed  rapidly  enough  or  been  sufficiently 
exploited  in  education  to  enable  our  social  institutions  to  keep  pace 
with  our  machinery,  thus  creating  the  unfortunate  situation  we  mentioned 
at  the  outset  of  this  chapter. 

With  the  development  of  Fascism,  Communism,  and  the  totalitarian 
states  in  Europe,  education  has  been  made  a  vehicle  of  political  propa- 
ganda and  of  economic  change.  It  is  also  inculcating  an  attitude  of 
super-patriotism  which  bodes  ill  for  the  future  peace  and  safety  of 
humanity.  In  Russia  we  have  the  first  notable  instance  of  an  educa- 
tional policy  and  system  devoted  primarily  to  the  instruction  and  well- 
being  of  the  lower  classes. 

The  foregoing  brief  survey  of  the  development  of  education  indicates 
the  major  landmarks  in  the  evolution  of  educational  theory  and  practice 
and  will  enable  us  to  discuss  with  greater  insight  the  outstanding  prob- 
lems of  contemporary  education. 

Mass  Education:   Plant,  Administration,  and  Curriculum 

One  of  the  major  influences  of  democracy  on  education  was  to  bring 
about  mass  education  and  to  make  the  latter  virtually  a  manifesta- 
tion of  big  business.  It  became  an  ever  firmer  conviction  that  democracy 
requires  mass  education.  This  impulse,  together  with  humanitarian 
influences,  led  to  the  passage  of  many  state  laws  forbidding  child  labor. 
An  ever  larger  number  of  children  were  thus  free  to  attend  school.  Com- 
pulsory education  laws  were  passed,  and  free  education  was  made  the 
opportunity  of  every  American  child.  The  expenses  of  school  attendance 
were,  more  and  more,  taken  over  by  public  authorities,  often  to  the  extent 
of  providing  children  with  their  textbooks  and  transportation  to  and 
from  school. 

Hence,  it  is  not  surprising  that,  by  1936,  there  were  enrolled  in  Ameri- 
can schools  and  institutions  of  higher  learning  approximately  30,600,000 
of  American  youth,  with  some  1,073,000  teachers  required  to  give  instruc- 


EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  735 

tion.2  About  one  fourth  of  the  whole  population  of  the  country  is  thus, 
at  any  time,  primarily  absorbed  in  the  business  of  education.  In  1900, 
there  were  only  696,000  pupils  in  secondary  schools,  while  this  number 
had  jumped  to  6,425,000  in  1936.  The  number  of  public  high  schools 
increased  from  16,300  in  1918  to  25,652  in  1936.  The  students  in  Ameri- 
can institutions  of  higher  education  numbered  some  237,000  in  1900,  and 
1,208,000  in  1936,  an  increase  of  about  350  per  cent.  The  population 
of  the  country  as  a  whole  had  increased  only  83  per  cent  in  these  36 
years. 

While  the  overwhelming  majority  of  pupils  in  elementary  and  second- 
ary schools  are  enrolled  in  public  institutions,  there  are  still  a  consider- 
able number  in  private  schools.  In  1933,  there  were  1,772,428  pupils  in 
private  elementary  schools  and  280,176  in  private  secondary  schools. 
Those  enrolled  in  Catholic  elementary  schools  made  up  over  95  per  cent 
of  the  total,  and  those  enrolled  in  Catholic  secondary  schools  constituted 
over  66  per  cent  of  all  attending  private  secondary  schools.  The  Catholic 
control  over  the  minds  of  millions  of  school  pupils  greatly  increases  the 
power  and  cohesiveness  of  the  Catholic  church  in  the  United  States.  This 
situation  has  been  criticized  by  many  students  of  education,  particularly 
in  view  of  the  fact  that  the  Catholics  have  also,  in  many  cities,  asserted 
a  dominant  influence  over  the  public  schools,  while  endeavoring  to  keep 
as  many  Catholic  children  as  possible  in  parochial  schools. 

The  table  on  page  736,  from  the  Statistical  Summary  of  Education, 
1935-36,  compiled  by  the  United  States  Office  of  Education,  give  a  com- 
prehensive picture  of  the  "business  of  education"  in  the  United  States 
in  1936. 

The  graphs  on  page  737,  compiled  by  the  United  States  Office  of  Educa- 
tion, indicate  the  remarkable  growth  of  educational  activity  and  enroll- 
ment in  the  United  States  from  1890  to  1936. 

To  those  familiar  with  the  days  of  the  little  red  school  house,  the 
village  academics,  and  our  quaint,  primitive  college  campuses  of  a  gen- 
eration back,  the  extent  and  nature  of  the  present  physical  plant  devoted 
to  American  education  are  almost  incredible.  The  total  value  of  all 
public  school  property  rose  from  550  million  dollars  in  1900  to  over 
$6,731,000,000  in  1936.  The  total  value  of  all  educational  property  in 
the  United  States  in  1936,  including  private  schools  and  institutions  of 
higher  learning,  was  $10,115,744,000,  with  an  additional  $2,237,340,000 
in  endowments  and  trust  funds,  making  a  grand  total  of  $12,353,084,000. 
The  increase  in  the  value  of  public  school  property  was  far  greater  than 
the  growth  of  school  enrollment.  In  1900  the  value  of  public  school  prop- 
erty per  pupil  stood  at  $35,  while  in  1930  it  stood  at  $241.  This  increase 
in  the  value  of  school  plant  was  also  accompanied  by  a  remarkable  im- 
provement in  the  size  and  design  of  school  buildings.  The  most  impor- 
tant development  here  was  the  abandonment  of  small,  especially  one- 
room,  schools,  and  the  building  of  consolidated  or  centralized  school 


2  The  highest  enrollment  was  32,392.749,  in  1934. 


§ 

H 

6 
o 


r 

O 

u 


o 

o 
w 


Fem 


3 


co     QrH 
3 
o"W    cs 

s 

ci 


O        OS        r-l*H        -F 

s  5S  f2sg  2 


^ 

?o 


eg     P 

S   ft 


I  S  22 


LQCJ500 

oooo 


« 


,52 


r- 

g   S 

o"    <rf 

CO       H 


IIP 
° 


:  £  QD 

•a  s 


o«w    .  ^ 

g°  :5 


fHtCOO 
T-KNrH 


3 


!!!! 


1 

H     P 


736 


•I  SI 


BQ 

fc 
O 


P 

I 

£ 


I 

I 
I 


8 

o 


I*  1 

sh  s 

jft«i  g 

.ill 


A    o  o 

a  8.      «. 


§       I       !       I 


£ 

w 

a 

CO 


g  S  g 


ail 

a  si 

i! 


"•  r« 


737 


738  EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

plants.  By  1930  there  were  over  16,000  such  consolidated  schools,  their 
number  increasing  at  the  rate  of  about  1,000  a  year.  There  still  remain, 
however,  about  110,000  one-room  schools  in  the  country,  usually  pro- 
viding inferior  instruction.  They  are  decreasing  at  a  rate  of  over  3,000 
each  year. 

School  buildings  are  more  scientifically  and  artistically  built  than  ever 
before.  The  modern  school  building  is  no  longer  a  sort  of  cross  between 
a  church  and  a  jail,  with  respect  to  architectural  design.  Nor  is  it  built 
without  much  consideration  for  light,  ventilation,  and  heating.  In  our 
day,  the  better  school  architecture  is  a  combination  of  good  engineering, 
architectural  talent,  and  school  hygiene.  Educational  experts  arc  now 
allowed  to  make  suggestions  as  to  proper  school  design.  School  buildings 
are  not  only  functionally  adapted  to  the  needs  of  instruction,  but  are  also 
constructed  to  insure  hygiene,  comfort,  and  convenience.  They  combine 
beauty  and  utility.  School  yards  are  made  to  provide  recreational  facili- 
ties and  proper  access  to  sunlight.  In  the  place  of  a  drab  collection  of 
dingy  classrooms  and  a  few  office  cubicles,  we  find  auditoriums,  gym- 
nasiums, libraries,  shops  of  many  kinds,  art  studios,  suites  for  health 
officers  and  nurses,  cafeterias,  rest  rooms,  and  the  like. 

While  our  normal  schools,  colleges,  and  universities — the  institutions 
of  higher  learning — do  not  represent  such  a  tremendous  outlay  for  plant 
as  the  public  schools,  they  arc,  nevertheless,  extremely  impressive  from 
the  physical  point  of  view.  There  were  1,690  accredited  institutions  of 
higher  learning  in  the  United  States  in  1938.  Some  600  were  publicly 
controlled,  and  1,090  privately  controlled.  They  represented  a  plant  in- 
vestment of  some  $2,556,000,000,  with  an  annual  bill  for  upkeep  of  about 
70  million  dollars.  Their  endowment  in  1938  was  some  $1,721,000,000. 
Their  receipts,  in  1938,  amounted  to  over  550  million  dollars,  as  compared 
to  a  paltry  40  million  dollars  in  1900,  the  latter  figure  even  including 
additions  to  endowment  during  the  year  1900,  while  the  1938  figure  is 
exclusive  of  endowment  gifts,  which  amounted  to  about  50  million  dollars 
in  that  year.  Expenditures  in  1938  were  in  excess  of  545  millions.  There 
were  in  1938  approximately  1,350,000  students  attending  these  institu- 
tions of  higher  learning,  with  about  190,000  receiving  degrees  each  year. 
There  were  123,677  full-time  faculty  members. 

Our  students  in  institutions  of  higher  learning  thus  constitute  over  one 
per  cent  of  the  total  population  of  the  country,  and  about  15  per  cent  of 
the  youth  of  college  age.  At  the  turn  of  the  century,  a  college  or  univer- 
sity with  a  thousand  students  was  a  large  institution.  Today  a  number 
of  universities  have  more  than  10,000  full-time  students;  two  have  over 
15,000  full-time  students;  and  six  have  a  total  yearly  attendance  of  full 
and  part-time  students  combined  of  over  15,000  each.  New  York  Uni- 
versity has  a  total  registration  of  over  35,000.  In  the  eastern  United 
States,  most  institutions  of  higher  learning,  are,  aside  from  normal  schools 
and  teachers  colleges,  mainly  private  institutions.  In  the  west,  most  of 
the  more  important  institutions  are  state  colleges  and  universities. 

The  physical  plant  of  our  larger  and  richer  universities  has  shown  an 


EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  739 

even  more  remarkable  transformation  than  our  public  school  buildings. 
A  generation  back,  many  of  our  campuses  possessed  buildings  of  archi- 
tectural beauty,  purity,  and  quiet  dignity,  but  few  of  them  were  like  the 
vast  and  impressive  structures  that  we  find  on  our  campuses  today. 
Some  of  these  are  attractively  designed;  a  few  are  artistic  gems,  such 
as  the  Ilarkness  Quadrangle  at  Yale,  the  new  Harvard  dormitories,  the 
Michigan  Law  Court,  and  Willard  Straight  Hall  at  Cornell.  Some  uni- 
versity dormitories  present  an  impressiveness  and  elegance  not  matched 
elsewhere  except  in  the  dwellings  of  multi-millionaires  and  great  metro- 
politan hotels.  As  one  observer  has  sardonically  remarked,  the  most 
elaborate  innovations  in  university  architecture  have  been  impressive 
and  expensive  sleeping  quarters.  The  campuses  are  also  embellished  by 
privately  owned  fraternity  houses,  often  very  expensive  and  pretentious. 
The  most  striking  architectural  additions  to  our  campuses  in  recent  years 
have  been  the  many  buildings  erected  in  state  colleges  and  universities 
through  federal  PWA  and  WPA  aid.  Many  of  these  institutions  were 
previously  somewhat  dismal.  However,  many  campuses  still  resemble 
architecturally  some  of  our  newer  minimum  security  prisons.  The  ex- 
tensive and  pretentious  architecture  of  our  large  universities  stands  out 
in  striking  contrast  to  the  few  and  unimpressive  buildings  which  consti- 
tute the  physical  plant  of  the  majority  of  the  more  famous  institutions  of 
higher  learning  in  Europe. 

The  sources  of  support  of  our  vast  institutions  of  higher  learning  make 
it  difficult  for  the  faculty  to  enjoy  true  independence  of  thought  in  many 
subjects,  especially  in  the  social  sciences.  Many  private  colleges  and 
universities  depend  on  endowments  from  the  rich.  Hence  there  is  little 
enthusiasm  for  faculty  criticism  of  the  existing  economic  order.  The 
state  universities  and  normal  schools  are  publicly  supported,  thus  making 
it  often  precarious  for  professors  to  criticize  existing  party  organizations 
and  political  machinery.  The  courageous  professor  may  find  himself  be- 
tween the  devil  of  vested  economic  interests  and  the  deep  blue  sea  of 
political  pressure  and  expediency. 

The  expenditures  of  our  educational  system  are  compatible  with  the 
extent  of  the  plant  and  the  enrollment  of  pupils.  In  1900,  the  total 
expenditures  of  all  public  schools  amounted  to  215  million  dollars.  By 
1936,  the  figure  had  grown  to  $2,232,000,000,  or  $74.48  per  pupil.  Even 
so,  many  authorities  believe  that  the  latter  amount  fell  far  short  of  what 
would  be  necessary  to  provide  a  thoroughly  adequate  educational  system 
for  American  youth.  It  has  been  suggested  that  to  bring  about  such  a 
result  would  require  an  annual  expenditure  of  at  least  10  billion  dollars. 
The  most  we  have  ever  spent  for  public  education  was  $2,605,000,000,  in 
1930.  The  first  table  on  page  740,  from  the  Statistical  Summary  of  Edu- 
cation, 1985-36,  presents  a  comprehensive  picture  of  the  expenditures  for 
education,  both  public  and  private,  in  that  year.  In  1937-38,  the  total 
annual  expenditures  for  public  education  in  the  continental  United  States 
were  $2,564,418,760,  of  which  sum  $2,233,110,054  went  for  the  support  of 
elementary  and  secondary  schools. 


740 


EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 


EXPENDITURES  FOR  SCHOOLS  REPORTING,  1935-36 
(INCLUDES  CAPITAL  OUTLAY) 


Schools 

Public 

Private 

Total 

1 

2 

3 

4 

Elementary  schools  (Including  kindergarten)   .  .  . 
High  schools  and  academies  

$1,204,696,632 
764,201,566 

1  $123,177,705 
1  45,411,980 

$1,327,874,337 
809,613,546 

Universities,  colleges,  and   professional   schools 
(including  preparatory  departments)2   

208,183,284 

244,097,836 

452,281,120 

Teachers  colleges  and  normal  schools  3  

39,007,811 

2,139,083 

41,146,894 

Schools  for  delinquents*  

5  2,103,053 

6  224,326 

5  2  327  378 

Schools  for  deaf  *  

6  870,100 

*  1,992,321 

8  2,862,511 

Schools  for  blind  4  

5  1,020,706 

8  352,218 

5  1  372,924 

Schools  for  mentally  deficient  *  

5  3,683,919 

6  283,318 

8  3,967,237 

Government  schools  for  Indians  *  ,  ,  . 

8,468,076 

8  468  076 

Total     expenditures     (continental     tlnlted 

States)    

2,232,235,236 

417,678,787 

2,649,914,023 

Federal     Government    schools    for     natives     of 
Alaska    

622,221 

622  221 

Territorial  public  school  in  Alaska 

695,162 

695  102 

1  Estimated. 

8 $30,788,863  public,  $57,002,946  private,  and  $87,851,809  total  expenditures  for  auxiliary 
enterprises  and  activities  not  included. 

8  $7,103,877  public,  $316,309  private,  and  $7,480,186  total  expenditures  for  auxiliary  enter- 
prises and  activities  not  included. 

*  State  and  private  residential  schools  only ;  city  public  schools  not  included. 

5  Includes  expenditures  for  instructional  purposes,  and  capital  outlay  (not  included 
previously),  for  schools  reporting  these  items. 

a  Not  including  amount  spent  for  tuition  in  public  schools — $653,419. 

II 

NATIONAL  INCOME,  TAX  COLLECTIONS,  AND  EXPENDITURES  FOR 
PUBLIC  EDUCATION,  1930  TO  1938 


Year      ] 

[ncome  payments 
to  individuals 

j       Total  tax 
collections 

Expenditures 
for    public 
education 

Per 
cent 
that 
tax 
col- 
lec- 
tions 
were 
of 
total 
in- 

Per 
cent 
that 
school 
ex- 
pend- 
itures 
were 
of 
total 
in- 

Per 
cent 
that 
school 
ex- 
pend- ' 
itures 
were 
of  tax 
col- 
lec- 

come 

come 

tions 

1 

2 

3 

4 

5 

6 

7 

1930.... 
1931 

$74,566,000,000 
63  459,000  000 

$10,266,000,000 
9  300  000  000 

$2,605,699,000 

13.8% 
147 

3.49% 

25.4% 

1932.... 

49,275,000,000 

8,147,000,000 

2,456,985,000 

16.5 

4.99 

30.2 

1933  

46,878,000,000 

7,501,000,000 

16.0 

1934  

54,138,000,000 

8,773,000,000 

1,940,133,000 

16.2 

3.58 

22.1 

1935.  .  .  . 

58,882,000,000 

9,731,000,000 

16.5 

1936  

68,051,000,000 

10,507,000,000a 

2,254,042,000 

15.4 

3.31 

21.5 

1937. 

71,960,000  000 

12,522,000,000a 

17.4 

1938.  .  .  . 

66,259,000,000 

14,000,COO,OOOb 

2,564,419,000 

21.1 

3.87 

18.3 

Sources:  Income  payments  from  U.  S.  Department  of  Commerce,  Bureau  of  Foreign  and 
Domestic  Commerce,  Division  of  Economic  Research,  Survey  of  Current  Business,  Vol.  20, 
p.  17-18,  October,  1940.  Tax  collections  from  National  Industrial  Conference  Board,  Cost 
of  Government  in  the  United  States,  1985*1981,  p.  33,  and  Economic  Almanac  for  1940, 
p.  341.  Education  expenditures  from  TT.  S.  Office  of  Education,  Biennial  Survey  of  Educa- 
tion, 1928-30,  J930-32,  1032-34,  1934-36,  1936-38.  (Figures  for  1936-38  are  advance 
data.) 


EDUCATION    IN  THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS  741 

The  second  table  on  page  740,  compiled  by  the  Research  Division  of  the 
National  Education  Association,  gives  a  comparative  statement  of  Na- 
tional Income,  Tax  Collections,  and  Expenditures  for  Public  Education 
since  the  Depression.  It  reveals  the  incredibly  small  proportion  of  the 
national  income  which  is  diverted  to  educational  purposes. 

In  1930,  54  per  cent  of  school  expenditures  went  for  teachers'  salaries, 
about  25  per  cent  for  current  operating  expenses,  about  3  per  cent  for 
textbooks  and  other  related  supplies,  approximately  3.5  per  cent  for 
general  administration  and  control,  and  16  per  cent  for  upkeep  and  other 
outlays.  The  following  table  from  the  Biennial  Survey  of  Education  in 
the  United  States,  1934-1936,  reveals  the  distribution  of  the  various  items 
in  the  total  expenditures  for  public  education  a  half-decade  later. 

DISTRIBUTION  OF  EXPENDITURES  FOR  PUBLIC  EDUCATION 

1934  TO  1936 

Current     expend!-  Total  expenditures 

tures       (Excluding  (Including   current 

Item  payments  for  out-  expenses,     outlays, 

jays,     bonds,     and  and  interest) 
interest) 


General  control           

4.1 

34 

Instruction 
Salaries    

69.2 

58.5 

Textbooks  and  supplies 

41 

34 

Operation       

10.2 

Maintenance    

3.9 

19.1 

Auxiliary  agencies  

5.9 

Fixed  charges     

2.6 

.Total 1CO.O 

Capital   outlays    8.8 

Interest 6.8 

Total         .  .  .  100.0 

The  average  salaries  of  school  teachers  showed  a  notable  gain  from 
1914  to  1930.  In  1914,  the  average  salary  was  $525;  in  1922,  $1,166;  in 
1930,  $1,420;  in  1934,  $1,227;  and  in  1938,  $1,374.  Of  course,  this  gain 
over  1914  was  in  part  offset  by  the  increased  cost  of  living,  the  latter 
being  66  per  cent  higher  in  1930  than  in  1914. 

The  administration  of  American  schools  has  exhibited  a  great  deal  of 
looseness  and  diversity.  The  Federal  government  has  never  attempted 
to  control  or  been  willing  to  support  American  public  education.  The 
48  states  dominate  the  public  educational  system.  The  state  systems  as 
a  whole  show  a  great  deal  of  diversity  of  control,  and  there  is  still  further 
variation  in  each  local  community.  A  few  states,  originally  led  by 
Massachusetts  and  Horace  Mann,  worked  out  fairly  good  systems  of 
public  instruction  before  1860,  and  other  states  have  followed  them  as 
models  to  a  considerable  degree.  Certain  minimum  standards  are  usually 
insisted  upon  by  the  state,  but  beyond  this,  much  leeway  is  given  to  local 
school  boards,  usually  composed  of  laymen  with  little  educational  knowl- 


742 


EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 


edge  or  insight.  Least  competent  of  all  has  been  the  control  of  one-room 
country  school  districts  by  rural  trustees,  who  have  usually  lacked  any 
knowledge  whatever  of  educational  problems.  In  over  30  states,  the  chief 
educational  executive  of  the  state  is  still  popularly  elected,  thus  putting 
the  office  at  the  mercy  of  party  politics.  In  the  better-administered 
states,  there  has  been  a  marked  trend  to  appoint  the  head  of  the  state 
school  system.  Usually  he  is  a  man  with  some  expert  knowledge  of 
pedagogy  and  considerable  experience  in  educational  administration. 
With  the  growth  in  the  number  and  size  of  American  cities,  the  city  school 
boards  have  exerted  an  ever  more  important  role  in  American  public  edu- 
cation. City  school  boards  have  recently  reduced  their  size  and  are  more 
inclined  to  accept  expert  advice  in  educational  matters  and  to  delegate 
technical  responsibilities  to  trained  experts.  Most  cities  have  a  profes- 
sional superintendent  of  schools.  While  much  remains  to  be  achieved 
in  the  way  of  securing  expert  and  impartial  educational  administration  in 
the  United  States,  the  progress  along  this  line  in  the  last  forty  years  has 
been  almost  as  notable  as  the  growth  of  school  enrollment  and  school 
plant. 

Most  of  the  funds  needed  to  support  our  school  system  are  raised  by 
local  taxation,  though  the  amount  of  state  aid  to  public  schools  has 
notably  increased  in  the  last  quarter  of  a  century.  Federal  aid  has  also 
grown  during  this  period,  but  even  by  1936  it  amounted  to  only  1.2 
per  cent  of  the  total.  The  following  table,  compiled  by  the  Research 

AMOUNT  AND  PER  CENT  OF  PUBLIC  ELEMENTARY-  AND 
SECONDARY-SCHOOL  REVENUE  a  FROM  FEDERAL, 
STATE,  AND  LOCAL  GOVERNMENTS  IN  1920, 
1930,  1934,  AND  1938 


Unit  of 
Government 

1988 

1934 

1930 

1920 

1 

2 

3 

4 

5 

Amount 

Federal 
State 

$26,535,473 
655  996  060 

$21,547,938 
423  178  215 

$7,333,834 
353  670  462 

$2,474,717 
160,084  682 

Local  

.       1,540,052,863 

1,365,553,792 

1,726,708,457 

807,560,899 

Total  ...     . 

$2,222,584,396 

$1,810,279,945 

$2,087,712,753 

$970,120,298 

Per  Cent 

Federal 

1  2 

12 

0.4 

0.3 

State     

29.5 

23.4 

16.9 

16.5 

Local    

.     .    .       69.3 

75.4 

82.7 

83.2 

Total 


100.0 


100.0 


100.0 


100.0 


Source:  U.  S.  Department  of  the  Interior,  Office  of  Education,  Biennial  Survey 
of  Education,  1918-1920,  1928-1930,  1932-1934,  1936-1938.  (Figures  for  1936-1938 
are  advance  data.) 

a  Revenue  receipts  only.  State  receipts  from  permanent  funds  and  from  school 
lands  are  included. 


EDUCATION    IN   THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  743 

Division  of  the  National  Education  Association,  reveals  the  sources  of 
the  revenue  expended  for  public  education  from  1920  to  1938,  according 
to  governmental  units. 

The  extension  of  educational  facilities  and  activities  has  brought  about 
a  greater  demand  for  competently  trained  teachers.  Normal  schools  and 
state  teachers'  colleges  have  increased  in  number.  They  have  also  im- 
proved their  educational  facilities  and  instruction.  Admirably  equipped 
professional  teachers'  colleges,  in  conjunction  with  the  larger  universities, 
have  been  provided.  The  most  notable  is  Teachers  College  at  Columbia 
University.  Elaborately  staffed  and  extensively  attended  summer  schools 
enable  teachers  to  extend  their  information  and  keep  up  to  date  through 
summer  study.  Many  of  the  better  school  systems  offer  promotional 
and  pecuniary  rewards  to  teachers  who  carry  on  their  studies  in  summer 
school  and  extension  courses,  along  with  their  teaching  work.  More 
teachers  have  tended  to  carry  on  graduate  work  and  professional  study, 
so  that  there  is  a  larger  body  of  better  trained  teachers  to  choose  from 
than  has  previously  been  the  case.  There  has  also  been  a  notable  ex- 
tension of  facilities  for  the  supervision  of  teaching,  thus  giving  special 
aid  and  counsel  to  inexperienced  or  relatively  untrained  teachers.  The 
higher  salaries  paid  and  the  more  exacting  requirements  for  teachers  have 
led  to  an  increase  in  the  relative  number  of  men  teachers  since  the  first 
World  War.  In  spite  of  all  this,  much  remains  to  be  done  in  the  way  of 
improving  the  training  of  teachers.  Approximately  25  per  cent  of  the 
elementary  school  teachers  have  had  less  than  two  years  of  education 
beyond  high  school,  and  over  10  per  cent  of  senior  high  school  teachers 
have  had  less  than  four  years  of  college  work. 

Effective  teaching  and  disciplinary  methods  have  been  guided  largely 
by  educational  psychology  and  scientific  pedagogy.  Punitive  discipline 
has  fallen  into  disrepute  in  the  better  schools;  emphasis  is  laid  upon 
arousing  the  interest  and  enthusiasm  of  pupils.  It  has  been  found  that 
the  learning  process  is  facilitated  if  it  is  made  pleasant  enough  to  enlist 
the  hearty  cooperation  of  the  pupil.  School  attendance  is  encouraged  by 
a  number  of  agreeable  and  helpful  forms  of  extra-curricular  activity, 
such  as  athletics,  folk-dancing,  and  dramatic  activities. 

While  the  curriculum,  from  the  elementary  school  to  the  graduate 
schools  of  our  universities,  is  still  archaic  and  traditional,  it  has  certainly 
been  notably  improved  in  the  twentieth  century.  We  have  already 
referred  to  these  changes  in  connection  with  the  colleges  and  universities. 
The  mo$t  notable  curricular  innovation  here  in  the  nineteenth  century 
was  the  growing  attention  and  respect  accorded  the  natural  sciences. 
In  the  twentieth  century,  the  greatest  gains  have  been  made  by  the  social 
sciences,  though  these  are  still  inadequately  provided  for. 

In  the  secondary  schools  in  1890,  most  of  the  instruction  was  limited 
to  English,  Latin,  Greek,  French,  German,  algebra,  geometry,  physics, 
chemistry,  and  history.  In  1930,  instruction  was  offered  in  approxi- 
mately fifty  subjects,  in  the  place  of  the  ten  that  dominated  the  field 
forty  years  earlier.  The  decline  in  the  relative  attention  given  to  the 


744  EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

classics  and  mathematics  has  been  especially  marked  since  the  first  World 
War.  The  drop  in  the  number  of  courses  offered  in  German  was  a 
temporary  and  pathological  episode  engendered  by  the  first  World  War. 
This  prejudice  has  been  revived  by  the  second  World  War,  and  it  will 
probably  be  some  decades  before  normal  and  desirable  attention  will 
once  more  be  given  to  instruction  in  German. 

For  many  decades,  the  secondary  schools  have  been  considered  chiefly  as 
a  preparation  for  the  professions  or  for  college.  The  secondary  schools 
are  still  prostituted  to  the  requirements  laid  down  for  college  entrance 
examinations;  however,  some  secondary  schools  do  prepare  students  for 
life  in  the  twentieth  century.  This  trend  is  shown  by  the  greater  variety 
of  courses  offered  and  their  greater  realism.  Notable  in  this  respect  is 
the  attention  given  to  the  social  studies,  to  manual  training  and  industrial 
arts,  and  to  commercial  education.  The  latter  has  been  so  extensively 
developed  in  some  secondary  schools  that  private  commercial  schools 
have  suffered  severely.  Instruction  in  manual  training  in  the  high 
schools  was  aided  by  the  passage  of  the  Smith-Hughes  law  in  1917,  pro- 
viding for  federal  aid  to  vocational  education  under  the  supervision  of 
the  Federal  Board  for  Vocational  Education. 

There  have  naturally  been  fewer  radical  changes  in  the  curriculum  of 
elementary  schools.  The  "three  R's"  have  to  be  studied  in  preparation 
for  further  educational  work.  Nevertheless,  the  elementary  school  cur- 
riculum has  been  broadened  to  include  history  and  the  social  studies  and 
various  industrial  arts.  There  has  also  been  much  experimentation  with 
more  effective  and  vital  types  of  instruction,  in  which  the  studies  are 
closely  related  to  life  situations  and  the  everyday  experiences  of  children. 
The  health  of  children  of  all  ages  in  the  public  schools  is  supervised,  and 
at  least  some  elementary  instruction  is  given  in  the  fundamentals  of 
health  and  personal  hygiene. 

Special  classes  have  been  created  for  handicapped  and  retarded  chil- 
dren, including  the  blind,  deaf,  subnormal,  and  feeble-minded.  In  some 
cases  school  facilities  are  made  available  during  the  entire  year,  thus 
eliminating  the  waste  of  plant  facilities  during  the  long  summer  vacation, 
the  period  when  the  educational  plant  may  actually  be  operated  with  a 
'minimum  of  expense.  The  summer  vacation  is  a  hold-over  from  a  farm- 
ing economy,  in  which  the  farmer  needed  his  children  at  home  to  help 
him  get  in  his  hay  and  carry  on  harvesting  activities.  It  is  probable 
that,  within  another  generation,  the  protracted  summer  vacation  will  be 
supplemented  by  briefer  vacations  between  the  quarters  of  a  school 
year  running  through  the  entire  twelve  months.  Year-around  education 
in  institutions  of  higher  learning  was  first  provided  for  by  President 
Charles  Rainey  Harper  at  the  University  of  Chicago  in  1892.  This  in- 
stitution has  always  operated  on  the  quarter  system  instead  of  the  usual 
semester  plan.  Many  Western  state  universities  now  operate  on  the 
quarter  system.  The  second  World  War  is  exerting  a  powerful  influence 
in  the  direction  of  year- around  operation  of  our  colleges  and  universities, 
and  the  practice  may  persist  in  many  places  in  post-war  years. 


EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  745 

A  new  type  of  institution  is  the  junior  high  school,  first  launched  in 
Berkeley,  Cal.,  in  1909,  and  very  widely  developed  since  the  first  World 
War.  In  1934,  there  were  over  1,948  junior  high  schools,  with  an  enroll- 
ment of  over  1,220,000  pupils.  Much  time  had  previously  been  wasted 
in  the  seventh  and  eighth  grades  in  perfunctory  review  of  the  material 
covered  in  earlier  years.  Attention  is  now  given  to  efficient  work  before 
the  seventh  grade,  and  then  the  seventh  and  eighth  grades  are  trans- 
formed into  a  junior  high  school,  where  instruction  is  given  in  subjects 
which  have  previously  been  restricted  to  the  high  school  curriculum. 
There  has  been  much  experimentation  with  the  curriculum  of  the  junior 
high  school,  most  gratifying  being  the  unusual  attention  given  to  the  so- 
cial studies  and  industrial  arts. 

By  taking  care  of  subjects  previously  handled  in  the  high  school,  the 
junior  high  school  makes  much  more  advanced  work  possible  in  the  senior 
high  school.  The  yariety  and  quality  of  instruction  in  the  better  senior 
high  schools  is  far  superior  to  that  given  in  colleges  a  half  century  ago. 
It  is  believed  by  many  experts,  such  as  Dean  Louis  Peckstein  of  the  Uni- 
versity of  Cincinnati,  that  in  due  time  the  senior  high  school  will  supplant 
the  conventional  college,  or  at  least  the  junior  college.  If  so,  this  will 
bring  about  a  condition  resembling  that  in  Europe,  where  the  German 
Gymnasium  and  the  French  Lycee  cover  much  the  same  ground  as  do 
the  American  colleges  in  the  first  two  or  three  years  of  their  work.  After 
the  European  student  finishes  work  in  one  of  these  institutions,  he  goes 
on  into  the  university,  which  resembles  our  upper-class  years  in  college 
and  the  work  of  the  university  graduate  schools. 

Junior  colleges  since  the  first  World  War  increased  from  46  in  1917  to 
415  in  1936,  with  an  enrollment  of  over  102,000.  The  junior  colleges 
have  taken  over  the  work  given  in  the  first  two  years  of  the  four-year 
college.  The  curriculum,  however,  is  generally  more  up-to-date  and 
experimental  than  the  undergraduate  curriculum  of  the  conventional 
college.  The  functions  and  relationships  of  junior  high  school,  senior 
high  school,  junior  college,  and  four-year  college  are  at  present  highly 
flexible  and  confused.  It  will  take  another  generation  to  solve  the  prob- 
lems they  raise,  but  in  the  end  we  can  expect  a  somewhat  more  rational 
distribution  of  functions  and  subject-matter. 

The  progress  in  human  knowledge,  the  shifts  in  curricular  material, 
and  the  social  changes  of  our  day  have  made  it  both  natural  and  essential 
to  consider  the  problem  of  adult  education.  Many  persons  were  denied 
the  privilege  of  college  education  in  youth.  Even  those  who  had  such  an 
education  now  find  it  grievously  out  of  date.  Moreover,  it  is  highly 
necessary  to  understand  the  social  changes  of  our  day,  the  reasons  there- 
for, and  possible  means  of  guiding  social  change  in  a  manner  more  bene- 
ficial to  the  mass  of  mankind.  Only  adult  education  can  effectively 
meet  such  needs  and  problems.  Certain  institutions  have  been  estab- 
lished to  provide  adult  education,  such  as  Cooper  Union,  especially  its 
People's  Institute,  and  the  New  School  for  Social  Research  in  New  York 
University  extension  courses,  especially  those  conducted  by  large 


746  EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCfAL  CRISIS 

metropolitan  universities,  have  done  much  to  facilitate  adult  education. 
The  Public  Forum  movement  has  provided  for  some  adult  education,  in 
default  of  more  adequate  facilities.  Dr.  John  W.  Studebaker,  United 
States  Commissioner  of  Education,  has  made  a  commendable  effort  to 
provide  federal  resources  to  support  a  well-planned  forum  movement 
throughout  the  United  States.  Labor  organizations  and  groups  have 
brought  into  existence  many  facilities  for  the  education  of  the  working 
class.  Particularly  worthy  of  mention  are  the  Rand  School  of  Social 
Science  in  New  York  City,  Labor  Temple,  also  in  New  York,  and  the 
educational  work  of  the  International  Ladies  Garment  Workers. 

Finally,  there  has  been  a  notable  extension  of  the  scientific  study  of 
education,  with  the  aim  of  suggesting  better  educational  methods. 
Teachers  College  at  Columbia  University,  a  pioneer  in  this  work,  was 
much  influenced  by  the  educational  philosophy  of  John  Dewey.  Some 
of  our  larger  foundations,  such  as  the  Carnegie  Foundation  for  the  Ad- 
vancement of  Teaching,  the  General  Education  Board,  the  Rosen wald 
Fund,  and  the  Commonwealth  Fund,  have  spent  money  lavishly  in  the 
study  of  contemporary  education.  Unfortunately,  such  studies  often 
view  the  problems  of  education  from  the  vantage  point  of  the  vested 
interests  in  contemporary  society.  They  are  more  interested  in  making 
education  a  bulwark  of  social  stability  than  in  developing  it  as  a  leading 
agent  of  intelligent  social  change.  Hence  they  have  been  limited  chiefly 
to  investigations  of  the  formalities  and  machinery  of  education  rather 
than  to  a  consideration  of  the  role  of  education  in  social  change  and  the 
relations  of  education  to  the  social  issues  of  our  time. 

Despite  the  extensive  educational  equipment  and  activity  in  the  United 
States,  there  are  a  very  large  number  of  Americans  who  have  not  made, 
or  been  able  to  make,  adequate  use  of  these  facilities.  The  census  of 
1940  revealed  the  fact  that  10,105,000  persons  over  25  years  of  age,  or 
13.5  per  cent,  had  never  gone  beyond  the  fourth  grade  in  school.  Some 
2,800,000,  or  3.7  per  cent,  had  never  finished  one  year  in  school.  Less 
than  a  quarter  (24.1  per  cent)  had  finished  high  school.  Only  4.6  per 
cent  were  college  graduates.  The  median  number  of  years  of  school  com- 
pleted by  those  over  25  years  of  age  was  8.4,  slightly  beyond  the  eighth 
grade.  General  Lewis  B.  Hershey,  head  of  selective  service,  stated  in 
May,  1942,  that  250,000  physically  fit  young  men,  the  equivalent  of  15 
divisions,  had  been  rejected  in  the  draft  because  of  illiteracy  and 
"mental  backwardness."  President  Roosevelt  was  reported  to  be  "startled 
by  these  figures." 


Some  Outstanding  Defects  of  Contemporary 
Education 

Education  is  still  administered  under  a  forbidding  intellectual  atmos- 
phere. The  punitive  and  penitential  attitude  still  lies  at  the  heart  of 
conventional  education,  however  much  it  may  have  been  repudiated  by 


EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  747 

the  more  progressive  types  of  professional  educational  psychology.  This 
attitude  towards  education  was  never  more  crisply,  pungently  or  candidly 
expressed  than  by  President  George  Barton  Cutten  of  Colgate  University, 
when  he  observed  that:  "It  doesn't  matter  what  you  study,  so  long  as 
you  hate  it." 

This  type  of  educational  motivation  is  an  outgrowth  of  at  least  four 
fundamental  causes.  The  first  is  the  orthodox  theological  assumption 
that  intellectual  virtue  can  best  be  assured  through  its  association  with 
an  attitude  of  solemnity  and  mental  misery. 

The  second  chief  cause  has  been  the  rationalized  defense  of  anachronis- 
tic subjects  in  the  curriculum.  Higher  mathematics,  a  most  valuable  and 
practical  preparation  for  applied  science  and  technology,  has  usually  been 
retained  as  a  requirement  in  high  schools  and  in  liberal  arts  colleges. 
The  classical  languages,  once  the  medium  of  expression  for  a  great  civi- 
lization, have  come  down  into  our  day  in  the  form  of  grammar  and  syn- 
tax, giving  but  little  attention  to  the  actual  life,  spirit,  and  achievements 
of  the  ancient  Greeks  and  Romans.  The  advocates  of  mathematics  and 
the  classics  have  been  forced  to  defend  them  on  the  ground  of  their  alleged 
disciplinary  value,  with  respect  to  both  the  intensity  of  mental  effort 
demanded  and  the  generally  distasteful  nature  of  the  subject-matter. 

A  third  cause  has  arisen  from  administrative  economy  and  convenience. 
In  order  to  standardize  educational  requirements  and  achievements  and 
to  grant  degrees  for  approximately  the  same  general  volume  and  level  of 
achievement,  it  has  been  necessary  to  work  out  set  courses,  a  schematic 
curriculum,  and  a  rigorous  set  of  examinations.  In  this  way,  the  authori- 
ties aim  to  test  the  quality  of  the  work  being  done  by  students  and  to 
provide  for  the  proper  mass  promotion  of  students  through  the  educa- 
tional machine. 

To  these  three  causes  there  should  be  added  a  fourth,  namely,  the  old 
doctrine,  drawn  from  theology  and  metaphysics,  to  the  effect  that  the 
human  will,  so-called,  can  be  trained  in  adequate  fashion  only  if  one 
is  forced  to  perform  many  tasks  for  which  he  feels  a  profound  disdain  and 
acute  dislike. 

All  of  these  attitudes  were  formulated  long  before  the  rise  of  modern 
dynamic  and  educational  psychology.  We  now  know  that  nothing  is 
more  fundamentally  opposed  to  mental  health  and  stimulating  intellectual 
life  than  undue  solemnity,  psychic  misery,  and  an  overdeveloped  sense  of 
personal  inferiority.  Nor  is  there  any  psychological  ground  whatever  for 
the  belief  that  special  and  unique  mental  discipline  can  be  derived  from 
the  study  of  a  particular  subject  or  group  of  subjects.  If  difficulty  were 
to  be  the  criterion  of  the  value  of  a  study,  then  we  should  supplant  Greek 
and  Latin  by  the  languages  of  the  Basque,  Eskimo,  and  Chinese. 
Method,  rather  than  subject-matter,  creates  mental  discipline,  in  so  far 
as  this  can  be  furthered  by  pedagogical  influences.  While  we  cannot 
hope  to  carry  on  any  extensive  system  of  education  without  at  least 
a  minimum  of  regimentation  and  administration,  nevertheless,  it  is  all  too 
easy  to  convert  the  machinery  for  education  into  the  actual  goal  of  educa- 


748  EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

tion  itself.  The  success  of  an  educational  plant  is  all  too  often  judged 
on  the  basis  of  its  size  and  the  smoothness  with  which  its  machinery 
operates.  The  aim  of  the  students  is  less  often  the  mastery  of  the  subject- 
matter  of  the  course  than  the  ability  to  "get  by"  in  periodic  examinations. 
Under  such  conditions  the  administrative  aspect  of  education  becomes  a 
handicap  rather  than  an  aid  to  the  learning  process. 

Modern  psychology  tells  us  that  what  was  once  known  as  "will  power" 
can  be  much  more  certainly  and  surely  attained  by  proper  attention  to 
the  rational  motivation  of  conduct  than  by  forcing  one  to  execute,  for 
no  good  reason  at  all,  a  series  of  distasteful  acts.  When  carried  into 
the  educational  process,  this  punitive  or  penitential  conception  of  mental 
discipline  and  will-training  is  much  more  likely  to  produce  hostility  to- 
wards the  subject-matter,  to  develop  paralyzing  inhibitions,  and  to  reduce 
mental  vigor  and  capacity.  Subjection  of  the  youth  of  the  land  to  the 
punitive  philosophy  of  education  and  to  the  administrative  machinery 
necessary  to  achieve  education  with  the  minimum  amount  of  effort  and 
expense  has  led  young  people,  for  the  most  part,  to  regard  education,  not 
as  a  privilege  to  be  exploited  with  joy  and  enthusiasm,  but  as  an  imposi- 
tion and  a  bore,  to  be  evaded  with  the  greatest  ingenuity,  irrespective  of 
its  financial  cost  to  the  individual  student. 

Closely  associated  with  the  punitive  ideal  is  the  solemnity-complex 
which  dominates  conventional  pedagogy.  The  whole  teaching  process 
is  assumed  to  be  a  gloomy  and  earnest  affair.  Light-hearted  enthusiasm 
here  is  in  as  bad  taste  as  a  horse-laugh  at  a  funeral.  Hence  it  is  not 
surprising  that  there  is  little  life  and  vitality  in  contemporary  education. 
Akin  to  this  is  the  notion  of  academic  dignity,  partly  an  outgrowth  of 
the  solemnity-complex  and  partly  a  defense  of  teachers  against  embar- 
rassing questions  and  intellectual  familiarity  from  students. 

It  is  disheartening  to  note  the  lack  of  real  interest  and  enthusiasm  on 
the  part  of  most  students ;  but,  to  explain  it,  we  cannot  rest  satisfied  with 
the  hypothesis  of  the  general  cussedness  of  the  younger  generation.  A 
good  part  of  the  explanation  lies  in  the  unfortunate  conditioning  of  the 
mind  of  the  student,  from  the  days  of  the  kindergarten  to  that  on  which 
the  official  committee  accepts  a  printed  dissertation  presented  for  the 
Ph.D.  degree.  Until  we  supplant  the  punitive  attitude  by  the  recogni- 
tion that  active  interest,  rather  than  mental  punishment,  is  the  only 
rational  motivation  of  dynamic  educational  practice,  we  need  not  expect 
that  students  in  our  schools  and  colleges  will  give  evidence  of  that 
buoyant  enthusiasm  which  is  the  cherished  aspiration  of  progressive 
education. 

Another  reason  for  the  lack  of  realism  and  interest  in  education  and  for 
the  absence  of  enthusiasm  on  the  part  of  students  is  the  all  too  prevalent 
lack  of  special  aptitude  and  gusto  on  the  part  of  teachers.  The  teachers 
in  public  schools  usually  have  some  formal  training  in  pedagogy  and  the 
psych9logy  of  education,  but  they  are  rarely  put  through  any  aptitude 
tests  to  determine  their  fitness  for  the  career  of  instructing  youth.  Unless 
they  are  miserably  incompetent  in  the  matter  of  elementary  classroom 


EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  749 

discipline,  they  can  usually  hold  their  jobs,  however  stultifying  their 
influence  over  pupils.  Many,  especially  young  women  teachers,  have  no 
deep  professional  interest  in  teaching,  and  plan  to  teach  only  until  they 
can  find  some  other  type  of  work  or  get  married. 

Personal  and  professional  aptitude  is  even  more  lacking  among  college 
and  university  teachers.  Many  professors  are  learned  and  charming 
men  and  many  are  well  fitted  to  do  research  and  write  books  in  their 
fields;  but  there  is  little  or  nothing  in  the  requirements  for  the  Ph.D. 
degree  which  has  the  most  remote  relation  to  capacity  to  impart  informa- 
tion to  students  in  competent  and  enthusiastic  fashion.  No  professional 
group  in  modern  society  is  so  ill-prepared,  indeed  unprepared,  for  its 
responsibilities  and  duties  as  are  teachers  in  institutions  of  higher  learn- 
ing. Some  are  superb  teachers,  but,  if  so,  it  is  only  a  happy  accident. 
Many  go  into  college  and  university  teaching  solely  because  there  is  noth- 
ing else  for  them  to  do  or  because  it  offers  a  life  of  dignity,  social  distinc- 
tion, relative  leisure,  and  opportunity  for  scholarly  research  and  reflection. 
It  is  obvious  that  bored  or  incompetent  instructors  cannot  do  much  to 
arouse  enthusiasm  for  learning  on  the  part  of  students. 

So  long  as  our  schools  remain  organizations  given  over  chiefly  to  regis- 
tering the  disappointing  effects  of  teaching  rather  than  to  assuring  prog- 
ress in  learning,  they  will  remain  places  which  are  mainly  efficient  in 
producing  and  recording  educational  failures.  This  general  point  of  view 
was  well  expressed  by  the  late  James  Harvey  Robinson  in  his  discussion 
of  the  motives  and  philosophy  of  the  New  School  for  Social  Research*, 
which  he  helped  to  found  some  years  back  as  an  institution  designed  to 
achieve  educational  ideals  such  as  he  had  in  mind: 

Teaching  and  learning  are  assumed  to  go  hand  in  hand.  But  no  one  who  is  not 
professionally  pledged  to  this  assumption  can  fail  to  see  that  teaching  commonly 
fails  to  produce  learning,  and  that  most  we  have  learned  has  come  without  teach- 
ing, or  in  spite  of  it.  The  gestures  and  routine  that  make  up  teaching  are 
familiar  enough  and  can  easily  be  acquired.  Recitations,  lectures,  quizzes, 
periodical  examinations,  oral  and  written,  textbooks,  readings,  themes,  problems, 
laboratory  work,  culminating  in  diplomas  and  degrees  cum  privilegiis  ad  eos 
pertinentibus,  form  the  daily  business  of  tens  of  thousands  of  teachers  and 
hundreds  of  thousands  of  boys  and  girls  in  thousands  of  smoothly  working 
institutions  dedicated  to  the  instruction  of  the  young.  Teaching  in  all  its  various 
manifestations  can  readily  be  organized  and  administered. 

As  for  learning,  that  is  quite  another  matter.  It  is  highly  elusive  and  no  one 
has  yet  discovered  any  very  secure  ways  of  producing  it.  Being  taught  and 
learning  are  obviously  on  different  psychological  planes;  they  involve  different 
processes  and  emotions;  are  subject  to  different  stimuli  and  ppring  from  different 
impulses.  Our  "institutions  of  learning"  are  essentially  institutions  for  teaching. 
Teaching  is  easy  but  learning  is  hard  and  mysterious,  and  few  there  be  that  attain 
to  it.  It  seldom  forms  the  subject  of  discussion  in  faculty  meetings  where  it  is 
tacitly  assumed  that  pupils  and  students  rarely  wish  to  lenrn,  and  that  the  main 
business  in  hand  is  to  see  that  those  obviously  indifferent  to  being  taught  are 
suitably  classified  and  promoted  or  degraded  according  to  the  prevailing  rules  of 
educational  accountancy.  .  .  . 8 


»  The  Human  Comedy,  Harper,  1936,  pp.  361-362;  see  also  below,  pp.  769  ff.,  777- 
778. 


750  EDUCATION   IN  THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS 

Another  outstanding  defect  of  contemporary  education  is  our  anti- 
quated and  archaic  curriculum  which,  in  spite  of  changes  in  the  last  half 
century,  is  still  out  of  accord  with  the  realities  of  contemporary  life  and 
the  needs  of  the  society  of  our  day. 

In  most  of  our  plans  for  the  reform  of  the  educational  curriculum  we 
refuse  frankly  to  face  the  fact  that  much  of  our  present-day  educational 
philosophy  and  most  of  the  curriculum  represent  a  heritage  from  an 
ancient  past,  which  is  as  ill-adapted  to  modem  thought  and  needs  as  the 
ox-cart  or  the  clepsydra.  Consequently,  most  educational  progress  con- 
sists in  attempting  to  engraft  upon  an  archaic  substructure  an  incongruous 
set  of  highly  modern  educational  notions  and  a  variety  of  novel  subjects 
in  the  curriculum.  The  average  high  school  or  college  of  today  is  not 
unlike  an  ancient  oriental  ox-cart,  to  which  have  been  subsequently 
attached  fragments  from  Greek  and  Roman  chariots,  armor  plate  from 
the  coat  of  mail  of  a  medieval  knight,  the  top  from  an  early  modern 
stagecoach,  pneumatic  tires,  an  automobile  steering-gear,  an  airplane 
propeller,  and  a  radio. 

Such  a  combination  as  this,  if  actually  exhibited  to  the  average  college 
president  or  dean,  a  conventional  professor  of  pedagogy,  or  the  usual  run 
of  school  superintendents,  would  cause  those  normally  solemn  individuals 
to  burst  into  hilarious  laughter.  They  fail,  however,  to  realize  that  the 
educational  system  and  institutions  over  which  they  preside  with  such 
dignity  and  satisfaction  are  a  no  less  amazing  museum-piece,  in  which 
even  the  highly  modern  equipment  is,  to  a  degree,  paralyzed  by  the 
anachronisms  to  which  it  is  attached.  It  is  rarely  understood  that,  if  one 
desires  a  modern  educational  machine,  he  must  scrap  the  whole  exhibit 
and  build  anew,  on  the  basis  of  contemporary  needs  and  knowledge,  in 
exactly  the  same  way  that  a  technician,  desiring  an  airplane,  builds  an 
airplane,  and  does  not  start  by  attaching  a  propeller  and  a  gasoline  tank 
to  a  Roman  chariot. 

The  objectives  of  a  large  proportion  of  the  older  subjects  in  the  curricu- 
lum can  scarcely  be  sustained  in  the  light  of  modern  knowledge.  Those 
subjects  relating  to  religion  have  come  down  from  the  primitive  oriental 
and  riTedieval  notion  that  the  basic  purpose  of  education  is  to  make  clear 
the  will  of  God  or  the  gods  to  mankind.  The  Greeks  and  Romans  added 
to  these  primitive  and  oriental  views  great  emphasis  on  the  value  of  train- 
ing in  rhetoric  and  argumentation  (public  speaking)  in  order  to  provide 
the  technique  for  achieving  success  in  the  political  life  of  the  classical 
period.  The  Middle  Ages  added  a  renewed  emphasis  upon  religion  and 
the  supernatural  in  education.  The  Humanists  contributed  the  notion 
that  the  classical  languages  embody  the  finest  flower  of  secular  learning 
and  are  unparalleled  modes  of  literary  expression.  The  invention  of 
printing  made  possible  the  worship  of  the  printed  page.  The  democratic 
enthusiasm  of  the  last  century  helped  to  establish  the  principle  that 
everybody  is  entitled  to  an  education  and  is  equally  capable  of  participat- 
ing in  a  complete  system  of  educational  activity. 

Scarcely  one  of  these  contentions  can  be  successfully  defended  in  the 


EDUCATION    IN  THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS  751 

light  of  our  present  knowledge  and  needs.  We  can  hardly  hope  to  ascer- 
tain the  will  of  the  gods.  Statesmen  are  in  much  greater  need  of  a 
knowledge  of  the  processes  of  government  and  of  the  statistical  facts 
relative  to  social  problems  than  they  are  of  an  oratorical  technique  which 
will  enable  them  to  avoid  the  split  infinitive  or  the  dangling  participle  or 
to  quote  impressive  passages  from  the  ancient  masters  of  oral  prose.  A 
man  with  Robert  Moses'  equipment  must  be  regarded  as  better  fitted  to 
deal  with  the  problems  of  government  than  the  most  exquisite  orators  of 
our  own  or  earlier  periods.  The  classics,  far  from  being  adequate  to 
serve  as  the  pivotal  item  in  the  whole  curriculum  of  higher  learning,  really 
constitute  but  a  minor  element  in  the  field  of  aesthetics.  Modern  differ- 
ential biology  and  psychology,  as  well  as  educational  experience,  prove 
clearly  enough  that  a  considerable  portion  of  mankind  is  unfitted  by 
reason  of  defective  endowment  to  participate  in  the  higher  ranges  of 
educational  endeavor. 

It  is  hardly  unfair  to  say  that  organized  education  today  is  really  more 
interested  in  perpetuating  the  ignorance  of  the  past  than  in  acquainting 
the  youth  of  the  land  with  new  and  saving  knowledge.  The  greater  part 
of  education  in  the  past  has  been  devoted  to  setting  off  its  products  from 
the  rest  of  society,  as  either  gentlemen  or  churchmen.  Hence  it  is  not 
surprising  that,  as  Horace  Kallen  has  suggested,  our  educational  heritage 
provides  a  distraction  from  life  rather  than  a  realistic  preparation  to  live 
successfully  in  the  twentieth  century. 

We  are  living  in  the  greatest  social  crisis  in  history  and  in  one  so  com- 
plicated that  we  need,  as  never  before,  the  counsel  of  organized  intelli- 
.gencc,  which  should  be  another  name  for  education.  Yet  education 
brings  riiore  inertia  and  confusion  than  clarity  of  vision  and  courage  of 
leadership.  The  social  sciences  are  inadequately  developed  and  pro- 
moted. Their  subject-matter  is  partially  irrelevant  and  their  tone  is 
conservative.  With  democracy  in  headlong  retreat  throughout  the 
modern  world,  we  still  refuse  to  provide  realistic  education  in  the  princi- 
ples of  citizenship  under  democratic  institutions.  The  evils  which  are 
sinking  the  ship  of  state  are  resolutely  obscured.  With  one  family  out 
of  every  six  going  on  the  rocks  and  winding  up  in  a  divorce  court,  we  still 
shy  off  from  thoroughgoing  sex  education  which  might  make  the 
monogamous  family  something  of  a  success. 

Above  all,  we  are  opposed  to  so-called  practical  subjects.  It  is  almost 
a  dogma  in  respectable  educational  circles  that  anything  which  is  directly 
useful  to  humanity  cannot  be  truly  educational.  Any  suggestion  that  we 
introduce  more  practical  subjects  in  institutions  of  higher  learning  is 
usually  vehemently  opposed  as  only  a  first  step  toward  transforming  them 
into  institutions  for  manual  training.  Indeed,  in  one  fairly  progressive 
women's  college,  known  to  the  writer,  exactly  this  objection  was  brought 
forward  when  it  was  proposed  to  outline  a  course  of  study  designed  to  be 
helpful  to  the  college  graduates  who  hoped  to  become  mothers  and  engage 
in  family  activities.  No  new  subjects  were  proposed.  All  that  was 
suggested  was  a  logical  organization  of  reputable  courses  already  being 


752  EDUCATION    IN   THE   SOCIAL   CRISIS 

taught,  but  outlined  in  a  natural  sequence,  designed  to  constitute  four 
years  of  profitable  academic  work.  It  was  denounced  by  the  ethereal 
pedants  on  the  faculty  as  a  mere  "housekeeping  major,"  a^nd  regarded  as 
akin  to  instruction  in  blacksmithing  and  cheese-making.  At  least  half  the 
subjects  now  being  taught  in  our  schools  and  universities  have  no  useful 
relationship  to  life  in  the  twentieth  century.  They  may  not  be  directly 
harmful  in  themselves,  but  they  prevent  adequate  attention  from  being 
given  to  subject-matter  upon  which  the  future  destiny  of  humanity  very 
literally  depends. 

Another  source  of  weakness  and  waste  in  contemporary  education  has 
been  an  inevitable  outgrowth  of  mass  education.  The  most  economical 
and  convenient  way  of  carrying  on  mass  education  is  to  try  to  put  all  the 
children  in  the  schools  and  colleges  through  the  same  curriculum  and  to 
handle  them  by  the  same  educational  machinery.  The  very  mental  tests 
which  the  educational  experts  have  done  so  much  to  provide  clearly  re- 
veal the  futility  of  such  procedure.  They  make  it  clear  that  the  school 
population  varies  in  intellectual  capacity  from  morons  to  geniuses. 
Further,  the  vocational  tests  which  educators  have  been  improving  during 
the  last  generation  indicate  the  wide  variety  of  special  talents  which  it 
should  be  the  function  of  education  to  recognize  and  encourage.  Yet,  we 
still  attempt  to  prescribe  the  same  subjects  and  modes  of  instruction  for 
the  moron,  the  average  student,  and  the  genius,  for  the  student  with  a 
literary  flourish  and  one  with  mechanical  genius.  While  we  have  begun 
to  introduce  special  classes  for  extremely  handicapped  and  retarded 
children,  we  have  only  scratched  the  surface  of  the  problem  of  differen- 
tiating education  according  to  special  abilities,  functions,  needs,  and 
personal  ambitions.  Little  has  been  done"  to  take  into  account  the  special 
requirements  and  opportunities  of  the  mentally  superior  children.  Our 
failure  to  differentiate  between  those  who  simply  go  to  college  because 
it  is  the  current  style  to  do  so  and  those  who  enter  higher  education  be- 
cause they  really  wish  to  learn  something  confuses  our  entire  system  of 
higher  education. 

In  our  effort  to  provide  administrative  machinery  to  facilitate  mass- 
education,  we  have  brought  about  a  system  that  turns  out  duplicate 
models  of  mental  docility,  instead  of  promoting  the  growth  of  intellectual 
alertness  and  curiosity.  The  original  and  independent  teacher  finds 
himself  restricted  on  every  hand  by  the  machinery  of  education.  The 
progressive  education  movement  has  been,  largely,  a  revolt  against  the 
limitations  upon  dynamic  education  imposed  by  the  whole  complex  of 
administrative  machinery. 

The  examination  bogey  also  restricts  mental  alertness  and  enthusiasm. 
We  must  have  some  tests  wherewith  to  determine  the  promotion  of  stu- 
dents in  the  educational  process;  but  we  have  carried  these  to  such  an 
extreme  that  "education"  is  often  a  matter  of  successfully  passing  peri- 
odic examinations.  Little  attention  is  given  to  the  quality  of  learning 
and  to  the  amount  of  useful  information  that  may  remain  in  the  mind  of 
the  student  after  he  has  passed  an  examination.  Moreover,  the  fears 


EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  753 

and  inhibitions  associated  with  examinations  all  too  often  impair  the 
mental  activity  of  even  capable  students. 

Concentration  upon  frequent  formal  examinations  as  the  chief  test 
of  the  educational  progress  of  students  is  one  of  the  most  deadly  of 
pedagogical  methods.  Sooner  or  later,  a  means  becomes  transformed 
into  an  end.  What  is  at  best  only  a  highly  imperfect  method  of  measur- 
ing intellectual  advancement  becomes  the  essence  of  the  educational 
process.  The  better  students  look  upon  educational  success  as  something 
which  is  demonstrated  by  an  imposing  string  of  "A's,"  while  the  mob 
regards  the  summum  bonum  as  attained  when  they  make  the  requisite 
number  of  "C's."  There  is  no  necessary  connection  between  true  learning, 
on  the  one  hand,  and  the  process  of  cramming  information  to  secure  a 
high  grade  in  formal  examinations,  on  the  other.  To  the  real  student, 
there  is  often  little  true  joy  in  the  learning  process  until  he  has  passed 
beyond  the  examination  nuisance — that  is,  beyond  the  scope  and  control 
of  official  education.  The  writer  has  heard  many  testify,  in  a  semi- 
humorous  and  semi-ironical  and  embittered  fashion,  to  the  fact  that  they 
obtained  little  enjoyment  from  their  educational  life  until  after  they 
had  completed  all  the  requirements  for  the  degree  of  doctor  of  philosophy. 
A  spirited  criticism  of  the  net  result  of  excessive  educational  machinery 
and  mass  education  has  been  offered  by  Porter  Sargent,  a  professional 
student  of  elementary  and  secondary  education  and  editor  of  the  im- 
portant annual,  A  Handbook  of  Private  Schools,  in  his  article  on  "The 
Crime  of  Teaching"  in  the  Yankee  Magazine.  It  is,  perhaps,  slightly 
overdrawn,  but  Mr.  Sargent  does  put  his  finger  upon  one  of  the  more 
serious  defects  of  contemporary  mass-education: 

It's  in  America  and  England  that  the  schoolhouse  and  the  bughouse  have 
become  the  conspicuous  blots  on  the  landscape.  Wherever  a  few  children  are 
gathered  together  there's  a  schoolhouse.  The  asylums  lie  about  the  great  centers 
of  population  like  the  outlying  forts  about  Paris.  Together  they  are  as  charac- 
teristic of  our  culture  as  the  Gothic  cathedral  of  medieval  Europe,  the  columned 
temple  of  Greece  or  the  stupa  and  pagoda  of  Buddhist  countries.  Whether  in 
New  England  or  Southern  California,  choice  hilltop  spots  are  crowded  with  great 
institutional  brick  piles — our  schools  or  our  asylums.  Before  the  gaze  of  heaven 
we  parade  the  human  sacrifices  of  our  civilization.  The  ultimate  causes  are 
deep  hidden  for  shame.  And  like  the  Aztecs,  it's  the  flower  of  our  youth  we 
sacrifice — geniuses,  men  of  promise  like  Clifford  Beers,  founder  of  the  mental 
hygiene  movement.  The  "untutored"  mind  escapes.  Those  who  go  to  the 
asylums  and  the  prisons  have  passed  through  the  sehoolhouses.  And  yearly  an 
increasing  percentage  of  the  schoolhouse  product  goes  on  to  the  bughouse.4 

According  to  Mr.  Sargent,  a  Harvard  alumnus,  it  is  frustration  which 
leads  to  both  educational  futility  and  the  great  increase  in  mental  disease. 
Education,  as  conducted  today,  is  little  more  than  organized  frustration 
for  the  youth  of  the  land.  It  is  almost  true  that  the  more  highly  educated 
a  person  is,  the  more  frustrated  he  is  likely  to  be: 

Frustration  is  the  one  thing  characteristic  of  the  present  generation.  It  is  a 
frustrated  world  we  live  in.  We  haven't  the  healthy  extrovert  attitude  toward 

4  Loc.    cit.,   Yankee,    Inc.,    Winter,    1938. 


754  EDUCATION    IN  THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS 

life  that  was  characteristic  of  the  Elizabethans  and  their  time  when  children  had 
less  schooling.  Today  we  rob  the  child  of  his  joy  in  this  wonderful  world  into 
which  he  has  been  born.  We  dull  his  edge.  We  bring  about  frustration.  In- 
creasingly for  several  generations  we  have  been  doing  this  and  now  as  a  people 
we  are  frustrated,  we  have  nowhere  to  go,  no  aims,  no  purposes,  no  ideals,  no 
drive.  The  academic  sophisticates  rather  pride  themselves  on  their  supercilious 
cynicism.  The  more  highly  educated  a  group,  the  more  frustrated  they  appear. 
Look  at  a  gathering  of  old  Harvard  grads,  bald,  jowled,  clewlapped,  stoop- 
shouldered,  pot-bellied.  They  are  dulled,  disillusioned.  There  is  no  sparkle, 
no  fire.  They  are  a  tamed,  dispirited  lot,  without  zest  for  life. 

It  is  Mr.  Sargent's  thesis  that  education  is  *'  misnomer  for  the  pro- 
cedure of  the  present  school  system.  Our  pupils  are  sent  to  school  but 
not  educated: 

The  people  we  see  about  us  today  have  been  schooled,  not  educated.  They 
have  been  taught  what  someone  thought  they  ought  to  know,  deprived  of  what 
they  hungered  for.  No  wonder  they  are  frustrated.  Twelve  years  of  schooling, 
four  years  of  college,  four  years  of  professional  training,  two  years  of  interneship 
or  apprenticeship  in  office  or  factory — twenty-two  years  of  teaching  and  educa- 
tion or  frustration  before  they  are  permitted  to  do  anything.  The  only  way  a 
child  during  the  last  few  generations  could  get  an  education  was  to  play  truant — 
and  he  got  licked  for  that. 

The  unfortunate  characteristics  of  excessive  educational  machinery  and 
mass  education  extend  to  our  institutions  of  higher  learning  as  well  as  to 
our  schools.  Much  critical  literature  has  been  produced  on  the  so-called 
factory  system  in  higher  education.  It  must  be  obvious  to  all  thoughtful 
and  candid  observers  that  the  increase  in  the  size  of  our  institutions  of 
higher  learning  has  brought  about  a  remarkable  transformation  in  ideals 
and  methods  since  the  day  when  the  perfect  college  was  one  symbolized 
by  Mark  Hopkins  on  one  end  of  a  log  and  a  half-dozen  exuberant  students 
on  the  other. 

It  is  necessary,  at  the  outset,  in  the  interest  of  accuracy  and  logic,  to 
distinguish  between  those  aspects  of  modern  university  life  which  arise 
chiefly  from  the  increased  size  of  institutions  and  those  which  have  grown 
Dut  of  contemporary  cultural  transformations  or  have  proceeded  from 
present-day  fads.  The  tendency  towards  swarming  to  institutions  of 
higher  learning,  indifference  to  serious  intellectual  endeavor,  abnormal 
consumption  of  liquor,  obsession  with  football,  scouring  the  countryside 
in  high-powered  cars,  and  freak  subjects  in  the  curriculum,  may  have 
been  in  some  cases  intensified  by  the  factory  system  in  education,  but 
they  cannot  honestly  be  said  to  have  been  produced  solely  by  large-scale 
higher  education  or  to  be  inevitable  products  of  it.  We  must  confine 
ourselves  to  those  situations  which  have  inevitably  arisen  out  of  the 
overgrown  state  of  many  large  universities. 

It  is  clear  that,  in  the  first  place,  our  larger  educational  factories  must 
be  primarily  places  for  teaching  rather  than  learning,  unless  the  endow- 
ment and  income  are  sufficiently  great  to  enable  classes  to  be  broken  up 
into  small  units  and  to  provide  really  competent  and  experienced  teach- 
ers for  all  such  groups.  Under  normal  circumstances,  a  maximum  of  in- 
struction must  be  dispensed  with,  a  minimum  of  effort  and  expense. 


EDUCATION    IN   THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS  755 

This  leads  to  overcrowded  lecture  courses,  the  enrollment  sometimes  run- 
ning as  high  as  several  thousand  in  a  single  course.  Later,  these  mobs 
are  broken  up  into  small  section-meetings,  where  they  are  more  or  less 
mechanically  quizzed  in  a  routine  fashion  by  cub  instructors.  The  latter 
aim  to  discover  the  talents  of  the  students  as  human  parrots,  measured  by 
their  ability  to  reproduce  the  lecture  material  dispensed  by  the  depart- 
mental orator-in-chief,  or  by  their  facility  in  mastering  the  required 
reading,  uniformly  assigned  to  all  students  in  the  course.  If  the  subject 
is  natural  science,  the  quizzes  on  subject-matter  are  supplemented  by 
the  laboratory  section  meetings,  likewise  presided  over  by  tyro  instruc- 
tors and  assistants  who  administer  the  system  through  enforced  compli- 
ance with  the  manual  of  procedure  prepared  by  the  chief  or  by  an 
eminent  professional  colleague.  In  this  way  adolescent  Newtons, 
Faradays,  Pasteurs,  Darwins,  Helmholtzes,  Einsteins,  and  Michelsons 
are  supposed  to  be  created  en  masse. 

All  of  this  group  instruction  is,  for  the  most  part,  administered  in 
accordance  with  the  precepts  of  the  penitential  and  punitive  educational 
philosophy,  based  upon  the  conception  of  education  as  a  matter  of 
assigning  tasks — mostly  unpleasant — and  exacting  rigorous  compliance 
with  such  requirements.  There  is  a  general  ignorance  of  the  fact  that 
ardent  interest  in  the  task  at  hand,  conceived  in  a  rational  and  practical 
manner,  is  the  only  real  key  to  educational  achievement  and  school 
hygiene  alike.  There  is  little  possibility,  under  such  conditions,  of 
arousing  student  interest  in  the  subject-matter,  either  by  the  inspiration 
growing  out  of  close  personal  contact  with  a  great  master  or  through  a 
glowing  and  enthusiastic  type  of  personal  exposition  of  academic  mate- 
rials. -The  whole  matter  tends  to  become  formal,  unreal,  artificial,  un- 
pleasant, and  repellent. 

Not  only  is  instruction  in  the  factory  type  of  university  for  the  most 
part  large-scale,  formal,  impersonal,  and  punitive.  This,  of  necessity, 
carries  with  it  great  reliance  upon  official  regimentation,  an  elaborate 
system  of  records,  resort  to  frequent  and  standardized  examinations,  and 
general  trust  in  formal  method  and  procedure  rather  than  in  creating 
an  inquiring  spirit.  This  standardization  often  goes  beyond  determining 
the  status  and  promotion  of  the  students  through  their  years  in  college, 
and  even  applies  to  their  teachers  as  well.  Some  of  our  larger  universi- 
ties base  the  tenure  and  promotion  of  their  instructors  upon  the  number 
of  printed  pages  which  they  have  published  during  any  year  or  group  of 
years. 

Large-scale  education  also  has  its  inevitable  effect  upon  the  general 
intellectual  and  social  life  of  the  students.  There  is  little  opportunity  for 
diversified  and  intimate  acquaintanceship.  There  can  be  little  common 
spirit  or  true  institutional  appreciation,  except  in  such  superficial  irrele- 
vancies  as  hysterical  loyalty  to  football  teams  or  participation  in  class 
festivities.  There  is  no  possibility  of  living  any  real  university  social 
life,  with  the  consequence  that  the  financially  more  fortunate  ones  drift 
into  snobbery  and  fraternity  cliques,  while  the  less  fortunate  swarm  about 


756  EDUCATION    IN   THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS 

in  temporary  and  aimless  gregariousness  or  retire  into  embittered  isola- 
tion. The  whole  situation  makes  for  artificiality  and  distraction,  and 
there  is  little  which  leads  to  calm  and  mature  reflection  or  stimulating 
intimacy  of  spirit.  The  faculty  is  affected  as  well  as  the  students. 

Closely  related  to  mass  education  and  the  customary  regimentation  in 
the  process  has  been  a  tendency  to  overstress  the  custodial  function  of 
our  schools  and  colleges.  As  a  result  of  our  material  civilization  and 
its  distractions,  the  educational  system  is  becoming  a  hierarchy  of 
dignified  institutions  of  child-care  and  supervision.  A  generation  or  so 
ago,  the  home  was  the  center  of  social,  educational,  and  recreational  life. 
There  was  little  incentive  to  seek  recreation  and  distraction  elsewhere 
and  little  opportunity  to  clo  so  if  the  inclination  arose. 

Today  the  movies,  golf  courses,  automobiles,  dance  halls,  night  clubs, 
theaters,  country  clubs,  and  the  like,  offer  allurement,  even  to  respectable 
classes.  Children  are  a  care  and  a  social  liability  to  those  who  want 
to  participate  in  such  social  and  recreational  activities,  and  this  burden 
cannot  be  fully  removed  by  turning  children  over  to  the  care  of  maids 
and  tutors  in  the  home.  Today  many  parents  engage  in  remunerative 
work  that  takes  them  out  of  the  home  for  most  of  the  day.  Conse- 
quently, in  addition  to  the  public  schools  and  state  universities,  we  have 
developed  a  great  hierarchy  of  institutions,  from  the  day  nursery  through 
the  private  schools  for  boys  and  girls,  to  preparatory  schools  and  col- 
leges. These  receive  and  safely  care  for  children  who,  while  not  unloved, 
prove  an  annoyance  and  special  cross  to  parents  who  want  freedom  from 
domestic  responsibilities.  Many  parents  have  fostered  the  development 
of  elaborate  summer  camps  for  boys  and  girls,  which  relieve  them  of 
parental  responsibility  during  the  non-school  months  as  well. 

Parents  do  not  always  recognize  their  desire  for  unencumbered  free- 
dom. They  usually  rationalize  their  action  on  the  ground  that  residen- 
tial schools  and  camps  offer  better  facilities  for  their  children  than  can  be 
obtained  at  home.  The  same  changes  in  civilization  that  have  made  it 
desirable  to  be  rid  of  children  have  brought  that  increase  in  prosperity 
which  has  made  it  possible  to  send  progeny  to  expensive  custodial  insti- 
tutions. Parents  who  do  not  want  or  are  unable  to  send  their  children 
a,way  before  college  years  still  hope  that  the  institutions  of  higher  learn- 
ing to  which  they  consign  their  offspring  will  be  places  of  safe  custody. 

Thus  the  chief  function  of  education,  in  the  minds  of  many  parents,  is 
the  custodial  function.  Children  in  preparatory  schools  and  colleges  are 
especially  hard  to  manage ;  they  simply  radiate  "problems"  due  to  puberty 
and  adolescence.  The  parents  are  glad  to  pass  on  the  responsibility  for 
their  control  to  the  educational  institutions.  The  schools  and  colleges 
accept  the  custodial  responsibility  and  formulate  their  rules  accordingly. 
Regimentation  and  administration  are  controlled  much  more  by  con- 
siderations incident  to  successful  custody  than  by  concern  for  intellectual 
stimulation.  There  are  rules  about  residence  and  absences  which,  in 
some  cases,  are  almost  as  rigorous  as  those  in  the  more  liberal  cor- 
rectional institutions. 


EDUCATION    IN  THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS  757 

The  success  of  a  college  is  often  measured  by  its  capacity  for  the  safe 
segregation  of  youth.  If  a  college  turns  out  class  after  class  with  few  or 
no  casualties,  scandals,  or  disappearances,  even  though  the  pretense  to 
educating  the  students  is  obviously  a  sham,  the  administration  is  praised 
as  brilliantly  performing  its  pedagogical  duties  and  fully  discharging  its 
social  responsibilities.  On  the  other  hand,  should  a  courageous,  ener- 
getic, and  stimulating  college  president  develop  some  degree  of  intellec- 
tual interest  on  the  part  of  the  students  and  actually  educate  a  few  of 
them,  his  achievement  would  immediately  be  nullified  in  parental  opinion 
if  one  eccentric  or  overbuoyant  student  should  escape  or  involve  the 
college  in  some  scandal,  indicating  possible  laxity  in  discipline.  It  is  a 
situation  not  unlike  that  in  the  penal  institutions,  where  the  warden 
is  rated  by  his  success  in  the  prevention  of  escapes. 

The  efficiency  and  status  of  college  professors  are  also  primarily  deter- 
mined by  their  success  in  promoting  the  record  of  the  institution  as  a 
place  for  safe  segregation.  A  professor,  however  boring,  monotonous, 
and  unstimulating  to  the  students,  is  a  valued  faculty  member  if  he 
creates  a  quiescent  attitude  on  the  part  of  the  students  and,  by  his 
somnolent  influence,  reduces  the  probability  of  student  thoughtfulness, 
scepticism,  recalcitrance,  or  insurrection.  Let  a  brilliant,  active  professor 
stir  his  students  to  independence  of  thought  and  action,  and  he  becomes 
a  challenge  to  the  whole  system  of  institutional  regimentation  and  will 
likely  be  let  out  at  the  earliest  opportunity. 

Besides  putting  the  custodial  function  of  a  college  far  ahead  of  its  edu- 
cational responsibility,  most  parents  are  even  fearful  of  real  education. 
H.  L.  Mencken  has  ironically  said  that  nothing  is  so  shocking  to  a  parent 
as  to  discover  intelligence  in  his  child,  and  nothing  could  be  more  repug- 
nant to  him  than  to  envisage  sending  his  child  to  an  institution  that 
proposed  actually  to  educate  him,  namely,  to  make  him  more  intelligent. 

One  of  the  major  obstacles  to  making  education  a  potent  vehicle  of 
social  enlightenment  is  the  influence  of  tradition,  habit,  and  the  conserva- 
tive longing  for  absolute  certainty  in  human  affairs.  For  nothing  does 
the  human  mind  yearn  more  persistently  than  for  a  sense  of  safety  and 
assurance  amidst  the  problems  forced  upon  us  by  the  facts  of  the  external 
world,  the  nature  of  our  own  biochemical  equipment,  and  association  with 
our  fellows.  We  have  a  deep-seated  desire  to  know  just  what  we  should 
do  and  how  and  when  we  should  do  it.  Dogma,  routine,  and  habit  are 
not  only  great  time-savers,  but  are  also  indispensable  to  the  creation  of 
that  enviable  feeling  of  intellectual  sufficiency,  moral  certainty,  and  eco- 
nomic security  which  characterizes  the  person  who  finds  himself  per- 
fectly adjusted  to  what  he  regards  as  the  best  of  all  possible  worlds. 

Down  to  the  twentieth  century,  it  was  possible  for  the  intellectual 
classes  to  possess  some  close  approximation  to  that  feeling  of  omniscience 
and  security  for  which  we  all  seek.  Primitive  folklore,  mythology  and 
mores,  and  later  the  dogmas  of  religion,  politics,  economics,  and  educa- 
tion, were  able  to  create  for  man  a  world  of  such  conceptual  simplicity 
that  one  could  believe  that  he  possessed  the  totality  of  saving  knowledge 


758  EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

with  respect  to  every  problem  confronting  man.  In  our  day,  however, 
the  achievements  in  modern  natural  science,  biblical  scholarship,  critical 
thought,  and  social  science  have  shown  that  the  conceptions  of  the  cosmos, 
the  world,  man  and  human  society  upon  which  the  older  dogmas  rested, 
were  an  almost  complete  illusion.  If  this  be  true,  then  the  dogmas  them- 
selves possess  no  more  validity  than  the  fictitious  world  order  from  which 
they  were  derived. 

Further,  and  even  more  disconcerting,  modern  science  and  scholarship 
have  shown  that  the  physical  cosmos  is  so  complex,  extensive,  and 
dynamic  that  we  can  never  hope  to  possess  absolute  certainty  with  re- 
spect to  anything.  One  of  the  basic  laws  in  modern  physics  is  Werner 
Heisenberg's  law  of  indeterminacy  which,  as  one  commentator  has  ob- 
served, implies  that  "the  only  certainty  in  the  physical  world  is  uncer- 
tainty." The  remarkable  progress  in  the  study  of  man  and  human 
society  from  the  angles  of  mechanistic  biology,  physiological  chemistry, 
comparative  and  dynamic  psychology,  and  the  various  social  sciences  has 
likewise  proved  that  man  and  his  culture  present  a  complexity  which  can 
no  longer  be  explained  within  the  categories  of  the  older  religious  and 
metaphysical  rationalizations. 

In  other  words,  after  having  taken  away  from  a  person  the  neat  antique 
dogmas,  done  up  in  mental  tinfoil  and  properly  distributed  in  the  nice 
cabinet  of  intellectual  pigeonholes,  which  contains  his  equipment  of  con- 
ventional knowledge,  there  are  no  carefully  assorted  and  clearly  tabulated 
packages  of  learning  to  hand  back  in  return.  Indeed,  we  must  even 
give  the  cabinet  of  pigeonholes  a  well-placed  kick.  There  is  considerable 
grief  about  so  much  "tearing  down"  of  ancient  beliefs  without  "putting 
anything  in  their  place,"  but  this  begs  the  whole  question.  The  first 
essential  of  the  modern  outlook  is  to  recognize  that  the  only  thing  which 
can  replace  the  older  cut-and-dried  dogmas  is  a  new  mental  attitude — 
namely  open-mindedness,  persistent  cerebration,  scientific  method,  and 
hard  study,  in  the  hope  of  ultimately  discovering  some  final  working 
approximations  to  truth.  This  point  has  been  emphasized  with  charac- 
teristic charm  and  lucidity  by  Carl  Becker: 

This  effort  to  find  out  what  it's  all  about  is,  in  our  time,  more  difficult  than 
jver  before.  The  reason  is  that  the  old  foundations  of  assured  faith  and  familiar 
custom  are  crumbling  under  our  feet.  For  four  hundred  years  the  world  of 
education  and  knowledge  rested  securely  on  two  fundamentals  which  were  rarely 
questioned.  These  were  Christian  philosophy  and  Classical  learning.  For  the 
better  part  of  a  century  Christian  faith  has  been  going  by  the  board,  and 
Classical  learning  into  the  discard.  To  replace  these  we  have  as  yet  no  founda- 
tions, no  certainties.  We  live  in  a  world  dominated  by  machines,  a  world  of 
incredibly  rapid  change,  a  world  of  naturalistic  science  and  of  physicp-chemico- 
libido  psychology.  There  are  no  longer  any  certainties  either  in  life  or  in  thought. 
Everywhere  confusion.  Everywhere  questions.  Where  are  we?  Where  did  we 
come  from?  Where  do  we  go  from  here?  What  is  it  all  about?  The  freshmen 
are  asking,  and  they  may  well  ask.  Everyone  is  asking.  No  one  knows;  and 
those  who  profess  with  most  confidence  to  know  are  most  likely  to  be  mistaken. 
Professors  could  reorganize  the  College  of  Arts  if  they  knew  what  a  College  of 
Arts  should  be.  They  could  give  students  a  "general  education"  if  they  knew 


EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  759 

what  a  general  education  was,  or  would  be  good  for  if  one  had  it.  Professors  are 
not  especially  to  blame  because  the  world  has  lost  all  certainty  about  these 
things.5 

Moreover,  much  of  the  grief  at  the  tearing-down  process  is  misplaced. 
There  is  often  much  constructive  service  in  the  process  of  tearing  down 
and  taking  away.  No  one  would  urge  a  surgeon  to  replace  an  inflamed 
appendix  by  a  malignant  tumor.  No  one  mourns  because  we  have  dis- 
rupted many  of  the  beliefs  and  practices  held  sacred  among  primitive 
peoples.  Several  centuries  from  now,  in  all  probability,  the  cultivated 
classes  will  view  the  most  "sacred"  beliefs  and  institutions  of  the  mid- 
twentieth  century  much  as  we  now  regard  cannibalism,  the  couvade,  and 
the  suttee.  Indeed,  one  of  the  results  of  modern  thought  has  been  to 
render  the  very  concept  of  "sacredness"  an  obstructive  anachronism. 
Nobody  has  stated  this  better  than  did  James  Harvey  Robinson  in  the 
following  paragraph: 

One  of  the  great  obstacles  to  a  free  reconsideration  of  the  details  of  our  human 
plight  is  our  tendency  to  regard  familiar  notions  as  "sacred";  that  is,  too  assured 
to  be  questioned  except  by  the  perverse  and  wicked.  This  word  sacred  to  the 
student  of  human  sentiment  is  redolent  of  ancient,  musty  misapprehensions.  It 
recalls  a  primitive  and  savage  setting-off  of  purity  and  impurity,  cleanness  and 
uncleanness.  .  .  .  Simple  prejudices  or  unconsidered  convictions  are  so  numer- 
ous that  the  urgence  and  shortness  of  life  hardly  permit  any  of  us,  even  the  most 
alert,  to  summon  all  of  them  before  the  judgment  seat.  Then  there  are  the 
sacred  prejudices  of  which  it  seems  to  me  we  might  become  aware  and  beware,  if 
we  are  sufficiently  honest  and  energetic.  History  might  be  so  rewritten  that  it 
would  at  least  eliminate  the  feeling  that  any  of  our  ideas  or  habits  should  be 
exempt  from  prosecution  when  grounds  for  indictment  were  suggested  by  ex- 
perience.6 

It  was  inevitable  that  this  unique  situation  would,  in  due  time,  impinge 
upon  the  intellectual  life  of  college  circles.  In  the  period  intervening 
between  the  college  days  of  the  parents  of  the  present  generation  of  college 
students  and  those  of  their  children  there  have  been  more  changes 
of  an  unsettling  nature  than  in  the  thousand  years  which  separated 
Charlemagne  from  Abraham  Lincoln.  This  fact  has,  however,  been  slow 
in  penetrating  the  thinking  of  college  circles.  Only  rarely  have  even  the 
professors  achieved  approximate  contemporaneity  in  their  intellectual 
outlook.  A  goodly  proportion  of  college  teachers  have  retained  unaltered 
the  dogmas  and  convictions  which  they  acquired  during  the  generation  in 
which  they  attended  college.  Others  are  intense  specialists  who  do  good 
work  in  their  particular  narrow  lines  of  research  but  lack  social  orienta- 
tion and  public  interests.  Few  college  teachers  become  such  because  of 
comprehensive  enlightenment  or  on  account  of  the  desire  to  bring  about 
such  a  beatific  state  on  the  part  of  their  students.  The  real  process  of 
becoming  a  professor  is  not  unlike  that  described  by  Clarence  C.  Little, 
ex-President  of  the  University  of  Michigan,  in  the  remarks  attributed  to 


B  Letter  in  Cornell  Sun. 

0  The  Human  Comedy,  Harper,  1936,  pp. 


760  EDUCATION    IN  THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS 

him  in  a  speech  delivered  some  years  ago  before  the  National  Student 
Federation: 

Most  professors  reach  their  positions  through  a  curious  process.  After  they 
receive  their  pass-key  to  that  intellectual  garret  of  Phi  Beta  Kappa,  the  devil, 
in  the  form  of  some  friend,  whispers  into  their  ears  that  they  should  teach.  They 
often  accept  the  suggestion,  and  after  securing  their  master's  degrees,  they  write 
a  thesis  on  some  such  subject  as  "The  Suspenders  of  Henry  VIII"  and  then  are 
qualified  to  teach.  A  thesis  subject  is  by  definition  a  subject  about  which  no  one 
has  ever  cared  to  write  before. 

This  type  of  man  is  then  put  in  charge  of  a  group  of  freshmen,  and  he  generally 
has  a  great  disdain  of  their  consummate  ignorance,  while  they  on  their  part  have 
a  great  disdain  for  his  consummate  learning.  Sometimes  someone  springs  up 
among  the  freshmen  with  the  declaration  that  the  suspenders  of  Henry  VIII  are 
the  most  important  things  in  the  world.  Immediately,  the  professor  picks  him 
up  from  the  bog  of  ignorance  in  which  the  rest  of  the  freshmen  lie  and  starts  him 
on  the  path  to  another  professorship. 

When,  however,  there  is  a  teacher  who  is  in  reasonable  rapport  with 
the  contemporary  age  and  is  possessed  of  at  least  average  powers  of 
articulation,  the  shocking  power  of  his  reflections  and  observations  is 
inevitably  great,  even  though  he  does  nothing  more  than  synthesize  the 
rudimentary  platitudes  of  twentieth-century  knowledge.  This  disturbing 
influence  need  not  be  due  in  any  sense  to  special  ability  or  peculiarly 
seductive  pedagogy  on  the  part  of  the  instructor.  It  is  merely  an  indi- 
cation of  the  wide  gulf  which  separates  us  from  the  assured  knowledge 
of  the  year  1900.  When  one  calmly  reflects  upon  the  reality  and  extent 
of  this  gulf,  he  is  likely  to  marvel,  not  at  the  frequency  with  which 
alarmed  parents  endeavor  to  tone  down  the  lectures  of  teachers  who  are 
endeavoring  to  dispense  information  and  attitudes  of  a  contemporaneous 
vintage,  but  rather  that  such  efforts  to  intimidate  university  instructors 
and  executives  do  not  occur  much  more  often.  The  custodial  tendency 
in  education,  which  we  examined  above,  helps  to  intensify  this  desire 
to  protect  youth  from  disconcerting  advances  in  human  knowledge. 

The  influence  of  conservatism  over  American  education  has  also  been 
extended  by  the  prevailing  tendency  to  gather  our  college  and  university 
boards  of  trustees  from  among  leaders  in  business  and  finance.  Since 
•our  higher  learning  has  become  a  big-business  affair  with  regard  to  plant, 
income,  and  expenditures,  it  has  been  felt  that  only  leaders  in  business 
and  finance  can  competently  direct  the  policies  of  our  colleges  and  univer- 
sities. It  has  been  particularly  maintained  that  they  are  absolutely  in- 
dispensable, in  order  to  raise  endowments  and  other  funds  needed  for 
current  operating  expenses.  No  doubt  the  fact  that  the  ultimate  power 
in  the  realm  of  higher  learning  resides  in  men  drawn  from  business  and 
finance  has  made  for  conservatism  in  university  policies  and  in  classroom 
instruction  alike.  The  illusion  that  businessmen  and  financiers  make  the 
best  trustees  and  are  indispensable  has  been  colorfully  punctured  by 
H.  L.  Mencken  in  his  comment  on  "Babbitt  in  the  Athenaeum": 

Of  the  superstitions  prevailing  in  the  United  States,  one  of  the  most  curious 
is  to  the  effect  that  businessmen  make  good  university  trustees.  Not  infre- 


EDUCATION    IN  THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS  761 

quently — nay,  usually — it  is  carried  to  the  length  of  holding  that  they  make  the 
only  good  ones. 

It  would  be  hard  to  imagine  anything  more  untrue.  In  fact,  very  few  men 
trained  to  business  seem  to  be  capable  of  grasping  what  a  university  is  about: 
they  constantly  assume  that  it  is  simply  a  kind  of  railroad,  or  a  somewhat  odd 
and  irrational  kind  of  rolling  mill.  That  it  differs  as  radically  from  such  enter- 
prises as  a  string  quartette  differs  from  a  two-ton  truck,  or  an  archangel  from,  a 
United  States  Senator,  or  Betelgeuse  from  a  baseball — this  seems  to  be  quite 
beyond  their  comprehension. 

Sometimes  one  hears  that  trustees  must  be  businessmen  because  running  a 
university  costs  a  great  deal  of  money,  and  they  alone  can  raise  it.  But  there 
is  no  proof  of  this  last  in  the  record.  Most  American  universities,  though  they 
are  run  by  businessmen,  are  always  on  the  edge  of  bankruptcy,  and  if  it  were  not 
for  occasional  windfalls  they  would  slip  over.  The  trustees  seldom  have  any- 
thing to  do  with  bringing  down  these  windfalls;  they  are  fetched  by  members  of 
the  faculty — either  by  making  a  noise  in  the  world  professionally,  or  by  making 
a  noise  otherwise.  In  one  of  the  greater  American  universities  a  single  member 
of  the  faculty  has  raised  more  money  during  the  past  thirty  years  than  all  of 
the  trustees  combined. 

I  believe  that  the  first  American  university  which  bars  businessmen — and 
especially  bankers — from  its  board  will  leap  ahead  so  fast  that  in  five  years  the 
rest  will  be  nowhere.  Let  it  substitute  any  other  class  of  men  it  pleases — movie 
actors,  Turkish  bath  rubbers,  steamboat  captains,  astrologers,  bootleggers,  even 
clergymen.  No  matter  which  way  it  turns  it  will  be  on  the  up-and-up. 

Businessmen  unquestionably  have  their  virtues,  and  no  sensible  person  would 
deny  their  great  value  to  society.  Many  of  them,  in  their  private  capacities,  are 
highly  intelligent.  But  there  is  something  in  their  make-up  which  makes  them 
distrust  and  misunderstand  a  university  as  they  distrust  and  misunderstand  the 
Bill  of  Rights.  They  are  as  out  of  place  in  the  grove  of  Athene  as  they  would  be 
in  the  College  of  Cardinals. 

The  twentieth  century  has  produced  a  striking  development  which 
either  distracts  attention  from  truly  educational  matters  or  is  directly 
antagonistic  to  the  true  interests  of  education.  We  refer  to  intercol- 
legiate athletics,  particularly  football.  While  the  abuses  associated  with 
these  athletic  enterprises  have  been  mainly  limited  to  colleges  and  uni- 
versities, they  have  now  become  very  widely  extended  to  our  secondary 
and  preparatory  schools.  When  the  average  American  thinks  of  Yale, 
Harvard,  and  Princeton,  he  is  more  likely  to  recall  their  football  teams 
and  star  players  than  their  faculties  and  scholastic  achievements. 
Famous  football  players  like  Red  Grange  and  Tom  Harmon  figure  far 
more  in  the  public  eye  than  even  the  most  eminent  university  president, 
such  as  the  late  Charles  W.  Eliot.  Star  athletes  make  much  better  copy 
than  the  most  distinguished  scholar,  not  even  excepting  Einstein  himself. 
When  Fortune  made  its  notable  survey  of  the  University  of  Chicago,  it 
stressed  as  an  amazing  fact  the  allegation  that  the  students  were  more 
interested  in  scholarly  controversies  than  in  the  standing  of  their  football 
team.  This  was  held  to  be  almost  unique  in  American  higher  education. 
Unfortunately,  the  editors  of  Fortune  were  probably  correct.  Finally, 
the  status  of  colleges  is  determined  quite  as  much  by  their  athletic 
achievements  as  by  the  distinction  and  scholarly  products  of  their  faculty. 

College  students  are  generally  thrilled  more  by  athletic  victories  than 
by  any  other  events  that  take  place  on  our  college  campuses.  Good 


762  EDUCATION    IN   THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS 

athletes  are  the  heroes  of  every  campus.  Scouts  visit  high  schools  and 
preparatory  schools  and  urge  promising  young  athletes  to  enroll  in  a 
particular  college.  Many  of  these  athletes  are  paid,  directly  or  indi- 
rectly, for  their  athletic  services  to  the  alma  mater.  Pressure  is  often 
applied  to  professors  to  see  to  it  that  indispensable  athletes  are  not 
handicapped  because  of  shortcomings  in  scholarship.  Athletic  coaches 
are  frequently  paid  more  than  college  deans,  and  occasionally  more 
than  college  presidents.  Their  lyrical  pronouncements  are  received  by 
the  public  with  greater  attention  and  respect  than  the  solemn  admonish- 
ments of  deans  and  presidents. 

Another  detrimental  effect  of  highly  organized  athletics  is  that  little 
or  no  attention  is  given  to  organized  play  for  the  majority  of  college 
students.  Instead  of  organized  competitive  games  for  the  majority  of 
.students,  we  have  only  the  punitive  compulsory  courses  given  by  athletic 
instructors  in  the  gymnasiums,  which  most  students  find  quite  intolerable. 
This  sacrifice  of  organized  communal  play  in  behalf  of  quasi-professional 
(exertions  on  the  part  of  a  few  athletes  is  a  physical  and  mental  loss  to 
the  majority  of  students. 

The  income  derived  from  athletics  often  figures  prominently  in  the 
budget  of  colleges,  and  discourages  serious  criticism  of  the  abuses  con- 
nected with  athletic  activities.  Not  only  pride  and  prestige  but  also 
vested  economic  interests  are  thus  tied  up  with  intercollegiate  athletics. 
The  most  comprehensive  study  yet  made  of  American  intercollegiate 
athletics  was  the  report  of  the  Carnegie  Foundation  in  1929,  American 
College  Athletics.  The  president  of  the  Foundation,  Dr.  Henry  S, 
Pritchett,  thus  summarized  some  of  the  more  important  abuses  of  the 
system: 

Intercollegc  athletics  are  highly  competitive.  Every  college  or  university 
longs  for  a  winning  team  in  its  group.  The  coach  is  on  the  alert  to  bring  the  most 
promising  athletes  in  the  secondary  schools  to  his  college  team.  A  system  of 
recruiting  and  subsidizing  has  grown  up,  under  which  boys  are  offered  pecuniary 
and  other  inducements  to  enter  a  particular  college.  The  system  is  demoralizing 
and  corrupt,  alike  for  the  boy  who  takes  the  money  and  for  the  agent  who 
arranges  it,  and  for  the  whole  group  of  college  and  secondary  school  boys  who 
know  about  it.  ... 

For  many  games  the  strict  organization  and  the  tendency  to  commercialize 
the  sport  have  taken  the  joy  out  of  the  game.  In  football,  for  example,  great 
numbers  of  boys  do  not  play  football,  as  in  English  schools  and  colleges,  for  the 
fun  of  it.  A  few  play  intensely.  The  great  body  of  students  are  onlookers.7 

While  the  abuses  associated  with  intercollegiate  athletics  are  not  yet 
so  prevalent  in  secondary  education,  the  trend  here  is  distinctly  in  the 
direction  of  the  college  situation.  High  school  football  teams  stimulate 
more  gusto  on  the  part  of  the  student  body  than  any  form  of  scholarly 
activity  or  achievements.  Some  socially  prominent  preparatory  schools 
lay  even  more  stress  upon  their  athletic  teams  than  do  many  of  the 
lesser  colleges.  There  is  little  doubt  that  organized  athletics  today  are 


7  Cited  in  Recent  Social  Trends,  McGraw-Hill,  Vol.  I,  p,  377.  There  have  been 
some  local  and  sporadic  reforms  since  1529,  but  the  general  picture  of  intercollegiate 
athletics  remains  much  the  same. 


EDUCATION    IN   THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS  763 

a  serious  menace  to  most  forms  of  truly  earnest  intellectual  endeavor. 
In  a  generation  like  ours,  rocked  by  a  devastating  world  war,  we  should 
call  attention  to  the  disastrous  and  dangerous  aspects  of  super-patriotic 
education.8  No  doubt  the  first  World  War  received  its  mental  prepara- 
tion from  the  highly  biased  and  intensely  patriotic  instruction  in  history 
and  allied  subjects  which  was  given  in  the  schools  of  Europe  before  1914. 
This  situation  was  carefully  studied  by  Jonathan  French  Scott  in  his 
important  book,  Patriots  in  the  Making.  The  education  received  by  the 
generation  before  1914  was  designed  to  make  the  citizens  of  each  state 
highly  suspicious  of  the  motives  and  morality  of  its  neighbors.  Unfor- 
tunately, no  lesson  was  learned  from  the  disastrous  effects  of  this  mode  of 
instruction  as  demonstrated  by  the  first  World  War.  Rather,  the  situ- 
ation after  1918  became  infinitely  worse  than  it  was  before  1914.  Na- 
tionalistic bias  and  super-patriotism  are  far  more  rampant  in  the  text- 
books of  today  in  Europe  than  in  any  earlier  period.  Professor  Scott 
demonstrated  this  in  his  study  of  post-war  education,  The  Menace  of 
Nationalism  in  Education.  His  dolorous  conclusions  were  extended  and 
confirmed  by  Profevssor  Charles  E.  Merriam,  in  his  Making  of  Citizens, 
which  summarized  the  results  of  an  elaborate  series  of  studies  of  patriotic 
education  in  the  contemporary  world.  With  the  growth  of  Fascism,  the 
situation  became  much  worse  than  before  1920.  Patriotism  has  literally 
been  elevated  to  the  rank  of  a  religion;  indeed,  it  is  the  major  religion  of 
Fascist  countries.  Russian  Communism  is  theoretically  international  in 
its  outlook,"  but  Stalin's  policy  of  "socialism  in  a  single  state,"  combined 
with  threats  of  a  Fascist  attack,  developed  an  intensely  nationalistic  and 
patriotic  tendency  in  Russian  education.  The  United  States  has  been 
far  better  off  in  these  respects  than  the  European  countries,  but,  as 
Bessie  L.  Pierce  and  others  have  amply  demonstrated,  much  remains  to 
be  done  in  our  own  country  to  put  our  instruction  in  history  and  the  social 
studies  on  an  impartial  basis  and  to  provide  an  objective  outlook  upon 
world  affairs.  The  defense  program  and  the  war  intensified  the  national- 
istic trend  in  our  own  education  and  textbooks.  Reactionaries  took  ad- 
vantage of  this  situation  to  start  a  drive  on  liberal  textbooks,  even  those 
of  liberal  interventionists  like  Harold  Rugg.  The  National  Association 
of  Manufacturers  started  an  investigation  of  school  textbooks  early  in 
1941,  but  it  was  at  least  temporarily  shamed  out  of  existence  by  the 
adroitness  of  Professor  Clyde  R.  Miller  and  others. 

Some  Aspects  of  a   Rational   System  of  Education 

Let  us  now  outline  briefly,  and  necessarily  quite  incompletely,  the 
essentials  of  a  rational  system  of  education  compatible  with  the  knowl- 
edge and  needs  of  our  day.9 

In  the  first  place,  we  should  make  a  thorough  use  of  the  most  reliable 


8  See  above,  pp.  219-221,  330-332. 

9  The  writer  has  made  no  attempt  here  to  include  comments  on  sex  education. 
He  has  dealt  with  this  subject  in  V.  F.  Calverton  and  S.  D.  Schmalhausen,  The 
New  Generation,  Macaulay,  1930,  pp.  632-672. 


764  EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

intelligence  tests  in  order  to  determine  the  type  of  education  to  which  the 
various  elements  in  the  population  should  logically  aspire.  The  tests 
should  be  concerned  not  only  with  such  things  as  vocational  guidance,  but 
also  with  the  degree  and  type  of  education  that  should  be  provided  for 
the  intellectual  groups  and  levels  disclosed  as  a  result  of  such  mental  tests. 
Those  with  a  low  intelligence  quotient  should  never  be  encouraged  to  go 
ahead  with  a  general  education  in  literature,  science,  and  the  arts,  but 
should  at  once  be  put  in  institutions  where  they  may  be  effectively  in- 
structed in  the  rudiments  of  their  native  language,  in  the  elements  of 
arithmetic  and  its  everyday  applications,  and  in  such  types  of  vocational 
training  as  will  enable  them  to  learn  a  particular  trade  and  maintain  a 
self-sustaining  existence  in  society. 

A  frank  recognition  of  the  fact  that  a  large  proportion  of  the  population 
can  profit  only  by  education  of  this  sort  would  help  to  solve  our  social 
problems  and  reduce  the  unnecessary  burdens  and  wastes  in  our  educa- 
tional system.  It  is  far  better  to  train  the  mentally  retarded  children  of 
America  to  make  a  decent  living,  though  they  never  hear  of  Browning  or 
Shakespeare.  Our  present  policy  is  to  burden  the  schools  with  a  horde 
whose  vocational  training  we  ignore,  in  a  vain  effort  to  make  them  appre- 
ciate the  finest  gems  of  art  and  literature.  Upon  the  completion  of  their 
"education"  they  are  unfitted  for  a  trade,  and,  instead  of  settling  down  to 
Milton  of  an  evening,  they  confine  their  literary  investigations  to  the 
daily  paper  or  the  pulp  magazines.  They,  likewise,  devote  their  artistic 
appreciation  to  an  intensive  observation  of  Mickey  Mouse*  or  Donald 
Duck  in  the  movies,  or  of  the  touching  photographs  in  the  movie  maga- 
zines and  the  illustrated  weeklies  and  monthlies. 

Having  sanely  provided  for  this  class,  which  has  no  real  place  in  the 
type  of  education  designed  to  carry  the  students  through  the  colleges,  we 
could  deal  more  effectively  with  those  who  are  intellectually  capable  of 
attaining  to,  and  profiting  by,  an  education  in  the  arts,  sciences,  and 
higher  technology. 

Once  a  rational  sorting  out  of  pupils,  according  to  mental  capacity  and 
vocational  aptitudes,  has  been  accomplished  and  the  appropriate  form 
of  education  prescribed  for  each  type,  we  shall  have  advanced  far  toward 
creating  a  rational  educational  program. 

Elementary  and  grammar-school  instruction  would  be  differentiated 
to  meet  the  needs  of  two  main  groups:  (1)  those  for  whom  manual  train- 
ing and  the  industrial  arts  are  most  relevant,  and  (2)  those  for  whom  a 
literary  education  is  justified  and  who  may  legitimately  aspire  to  go  on 
through  high  school  and  college. 

With  respect  to  the  first  group,  education  should  be  brought  more 
closely  into  relationship  with  everyday  life  situations  and  problems. 
The  formalities  and  abstractions  of  education  should  be  reduced  to  a 
minimum.  Elementary  instruction  in  the  social  sciences  must  surely  be 
provided,  for  under  a  democracy  these  pupils  will  ultimately  have  the 
same  public  responsibilities  as  the  mentally  more  talented  groups.  When 
we  come  to  the  education  of  the  latter,  far  more  attention  should  be 


EDUCATION    IN  THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS  765 

given  to  the  social  studies,  beginning  in  the  very  early  grades.  Here 
also  should  begin  the  study  of  the  foreign  languages,  so  that  we  may 
put  an  end  to  the  travesty  of  finding  mature  college  students  wrestling 
with  the  elements  of  French,  Spanish,  and  German  grammar. 

A  further  development  of  the  junior  high  school  will  make  it  possible 
to  take  care  of  a  great  deal  of  the  instruction  now  given  in  the  senior 
high  school.  Most  of  the  formal  and  disciplinary  subjects  should  be 
cleared  away  during  the  junior  high  school  course.  Rhetoric,  elementary 
mathematics,  and  all  formal  linguistic  studies  should  be  mastered  by  the 
student  by  the  time  he  enters  the  senior  high  school.  There  should  also 
be  plenty  of  opportunity  for  further  work  in  the  social  studies.  Certain 
junior  high  schools  would,  of  course,  specialize  almost  entirely  in  voca- 
tional training  and  the  industrial  arts,  though  continuing  essential  work 
in  the  social  studies. 

The  senior  high  school  should  be  free  from  most  of  the  academic  rub- 
bish which  occupies  the  attention  of  pupils  in  this  institution  today.  A 
rational  use  of  the  pupil's  time  before  the  senior  high  school  would  easily 
make  this  possible.  The  whole  curriculum  of  the  high  school  should  be 
reconstructed  to  prepare  the  student  for  life  rather  than  for  entrance 
into  college  later  on.  The  colleges  must  have  students,  and  they  would 
readily  accept  high  school  graduates  who  have  had  a  realistic  education, 
if  the  high  school  authorities  would  only  rebel  against  the  tyranny  of 
the  conventional  college  board  examinations.  Our  senior  high  school  cur- 
riculum should  be  reorganized  around  four  major  divisions:  natural  sci- 
ence, industrial  arts,  the  social  studies,  and  aesthetics.  The  industrial 
arts  course  should  be  broadened  to  include  essential  commercial  studies. 
Most  high  school  students  will  not  go  further  in  their  educational 
career.  Hence  they  should  be  prepared  in  this  institution  for  a  successful 
personal  and  social  life.  If  we  wish  to  keep  our  high  school  graduates 
out  of  the  crime  and  vice  which  unemployment  and  loafing  stimulate,  we 
must  prepare  them  for  some  sort  of  remunerative  career  before  they 
graduate.  If  necessary,  the  course  could  be  lengthened  to  five  years. 
But  a  rational  planning  of  the  pre-high  school  period  in  education  would 
make  it  possible  to  work  wonders,  even  with  a  four-year  senior  high  school 
course.  Such  a  plan  as  we  have  outlined  here  would  provide  the  high 
school  graduate  with  a  better  and  more  advanced  education  than  is  pos- 
sessed today  by  the  graduate  of  a  junior  college.  If  we  keep  the  junior 
college  and  expand  its  use,  the  more  advanced  character  of  high  school 
instruction  would  permit  the  introduction  of  a  more  mature  and  useful 
type  of  junior  college  curriculum. 

We  may  now  approach  the  problem  of  higher  education,  about  which 
there  is  today  a  vast  amount  of  controversy  and  confusion.  Most  of  this 
could  be  eliminated  if  we  were  honest  enough  to  differentiate  between 
institutions  which  minister  primarily  to  the  needs  of  such  students  as 
merely  desire  to  go  to  college  and  those  which  would  meet  the  needs  of 
that  minority  of  serious  students  who  look  forward  to  college  as  a  means 
of  acquiring  a  real  education. 


766  EDUCATION    IN  THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS 

The  greater  part  of  those  who  go  to  college  today  do  so  because  it  is  the 
fashionable  thing  to  do  so.  This  tendency  should  not  be  discouraged, 
but  it  should  be  met  in  a  rational  fashion.  Institutions  for  such  students 
should  prepare  them  for  the  rough-and-tumble  game  of  life,  success  in 
which,  at  the  present  time,  rarely  depends  upon  erudition  or  high  intellec- 
tual attainments.  Indeed,  Mr.  Carlisle,  a  prominent,  banker,  once  told 
a  group  of  Princeton  students  that  the  literary  college  education  was  a 
handicap  in  business.  In  other  words,  the  factory  plant  in  higher  educa- 
tion should  frankly  be  adapted  to  the  factory  type  of  student. 

If  this  situation  were  candidly  faced,  an  educational  revolution  would 
be  achieved.  We  would  no  longer  try  to  educate  highly  capable  and 
serious  students  in  such  unwieldy  institutions.  We  would  make  over 
the  whole  curriculum  in  such  a  way  as  to  handle  the  great  mass  of  college 
students  rationally  and  efficiently.  Many  phases  of  the  indictment  of 
our  overgrown  universities  would  disappear.  Criticism  of  overatten- 
tion  to  intercollegiate  sports  and  social  diversions  would  be  beside  the 
point.  Such  activities  might  well  play  as  vital  a  role  as  does  the  academic 
subject-matter  in  the  training  of  those  who  logically  should  be  attending 
these  factory  institutions. 

After  all,  football,  motoring,  and  terpsichorean  endeavor  have  far  more 
relevance  to  the  after-college  life  of  most  students  than  have  calculus  and 
philology.  The  ability  to  adjust  a  bow-tie  to  a  wing  collar  is  more  vital 
to  the  average  male  than  higher  differential  equations  or  the  theory  of 
valency.  To  be  able  to  act  as  a  charming  hostess  at  a  sorority  party  is  a 
far  more  useful  accomplishment  to  the  average  female  student  than  a 
mastery  of  the  future  periphrastic  or  the  second  law  of  thermodynamics. 
Once  we  honestly  face  the  facts  as  to  the  type  of  guidance  that  the  ma- 
jority of  college  students  require,  we  shall  no  longer  expect  the  large 
universities  to  meet  the  needs  of  the  few  earnest  and  highly  capable  stu- 
dents. We  shall  awaken  to  the  fact  that  they  have  a  very  special  adapta- 
bility to  serving  that  great  army  of  students  who  have  produced  our 
educational  factories  through  the  sheer  pressure  of  numbers. 

In  these  large  institutions  for  the  mediocre  and  indifferent  mass,  inter- 
collegiate athletics  might  reach  a  high  stage  of  development  and  occupy 
a  considerable  part  of  the  students'  time.  Thoroughgoing  provision 
should,  however,  be  made  for  intramural  athletics,  with  universal  par- 
ticipation, in  order  to  develop  health  and  teach  the  psychological  and 
social  lessons  of  organized  play  to  all.  The  physical  health  of  students 
should  be  safeguarded  in  every  possible  way  and  candid  instruction  in 
personal  hygiene  should  constitute  an  important  element  in  the  cur- 
riculum. Training  in  the  habits  of  obedience  and  social  responsibility 
might  well  be  provided,  not  only  through  athletics,  but  also  through  other 
forms  of  drill  and  regimentation,  which  should  not,  of  course,  be  too 
extensive  or  distasteful.  In  handling  upper-classmen,  student  self-gov- 
ernment might  well  be  experimented  with,  so  that  the  graduates  will  have 
had  some  training  in  the  art  of  self-control  and  some  conception  of  the 
duties  and  responsibilities  of  democratic  citizenship. 


EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  767 

A  varied  and  extensive  social  life  would  be  desirable  in  such  institu- 
tions. Etiquette  and  social  intercourse  should  be  stressed  so  that  the 
graduates  may  be  turned  out  as  polished  ladies  and  gentlemen  in  the 
conventional  sense  of  the  term,  or  at  least  with  reasonably  passable  man- 
ners. Attention  should  also  be  paid  to  the  cultivation  of  a  not  too 
abstruse  type  of  aesthetic  interests.  In  this  way,  the  students  in  such 
institutions  could  be  helped  to  realize  how  to  dispose  of  their  leisure 
time  in  a  civilized  manner  in  later  life. 

The  academic  requirements  in  institutions  of  this  sort  would  naturally 
be  reduced  to  a  minimum,  perhaps  lower  than  that  of  the  "pass  students" 
in  the  English  colleges.  Instruction  should  be  directly  designed  to  equip 
the  student  with  a  general  knowledge  of  the  world  in  which  he  is  living, 
the  whole  purpose  being  to  provide  at  least  a  veneer  of  understanding  and 
culture,  in  the  popular  sense  of  this  term.  The  graduate  should  be  able 
to  leave  college  a  facile  and  intelligent  conversationalist.  The  method 
and  procedure  followed  in  the  recent  so-called  "outlines"  of  history,  sci- 
ence, technology,  literature,  and  art  would  seem  to  be  excellently  de- 
signed for  the  purpose  of  such  institutions.  No  attempt  should  be  made 
to  secure  intensive  education  in  any  special  field,  but  equal  care  should 
be  taken  to  guard  against  abysmal  ignorance  with  respect  to  any  major 
phase  of  modern  knowledge. 

The  courses  here  would  be  "orientation"  courses  exclusively  and  par 
excellence.  We  would  thus  avoid  the  all  too  frequent  results  of  the  con- 
ventional university  career  of  today,  namely,  the  situation  where  the 
average  college  graduate  has  never  heard  of  Willard  Gibbs,  Richard 
Wagner,  or  Rodin,  where  even  the  capable  student  may  have  heard  of 
Helmholtz  but  imagines  that  Brahms  was  a  Bohemian  chemist  and 
Pavlov  a  Russian  ballet  dancer,  or  where  another  equally  able  youth 
can  be  a  master  of  Liszt  but  hold  that  Pasteur  was  a  distinguished  Rus- 
sian historian. 

Along  with  this  initiation  into  the  culture  of  the  human  past  and  pres- 
ent, a  leading  aim  of  instruction  in  these  large  institutions  should  be  the 
cultivation  of  intellectual  urbanity  and  amiable  open-mindedness.  The 
chief  mechanisms  of  human  behavior  should  be  presented  and  the  stupidity 
of  unthinking  conservatism  and  dogmatic  bigotry  relentlessly  exposed. 

The  instruction  should,  for  the  most  part,  be  given  by  highly  capable 
and  entertaining  lecturers,  meeting  very  large  groups,  in  order  to  reduce 
the  burden  of  teaching  to  a  minimum  and  to  exploit  to  the  maximum 
marked  ability  to  provide  both  classroom  entertainment  and  enlighten- 
ment. So  far  as  possible,  surpassingly  capable  lecturers,  of  varied 
talents,  such  as  William  Lyon  Phelps,  Edward  A.  Ross,  George  E.  Vin- 
cent, Harry  Gideonse,  Lothrop  Stoddard,  Norman  Thomas,  Will  Durant, 
John  Erskine,  Harry  Overstreet,  Gene  Tunney,  and  Carlton  Hayes,  should 
be  sought  for  such  positions,  even  though  not  enough  with  the  talent  of 
the  above  named  could  be  secured.  The  lecturers  might  be  aided  to 
a  certain  extent  by  tutors,  who  would  act  as  special  guides  to  that 
minority  of  students  who  might  desire  something  beyond  the  minimum 


768  EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

of  requirements.  Few  examinations  would  need  to  be  given  but  at- 
tendance at  all  class  exercises  should  be  compulsory.  Every  effort  would 
be  made  to  make  the  instruction  and  college  life  highly  interesting. 

The  professors  in  such  institutions,  aside  from  the  few  competent  and 
facile  lecturers  who  would  be  required  for  the  practical  instruction,  might 
well  be  research  professors  whose  scientific  activities  would  be  supported 
in  princely  fashion  by  the  tuition  which  might  legitimately  be  required 
of  students  in  this  class  of  institutions.  We  would  realize  in  this  way  an 
almost  ideal  situation,  namely,  one  in  which  an  institution  made  up  of 
students  who  do  not  desire  to  be  taught  will  be  manned  in  part  by  pro- 
fessors who  prefer  not  to  teach. 

Some  might  ask  why  we  insist  upon  having  these  research  professors 
engaged  in  their  investigations  on  the  campuses  of  the  institutions  which 
are  not  devoted  to  rigorous  intellectual  endeavor.  Why  not  take  a  part 
of  the  revenue  derived  from  these  institutions  to  support  great  scientific 
laboratories,  entirely  apart  from  these  enterprises  that  are  designed 
merely  to  promote  self-control,  a  veneer  of  cultural  appreciation,  and 
intellectual  urbanity  among  the  hordes  of  mediocre  and  indifferent  col- 
legians of  today? 

The  writer  by  no  means  presses  this  point,  but  it  would  seem  to  him 
that  it  has  a  special  advantage.  To  have  accessible  on  the  campus  build- 
ings which  would  house  alert  and  active  scientists,  experimental  tech- 
nologists, productive  investigators  in  the  social  sciences,  and  creative 
artists  in  various  lines,  and  could  exhibit  the  products  of  their  work,  would 
be  of  a  high  potential  educational  significance.  They  might  have  in 
each  institution  somewhat  the  same  function  that  the  Museum  of  Natural 
History,  the  New  York  Public  Library,  the  New  School  for  Social  Re- 
search and  the  Metropolitan  Museum  of  Art  have  in  New  York  City. 
Students  might,  from  time  to  time,  be  taken  on  excursions  into  these 
buildings  and  come  to  have  a  first-hand  consciousness  of  the  exist- 
ence of  such  centers  of  human  activity  and  begin  to  realize  what  scientific 
experimentation,  productive  scholarship,  and  creative  artistic  endeavor 
actually  mean. 

It  will,  of  course,  go  without  saying  that,  in  case  certain  students  who 
originally  enrolled  without  any  deep  interest  in  education  become  stirred 
to  intellectual  endeavor  during  their  period  of  residence,  provision  should 
be  made  for  transferring  them  to  the  institutions  for  serious  higher  educa- 
tion which  are  shortly  to  be  described.  As  to  the  time  essential  for  the 
completion  of  the  work  in  these  "civilizing  institutions,"  it  may  probably 
be  maintained  that  two,  or  at  most,  three  years  would  be  wholly  adequate. 
In  this  way  the  problems  of  both  a  realistic  junior  college  and  of  factory 
education  would  be  rationally  solved  by  a  single  set  of  institutions. 

The  years  saved  from  the  four-year  course  of  today  could  then  be  used 
for  specialized  training  in  schools  of  engineering,  business  administration, 
domestic  science,  applied  arts,  and  the  like.  As  a  result,  after  four  years, 
these  young  people  would  not  only  be  civilized  but  prepared  for  work  and 
marriage.  At  the  present  time,  the  college  graduate  is  rarely  a  polished 


EDUCATION    IN  THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS  769 

person  or  one  prepared  to  take  up  either  professional  or  conjugal  responsi- 
bility. 

To  many  such  a  scheme  as  this  outlined  above  may  suggest  that  the 
author  has  not  been  duly  serious  and  sets  forth  the  proposition  in  a  quasi- 
humorous  vein,  but  he  may  assure  his  readers  that  such  is  not  the  case 
and  that  the  proposal  is  meant  very  literally  and  offered  in  all  serious- 
ness.10 He  would  further  challenge  anyone  to  demonstrate  that  such  a 
system  would  not  produce  better  preparation  for  the  general  run  of  situa- 
tions encountered  by  the  majority  of  our  present-day  college  graduates 
than  does  the  college  of  today.  It  implies  a  recognition,  at  the  outset,  of 
what  the  average  college  man  and  woman  is  going  to  do  and  be  in 
life,  and  a  firm  resolution  to  train  them  for  such  a  status  if  nothing 
more.  If  we  adhered  to  the  program  outlined  above,  the  factory  system 
in  education  could  be  made  to  do  well  in  the  one  function  which  it  can 
actually  execute  with  any  efficiency  or  propriety.  Colleges  would  cease 
to  be  the  failure  that  they  are  today  with  respect  to  either  civilizing  or 
educating  their  students.11  College  graduates  might  then  at  least  be 
urbane  and  cultivated  ladies  and  gentlemen,  even  if  they  were  not 
scholars. 

It  is  frequently  objected  that  these  great  civilizing  institutions  would 
be  regarded  with  suspicion  or  contempt  and  that  it  would  be  considered 
a  disgrace  to  attend  them.  Such  is  not  tlie  case.  They  would  be  the 
Yales  and  Princetons  of  the  future,  socially  more  respectable  and  more 
eagerly  sought  after  than  the  truly  educational  colleges  to  be  described 
below.  Though  they  might  actually  be  civilizing  mills,  they  would  not  be 
formally  so  designated.  Rather,  they  would  be  christened  in  a  properly 
impressive  manner  and  would  carry  appropriate  social  prestige.  They 
would,  of  course,  be  open  to  both  the  well-to-do  and  the  poor,  as  are  our 
great  private  and  state  universities  of  today. 

Turning  to  the  second  set  of  institutions — small  colleges  designed  for 
that  minority  of  students  who  really  want  an  education — we  should  pro- 
vide a  quite  different  curriculum  and  intellectual  atmosphere. 

In  the  first  place,  such  institutions  should  be  manned  exclusively  by 
professors  who  desire  to  teach  and  promote  learning  and  are  able  to  do  so, 
their  tenure  and  promotion  depending  upon  their  capacity  to  provide 
substantial  instruction  and  effective  intellectual  stimulation.  We  would 
thus  eliminate  from  such  institutions:  (1)  those  who  try  to  teach  because 
they  know  of  nothing  else  which  they  can  or  want  to  do,  and  (2)  those 
who  regard  affiliation  with  the  teaching  profession  as  the  easiest  method 
whereby  they  can  face  the  landlord,  the  grocer,  and  the  tailor  with  assur- 
ance and  complacency.  The  class  of  professors  who  enter  education 
chiefly  for  the  purpose  of  writing  and  research  would,  as  we  have  already 


10  Since  the  author  first  set  forth  this  suggestion  in  Current  History  some  years 
back,  a  similar  plan  has  been  recommended  by  Dean  Charles  M.  McConn  of  Lehigh 
and  New  York  Universities,  and  Professor  David  Snedden  of  Columbia  University. 

11  For  devastating  material  on  the  futility  of  the  present  liberal  college  education, 
see  Harvey  Smith,   The  Gang's  All  Here,  Princeton  University  Press,  1941;   and 
J.  R.  Tunis,  Was  College  Worth  While?  Harcourt,  Brace,  1936. 


770  EDUCATION    IN   THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS 

seen,  be  taken  care  of  by  the  rich  and  numerous  institutions  supported  by 
the  attendance  of  those  who  merely  go  to  college. 

Professors  in  the  second  class  of  institutions  would  be  allowed  to  write 
or  carry  on  research,  but  should  not  be  compelled  to  do  so  on  a  large  scale 
to  maintain  their  status  and  tenure.  Their  rank  and  reward  should  de- 
pend upon  their  ability  to  teach  and  to  impart  intellectual  enthusiasm. 
Men  like  William  Graham  Sumner,  Albion  W.  Small,  Frederick  Jackson 
Turner,  Herbert  Joseph  Davenport,  George  Lincoln  Burr,  Ferdinand 
Schevill,  James  Harvey  Robinson,  Charles  H.  Haskins,  Charles  Austin 
Beard,  Alexander  Meiklejohn,  Morris  Cohen,  Max  Otto,  Benjamin 
Kendrick,  and  others,  would  immediately  come  to  mind  as  the  sort  of 
teachers  desirable  in  institutions  of  this  type.  If  it  is  asked  where  we 
are  to  find  such  teachers,  it  may  be  answered  that  there  are  plenty  of 
them  available  but,  as  Professor  Ise  points  out  later  on,  it  is  hard  for 
them  to  get  a  post  in  a  college  or  university  today. 

Besides  stimulating  lecturers  and  leaders  of  discussion,  the  tutorial 
system  should  be  used  to  guide  intellectual  enthusiasm  in  a  scientific 
manner — but  not  as  a  special  means  of  policing  and  bulldozing  reluctant 
youths  whose  thoughts  gravitate  more  towards  the  saxophone  or  the  goal 
posts  than  towards  Einstein  or  John  Dewey.  Provision  should  be  made 
through  scholarships  and  fellowships  for  students  of  superior  intelligence 
and  intellectual  earnestness  who  are  unable  to  enjoy  a  college  education 
at  their  own  expense.  In  case  any  students  start  out  with  serious  inten- 
tions, but  later  decide  that  they  would  rather  become  civilized  extraverts 
in  one  of  the  mass-production  colleges,  they  could  readily  be  transferred 
to  such  an  institution  of  their  choice. 

Recognizing  that  these  institutions  for  the  minority  who  desire  an  edu- 
cation represent  the  only  place  in  which  it  is  worth  while  to  work  out  a 
complete  curriculum  for  an  exacting  scheme  of  higher  education,  we  may 
now  briefly  summarize  what  appears  to  the  present  writer  to  be  the  essen- 
tials of  such  a  program. 

In  the  first  place,  there  should  be  adequate  provision  in  the  pre-college 
years  for  a  complete  mastery  of  that  indispensable  tool  of  all  learning: 
namely,  language.  A  college  student  should  be  at  least  tolerably  ac- 
quainted with  the  language  of  his  own  country,  and  thoroughly  able  to 
read  at  least  two  other  important  modern  languages.  If  our  present 
elementary,  grammar,  and  high  schools  were  cleared  of  the  debris  of 
relatively  worthless  subject-matter,  there  would  be  no  difficulty  what- 
ever in  making  every  prospective  college  student  a  master  of  the  linguistic 
machinery  of  learning  before  he  sets  foot  in  college.  This  would  mean 
that  language  courses  would  practically  disappear  from  institutions  of 
higher  learning,  except  for  those  highly  specialized  courses  providing 
instruction  in  the  ancient  or  oriental  languages,  indispensable  for  cer- 
tain types  of  research  in  ancient  culture  and  for  economic  and  com- 
mercial enterprise  in  oversea  areas  today. 

The  first  or  basic  stage  of  a  rational  curriculum  would  be  devoted  to 
informing  the  students  with  respect  to  the  nature  of  the  material  world, 
from  the  cosmos  to  the  atom,  by  the  most  direct  and  efficient  method 


EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  771 

conceivable.  No  student  would  be  graduated  who  was  not  reasonably 
conversant  with  the  outstanding  discoveries  of  modern  science  with  re- 
spect to  the  material  universe  in  which  we  are  situated. 

Next,  we  should  insist  upon  the  acquisition  of  a  thorough  knowledge 
of  the  nature  and  requirements  of  man  as  the  highest  form  of  animal  life 
on  the  planet  and  as  a  member  of  social  groups.  This  would  entail  a  rea- 
sonable mastery  of  the  outstanding  contributions  of  anthropogeography, 
comparative  biology,  physiology,  psychology,  anthropology,  and  soci- 
ology. 

Having  acquired  a  knowledge  of  the  world  and  of  man,  one  would 
pass  on  to  instruction  as  to  how  to  exploit  the  material  world  so  as  to 
promote  the  happiness  and  prosperity  of  mankind.  This  would  require, 
at  the  outset,  a  thorough  acquaintance  with  the  contributions  of  modern 
technology.  In  other  words,  no  man  can  be  regarded  as  educated  who  is 
not  informed  with  respect  to  the  status  of  material  culture  and  the  devel- 
opments through  which  it  has  passed  to  attain  its  present  level.  Then, 
the  social  sciences  should  be  cultivated,  in  order  that  students  may  learn 
how  our  institutional  life  might  be  brought  up  to  something  like  the  same 
order  of  achievement  which  has  been  reached  in  technology  and  science. 
The  outstanding  problem  of  contemporary  civilization  is  to  bring  our  in- 
stitutional life  into  closer  harmony  with  the  requirements  of  our  existing 
material  culture.  Unless  we  are  successful  in  so  doing,  there  is  little 
probability  that  humanity  will  succeed  in  coping  with  the  complexities 
produced  by  modern  mechanical  civilization.  If  this  be  the  case,  then 
more  emphasis  should  be  laid  upon  the  social  sciences  than  upon  any 
other  aspect  of  contemporary  education. 

Next  in  importance  to  learning  the  nature  of  man  and  the  procedure 
involved  in  the  exploitation  of  the  material  world  through  the  cooperation 
of  technology  and  social  science,  is  comprehensive  instruction  in  the  field 
of  aesthetics.  After  all,  a  civilization  rendered  prosperous  through  a 
remarkable  technology  and  efficient  social  institutions  would,  neverthe- 
less, to  use  Plato's  phrase,  remain  essentially  "a  city  of  pigs."  Therefore, 
greater  attention  should  be  given  to  the  aesthetic  aspects  of  human  en- 
lightenment, thus  creating  a  "supra-pig"  culture.12  And  in  this  depart- 
ment of  aesthetics  should  be  placed  not  merely  plastic  and  chromatic  art 
and  music,  but  also  literature,  which  is  usually  associated  with  punitive 
linguistic  studies  and  philology.  This  generalized  curriculum  in  no  way 
precludes  specialization.  Indeed,  it  is  the  best  basis  for  later  specializa- 
tion. Leaders  in  the  professional  groups  would  naturally  be  recruited 
from  graduates  of  these  institutions  of  learning  who  had  been  trained  in 
rigorous  professional  schools  after  graduation. 

While  regarding  Dean  Alexander  Meikle John's  now  lamentably  aban- 
doned experimental  college  at  the  University  of  Wisconsin  as  far  more 
promising  than  the  conventional  institution,  yet  we  hold  that  the  sequence 
outlined  above  is  more  rational  and  comprehensive  than  his  proposal  to 


12  See  below,  pp.  795-797,  827  ff. 


772  EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

devote  the  first  two  years  to  a  study  of  Hellenic  civilization  and  of  the 
Industrial  Revolution  and  its  effects,  and  then  to  pass  the  students  along 
to  complete  their  upper-class  years  in  the  conventional  curriculum. 

As  the  dominating  psychology  of  these  institutions  of  learning,  we 
should  recognize  that  an  active  interest  on  the  part  of  the  student  is  the- 
key  to  any  degree  of  success  in  educational  enterprise.  Everything  pos- 
sible should  be  done  to  make  the  educational  process  a  spontaneous  and 
pleasant  affair,  entered  into  with  enthusiasm  by  both  student  and  teacher. 
Inasmuch  as  students  in  these  educational  institutions  would  be  there 
primarily  for  the  purpose  of  learning,  it  would  not  be  necessary  to  goad 
them  to  perfunctory  and  sporadic  cerebral  activity  by  periodic  examina- 
tions. General  examinations  at  the  end  of  courses  and  a  comprehensive 
final  examination  at  the  end  of  the  four  years  of  college  would  be  ader 
quate.  In  this  way  the  examination  bogey,  a  nuisance  and  an  irritation 
to  the  real  teacher  and  the  good  student  alike,  would  be  reduced,  while 
retaining  whatever  good  features  it  may  possess.  The  plan  introduced 
at  the  University  of  Chicago  by  President  Robert  M.  Hutchins  has  been 
the  most  notable  achievement  along  this  line.  Here  the  specific  residence 
requirement  for  granting  a  bachelor's  degree  has  been  replaced  by  a 
comprehensive  general  examination.  At  any  time  during  his  college 
career  a  student  may  apply  for  admission  to  the  examination.  If  he 
satisfactorily  passes  the  examination,  he  is  awarded  his  degree.  This 
new  program,  besides  doing  away  with  the  conventional  examination 
bogey,  repudiates  the  custodial  function  for  institutions  of  higher  learn- 
ing.124 

Education  and  Social  Change 

If  we  hope  to  bridge  the  alarming  gulf  between  our  institutions  and 
our  thinking,  we  must  prepare  to  face  the  necessity  of  very  extensive  so- 
cial change.  Our  ideas  and  institutions  must  be  brought  up  to  some- 
thing like  the  same  level  of  intelligence  and  efficiency  that  we  have 
already  attained  in  the  scientific  and  mechanical  realms. 

There  are  two  possible  methods  of  social  change.  One  is  orderly  and 
gradual  change.  The  other  is  that  violent  change  which  we  call  revolu- 
tion, based  upon  exasperation  and  desperation,  motivated  by  hatred  and 
oppression,  and  all  too  often  guided  by  deep  emotions  rather  than  by  in- 
formed intelligence.18  So  far,  it  must  be  admitted,  the  powers  in  control 


12a  This  admirable  administrative  reform  introduced  by  President  Hutchins  should 
not  be  confused  with  his  reactionary  and  quasimedieval  educational  philosophy. 
President  Hutchins  is  a  paradoxical  case.  He  is  a  stalwart  social,  economic,  and 
political  progressive,  and  one  of  the  most  courageous  defenders  of  academic  free- 
dom. Moreover,  he  is  a  radical  in  administrative  reforms  in  education.  On  the 
other  hand,  under  the  influence  of  Mortimer  Adler,  Scott  Buchanan,  and  others,  he 
has  evolved  a  philosophy  of  education  which  comes  dangerously  near  to  medieval 
Scholasticism.  On  this  see  the  articles  by  John  Dewey  in  The  Social  Frontier, 
January  and  March,  1937. 

18  See  A.  E.  Osborne,  An  Alternative  for  War  and  Revolution,  Educational 
Screen,  Inc.,  1939. 


EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  773 

of  society  have  never  surrendered  to  change  without  either  violence  or 
collapse.  In  some  cases,  as  in  the  western  Roman  Empire,  they  have 
held  on  until  the  bottom  of  the  system  dropped  right  out  from  under 
them.  In  others,  like  the  French  Revolution,  they  have  resisted  change 
until  the  revolutionary  mob  unseated  and  destroyed  them.  Some  claim 
that,  in  England  and  the  United  States,  we  have  witnessed  the  change 
from  one  social  system  to  another  by  gradual  and  peaceful  methods.  But 
this  is  not  historically  true.  In  both  countries  the  social  system  under 
which  the  people  now  live  was  based  on  revolution — the  revolutions  of 
1645-1669  and  168S-1689  in  England,  and  that  of  1775-1783  in  the 
United  States.  The  present  capitalistic  and  nationalistic  social  system 
has  been  supplanted  in  but  one  place — Russia — and  that  change  was 
effected  by  revolution.  Even  the  less  sweeping  changes  in  Italy  and 
Germany  were  accomplished  by  violence  and  war.  Hence  the  verdict  of 
history  would  seem  to  indicate  that  we  are  altogether  too  likely  to  have 
to  depend  upon  revolution  for  social  change  of  an  important  and  far- 
reaching  character.  The  opposition  of  the  vested  interests  to  the  mild 
reform  measures  of  President  Roosevelt  would  seem  to  add  further  con- 
firmation to  this  thesis. 

However,  an  able  and  wise  social  philosopher,  Lester  F.  Ward,  was 
wont  to  emphasize  that  social  development  in  the  past  had  to  be  spon- 
taneous, and,  all  too  often,  violent,  because  we  had  no  definite  conception 
of  progress  and  no  body  of  information  adequate  to  guide  social  change  in 
competent  fashion.  The  situation  has  now  changed.  We  have  wide 
knowledge  of  the  advances  of  mankind  in  the  past.  The  social  sciences 
provide  a  body  of  new  and  cogent  information,  the  chief  justification  and 
relevance  of  which  lie  in  its  service  to  the  scientific  ordering  of  social 
change.  We  may  bring  about  social  change  in  an  orderly  and  beneficial 
manner  today,  if  we  can  only  secure  popular  support  for  such  a  program. 
The  chief  obstacle  lies  in  the  fact  that  organized  education  has,  thus  far, 
tended  to  inculcate  information  and  attitudes  which  resist  social  change 
and  has  accorded  too  little  attention  and  respect  to  the  social  sciences. 

We  can  hope  to  modernize  our  social  ideas  and  institutions  only  by  an 
extension  and  improvement  of  the  social  studies.  The  responsibility  of 
education  to  society  should  boil  down  to  three  major  phases  of  educa- 
tional activity:  (1)  a  discriminating  conservation  of  the  social  heritage; 
(2)  fearless  social  criticism;  and  (3)  resolute  and  informed  social  plan- 
ning. 

It  is  as  important  as  ever  that  education  should  transmit  the  heritage 
of  the  past.  Without  this  knowledge,  especially  the  knowledge  required 
to  operate  our  present  technology  and  social  system,  man  would  be  help- 
less. But  there  is  no  longer  any  reason  why  we  should  uncritically  accept 
the  total  social  heritage.  Our  past  tendency  to  do  this  has  created  the 
social  crisis  of  our  day.  We  must  sift  the  social  heritage  through  in- 
formed analytical  examination.  We  must  eliminate  from  it  those  ob- 
structive antiques  which  are  obviously  the  product  of  past  ignorance, 
superstition,  and  dogma. 


774  EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

In  sifting  the  social  heritage  and  in  the  creation  of  a  mental  attitude 
favorable  to  this  process,  historical  studies  can  make  the  most  potent 
contribution.  The  possible  service  of  historical  insight  to  social  better- 
ment was  clearly  shown  by  James  Harvey  Robinson.  His  work,  in  this 
respect,  may  be  regarded  as  one  of  the  outstanding  contributions  of  the 
twentieth  century  to  constructive  educational  doctrine.  Certainly,  noth- 
ing is  more  urgently  needed  than  the  capacity  to  face  the  past  with  dis- 
criminating appreciation,  free  alike  from  both  reverence  and  cynical  in- 
difference. No  other  study,  save  history,  assumes  any  direct  responsi- 
bility for  bringing  about  such  a  state  of  mind.  This  creation  of  an 
intelligent  attitude  toward  the  past  is  indispensable  as  the  preparation 
for  the  second  major  function  of  education,  viewed  as  an  instrument  of 
social  progress,  namely,  an  appraisal  of  the  existing  social  order.  We 
cannot  approach  the  present  structure  of  society  with  any  degree  of 
objectivity  unless  we  can  view  its  origins  with  tolerant  understanding. 
Likewise,  we  cannot  be  interested  in  working  for  a  better  social  future 
until  we  arc  clearly  aware  of  the  weaknesses  and  inadequacies  of  the 
social  order  in  which  we  live. 

After  history  has  provided  a  discriminating  appraisal  of  the  past,  the 
other  social  studies  must  supply  us  with  the  means  of  critically  assessing 
the  social  structures  of  our  own  time.  First  they  must  describe,  realisti- 
cally and  completely,  every  aspect  of  the  society  in  which  we  move.  If 
this  job  is  well  done,  the  critical  function  of  the  social  studies  will  emerge 
naturally  and  inevitably.  Any  competent  description  of,  say,  our  social, 
economic,  and  political  institutions,  will  inevitably  reveal  their  weak- 
nesses and  failures,  as  well  as  their  strength  and  successes.  Social  criti- 
cism is,  obviously,  not  the  sole  task  or  responsibility  of  the  social  studies, 
but  it  is  certainly  an  indispensable  phase  of  their  contribution  to  the  edu- 
cational process.  Until  we  possess  a  complete  understanding  of  the  exist- 
ing social  order  we  cannot  have  any  precise  conception  of  what  is  actu- 
ally required  to  bring  about  a  better  day. 

An  immediate  responsibility  of  education  to  society,  right  now,  is, 
moreover,  the  preparation  of  a  blueprint  of  a  better  social  system  and  a 
.realistic  indication  of  how  we  may  bring  this  into  existence  in  a  gradual, 
peaceful,  and  intelligent  fashion.  We  have  already  made  it  clear  that 
human  society  is  rapidly  approaching  the  point  where  Utopia  and  chaos 
are  the  only  alternatives.  The  guidance  of  society  by  realistic  education 
appears  to  many  to  be  the  only  guarantee  that  we  could  attain  utopia. 
Certainly,  it  provides  the  only  reasonable  hope  that  this  move  can  be 
made  without  violence  and  destruction.  Education  has  a  very  definite 
self-interest  in  this  matter.  Unless  we  avoid  economic  collapse,  social 
chaos,  and  dictatorship,  organized  education  cannot  be  maintained  in  a 
state  of  dignity,  independence,  and  social  prestige.  Education  must  save 
democratic  civilization  if  it  is  to  save  itself. 

We  have  already  suggested  that  the  functions  of  realistic  education  in 
the  social  sciences  should  be  a  highly  selective  conservation  of  the  social 
heritage,  a  fair  but  resolute  criticism  of  the  social  order,  the  formulation 


EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  775 

of  a  program  for  the  improvement  of  society,  and  an  outline  of  peace- 
ful and  intelligent  methods  of  executing  this  program.  Let  us  see  how 
.well  education  is  measuring  up  to  these  major  social  responsibilities. 

Viewed  in  any  broad  way,  we  must  honestly  admit  that  education 
blindly  conserves  the  heritage  from  the  past,  without  any  important  pre- 
tense to  critical  selection,  save  in  fields  of  science  and  technology.  With 
respect  to  our  basic  institutions  and  beliefs,  our  educational  system  con- 
serves the  past  almost  as  completely  and  religiously  as  did  the  primitive 
council  of  elders  and  the  tribal  medicine  men.  Any  resolute  attempt  to 
reject  or  discard  fundamental  but  antiquated  items  in  our  cultural 
heritage  would  immediately  place  in  jeopardy  any  educational  system  or 
any  body  of  educators.  Indeed,  the  very  proposal  to  do  such  would  be 
regarded  as  rank  heresy  and  fit  subject  for  investigation  by  the  Dies 
Committee.  Even  our  most  daring  educational  reforms  are,  essentially, 
only  superficial  suggestions  for  improving  the  structure  and  administra- 
tion of  our  educational  machinery. 

There  is  also  amazingly  little  criticism  of  our  social  order,  though  such 
criticism  is  absolutely  indispensable,  if  we  are  to  discover  those  weak- 
nesses which  threaten  the  very  existence  of  free  and  orderly  society  and 
if  we  are  to  recognize  the  alterations  which  are  essential  to  preserve  civi- 
lization. We  live  in  an  age  which  has  given  unprecedented  lip-service  to 
the  necessity  and  saving  virtues  of  social  research  and  organized  investi- 
gation. We  contend  that  "facts  will  talk,"  and  we  propose  to  let  only 
facts  talk.  Tens  of  millions  of  dollars  have  been  freely  spent  in  order  to 
investigate  every  conceivable  type  of  secondary  social  problem.  Yet, 
instead  of  actually  letting  the  facts  talk,  our  investigators  have  seen  to  it 
that  disagreeable  and  challenging  facts  "pipe  down."  Such  facts  as  are 
played  up  are  all  too  often  the  conventional,  the  self-evident,  and  the 
platitudinous,  so  that  much  social  research  has  been  no  more  than  expen- 
sive and  pompous  documentation  of  the  obvious. 

Many  of  these  investigations  have  been  supported  by  funds  derived 
from  sources  which  could  not  tolerate  the  clear  formulation  of  the  mo- 
mentous conclusions  naturally  flowing  therefrom.  Most  of  our  social 
research,  therefore,  has  not  only  been  timid  in  drawing  deductions,  but 
has  been  devoted  chiefly  to  looking  into  trivialities  and  details.  It  has 
rarely  made  any  pretense  to  investigating  the  adequacy  of  our  basic  insti- 
tutions. Education  has  thus  failed  as  signally  in  its  critical  analysis  of 
our  social  order  as  it  has  in  a  discriminating  appraisal  of  the  cultural 
heritage  from  the  past. 

The  function  of  social  criticism  has  been  allowed  to  go  by  default  to 
government  investigators,  journalists,  and  free-lance  economists  and 
publicists.  One  has  only  to  mention  such  characteristic  names  as  Stuart 
Chase,  Gardiner  Means,  Abraham  Epstein,  Charles  Austin  Beard,  Her- 
bert Agar,  Lewis  Mumford,  David  Cushman  Coyle,  Ferdinand  Lundberg, 
George  Seldes,  Ernest  Sutherland  Bates,  John  Chamberlain,  John  T. 
Flynn,  and  Alfred  Bingham  to  realize  the  extent  to  which  realistic  criti- 
cism is  carried  on  outside  academic  circles.  Not  so  long  ago,  it  was  the 


776  EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

writer's  privilege  to  give  a  series  of  lectures  before  graduate  students  of 
education  in  one  of  our  foremost  schools  of  education.  He  was  surprised 
to  find  that  the  students  were  actually  thrilled  and  excited  over  informa- 
tion that  would  have  been  a  commonplace  in  their  junior  high  school 
period  if  education  were  fulfilling  its  function  in  social  criticism. 

It  follows  that  education,  having  failed  in  the  function  of  social  criti- 
cism, has  been  deficient  in  planning  for  a  more  efficient  social  order.  As 
a  matter  of  fact,  realistic  observers  must  admit  that  formal  education  has 
proved  one  of  the  greatest  obstacles  in  the  path  of  social  reform.  By 
tending  to  breed  reverence  for  the  present  social  order,  it  distinctly  and 
deliberately  loads  the  dice  in  behalf  of  cultural  tradition  and  social  stag- 
nation. It  stimulates  a  spirit  of  social  intolerance  rather  than  an  at- 
titude of  courageous  experimentation.  It  tends  to  discourage  even  the 
minimum  reforms  necessary  to  preserve  a  democratic  civilization. 

We  have  made  it  clear  that  science  and  technology  are  widening  and 
deepening  the  already  menacing  gulf  between  machines  and  institutions. 
Yet  the  prevailing  attitude  of  most  scientists  and  engineers  is  one  of  social 
quietism.  Our  scientists  tell  us  that  science  may  create  unprecedented 
material  advances  and  social  maladjustments,  but  that  it  cannot  furnish 
any  immediate,  direct,  and  authoritative  guidance  as  to  how  to  meet 
these  problems  with  expert  intelligence.  This  is  the  message  of  an  able 
president  of  the  American  Association  for  the  Advancement  of  Science, 
himself  one  of  the  outstanding  American  social  scientists.14  The  scientists 
are  quite  willing  to  assume  the  responsibility  for  "advancing  science,"  but 
they  hang  back  when  it  comes  to  "advancing  society."  They  ignore  or 
evade  the  obvious  fact  that,  unless  our  social  institutions  overtake  scien- 
tific and  technical  achievements,  all  will  go  down  together  in  a  common 
ruin  before  many  generations  have  passed.  Certainly,  if  science  can- 
not lead  the  social  procession  nothing  can.  For  those  who  wish  to  follow 
out  this  line  of  thought  I  would  commend  the  challenging  book  of  Robert 
S.  Lynd,  entitled  Knowledge  for  Whatf™  a  much  needed  and  resolute 
arraignment  of  the  quietism  and  evasive  philosophy  of  our  intellectual 
leaders  in  the  social  studies  movement. 

Organized  education  not  only  fails  to  execute  its  indispensable  function 
of  social  guidance;  its  leaders  usually  assume  an  attitude  of  hostility  to- 
ward the  few  educators  who  realize  their  social  responsibility  and  make 
even  a  faint-hearted  effort  to  do  their  duty. 

When  we  examine  the  content  of  the  teachings  of  the  so-called  subver- 
sive educators,  we  find  little  cause  for  any  alarm.  Our  educational 
sociologists  have  stolen  no  thunder  from  Stalin,  nor  even  from  Norman 
Thomas.  At  the  best,  they  are  only  giving  what  Lester  F.  Ward  said 
more  candidly  and  far  more  thoroughly  over  fifty  years  ago.  Even 
John  Dewey,  rightly  regarded  as  our  most  stimulating  and  progressive 
educational  theorist,  rarely  presumed  to  get  explicit  in  the  matter  of 


«  W.  C.  Mitchell,  "Science  and  the  State  of  Mind,"  in  Science,  January  6, 
i5  Princeton  University  Press,  1939. 


EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  777 

social  guidance  until  he  left  the  profession  of  education  for  that  of  active 
political  agitation.  When  Dewey  entered  the  political  arena  he  gave  us 
something  that* we  can  actually  bite  into.  But  not  one  out  of  ten  of 
Dewey's  ardent  pedagogical  disciples  has  the  slightest  familiarity  with 
Dewey's  doctrines,  which  he  expressed  as  a  leader  of  the  League  for 
Progressive  Political  Action  and  the  People's  Lobby. 

To  sum  up,  we  may  say  that  American  educators  face  two  very  dis- 
tinct alternatives.  They  can  arouse  themselves  to  the  social  responsi- 
bility of  education,  teach  realistically  and  courageously  those  things 
which  are  essential  to  the  preservation  of  democratic  civilization,  and 
organize  themselves  with  sufficient  coherence  to  make  sure  of  their  tenure 
while  thus  engaged.  They  may  not  succeed,  if  they  literally  shoulder  the 
current  social  responsibilities  of  education,  but  at  least  they  can  go  down 
fighting,  having  the  satisfaction  of  knowing  that  they  "kept  the  faith  and 
fought  a  good  fight." 

If  our  educators  refuse  to  take  up  the  fight  for  gradual  reform  while 
there  is  yet  time,  it  is  almost  inevitable  that  some  form  of  regimentation, 
roughly  similar  to  European  Fascism,  will  settle  down  upon  us.  Then  the 
condition  of  American  educators  will  be  unhappy  indeed.  Many  will 
lose  their  positions,  for,  under  Fascism,  education  is  a  much  more  simple 
affair  than  under  democracy.  No  such  extensive  and  diversified  per- 
sonnel is  required.  Those  who  remain  employed  will  be  parrots  in  the 
classroom,  and  professionally  a  cross  between  "kicked  dogs  and  scared 
rabbits."  And  this  condition  is  not  far  off.  The  writer  was  personally 
very  familiar  with  Germany  and  the  Germans  in  the  mid- 'twenties. 
Adolf  Hitler  was  more  inconspicuous  at  the  time  than  our  second-rate 
champions  of  Fascism.  He  was  literally  an  unknown,  when  compared 
with  our  proto-Fascists. 

In  a  forthright  article  in  The  Social  Frontier,  Professor  John  Ise  raises 
the  question  of  what  the  teachers,  especially  the  college  professors,  are 
going  to  do  about  it  all.  Are  they  doing  much  to  promote  the  fortunes 
of  the  " American  Way"?  He  doubts  if  they  are  and  does  not  see  any 
immediate  prospect  that  they  will  be,  for  some  time  to  come.  He  under- 
stands that,  for  all  practical  purposes,  it  is  the  teachers  of  the  social  sci- 
ences upon  whom  will  fall  the  brunt  of  the  burden  involved  in  putting 
education  behind  the  movement  for  social  progress.  But  it  is  nearly  im- 
possible today  to  get  courageous  and  progressive  minds  into  social-science 
professorships  and  to  keep  them  there  long  enough  to  accomplish  anything 
of  moment.  Educational  authorities  wish  to  play  safe.  They  want  to 
prevent  annoyances,  even  if  civilization  breaks  down  in  a  decade.  Pro- 
fessor Ise  goes  to  the  heart  of  the  matter  in  the  following  words : 

Most  colleges  and  universities  are  not  supremely  interested  in  securing  really 
able  men.  They  want  personality,  dress,  teaching  ability — which  may  mean 
mediocrity  to  avoid  shooting  over  the  students'  heads.  They  also  want  safe  and 
sane  economic  views;  and  not  infrequently  last  of  all — intellectual  power. 

There  are  hundreds  of  amiable  young  men  teaching  in  our  colleges  whose  judg- 
ment on  critical  problems  is  of  little  value,  while  really  brilliant  men  of  less 


778  EDUCATION    IN   THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS 

attractive  personality,  or  of  radical  views,  warm  their  toes  in  the  graduate  offices, 
hoping  for  jobs. 

Particularly  in  insisting  on  conservative  views,  colleges  narrow  their  chances  of 
securing  able  men,  for  a  rather  large  proportion  of  the  brilliant  minds  in  any 
academic  society  are  liberals  or  radicals.1511 

Adult  Education 

In  the  period  since  the  first  World  War  special  interest  has  developed 
in  adult  education.  This  has  been  due,  in  the  first  place,  to  the  fact  that 
only  recently  has  more  than  a  very  small  percentage  of  the  population 
been  able  to  take  advantage  of  senior  high  school  and  college  education. 
But  many  of  those  who  were  denied  this  privilege,  having  since  gained 
the  necessary  resources  and  leisure,  seek  instruction  in  institutions  de- 
signed to  deal  with  adults.  In  the  second  place,  so  rapidly  has  the 
character  of  information  changed  that  even  those  who  have  had  a  college 
education  may  find  their  information  out  of  date.  Therefore,  they  seek 
to  supplement  their  previous  educational  experience  through  adult  edu- 
cation. Finally,  the  social  crisis  has  become  so  immediate  that  adult 
education  seems  to  many  to  be  the  only  possible  way  in  which  education 
can  be  made  to  serve  as  our  chief  instrument  of  social  change.  The  con- 
ventional education  in  the  schools  and  colleges  is,  as  we  have  seen,  not 
very  well  adapted  to  serving  the  cause  of  social  change.  Even  if  it  were, 
we  should  probably  have  to  take  some  decisive  form  of  action  in  the  social 
crisis  before  those  now  in  school  and  college  can  grow  up  and  assume  a 
very  prominent  part  in  determining  public  policy.  Only  by  bringing 
realistic  and  cogent  education  before  adults  can  we  hope  to  put  education 
at  the  service  of  social  change  and  bring  about  the  latter  in  an  intelligent 
and  peaceful  manner.  There  are  other  justifiable  reasons  for  interest  in 
adult  education,  but  the  three  just  mentioned  are  the  outstanding  ones. 

There  are  various  types  of  adult  educational  enterprises.  First,  one 
may  mention  the  well-known  continuation  schools,  in  which  young  per- 
sons, particularly  those  working  during  the  daytime,  carry  forward  their 
educational  experience.  This  type  of  education  has  been  primarily 
vocational,  though  more  attention  has  of  late  been  given  to  cultural 
subjects.  Closely  associated  with  continuation  courses  are  those  devoted 
primarily  to  remedying  the  deficiencies  of  a  person's  education  in  earlier 
life,  and  to  bringing  his  information  thoroughly  up  to  date. 

A  prominent  and  important  form  of  adult  education  is  what  has  been 
called  functional  group  education.  The  first  conspicuous  development  of 
functional  group  education  (folk  schools)  was  introduced  among  farmers 
in  Denmark  after  the  war  of  1862.  The  social  and  economic  crisis  in 
Danish  farming  life  impelled  the  farmers  to  get  together  and  study  their 
economic  and  public  problems.  As  a  result,  an  effective  reconstruction 
of  Danish  agriculture  and  rural  culture  was  brought  about.  The  success 
of  these  folk  schools  encouraged  similar  developments  in  other  areas  in 
the  decades  following. 


"Shackles  on  Professors,"  in  Social  Frontier,  May,  1937,  p.  243. 


EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  779 

Until  the  second  World  War,  folk  Schools,  first  associated  with  the 
growth  of  the  cooperative  movement  in  Denmark  proved  the  most  popu- 
lar type  of  adult  education  in  all  the  Scandinavian  countries  and  in 
Germany.  These  schools  usually  were  resident  institutions  patronized 
by  young  men  and  women.  Their  main  purpose  was  to  familiarize  the 
students  with  historical  and  cultural  subjects  and  to  give  them  a  proper 
orientation  with  respect  to  social,  economic,  and  other  current  problems. 
They  were  devoted  solely  to  the  purpose  of  learning,  had  no  entrance 
examinations,  and  conferred  no  degrees. 

Workers'  education  has  been  the  other  outstanding  example  of  func- 
tional group  education.  More  than  a  century  ago,  Robert  Owen  in 
England  and  Thomas  Skidmore  in  the  United  States  urged  the  education 
of  the  masses.  In  the  middle  of  the  nineteenth  century,  Karl  Marx  and 
Friedrich  Engels  did  their  best  to  promote  the  education  of  workers.  The 
English  Fabian  Society,  headed  by  leading  English  intellectuals,  was 
especially  sympathetic  towards  labor  education.  University  extension 
facilities  have  been  provided  for  workers  by  institutions  of  higher  learn- 
ing which  have  taken  a  kindly  attitude  towards  labor  education.  This  has 
been  particularly  true  in  England.  Labor  colleges  have  been  established. 
Among  the  most  notable  are  Ruskin  College,  Oxford,  established  in  1899 
by  English  and  American  radicals,  and  Brookwood  Labor  College  at 
Katonah,  N.  Y.,  founded  through  the  collaboration  of  academic  radicals 
and  American  trade-unions.  In  Germany,  after  the  first  World  War,  a 
number  of  important  labor  schools  were  set  up,  the  most  famous  being 
the  Berlin  Trade  Union  School,  opened  in  1919,  and  the  Academy  of 
Labor  at  Frankfort,  established  in  1920.  The  Rand  School  of  Social 
Science,  opened  in  New  York  City  in  1906  to  promote  socialistic  educa- 
tion, has  had  an  important  influence  in  vitalizing  the  labor  movement 
in  the  United  States. 

Interest  in  adult  education  in  the  United  States  was  promoted  by  the 
Carnegie  Corporation,  which  appointed  an  advisory  committee  on  adult 
education  and  conducted  several  notable  surveys  of  the  needs  and 
facilities.  A  national  conference  on  adult  education  was  held  in  Cleve- 
land under  its  auspices  in  1925,  and  the  American  Association  for  Adult 
Education  was  then  created.  The  American  Association  for  Adult 
Education  maintains  its  headquarters  in  New  York  City  and  is  a  general 
clearing  house  and  coordinator  for  all  adult  educational  activities  in  the 
United  States.  The  outstanding  institutions  for  adult  education  in  the 
United  States  are  the  New  School  for  Social  Research,  founded  in  New 
York  City  in  1919  by  James  Harvey  Robinson,  Charles  A.  Beard, 
Thorstein  Veblen,  and  other  progressive  scholars,  and  the  People's  Insti- 
tute of  Cooper  Union  in  New  York  City,  long  directed  by  Everett  Dean 
Martin. 

The  adult  education  movement  long  suffered  a  handicap  from  the  popu- 
lar conviction  that  it  is  difficult  for  older  people  to  learn.  Edward  L. 
Thorndike,  however,  in  his  work  on  Adult  Learning,  published  in  1928, 
showed  that  the  curve  of  learning  ability  reaches  its  height  at  about  25 


780  EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

and  then  slowly  drops  until,  at  the  age  of  45,  one's  ability  to  learn  is  about 
exactly  what  it  was  at  the  age  of  18.  But  the  difference  between  the 
ability  to  learn  at  the  ages  of  25  and  45  is  so  slight  that  it  offers  no  logical 
obstacle  to  enthusiasm  for  adult  education.  The  conclusion  is  that  adults 
under  50  can  readily  learn  anything  which  they  really  want  to  learn. 
Moreover,  the  ability  to  learn  does  not  cease  until  the  individual  reaches 
a  period  of  senile  dementia.  There  are,  then,  no  important  psychological 
reasons  why  adult  education  cannot  succeed. 

There  have  been  numerous  statements  of  late  by  eminent  social  scien- 
tists and  educators  to  the  effect  that  the  social  crisis  is  so  imminent  that 
adult  education  is  absolutely  indispensable,  if  we  are  to  have  intelligent 
direction  of  social  change.  But  there  has  been  little  concentrated  effort 
to  act  on  the  basis  of  such  a  conviction.  The  only  notable  venture  has 
been  that  conducted  by  Dr.  John  W.  Studebakcr,  United  States  Com- 
missioner of  Education.  He  began  his  work  while  superintendent  of 
schools  of  Des  Moines,  Iowa,  by  conducting  a  nationally  famous  ex- 
perimental discussion  forum.  This  enterprise  demonstrated  its  success 
and  practicability.  Dr.  Studebaker  carried  over  his  enthusiasm  and 
program  as  Commissioner  of  Education,  to  which  office  he  was  appointed 
in  1934.  Making  use  of  a  federal  grant,  he  established  a  number  of 
Public  Forum  Demonstration  Centers  in  selected  states  throughout  the 
country.16  He  engaged  as  lecturers  distinguished  and  capable  scholars 
and  publicists,  and  thus  stirred  up  a  great  deal  of  intelligent  interest  in 
public  problems.  Dr.  Studebaker  has  been  motivated  primarily  by  the 
notion  that  forums  constitute  an  indispensable  type  of  training,  if  we 
are  to  salvage  democracy  and  avoid  Fascism  in  the  United  States.  The 
major  results  which  he  hopes  to  achieve  through  these  forums  have 
been  summarized  as  follows: 

Citizens  will  be  able  to  view  our  problems  from  a  national  rather  than  a  sec- 
tional point  of  view. 

They  will  be  trained  in  the  essential  equipment  of  democracy,  the  ability  to 
discuss  problems  intelligently  in  public. 

These 'forums  will  promote  tolerance  and  balance  and  will  enable  participants 
to  safeguard  themselves  against  the  "rabble-rouser." 

'  Public  meetings  in  America  will  be  enabled  to  take  on  a  more  intelligent 
atmosphere. 

Demagogues  may  be  more  effectively  checked  and  held  up  to  just  ridicule. 

A  new  enthusiasm  and  interest  in  public  affairs  may  be  engendered. 

It  is  to  be  hoped  that  this  program  of  adult  education  will  be  greatly 
extended  and  loyally  supported.  The  Fascist  propaganda  is  extremely 
powerful  and  persistent.  The  only  hope  of  maintaining  democracy  is 
to  educate  the  citizens  of  a  democracy  as  to  the  problems  and  responsi- 
bilities involved  in  democratic  government.  The  school  system  does  this 
very  imperfectly  today  and,  as  we  have  seen,  we  shall  probably  have  to 
rely  for  guidance  and  direction  in  the  social  crisis  upon  those  who  have 
already  passed  through  the  school  period.  It  is  literally  true  that  the 

16  See  J.  W.  Studebaker,  Plain  Talk,  National  Home  Library  Foundation,  1936. 


EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  781 

destinies  of  democracy  are  largely  tied  up  with  the  success  of  adult 
education  in  democratic  countries,  but  most  of  this  work  has  been  sus- 
pended or  curtailed  in  wartime. 

The  Raids  on   Education 

It  is  obvious  that  economic  depressions  and  other  serious  breakdowns 
in  our  social  and  economic  order  are  proof  of  inadequacies  in  the  educa- 
tional system.  Today,  we  have  efficient  technology  and  abundant 
natural  resources  to  produce  all  the  food  and  goods  which  are  needed  for 
a  high  standard  of  living.  The  fact  that  we  have  starvation,  misery,  a 
great  relief  problem,  and  a  second  World  War  is  obviously  the  result  of 
erroneous  ideas.  Only  through  education  can  these  be  supplanted  by 
accurate  and  up-to-date  ideas.  Therefore,  greater  expenditures  for 
education  and  the  encouragement  of  more  realistic  and  courageous  teach- 
ing are  called  for.  But  the  educational  budget  was  cut  ruthlessly  after 
the  depression  of  1929  set  in,  and  there  has  been  a  vigorous  drive  against 
the  intellectual  independence  of  teachers  almost  without  parallel  in  our 
educational  history. 

The  financial  raid  upon  American  education  since  1929  is  especially 
serious,  for  financial  support  of  education  was  inadequate  even  in  pros- 
perous days.  Reasonable  educators  have  estimated  that  a  completely 
adequate  scheme  of  public  education  in  the  United  States  would  require 
an  annual  budget  of  over  10  billion  dollars — certainly  not  an  unreasonable 
expenditure  if  we  received  from  education  the  social  contributions  which 
we  might  legitimately  expect.  Yet  even  in  our  most  prosperous  years 
the  appropriation  made  for  public  education  has  never  reached  more  than 
one  fourth  of  this  figure.  The  total  expenditures  for  public  education 
in  1930  were  $2,605,699,000,  the  all-time  high  to  date.  Hence  we  need 
not  be  surprised  at  the  report  of  the  United  States  Office  of  Education 
showing  that,  even  in  the  prosperous  days  of  1929,  there  were  over  2 
million  children  of  school  age  who  were  not  in  school  at  all.  Ten  per 
cent  of  our  children  did  not  reach  the  sixth  grade;  over  14  per  cent  did 
not  reach  the  seventh  grade;  over  25  per  cent  did  not  reach  the  eighth 
grade ;  45  per  cent  did  not  reach  high  school ;  and  90  per  cent  did  not  have 
the  opportunity  to  attend  college.  These  facts  are  certainly  not  in 
harmony  with  the  ordinary  assumptions  of  adequate  free  public  instruc- 
tion in  a  democratic  society.  Moreover,  from  the  same  source  we  learn 
that  approximately  one  fifth  of  all  school  children  were  suffering  from 
starvation,  malnutrition,  and  inadequate  medical  care.  Only  when  we 
understand  this  situation  with  respect  to  education  in  prosperous  days 
can  we  comprehend  the  serious  implications  of  the  contraction  of  financial 
support  of  education  since  the  depression  fell  upon  us. 

Total  expenditures  for  public  education  fell  from  $2,605,699,000  in 
1930  to  $1,940,133,000  in  1934.  Farming  communities  became  so  im- 
poverished that  they  literally  found  it  almost  impossible  to  provide 
adequate  support  for  their  schools.  The  income  of  the  farming  popula- 
tion declined  from  about  17  billion  dollars  in  1920  to  $5,200,000,000  in 


782  EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

1932.  Even  in  1929,  the  average  per  capita  income  of  the  farmers  was 
only  $273,  as  against  $908  for  the  rest  of  the  population.  The  federal 
government,  in  spite  of  generous  expenditures  for  relief  elsewhere,  has 
failed  to  come  to  the  rescue  of  public  education  in  any  serious  manner, 
save  for  land-grant  colleges  and  vocational  education. 

In  American  cities  there  was  an  average  falling  off  of  80  per  cent  in 
expenditures  for  school  buildings  between  1931  and  1934.  When  we 
reflect  that  American  school  children  were  not  adequately  housed  in 
1929,  we  need  not  be  surprised  at  the  scandalous  overcrowding  which 
exists  today.  Almost  a  million  and  a  half  American  children  occupy 
school  buildings  which  have  been  condemned  as  unsafe  or  unsanitary. 
Many  schools  have  been  closed  altogether.  The  serious  situation  was 
remedied  only  slightly  by  the  aid  to  school  construction  given  by  the 
federal  government  through  the  Public  Works  Administration  and  the 
Works  Progress  Administration.  Speaking  in  1941  in  behalf  of  the 
Federal  school  nid  bill,  which  would  appropriate  300  million  dollars  for 
educational  assistance,  Federal  Security  Administrator  Paul  McNutt  and 
Dr.  Howard  A.  Dawson  of  the  National  Education  Association  pointed 
out  that  some  265,000  American  school  children  were  without  any  school 
facilities. 

Between  1930-31  and  1934-35  the  median  salary  of  teachers  in  our 
largest  cities  dropped  at  least  10  per  cent,  and  in  small  cities  (under 
30,000)  the  median  decreased  20  per  cent.  In  many  individual  cities  the 
situation  was  far  worse.  In  Toledo,  Ohio,  for  example,  the  cuts  amounted 
to  55  per  cent.  In  1929-30  the  average  salary  of  all  teachers  (including 
superintendents)  was  $1,420,  while  in  1934  it  had  dropped  to  $1,227.  One 
third  of  all  employed  teachers  are  getting  less  than  $750  a  year.  Some 
84,000  rural  teachers  get  less  than  $450  a  year.  On  top  of  this,  there 
have  been  frequent  demands  that  teachers  turn  back  at  least  part  of  their 
salaries  as  compulsory  donations,  while  in  some  cities  teachers  went 
entirely  unpaid  for  long  periods  after  1931. 

Nevertheless,  the  decrease  in  teacher  reward  in  the  form  of  salaries  was 
accompanied  by  an  actual  increase  in  work  required  of  teachers.  There 
was  a  great  deal  of  doubling  up  and  an  increase  in  the  teaching  hours  re- 
quired. All  this  meant  that  the  educational  cost  per  pupil  (elementary 
and  secondary)  dropped  from  $86.70  in  1929-30  to  $67.48  in  1933-34. 

The  false  policies  of  economy  practiced  between  1929  and  1934  touched 
such  vital  spots  as  textbooks.  In  spite  of  the  fact  that  textbooks  account 
for  only  about  3  per  cent  of  total  educational  costs,  the  expenditures  for 
textbooks  fell  off  about  30  per  cent.  Archaic  books  were  retained,  as 
well  as  newer  books  which  were  falling  to  pieces  through  excessive  use. 
In  some  cases,  books  abandoned  a  generation  ago  were  taken  out  of 
storage  and  returned  to  use  in  the  schools  because  they  were  in  better 
physical  condition  than  the  books  which  had  replaced  them.  A  particu- 
larly deplorable  aspect  of  such  enforced  educational  economy  is  thai 
recent  innovations,  such  as  experimental  schools,  clinics,  and  new  de- 
velopments in  the  social  studies,  are  sacrificed  first  of  all.  This  happens,, 


EDUCATION    IN  THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS  783 

in  spite  of  the  fact  that  these  innovations  represent  the  most  important 
additions  to  educational  theory  and  practice  in  our  generation. 

This  financial  raid  on  education  has  been  accompanied  by  a  drive  with- 
out parallel  against  the  freedom  and  independence  of  the  teaching  profes- 
sion. Since  the  first  World  War  more  laws  have  been  passed  interferring 
with  the  freedom  of  teaching  in  public  schools  than  in  all  of  our  previous 
educational  history  put  together.1611  The  policies  and  legislation  restrict- 
ing educational  freedom  in  our  day  may  be  divided  into  two  major  types. 
The  first  represents  annoying  restrictions  which  do  not  present  any  grave 
immediate  obstacle  to  educational  freedom  but  do  set  an  extremely 
dangerous  precedent  for  far  more  sweeping  drives  against  the  teaching 
profession  and  educational  independence.  The  other  type  represents 
menacing  immediate  threats  to  the  independence  and  integrity  of  our 
educational  process. 

We  shall  first  consider  some  representative  examples  of  the  growing 
body  of  annoying  restrictions  upon  teachers.  In  a  number  of  states 
there  has  been  a  definite  movement  to  break  down  the  separation  of 
church  and  state  which  the  framers  of  the  Constitution  particularly 
cherished.  In  12  states  the  reading  of  the  Bible  in  public  schools  is  com- 
pulsory, while  in  24  it  has  been  made  permissible.  The  State  of  North 
Dakota  prescribes  by  law  that  the  Ten  Commandments  shall  be  posted  on 
the  walls  of  every  schoolroom  in  the  state.  In  four  states,  it  is  legal  to 
give  religious  instruction  on  school  time,  and  in  30  states  such  instruction 
during  school  hours  is  practiced  without  authority  of  the  law.  Directly 
associated  with  this  tendency  to  mix  religion  and  public  affairs  was  the 
campaign  to  outlaw  the  teaching  of  evolution.  Between  1921  and  1929, 
37  anti-evolution  bills  were  introduced  in  some  20  legislatures;  mainly  in 
the  South  and  West.  Four  such  laws  were  passed,  the  State  of  Oklahoma, 
however,  later  repealing  its  law.  Where  sweeping  anti-evolution  legis- 
lation has  not  been  possible,  Fundamentalists  have  been  able  to  ban  the 
teaching  of  evolution  by  bringing  pressure  upon  textbook  companies, 
boards  of  education,  and  teachers.  In  the  public  schools  and  smaller 
colleges  of  the  South  and  West  the  teaching  of  evolution  remains  highly 
precarious. 

Patriotic  instruction  in  the  schools  has  been  notably  extended  since  the 
first  World  War.  If  the  instruction  given  were  of  a  broad  and  funda- 
mental type,  this  would  be  a  notable  gain.  But,  for  the  most  part, 
patriotic  instruction  is  of  a  narrow  and  provincial  type,  the  ultimate  result 
of  which  is  to  give  the  student  a  warped  idea  of  both  his  own  country  and 
the  other  states  of  the  world.  Moreover,  the  teaching  of  patriotism  has 
become  identified  with  a  defense  of  the  present  economic  order  as  well  as 
of  our  country.  Indeed,  in  the  District  of  Columbia  any  instruction 
dealing  with  the  principles  of  Communism  was  banned  by  law  in  1935. 
This  is  logically  as  indefensible  as  to  identify  patriotism  with  the  teach- 
ing of  some  form  of  economic  radicalism.  There  is  a  large  amount  of 


10aSee  American  Civil  Liberties  Union  Bulletin,  "The  Gag  on  Teaching,"  1940. 


784  EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

flag-saluting  and  other  patriotic  ritual  prescribed  by  law  today.  In 
14  states,  flag-saluting  ceremonies  are  required.  In  13  states  general 
patriotic  exercises  are  demanded  by  law.  The  flag-saluting  legislation 
has  borne  particularly  hard  upon  certain  religious  sects,  notably  Jehovah's 
Witnesses,  who  have  conscientious  scruples  against  this  type  of  cere- 
monial. A  number  of  pupils  belonging  to  this  sect  have  been  expelled 
from  public  schools.165 

In  some  29  states  the  teaching  of  foreign  languages  below  the  junior 
high  school  grades  is  prohibited  by  law.  This  is  obviously  contrary  to 
all  sound  pedagogical  principles.  The  logical  time  to  begin  such  in- 
struction is  in  the  elementary  grades. 

Some  43  states  compel  the  teaching  of  the  Constitution.  On  the  face 
of  it,  this  is  an  admirable  idea.  But  the  instruction  given  is  usually 
totally  unenlightened.  Little  realistic  information  is  given  as  to  the 
background  or  nature  of  our  Constitution.  Instruction  under  these  laws 
is  primarily  an  attack  upon  intellectual  and  economic  liberalism.  It  is 
usually  as  far  removed  in  spirit  and  content  from  the  political  ideals  of 
those  who  framed  our  Constitution  as  it  is  from  the  principles  which 
dominate  Soviet  Russia  or  the  Fascist  states  of  Europe.  Some  21  states 
specifically  require  the  teaching  of  patriotism,  and  in  almost  all  instances 
this  teaching  consists  of  a  fervent  defense  of  the  Constitution,  of  the 
major  political  parties,  and  of  the  capitalistic  system.160 

The  most  novel,  and  in  many  ways  the  most  ominous,  of  all  this 
restrictive  legislation  requires  teachers  to  take  special  oaths  of  loyalty  to 
the  Constitution.  Such  an  oath  is  not  usually  required  of  other  public 
servants,  but  it  is  now  prescribed  by  law  for  teachers  in  some  24  states. 
The  campaign  of  publicity  which  led  to  these  loyalty  oaths  was  led  by 
the  Hearst  press,  the  Daughters  of  the  American  Revolution,  and  other 
groups  devoted  to  a  rather  narrow  conception  of  patriotism.  In  the  light 
of  the  wide-spread  criticism  of  Hearst's  inflammatory  statements  just 
preceding  the  assassination  of  President  McKinley,  it  was  somewhat 
ironical  to  find  the  Hearst  press  taking  the  lead  in  upholding  the  principle 
of  loyalty  to  the  American  Constitution.  These  loyalty  oaths  in  them- 
selves are  not  directly  dangerous.  But,  as  a  precedent  for  further  re- 
strictive legislation,  they  are  extremely  menacing.  They  may  readily  be 
followed  by  other  laws  specifically  interpreting  what  is  meant  by  loyalty 
to  the  Constitution.  Or,  boards  of  education  may  interpret  loyalty  to 
mean  fanatical  support  of  a  particular  economic  theory  or  political 
regime. 

We  may  now  turn  to  those  phases  of  the  limitation  of  the  freedom  of 
teaching  which  are  immediately  menacing  to  academic  freedom.  We 
may  first  make  reference  to  the  attempt  to  restrict  the  activities  of 


16b  See  W.  G.  Fennel  and  Edward  J.  Friedlander,  "Compulsory  Flag  Salute  in  the 
Schools,"  American  Civil  Liberties  Union  Bulletin,  1938. 
ific  See  H.  A.  Bennett,  The  Constitution  in  School  and  College,  Putnam,  1935, 


EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  785 

students  with  regard  to  the  freedom  of  intellectual  discussion.17  There 
is  rarely  any  effort  to  curb  reactionary  publications  or  educational  or- 
ganizations. Seldom,  if  ever,  is  an  extremely  reactionary  speaker  denied 
the  right  to  address  any  university  group.  There  have,  however,  been 
many  cases  of  censorship  or  suppression  of  liberal  publications  in  schools 
and  colleges,  and  in  numerous  instances  the  editors  have  been  disciplined 
or  even  expelled  from  the  institution.  The  articles  have  rarely  been 
objected  to  on  the  ground  of  obscenity  or  bad  taste.  Most  of  them  have 
presented  a  liberal  point  of  view  on  economic  doctrines.  Liberal  clubs 
and  other  progressive  forums  have  been  frequently  suppressed.  World 
famous  liberals  have  been  denied  the  right  to  address  student  groups. 
Among  such  persons  have  been  Mrs.  Dora  Russell,  Scott  Nearing, 
Clarence  Darrow,  Arthur  Garfield  Hays,  Kirby  Page,  John  Nevin  Sayre, 
and  others  of  equal  prominence.  At  a  time  when  the  R.O.T.C.  was  gain- 
ing ground  in  our  institutions  of  higher  learning,  peace  meetings  organ- 
ized by  students  were  frequently  suppressed  and  the  organizers  of  such 
meetings  disciplined.  Liberal  textbooks  have  been  vigorously  attacked, 
most  notorious  being  the  drive  against  the  social  studies  texts  prepared 
by  Harold  Rugg.  Most  of  the  texts  attacked  were  to  be  criticized,  if  at 
all,  for  their  excessive  moderation  and  timidity. 

In  the  last  decade  or  so  there  have  been  many  dismissals  of  college 
professors  because  they  have  sponsored  some  form  of  intellectual  liberal- 
ism. Among  the  most  conspicuous  cases  have  been  the  dismissal  of  Max 
F.  Meyer  from  University  of  Missouri  in  1930,  of  Herbert  Adolphus  Miller 
from  Ohio  State  University  in  1931,  of  Ralph  E.  Turner  from  University 
of  Pittsburgh  in  1934,  of  Jerome  Davis  from  Yale  University  in  1937, 
and  of  Granville  Hicks  from  Rensselaer  Polytechnic  Institute.  Pro- 
fessor Meyer  had  given  advice  relative  to  a  dignified  sex  questionnaire. 
Professor  Miller  had  opposed  compulsory  military  training  and  other 
forms  of  reactionary  policy.  Professor  Turner  had  collaborated  with 
Governor  Pinchot  in  progressive  labor  legislation.  Professor  Davis  had 
defended  the  scholarly  views  relative  to  the  origins  of  the  first  World 
War,  had  advocated  that  Christianity  support  the  cause  of  social  justice, 
and  had  participated  prominently  in  the  work  of  the  American  Federation 
of  Teachers.  Professor  Hicks  was  dismissed  for  assigning  Henry  George's 
Progress  and  Poverty  as  reading  in  a  course  in  American  literature.  In 
addition  to  the  teachers  dismissed,  many  more  were  compelled  to  exercise 
great  discretion  in  their  teaching,  a  situation  which  more  sweepingly 
hampers  intellectual  freedom  than  do  the  relatively  few  dismissals  of 
courageous  teachers.  There  is  no  record  of  any  professor  having  been 
dismissed  because  of  reactionary  teachings,  though  many  American  pro- 
fessors have  definitely  fascist  leanings  and  both  hold  and  teach  opinions 
far  more  contrary  to  the  American  Constitution  than  moderate  Socialism. 


17  See  the  valuable  recent  booklet,  "What  Freedom  for  American  Students?" 
prepared  by  the  American  Civil  Liberties  Union,  April,  1941. 


786  EDUCATION    IN   THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS 

A  particularly  menacing  technique  which  has  been  adopted  by  many 
adroit  and  reactionary  college  presidents  is  that  of  exercising  a  vast 
amount  of  care  in  selecting  the  teaching  staff,  so  as  to  appoint  only  con- 
servative professors.  Then  much  publicity  is  given  to  the  fact  that  the 
utmost  freedom  is  accorded  to  these  men,  who  never  entertain  a  progres- 
sive idea.18 

Perhaps  the  greatest  threat  to  academic  freedom  today  is  the  savagery 
meted  out  to  those  who  take  any  prominent  part  in  promoting  the  organ- 
ization of  teachers,  particularly  in  working  for  membership  in  the  Amer- 
ican Federation  of  Teachers.  It  is  extremely  precarious  for  public  school 
teachers  to  take  any  steps  leading  to  the  organization  of  units  of  the 
American  Federation  of  Teachers,  and  in  many  colleges  solicitation  of 
membership  in  the  Teachers  Union  places  a  professor  in  grave  jeopardy. 
This  situation  is  particularly  lamentable  because  it  is  readily  apparent 
that  only  the  thoroughgoing  organization  of  teachers  can  give  the  teaching 
profession  any  real  professional  security  and  independence. 

An  especially  vicious  attack  on  the  Teachers  Union  was  made  in  New 
York  City  in  1940-41  by  the  Rapp-Coudert  Legislative  Committee,  which 
attempted  to  smear  the  Union  with  communism  and  to  intimidate  teach- 
ers in  high  schools  and  colleges  who  belonged  to  the  Union.  As  the 
Committee  for  the  Defense  of  Public  Education  pointed  out,  the  doings 
of  the  Ilapp-Coudert  Committee  were  strangely  reminiscent  of  the  edu- 
cational practices  of  the  Soviet  Union  and  Nazi  Germany.  A  schoolgirl's 
home  was  invaded  at  night  by  a  process  server.  Teachers  were  dis- 
charged on  the  wildest  accusations  made  by  those  who  held  some  per- 
sonal grudge  against  them.  One  college  teacher  was  thrown  into  jail  on 
an  apparently  trumped-up  charge  of  perjury.  Membership  lists  and 
records  of  the  Teachers  Union  were  illegally  seized.  Union  members 
were  shadowed  by  plainclothesmen.  Youthful  students  were  subjected 
to  Third  Degree  methods.  Hearings  were  frequently  held  in  secret,  and 
so  on.19 

Some  protection  has  been  afforded  to  teachers  by  the  growth  of  tenure 
laws  since  the  first  World  War.  Back  in  1924,  some  37  states  had  no 
tenure  legislation  of  any  sort,  and  only  imperfect  protection  was  afforded 
by  the  other  11  states.  The  situation  has  improved  considerably  since 
that  time,  mainly  as  a  result  of  agitation  by  the  American  Federation 
of  Teachers,  aided  by  some  aggressive  teachers'  organizations.  The  Na- 
tional Education  Association  thus  summarizes  the  situation: 

Today  15  states  and  Alaska  have  no  state  tenure  laws;  37  and  Hawaii  have 
either  tenure  laws  continuing  contract  laws,  or  provision  for  long-term  contracts. 
Seven  and  Hawaii  provide  permanent  tenure  after  a  probationary  period;  16 
grant  permanent  tenure  in  certain  districts;  ten  provide  for  continuing  contracts; 


18  See  below,  p.  788. 

19  Bella  V.  Dodd,  "The  Conspiracy  Against  the  Schools,"  Committee  for  the  De- 
fense of  Public  Education,  N.  Y.,  1941.    See  also  the  cogent  criticism  of  the  Rapp- 
Coudert  Committee  by  James  Marshall,  president  of  the  Board  of  Education  of  New 
York  City,  in  the  spring  of  1942. 


EDUCATION    IN   THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS  787 

four  permit  the  signing  of  contracts  for  more  than  one-year  periods,  at  least  in 
certain  districts;  one  allows  local  citizens  to  vote  permanent  tenure  in  each 
district.20 

In  the  better  colleges  and  universities  it  is  usual  for  permanent  tenure 
to  be  granted  after  a  probationary  period,  often  three  years.  But  this 
provision  usually  applies  only  to  faculty  members  above  the  rank  of 
instructor,  and  it  can  be  readily  evaded  even  in  case  of  full  professors. 

The  Problem  of  Academic  Freedom 

When  academic  freedom  is  discussed,  it  is  usually  believed  that  the 
most  serious  aspect  of  the  situation  lies  in  the  occasional  dismissals  of 
progressive  and  courageous  teachers.  However,  these  dismissals  con- 
stitute the  least  menacing  aspect.  The  worst  feature  is  that  the  generally 
conservative  and  traditional  cast  of  our  educational  system  brings  about 
a  condition  which  produces  teachers  .entirely  in  accord  with  a  regime  of 
intellectual  lethargy  and  cultural  lag.  The  great  majority  of  teachers 
have  nothing  to  say  which  would  disturb  anybody,  even  the  most  alert 
patrioteer  and  plutocrat.  They  have  no  feeling  that  their  freedom  is  in 
any  way  threatened  by  reactionary  pressure  and  propaganda.  Few 
teachers  entertain  opinions  about  our  world  which  differ  in  any  notable 
way  from  those  of  the  man  in  the  street  except,  very  often,  to  be  more 
romantic  and  antiquated.  This  is  the  most  distressing  thing  about  the 
whole  intellectual  atmosphere  of  American  education.  It  also  explains 
why  most  teachers  have  little  or  no  sympathy  with  their  courageous  col- 
leagues who  get  into  difficulties.  Perhaps  the  most  pathetic  figure  in 
education  today  is  the  teacher  of  the  social  sciences  who  does  not  have 
any  gense  of  being  restricted  in  his  teaching.  No  more  damaging,  if 
unconscious,  confession  of  incompetence  could  well  be  imagined. 

There  is  a  considerable  number  of  relatively  intelligent  teachers  who 
entertain  sensible  ideas  and  sound  convictions  and  are  personally  pro- 
gressive in  their  outlook.  But  the  social  pressures  intimidate  them  and 
force  them  into  extremely  discreet  ways.  They  could  bring  reality  into 
the  classroom,  but  hesitate  to  do  so,  for  fear  of  getting  involved  in  diffi- 
culties and  possibly  losing  their  professional  security.  It  is  obvious  that 
it  is  a  more  serious  matter  to  find  50  teachers  who  might  say  something 
worth  while  but  do  not  dare  to  do  so,  than  it  is  to  find  one  teacher  who 
speaks  out  and  gets  dismissed  for  doing  so.  This  situation  produces  a 
soul-searing  hypocrisy  among  teachers,  which  has  been  pointed  out  by 
Howard  K.  Beale  in  his  book  Are  Teachers  Free?: 

Lack  of  freedom  leads  to  a  more  disastrous  quality  than  cowardice,  namely, 
hypocrisy.  The  author  was  appalled  by  its  prevalence.  From  one  end  of  this 
country  to  another  children  are  being  trained  under  teachers  who,  if  one  is 
realistic,  must  be  branded  hypocrites. 

They  solemnly  teach  the  evils  of  alcohol;  they  drink  discreetly  in  private. 
They  know  of  crying  evils  in  the  community,  and  their  pupils  know  that  they 

20  Data  supplied  in  May  1942  by  the  Research  Division  of  the  National  Education 
Association. 


788  EDUCATION   IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

know  of  them.  Yet  in  class  they  teach  beautiful  theories  in  the  abstract  and 
then  praise  the  local  men  responsible  for  flagrant  violations  of  those  theories; 
outside  of  class  they  fawn  on  these  same  bad  citizens  because  they  are  powerful 
or  socially  important. 

They  teach  ideal  forms  of  government  and  teach  children  to  believe  that  that 
is  the  way  democracy  really  works.  Later  these  children  make  contact  with  the 
local  machine  or  corruption  in  high  places  and  then  realize  that  their  teacher 
knew  about  all  of  it,  even  when  he  was  describing  to  them  empty  forms  that 
would  blind  them  to  any  evils  in  the  system. 

They  express  one  set  of  views  in  the  classroom  and  in  public  places;  they  hold 
a  different  faith  among  intimate  friends.  Usually  teachers  rationalize  all  of  this 
double  dealing  out  of  existence.  They  are  forced  to  it;  so  they  find  theories  to 
support  it. 

The  greatest  hypocrisy  of  all  is  their  educational  theory.  They  solemnly  talk 
of  all  sorts  of  fine  purposes  of  education.  Yet  they  teach  on  entirely  different 
principles  when  they  get  into  the  classroom.  The  present  author  has  talked  to 
superintendents  who  have  made  to  him  solemn  statements  which,  while  the 
superintendent  was  making  them,  he  knew  from  irrefutable  evidence  were  abso- 
lutely untrue. 

America  needs,  not  better  ideals  of  education,  but  educators  who  will  not 
pretend  to  follow  thorn  unless  they  really  do.  This  pretense  extends  down 
through  the  whole  school  system.  Teachers,  over  and  over  again,  have  apologized 
for  something  they  were  doing  or  teaching  by  explaining  that  they  knew  better, 
but  of  course  it  would  not  be  discreet  to  teach  it.  They  did  not  see  that  this 
admission  damned  them  more  completely  than  ignorance.21 

We  have  already  referred  to  the  revival  of  extensive  dismissals  of  pro- 
fessors since  the  first  World  War.  Considering  the  number  of  professors 
now  engaged  in  teaching,  however,  the  total  of  those  dismissed  in  the  last 
20  years  is  not  alarming.  Far  more  important  is  the  situation  to  which 
we  have  referred,  namely,  the  intimidation  of  many  progressive  teachers, 
and  the  tendency  to  select  a  conservative  and  tried  teaching  force,  so 
that  it  will  be  extremely  rare  that  any  cause  for  dismissal  will  arise. 
Special  stress  is  laid  upon  the  complete  freedom  accorded  to  this  carefully 
picked  faculty.  It  is  obvious  that  this  method  is  far  more  sinister  and 
effective  than  the  forthright  firing  of  a  few  courageous  men.  As  Pro- 
fessor Willard  Waller  has  observed,  "principles  of  academic  freedom  have 
little  to  do  with  the  case.  Most  of  the  teachers  do  not  even  realize  that 
they  are  not  free."  This  method  of  sterilizing  the  academic  intellect  is 
particularly  safe  and  effective  because  it  never  arouses  any  serious  pro- 
tests. When  a  famous  professor  is  dropped,  much  publicity  ensues.  But 
the  quiet  intellectual  emasculation  of  a  whole  faculty  by  a  careful  selec- 
tion of  the  teaching  force  is  a  matter  which  never  receives  adverse 
publicity;  indeed,  receives  no  publicity  at  all.  This  adroit  procedure  was 
first  introduced  by  President  A.  Lawrence  Lowell  of  Harvard  University 
and  is  known  as  "the  Lowell  formula,"  but  it  has  become  very  general 
among  the  more  respectable  institutions  of  higher  learning.  Yale  Uni- 
versity has  been  the  only  distinguished  institution  of  higher  learning 
which  has  recently  resorted  to  the  old-fashioned  method  of  dismissing  a 
well-known  professor  outright. 


21  Are  American  Teachers  Free?  Scribner,  1936,  pp.  776-777. 


EDUCATION    IN  THE   SOCIAL  CRISIS  789 

Teachers  have  created  various  organizations  designed  to  protect  them. 
Conspicuous  has  been  the  American  Association  of  University  Professors, 
which  was  organized  in  1915.  This  has  given  special  attention  to  prob- 
lems of  academic  tenure  and  to  investigations  of  dismissals.  It  has 
handed  in  many  masterly  reports  upon  specific  episodes  of  academic 
martyrdom.  It  seems  probable  that  these  must  have  exerted  some  re- 
straining influence  upon  the  more  reactionary  college  presidents.  But, 
on  the  whole,  the  protection  offered  by  the  Association  is  extremely 
limited.  It  rarely  acts  until  after  a  professor  has  been  dismissed.  Hence, 
its  main  function  is  to  prepare  eloquent  and  authoritative  academic 
obituaries.  Indeed,  the  Association  does  the  martyred  professors  far 
more  harm  than  good.  It  gives  much  publicity  to  each  case  and  thereby 
scares  off  college  presidents,  deans,  and  professors  from  offering  the  dis- 
missed professor  another  position  no  matter  how  capable  the  man  may  be. 
Dr.  Donald  Slesingcr  contends  that  no  professor  of  prominence,  who  has 
been  dropped  from  an  American  university  and  has  been  given  publicity 
— however  favorable — by  the  American  Association  of  University  Pro- 
fessors, has  ever  been  able  to  obtain  another  satisfactory  academic 
appointment.  The  greatest  reflection  upon  the  teaching  profession  is  the 
fact  that,  more  often  than  not,  it  is  the  professors  rather  than  the  uni- 
versity presidents  and  deans  who  most  frequently  refuse  to  recommend 
the  appointment  of  a  professor  who  has  been  dismissed  from  another 
institution,  no  matter  how  creditable  the  dismissal  was  to  the  professor 
who  was  dropped. 

Dr.  Donald  Slesinger,  who  has  filled  some  of  the  most  important 
executive  positions  in  American  education,  among  them  a  deanship  at 
one  of  America's  leading  universities,  places  the  responsibility  for  the 
amazing  lack  of  professorial  independence  and  freedom  squarely  upon 
the  professors  themselves: 

The  plain  conclusion  of  my  experience  forced  on  me  was  this:  that,  with  few 
exceptions,  the  professors  themselves  were  the  greatest  enemies  of  academic 
freedom.  In  places  where  it  was  irrelevant  they  used  the  slogan  [of  freedom] 
precisely  as  the  Republicans  used  the  Constitution  in  the  last  campaign  [1936], 
as  a  weapon  of  reaction;  where  it  was  relatively  unimportant  they  gave  it 
lip  service  but  no  cash;  and  where  it  really  mattered  their  opposition  was  open 
and  bitter  and  unscrupulous.22 

In  the  opinion  of  Dr.  Slesinger,  most  professors  are  themselves  conven- 
tional and  reactionary  in  their  social  and  political  outlook.  They  do 
not  sympathize  with  those  of  their  colleagues  who  get  into  trouble  be- 
cause of  progressive  ideals.  This  agrees  with  the  view  taken  by  Pro- 
fessor Beale  regarding  the  usual  attitude  of  a  college  professor  toward 
a  colleague  who  has  got  into  trouble  by  being  overcandid:  "Well,  of 
course  it's  true,  but  why  did  the  damned  fool  want  to  say  so?"  The 
only  interest  of  the  usual  run  of  college  professors  in  academic  freedom 
relates  to  their  own  security.  They  are  usually  absorbed  in  petty  routine 


22  "Professor's  Freedom,"  Harper's,  October,  1937. 


790  EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL   CRISIS 

matters  of  academic  life.  They  are  thoroughly  trained  in  docility  by 
the  very  facts  of  the  academic  regimen.  Dr.  Slesinger  illustrates  his 
point,  for  example,  by  the  fracas  at  the  University  of  Chicago,  where  a 
raid  against  certain  liberal  social  science  professors  was  launched  by 
Hearst  and  a  Chicago  drug  merchant  by  the  name  of  Walgreen.  It  is 
popularly  supposed  that  the  victory  for  academic  freedom  was  won 
through  the  resolute  and  courageous  action  of  the  Chicago  faculty.  As  a 
matter  of  fact,  it  was  won  through  the  steadfast  and  courageous  attitude 
of  President  Robert  M.  Hutchins  and  a  very  few  of  the  more  progressive 
Chicago  professors.  The  majority  of  the  faculty  were  indifferent,  scared, 
or  hostile  toward  the  professors  who  were  attacked.  The  victory  for 
academic  freedom  was  a  triumph  over  the  majority  of  the  faculty  as 
well  as  over  Hearst  and  Walgreen: 

Eventually  there  was  a  public  hearing,  and  the  excellent  showing  of  the  uni- 
versity won  the  acclaim  even  of  the  pusillanimous.  But  that  showing  was  due 
to  the  persistence  of  the  president  and  the  backing  he  received  from  such  men 
as  Charles  E.  Mcrriam,  who  admitted  that  the  university  was  progressive,  and 
was  willing  to  take  his  full  share  of  the  responsibility  for  making  it  so;  and 
Robert  Morss  Lovett,  who  knew  that  pacifists  went  to  jail  but  insisted  on 
remaining  one.  The  victory  was  not  over  Hearst  and  Walgreen  alone,  but  over 
the  weak-kneed  conformists  of  one  of  the  most  independent  faculties  of  the 
country.28 

Perhaps  the  reductio  ad  absurdum  of  the  whole  discussion  of  academic 
freedom  was  the  statement  recently  made  by  a  cultivated  and  learned, 
but  reactionary,  publicist,  to  the  effect  that  academic  freedom  means 
only  "freedom  concerning  those  things  which  are  purely  academic."  He 
went  on  to  say  that  this  means  that  teachers  should  expect  to  have  free- 
dom of  discussion  only  in  regard  to  those  literary,  philosophical,  and 
mathematical  issues  which  have  no  practical  bearing  on  life  and  society. 
The  American  Civil  Liberties  Union  has  recently  drawn  up  a  Bill  of 
Rights  for  Teachers  which  appears  sensible  and  fair  to  all  parties  con- 
cerned. Its  essentials  are  summarized  in  the  following  five  points: 

1.  The  teacher's  freedom  in  investigation  should  be  restricted  only  by  the 
demands  of  his  assigned  teaching  duties. 

,2.  The  teacher's  freedom  in  presenting  his  own  subject  in  the  classroom  or 
elsewhere  should  not  be  impaired,  except  in  extraordinary  cases  by  specific 
stipulations  in  advance,  fully  understood  and  accepted  by  both  the  teacher  and 
the  institution  in  which  he  gives  instruction. 

3.  The  teacher,  when  he  speaks  or  writes  outside  of  the  institution  on  subjects 
not  within  his  own  field  of  study,  is  entitled  to  precisely  the  same  freedom  and 
is  subject  to  the  same  responsibility  as  attach  to  all  other  citizens. 

4.  No  teacher  should  be  dismissed  or  otherwise  disciplined  because  of  his 
beliefs  or  membership  in  any  lawful  organization.    Charges  of  improper  actions 
by  a  teacher  should  relate  to  specific  instances  of  asserted  misconduct.    They 
should  not  be  based  merely  upon  inferences  drawn  from  the  fact  of  organizational 
affiliations  of  a  legal  character. 

5.  The  contention  that   certain  organizations   impose   obligations   on   their 
members  inconsistent  with  their  duties  as  teachers,  is  no  ground  for  disciplining 


28  Slesinger,  loc.  cit. 


EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  791 

them.  If  this  contention  is  as  all  embracing  as  it  is  supposed  to  be,  then  the 
teachers'  conduct  will  produce  grounds  for  disciplinary  action;  if  not,  the  uni- 
versality of  the  statement  is  open  to  such  serious  question  that  disciplinary  action 
is  not  warranted  on  mere  membership  alone.24 

One  should  keep  in  mind  the  fact  that  academic  freedom  means  not 
only  freedom  for  teachers  but  also  freedom  for  students  to  organize  their 
societies,  carry  on  free  discussion,  have  reputable  speakers  address  them, 
and  air  their  grievances  in  dignified  fashion  relative  to  the  administra- 
tion, and  the  faculty.  The  American  Civil  Liberties  Union  has  recently 
published  the  results  of  a  comprehensive  examination  of  this  subject.25 

On  the  whole,  college  students  have  rather  more  freedom  for  organiza- 
tion and  discussion  than  they  did  a  generation  back.  But  there  are  still 
many  severe  handicaps  to  full  intellectual  freedom  for  students,  short 
of  any  license  or  obvious  abuses  of  freedom.  There  is  widespread  intol- 
erance of  somewhat  radical  students  organizations,  like  the  American 
Student  Union,  and  in  some  cases  even  towards  the  mild  liberal  clubs. 
The  college  press  is  pretty  well  censored  in  a  majority  of  colleges  and 
universities.  Compulsory  military  training  is  in  operation  in  many 
universities,  especially  state  universities.  Peace  meetings  and  protests 
against  war  were  widely  discouraged  or  prohibited  altogether  for  several 
years  before  our  entry  into  the  second  World  War.  Thirteen  students 
were  dismissed  en  bloc  from  the  University  of  Michigan  in  1940  for 
alleged  radical  and  pacific  affiliations.  Radical  and  pacifist  speakers  are 
wridcly  banned  on  college  campuses.  There  is  no  instance  of  the  banning 
of  any  notorious  reactionary.  Student  self-government  is  a  rare  excep- 
tion. Conservative  pressures  of  various  kinds,  both  within  and  outside 
the  student  body,  serve  to  repress  student  liberalism  and  independence. 
As  the  report  well  summarizes  the  situation:  "In  the  face  of  these  mani- 
fold pressures  it  is  encouraging  that  freedom  for  student  activities  fares 
as  well  as  it  does." 26 

The  Organization  of  Teachers 

Thoughtful  educators  generally  admit  that  the  educational  forces  of 
the  country  cannot  rise  to  a  position  of  social  effectiveness  in  the  realm 
of  social  change  unless  they  are  able  to  present  an  organized  front  against 
the  opposition  of  the  vested  interests.  There  are  few  persons  more  help- 
less than  the  isolated  teacher.  The  average  teacher  is  not  well  trained 
to  enter  any  other  dignified  and  prosperous  profession.  If  the  teacher 
loses  his  or  her  job,  economic  disaster  stares  the  unfortunate  person  in 
the  face.  Teachers'  salaries  are  not  sufficient  to  allow  the  accumulation 
of  a  sufficient  financial  reserve  to  provide  for  economic  independence. 
Moreover,  no  teacher  is  today  absolutely  indispensable. 


24  Bulletin,  February  2,  1942. 

25  "What  Freedom  for  American  Students?"  April,  1941. 

26  Loc.  cit.f  p.  44. 


792  EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

The  surplus  of  unemployed  teachers  is  vastly  greater  than  in  any  pre- 
ceding decade.  Normal  schools,  teachers'  colleges,  and  graduate  schools 
are  turning  out  an  ever  greater  army  of  formally  qualified  instructors. 
At  the  same  time,  the  depression  has  restricted  the  number  of  posts 
available.  Foreign  teachers,  fleeing  from  oppression  abroad,  have  also 
taken  many  of  the  college  and  university  posts  formerly  open  to  native- 
born  teachers.  Supply  outruns  demand  as  never  before  in  American 
public  education.  Conditions  bid  fair  to  get  worse.  As  war  costs  in- 
crease, the  proportion  of  public  funds  allotted  to  education  will  be  cut 
down.  The  decline  of  income  from  private  investments  may  make  it 
necessary  to  curtail  or  close  down  many,  if  not  most,  endowed  schools 
and  colleges.  With  over  200,000  unemployed  certified  teachers,  the 
threat  of  resignation  by  a  harassed  teacher  will  achieve  nothing.  Scores 
of  qualified  teachers  stand  eager  to  seize  the  position  left  vacant.  No 
professional  esprit  de  corps  is  in  operation  to  restrain  them  from  such 
procedure.  Not  only  are  the  teachers  unorganized  as  a  group,  but  they 
have  few  affiliations  to  serve  as  protection,  in  case  they  find  it  necessary 
to  run  counter  to  the  social  and  economic  prejudices  of  the  community. 

Therefore,  it  is  overwhelmingly  obvious  that  the  first  step  in  attaining 
any  position  of  social  leadership  must  be  a  nation-wide  organization 
of  the  teaching  profession.  Only  in  this  way  can  teachers  achieve  a 
powerful  united  front  in  promoting  the  movement  for  rational  social 
change.  Standing  alone,  the  teacher  is  fair  game  for  sniping  and  per- 
secution by  those  who  are  blind  to  the  necessity  of  social  change. 

There  are,  of  course,  dangers,  as  well  as  advantages  in  organization. 
The  fundamental  purpose  of  the  organization  of  teachers  is  to  promote 
social  effectiveness  on  a  broad  scale.  But  organizations  have  a  fatal 
tendency  to  degenerate  into  selfish  pressure  groups,  dominated  primarily 
by  the  aim  of  promoting  the  interests  of  the  organization  and  securing 
offices  and  emoluments  for  its  officialdom.  Selfish  bureaucracy  all  too 
cften  replaces  social  vision  and  public  spiritedness. 

The  movement  for  the  organization  of  teachers  must  be  accompanied 
by  a  persistent  consciousness  of  the  necessity  of  preserving  a  humane 
§ocial  perspective,  without  at  the  same  time  sacrificing  any  fundamentals 
of  organized  strength.  Above  all,  organized  teachers  must  repudiate 
such  antisocial  and  conservative  practices  as  are  found  all  too  frequently 
in  some  labor  organizations  in  the  United  States.  The  union  of  teachers 
can  assure  social  leadership  only  when  its  philosophy  and  practices  dem- 
onstrate a  sincere  devotion  to  social  betterment  for  mankind. 

The  chief  teachers'  organization  in  the  country  is  the  American  Fed- 
eration of  Teachers,  founded  in  1916.  It  is  affiliated  with  the  American 
Federation  of  Labor.  It  has  over  25,000  members,  with  more  than  250 
locals.  While  the  membership  is  scattered  throughout  the  country,  most 
of  it  is  concentrated  in  the  larger  cities,  particularly  New  York,  Chicago, 
St.  Paul,  Minneapolis,  Detroit,  Toledo,  Cleveland,  Philadelphia,  Wash- 
ington, Atlanta,  and  Chattanooga.  Its  members  are  drawn  mainly  from 
public  school  teachers  in  these  larger  cities,  though  a  number  of  the 


EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS  793 

more  progressive  college  professors  belong  to  the  Federation.    The  Fed- 
eration has  announced  its  program  as  follows: 

To  bring  associations  of  teachers  into  relations  of  mutual  assistance  and 
cooperation. 

To  obtain  for  them  all  the  rights  to  which  they  are  entitled. 

To  raise  the  standard  of  the  teaching  profession  by  securing  the  conditions 
essential  to  the  best  professional  service. 

To  promote  such  a  democratization  of  the  schools  as  will  enable  them  better 
to  equip  their  pupils  to  take  their  place  in  the  industrial,  social  and  political 
life  of  the  community. 

The  Federation  has  worked  chiefly  through  influencing  public  opinion 
and  securing  favorable  legislation,  especially  teacher's  tenure  laws,  and 
has  never  resorted  to  strike  tactics.  It  has  accomplished  a  great  deal  in 
promoting  legislation  with  respect  to  tenure,  salaries,  teachers'  pensions, 
and  the  like.  It  was  mainly  responsible  for  the  passage  of  the  unique 
state-wide  permanent  tenure  act  passed  in  the  State  of  Pennsylvania.  It 
has  fought  vigorously  against  the  attempt  to  gag  teachers  through  re- 
strictive legislation.  It  has  also  frequently  investigated  dismissals.  Its 
investigation  and  report  on  the  case  of  Jerome  Davis  at  Yale  was  an 
especially  impressive  piece  of  work.  An  international  Federation  of 
Teachers'  Associations,  having  something  over  half  a  million  members, 
has  been  organized,  with  headquarters  originally  in  Paris. 

As  we  hinted  above,  the  work  of  the  Federation  and  the  movement 
to  secure  more  members  have  been  hampered  by  the  local  intimidation  of 
active  teacher  organizers  within  the  Federation.  Moreover,  many  teach- 
ers not  only  fear  to  join  the  Federation,  but  are  even  disinclined  to  do 
so  because  it  is  affiliated  with  the  labor  movement.  The  teachers  are 
still,  to  a  large  degree,  victims  of  "the  American  dream,"  which  makes 
the  terms  "labor  movement"  and  "unionism"  synonomous  with  manual 
labor  and  servility.  On  the  whole,  one  may  concede  that  the  movement 
for  the  organization  of  teachers  mainly  indicates  hope  for  the  future 
rather  than  an  assured  achievement. 

This  chapter  should  drive  home  the  fact  that  the  teachers  of  America 
face  the  necessity  of  deciding  whether  they  will  "serve  Jehovah  or 
Baal."  Serving  the  latter  may  seem  the  easiest  way;  but  in  the  end 
it  will  bring  far  greater  disaster  to  education  than  a  resolute  determina- 
tion on  the  part  of  educators  to  make  good  their  pretensions  to  serving 
as  the  intellectual  leaders  of  humanity.  The  depression  has  made  it  clear 
what  we  may  expect  from  the  present  social  order,  in  even  the  milder 
manifestations  of  the  era  of  declining  capitalism.  What  lies  beyond  this 
may  be  seen  from  the  example  afforded  by  educational  conditions  in 
fascist  countries  abroad,  for  Fascism  represents  the  condition  of  capi- 
talism in  the  last  stages  of  its  disintegration.  If  we  do  not  move  on  to 
a  better  economic  order,  more  serious  depressions,  bloodier  wars,  and 
ultimate  collapse  are  the  only  alternatives. 

If  education  boldly  asserts  its  role  as  the  leader  in  social  progress,  it 
may  avert  such  educational  conditions  as  exist  in  fascist  countries 


794  EDUCATION    IN  THE  SOCIAL  CRISIS 

abroad,  and  may  also  lead  society  into  the  promised  land  of  abundance 
and  the  good  life,  which  will  provide  both  security  and  intellectual  inde- 
pendence. But  if  it  evades  and  delays,  it  will  not  be  many  years  before 
this  opportunity  will  have  been  lost,  as  the  social  tension  becomes  more 
marked  and  the  already  diminishing  tolerance  of  the  vested  interests 
evaporates  entirely  or  is  replaced  by  the  violence  of  revolution.27 


27  Cf.  H.  D.  Langford,  Education  and  Social  Conflict,  Macmillan,  1936. 


CHAPTER  XIX 
Leisure/  Recreation/  and  the  Arts 

Civilization  on  the  Supra-Pig  Level 

FAB  AND  AWAY  the  greater  part  of  human  activity  in  the  past  has  been 
devoted  to  obtaining  enough  material  necessities  to  make  living  possible. 
Man  has  struggled  for  food,  clothing,  and  shelter.  He  has  set  up  forms 
of  government  designed  to  make  him  relatively  secure  in  the  possession  of 
those  material  necessities  which  he  has  collected.  Only  a  small  segment 
of  humanity  has  ever  been  able  to  amass  enough  material  necessities  for 
the  enjoyment  of  life.  And  this  small  minority  has  been  mainly  absorbed 
in  amassing  more  material  things.  Only  a  slight  amount  of  time  and 
attention  has  been  given  by  this  minority  to  the  non-material  interests 
which  it  has  been  in  an  unusually  favorable  position  to  enjoy. 

Certainly  at  least  90  per  cent  of  mankind  has  failed  to  reach  the 
level  of  "happy  pigs,"  for  any  good  farmer  will  admit  that  a  healthy 
pig  is  entitled  to  enjoy  adequate  food  and  shelter.  To  a  large  extent,  this 
unfortunate  condition  of  the  majority  of  mankind  in  the  past  has  been 
due  to  the  inadequacy  of  productive  facilities.  The  tools  and  machines 
were  too  inefficient  to  permit  a  sufficiently  thorough  conquest  of  nature 
to  assure  abundance  for  all.  To  be  sure,  social  inequalities,  exploitation, 
and  defects  in  distribution  all  played  their  part  in  impoverishing  the 
masses  in  the  past.  But  even  an  efficient  social  order  could  not  have 
insured  plenty  for  everybody  until  after  the  middle  of  the  eighteenth 
century,  when  the  empire  of  machines  came  into  being.  For  the  first 
time  in  the  history  of  humanity,  we  now  have  the  mechanical  equipment 
to  produce  plenty  for  everybody.  All  of  mankind,  in  civilized  countries, 
could  attain  the  pig-level,  and  have  plenty  of  leisure  time  for  those 
achievements  on  the  "supra-pig"  level  which  constitute  the  true  and  unique 
human  culture. 

This  idea  that  a  truly  human  civilization  lies  on  the  supra-pig  level 
was  first  set  forth  by  Plato  in  the  Republic.  In  this  book,  Plato  traces 
the  evolution  of  the  ideal  society,  based  upon  the  division  of  labor.  He 
first  analyzes  human  material  needs,  and  then  describes  the  evolution  of 
the  professions  and  classes  necessary  to  provide  for  these  needs.  In  the 
following  paragraphs  Plato  describes  the  daily  life  of  man,  after  provision 
has  been  made  for  supplying  his  material  needs  in  abundant  fashion: 

Let  us  then  consider  what  will  be  their  mode  of  life,  now  that  we  have  thus 
established  them.  Will  they  not  produce  corn,  and  wine,  and  clothes,  and  shoes, 
and  build  houses  for  themselves?  And  when  they  are  housed,  they  will  work, 

795 


796          LEISURE,   RECREATION,   AND  THE  ARTS 

in  summer  commonly  stripped  and  barefoot,  but  in  winter  substantially  clothed 
and  shod. 

They  will  feed  on  barley  meal  and  flour  of  wheat,  baking  and  kneading  them, 
making  noble  cakes  and  loaves;  these  they  will  serve  up  on  a  mat  of  reeds  or  on 
clean  leaves,  themselves  reclining  the  while  upon  beds  strewn  with  yew  or  myrtle. 
And  they  and  their  children  will  feast,  drinking  of  the  wine  which  they  have 
made,  wearing  garlands  on  their  heads,  and  hymning  praises  of  the  gods,  in 
happy  converse  with  one  another. 

And  they  will  take  care  that  their  families  do  not  exceed  their  means;  haying 
an  eye  to  poverty  or  war.  Of  course  they  must  have  a  relish-salt,  and  olives, 
and  cheese,  and  they  will  boil  roots  and  herbs  such  as  country  people  prepare; 
for  a  dessert  we  shall  give  them  figs,  and  peas,  and  beans;  and  they  will  roast 
myrtle  berries  and  acorns  at  the  fire,  drinking  in  moderation.  And  with  such  a 
diet  they  may  be  expected  to  live  in  peace  and  health  to  a  good  old  age,  and 
bequeath  a  similar  life  to  their  children  after  them.1 

To  many,  such  a  state  of  life  would  seem  nearly  Utopian.  Two  thirds 
of  the  American  population  had  not  attained  it  in  1928  or  1929.  It  was 
such  a  condition  which  Herbert  Hoover  had  in  mind  when  he  promised 
us  in  the  campaign  of  1928  what  seemed  to  him  a  Utopia,  namely,  the 
abolition  of  poverty,  a  chicken  in  every  pot,  and  two  cars  in  every 
garage.  To  European  workers  and  peasants,  even  before  the  war,  this 
"simple  life"  portrayed  by  Plato  would  have  seemed  even  more  idyllic. 
European  peasants  could  hardly  afford  to  consume  their  own  eggs,  butter, 
and  milk.  Even  in  Holland,  peasants  felt  themselves  lucky  to  get  eggs 
even  on  Sundays.  In  European  and  American  slums  there  has  not  been 
the  access  to  fresh  air  and  romping  space  which  almost  every  well  cared- 
for  pig  enjoys. 

But  Plato  sternly  rebuked  any  tendency  to  be  satisfied  with  material 
plenty.  He  frankly  described  such  a  material  utopia  as  only  a  "city  of 
happy  pigs."  He  maintained  that  any  civilization  truly  worthy  of 
mankind  must  be  created  on  the  supra-pig  level.  It  would  involve  the 
addition  of  activities  and  interests  related  to  philosophy,  literature,  art, 
drama,  music,  play,  and  athletics.  These  represent  interests  which  are 
not  concerned  with  securing  material  necessities.  Plato  thus  describes, 
in  part,  the  mode  of  existence  and  the  type  of  activities  which  are  in- 
volved in.  a  truly  human  culture  on  the  supra-pig  level: 

I  suspect  that  many  will  not  be  satisfied  with  the  simpler  way  of  life.  They 
will  be  for  adding  sofas,  and  tables,  and  other  furniture;  also  dainties,  and  per- 
fumes, and  incense,  and  courtesans,  and  cakes,  and  all  these  not  of  one  sort  only, 
but  in  every  variety. 

We  must  go  beyond  the  necessaries  of  which  I  was  first  speaking,  such  as 
houses,  and  clothes,  and  shoes:  the  arts  of  the  painter  and  the  embroiderer  will 
have  to  be  set  in  motion,  and  gold  and  ivory  and  all  sorts  of  materials  must  be 
procured.  Then  we  must  enlarge  our  borders;  for  the  original  healthy  State  is 
no  longer  sufficient. 

Now  will  the  city  have  to  fill  and  swell  with  a  multitude  of  callings  which  are 
not  required  by  any  natural  want;  such  as  the  whole  tribe  of  artists  and  actors, 
of  whom  one  large  class  have  to  do  with  forms  and  colors;  another  will  be  the 
votaries  of  music-poets,  and  their  attendant  train  of  rhapsodists,  players,  dancers, 


i  Republic  II,  p.  372. 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,   AND  THE  ARTS         797 

contractors;   also  the  makers  of  diverse  kinds  of  articles,  including  women's 
dresses. 

And  we  shall  want  more  servants.  Tutors  will  also  be  in  request,  and  nurses, 
wet  and  dry,  tirewomen,  and  barbers,  as  well  as  confectioners  and  cooks,  who 
were  not  needed  and  therefore  had  no  place  in  our  former  edition  of  the  State, 
but  are  needed  now.  They  must  not  be  forgotten:  and  there  will  be  animals  of 
many  other  kinds,  if  people  eat  them.  And  living  in  this  way  we  shall  have 
much  greater  need  of  physicians  than  before.2 

In  Plato's  day  this  was  in  part  a  dream.  It  was  all  part  and  parcel  of 
the  ideal  or  Utopian  society  which  he  was  describing  in  his  Republic. 
To  be  sure,  a  few  of  the  more  wealthy  and  fortunate  Greeks  could  enjoy 
this  life  of  luxury  and  contemplation  which  Plato  envisaged  on  the 
supra-pig  level.  But  the  great  majority  were  common  workmen,  peas- 
ants, or  slaves,  who  had  not  attained  the  enviable  comforts  of  well  cared- 
for  pigs.  Indeed,  even  in  his  Utopian  imaginings  Plato  himself  planned 
to  have  only  the  able  minority  enjoy  the  blessings  of  supra-pig  ex- 
istence. It  is  only  in  our  time  that  the  mechanical  basis  has  been 
provided  to  make  possible  a  supra-pig  existence  for  the  whole  of  human- 
ity in  all  countries  which  have  passed  out  of  a  primitive  economy. 

But  perhaps  the  most  important  consideration  is  the  conception  of  life 
on  the  supra-pig  level.  Hitherto,  we  have  imagined  that  the  really  seri- 
ous interests  and  activities  of  man  should  be  concentrated  upon  getting 
a  living,  or  amassing  material  wealth.  We  have  regarded  leisure  as  ques- 
tionable, indeed,  as  an  incitement  to  evil-doing.  We  have  looked  upon 
recreation,  the  arts,  philosophy,  and  contemplation  as  constituting  the 
mere  superficial  frills  of  life,  unworthy  of  the  serious  attention  of  earnest 
persons.  But,  when  we  look  at  the  issue  realistically,  the  efforts  to  sat- 
isfy material  necessities,  however  essential,  represent  a  relatively  low 
order  of  human  activity.  Man  shares  these  interests  and  activities  with 
the  beasts  of  the  field.  Those  things  which  set  him  off  from  the  rest  of 
the  animal  kingdom  and  constitute  uniquely  human  concerns  are  those 
matters  which  pertain  almost  exclusively  to  the  supra-pig  level.  The 
recognition  of  this  fact  and  an  extension  of  this  recognition  into  daily 
life  will  constitute  the  most  fundamental  revolution  in  the  whole  history 
of  human  culture.  It  will  also  constitute  an  unprecedented  boon  to  the 
human  race.  We  shall  devote  the  remainder  of  this  chapter  to  a  con- 
sideration of  the  achievement,  facilities,  and  prospects  of  a  supra-pig 
civilization  in  the  new  era  of  leisure  which  has  been  created  for  us  by 
the  contributions  of  our  empire  of  machines. 

Some  Phases  of  the  Evolution  of  Leisure 

Leisure  today  in  civilized  areas  is  still  based  in  part  upon  the  exploita- 
tion of  human  beings.  But  it  is  founded  primarily  upon  recent  tech- 
nological progress.  Machines  have  become  more  and  more  efficient  and 
hence  less  man-power  is  needed  to  produce  the  goods  required.  Down 


2  Ibid.,  II,  372-373. 


798          LEISURE,   RECREATION,   AND  THE  ARTS 

to  the  time  of  the  Industrial  Revolution,  leisure  was  limited  to  a  small 
group  who  obtained  it  by  the  subjugation  or  exploitation  of  the  rest  of 
the  human  race.  Above  all,  slavery  and  serfdom  were  responsible  for 
providing  most  of  the  leisure  and  luxury  enjoyed  by  the  fortunate  few 
before  our  present  mechanical  era. 

In  primitive  society,  men,  who  had  to  be  free  to  hunt  and  fight,  en- 
joyed a  considerable  freedom  from  drudgery  as  compared  with  women. 
There  is  no  special  evidence  that  the  women  resented  this  seemingly 
natural  and  desirable  division  of  labor. 

At  first  certain  professions  enjoyed  freedom  from  heavy  labor. 
Later  there  arose  whole  classes  who  were  able  to  live  handsomely,  with- 
out manual  effort.  Perhaps  the  earliest  of  the  leisure  groups  in  human 
society  were  the  priests,  who  mediated  between  the  social  groups  and  the 
supernatural  powers.  So  important  were  their  services  regarded  that 
priests  were  cheerfully  freed  from  other  responsibilities.  When  man  had 
thus  assured  his  protection  from  the  supernatural  world,  he  had  to  turn 
his  attention  to  defense  against  mortal  enemies.  This  necessity  led  to 
the  rise  of  the  warrior  class  who  were,  in  turn,  emancipated  from  manual 
effort.  Out  of  the  warrior  group  arose  the  rulers  and  the  nobility,  who 
were  able  to  escape  any  physical  effort  to  secure  material  necessities  by 
establishing  the  institution  of  slavery  and,  later,  serfdom.  Finally,  we 
find  the  scribes  and  scholars,  who,  while  they  were  not  permitted  any 
complete  idleness,  were  not  compelled  to  engage  in  manual  toil  for  their 
livelihood.  In  certain  countries,  like  ancient  China,  the  scholars  were 
so  highly  esteemed  that  they  attained  almost  to  the  level  of  the  priest- 
hood and  were  permitted  to  enjoy  a  life  of  contemplation. 

The  priests,  nobility  and  regal  circles  constituted  the  bulk  of  the  leisure 
class  down  to  the  time  of  the  Commercial  and  Industrial  Revolutions 
after  1500.  In  ancient  Rome  there  was  a  considerable  wealthy  bourgeois 
element — the  so-called  equites,  or  knights — who  had  made  their  money 
out  of  various  forms  of  commercial  effort  and  public  finance. 

With  the  Commercial  Revolution  of  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth 
centuries,  we  come  upon  the  rise  of  the  bourgeois  capitalists,  who  drew 
their  wealth  from  commercial  and  industrial  efforts.  At  first,  both  the 
merchants  and  the  industrialists  participated  personally  in  the  acqui- 
sition of  their  riches.  Though  they  might  not  indulge  in  any  manual 
work,  they  did  labor  hard  in  their  own  fields  of  endeavor..  With  the  full 
development  of  capitalism,  however,  especially  after  the  development  of 
the  corporation  and  the  separation  of  ownership  from  management,  we 
find  the  truly  leisured  bourgeoisie — the  class  of  literal  "coupon  clippers." 

Most  of  the  actual  work  in  modern  industry  and  commerce  is  carried 
on  by  engineers,  business  managers,  clerks,  and  other  functionaries.  The 
true  capitalist  simply  hands  over  his  money  to  be  invested  by  bankers 
and  brokers,  taking  little  or  no  active  part  in  the  management  of  busi- 
ness concerns.  As  we  have  already  pointed  out,  this  type  of  capitalist 
is  doubly  separated  from  active  business  endeavor.  Through  the  corpo- 
ration and  the  holding  company,  control  of  business  has  been  divorced 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         799 

from  its  ownership.  In  turn,  active  management  is  partly  divorced  from 
control.  The  actual  direction  of  industry  and  commerce  is  in  the  hands 
of  trained  business  executives.  Boards  of  directors  of  corporations 
rarely  participate  directly  in  the  details  of  business  operation.  Only 
in  the  so-called  "little  business"  do  the  owners  take  a  direct  and  imme- 
diate part  in  the  administration  of  their  concerns. 

It  cannot  be  denied  that  the  leisure  classes  in  the  past  have  been  re- 
sponsible for  most  of  what  we  ordinarily  regard  as  civilization.  The 
leisure  class  first  established  political  order  on  a  large  scale,  thus  making 
life  relatively  safe  and  insuring  some  degree  of  law  and  justice.  Their 
needs,  interests,  and  whims  led  to  great  engineering  projects,  from  the 
pyramids  of  ancient  Egypt  to  the  roads  and  aqueducts  of  Rome  and  the 
cathedrals  of  the  Middle  Ages.  The  leisure  class  has  been  the  patron  of 
art.  The  ancient  temples,  palaces,  mansions,  sculptures,  and  paintings 
were  produced  for,  and  supported  by,  those  who  enjoyed  wealth  and 
leisure.  The  same  was  true  of  learning — literature,  philosophy,  and  sci- 
ence. From  the  rites  of  the  primitive  medicine  man  to  the  great  inter- 
national state  which  was  medieval  Catholicism,  religion  has  been  in  the 
hands  of  a  leisure  group.  The  great  business  structures  of  modern 
times  have  been,  to  a  large  extent,  the  creation  of  the  bourgeois  entre- 
preneur. 

These  achievements,  however,  were  not  solely  the  product  of  the  leisure 
class.  The  actual  labor  connected  with  all  of  these  projects — the  fight- 
ing, the  government,  the  engineering,  the  artistic  achievements,  the 
philosophical  systems,  the  machines,  and  factory  administration  have 
been  carried  out  by  men  who  worked  hard.3  For  example,  the  Great 
Pyramid  of  Gizeh  contains  about  two  and  a  half  million  limestone  blocks, 
weighing  on  a  average  of  two  and  a  half  tons  each.  They  had  to  be 
dragged  in  blistering  heat  by  man-power  for  many  miles.  It  is  said  that 
100,000  men  worked  on  the  pyramid  for  twenty  years.  Though  they 
could  not  have  functioned  without  the  support  of  the  wealthy  and 
leisured,  the  men  who  wrought  these  impressive  achievements  enjoyed 
relatively  little  leisure  themselves. 

We  must  not  overlook  the  enormous  price  that  man  has  paieh  for  the 
services  rendered  by  the  wealthy.  The  slave  system  was  accompanied 
by  incredible  cruelty  and  depredation,  practiced  upon  countless  millions 
of  human  beings  who  often  led  an  existence  below  the  level  of  the  more 
fortunate  domestic  animals.  This  deplorable  situation  is  thus  described 
by  Professor  Breasted  in  writing  of  Roman  slavery: 

The  life  of  the  slaves  on  the  great  plantations  was  little  better  than  that  of 
beasts.  Worthy  and  free-born  men  from  the  eastern  Mediterranean  were  branded 
with  a  hot  iron  like  oxen,  to  identify  them  forever.  They  were  herded  at  night 
in  cellar  barracks,  and  in  the  morning  were  driven  like  half-starved  beasts  of 
burden  to  work  in  the  fields.  The  green  fields  of  Italy,  where  sturdy  farmers 
once  watched  the  growing  grain  sown  and  cultivated  by  their  own  hands,  were 


3  See  C.  0,  Ward,  The  Ancient  Lowly,  2  vols.,  Kerr,  1907. 


800          LEISURE,    RECREATION,   AND  THE  ARTS 

now  worked  by  wretched  and  hopeless  creatures  who  wished  that  they  had  never 
been  born.4 

Most  of  those  who  escaped  from  slavery  led  a  life  of  poverty  and 
misery.  It  is  probably  true  that,  down  to  our  own  day,  the  overwhelm- 
ing majority  of  men  and  women  would  have  been  better  off  if  they  had 
died  at  birth.  They  enjoyed  little  which  makes  life  truly  worth  living. 
Moreover,  the  leisure  class  has  partly  wasted  in  luxury  and  debauchery 
the  products  of  slavery  and  grinding  poverty  on  the  part  of  the  exploited 
masses.  Only  a  small  portion  of  the  wealth  created  as  a  result  of  human 
exploitation  has  gone  into  imperishable  works  of  art  or  immortal  systems 
of  philosophy.  This  luxury  and  waste  have  encouraged  and  all  too  often 
actually  caused  the  economic  ruin  of  successive  civilizations.  Through 
its  control  over  political  life,  the  leisure  class  has  been  responsible  for 
most  of  the  graft  and  incompetence  which  have  led  to  the  decay  of  king- 
doms, empires,  and  republics.  And,  if  one  adopts  a  puritanical  standard 
of  judgment,  the  leisure  class  has  been  responsible  for  most  of  the  "sin" 
which  has  existed  in  the  world,  from  the  days  of  ancient  Babylon  to  the 
Bourbon  court  of  eighteenth  century  France  and  the  cafe  society  of 
American  metropolitan  society. 

Under  modern  capitalism  the  leisure  class  has  developed  numbers, 
power,  wealth,  and  prestige  beyond  comparison  with  anything  which 
existed  in  the  pre-industrial  age.  With  the  growth  of  large  fortunes, 
there  has  come  about  a  marked  proclivity  to  attach  much  prestige  to  the 
possession  of  vast  riches  and  to  venerate  the  various  social  rites  and 
frolics  that  opulence  induces  in  conduct.5 

Of  all  these  attitudes,  none  is  more  important  than  the  element  of  "con- 
spicuous waste,"  as  a  criterion  of  the  possession  of  wealth.  Nothing  is  a 
more  dramatic  proof  of  economic  independence  than  the  ability  to  waste 
huge  sums  of  money  on  nonsocial  and  nonproductive  enterprises,  such  as 
ostentatious  dress  and  equipage,  elaborate  and  wasteful  forms  of  social 
entertainment,  and  grotesquely  pretentious  and  elaborate  dwellings. 
Above  all  stands  complete  abstinence  from  any  sign  of  manual  labor. 
Since  these  forms  of  conduct  and  such  psychic  attitudes  are  supposed  to 
characterize  the  most-to-be-envied  of  all  classes  in  modern  society,  they 
have  become  the  approved  norms  for  the  creation  of  reverence  and  defer- 
ential obeisance  on  the  part  of  the  masses. 

Along  with  this  reverence  for  the  characteristic  attitudes  and  practices 
associated  with  great  wealth  we  have  the  parallel  effort  of  the  wealthy 
to  insist  upon  the  servility  of  the  laboring  classes.  The  latter  are  stig- 
matized by  the  necessity  of  manual  labor,  in  the  same  way  that  the 
wealthy  are  distinguished  by  their  general  abstinence  from  any  such 
menial  effort.  It  has  been  possible  thus  far  to  make  the  industrial 
proletariat  defer  to  the  standards  and  tastes  of  the  wealthy  and,  at  the 


4J.  H.  Breasted,  Ancient  Times,  Ginn  and  Company,  Second  Edition,  1935,  p. 
642. 

6  See  below,  pp.  801-803,  844,  846. 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         801 

same  time,  to  accept  as  somewhat  inevitable  its  lowly  status.  It  is  true 
that  there  are  some  signs  of  a  decline  of  the  theories  and  practices  of  the 
leisure  class  among  the  more  wealthy.  There  is  also  a  growing  reluctance 
on  the  part  of  the  industrial  proletariat  to  accept  as  inevitable  their  lowly 
and  servile  station.  Nevertheless,  the  situation  described  has  prevailed 
very  generally  during  the  last  century  or  more.  In  order  to  illustrate 
more  fully  what  is  meant  by  the  theory  of  the  leisure  class  and  their 
methods  of  "honorific  consumption"  and  "conspicuous  waste,"  we  refer 
the  reader  to  an  earlier  quotation  from  Veblen's  remarkable  book  The 
Theory  of  the  Leisure  Class* 

Professor  Veblen's  abstractions  may  be  given  greater  vividness  by  the 
following  description  of  the  conspicuous  waste  practiced  by  the  American 
rich  in  the  latter  part  of  the  nineteenth  century,  taken  from  Matthew 
Josephson's  The  Robber  Barons: 

Limited  in  their  capacity  of  enjoyment  and  bored,  yet  prompted  to  outdo  each 
other  in  prodigality,  the  New  Rich  experimented  with  ever  new  patterns  or 
devices  of  consumption.  In  the  late  70's,  the  practice  of  hiring  hotel  rooms  or 
public  restaurants  for  social  functions  had  become  fashionable.  At  Delmonico's 
the  Silver,  Gold  and  Diamond  dinners  of  the  socially  prominent  succeeded  each 
other  unfailingly.  At  one,  each  lady  present,  opening  her  napkin,  found  a  gold 
bracelet  with  the  monogram  of  the  host.  At  another,  cigarettes  rolled  in  hun- 
dred-dollar-bins were  passed  around  after  the  coffee  and  consumed  with  an 
authentic  thrill.  .  .  .  One  man  gave  a  dinner  to  his  dog,  and  presented  him 
with  a  diamond  collar  worth  $15,000.  At  another  dinner,  costing  $20,000,  each 
guest  discovered  in  one  of  his  oysters  a  magnificent  black  pearl.  Another  dis- 
tracted individual  longing  for  diversion  had  little  holes  bored  into  his  teeth,  into 
which  a  tooth  expert  inserted  twin  rows  of  diamonds;  when  he  walked  abroad 
his  smile  flashed  and  sparkled  in  the  sunlight.  .  . 

As  the  years  pass  new  heights  of  fantasy  and  extravagance  are  touched.  One 
season,  it  is  a  ball  on  horseback  which  is  the  chief  sensation.  To  a  great  hotel  the 
guests  all  come  in  riding  habit;  each  of  the  handsomely  groomed  horses,  equipped 
with  rubber-padded  shoes,  prances  about  bearing  besides  its  millionaire  rider  a 
miniature  table  holding  truffles  and  champagne.  Finally  a  costume  ball  given 
by  Bradley  Martin,  a  New  York  aristocrat,  in  1897,  reached  the  very  climax  of 
lavish  expenditure  and  "dazed  the  entire  Western  world."  "The  interior  of  the 
Waldorf-Astoria  Hotel  was  transformed  into  a  replica  of  Versailles,  and  rare 
tapestries,  beautiful  flowers  and  countless  lights  made  an  effective  background  for 
the  wonderful  gowns  and  their  wearers.  .  ."  One  lady,  impersonating  Mary 
Stuart,  wore  a  gold-embroidered  gown,  trimmed  with  pearls  and  precious  stones. 
"The  suit  of  gold  inlaid  armor  worn  by  Mr.  Belmont  was  valued  at  ten  thousand 
dollars." 7 

How  the  poor  were  living  in  the  slums  of  New  York  at  the  time  is  evident 
from  the  following  case,  cited  by  Smith  Hart  in  his  The  New  Yorkers: 

In  a  dark  cellar  filled  with  smoke,  there  sleep,  all  in  one  room,  with  no  kind  of 
partition  dividing  them,  two  men  with  their  wives,  a  girl  of  thirteen  or  fourteen, 
two  men  and  a  large  boy  of  about  seventeen  years  of  age,  a  mother  with  two 


BSee  above,  pp.  192-193. 

7  Harcourt  Brace,  1934,  pp.  33&-3S9.  See  the  famous  work  of  Jacob  A.  Riis,  How 
the  Other  Half  Lives,  for  a  description  of  the  horrible  poverty  in  which  the  masses 
were  living  in  New  York  at  this  time. 


802          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

more  boys,  one  about  ten  years  old,  and  one  large  boy  of  fifteen;  another  woman 
with  two  boys,  nine  and  eleven  years  of  age — in  all  fourteen  persons.7* 

That  the  wealthy  men  of  the  late  nineteenth  century  made  any  con- 
tribution to  the  arts  and  to  civilization  at  all  commensurable  with  their 
wealth  and  economic  power  may  well  be  doubted.  The  noted  New 
England  scholar  and  publicist,  Charles  Francis  Adams,  said  of  them: 

Indeed,  as  I  approach  the  end,  I  am  more  than  a  little  puzzled  to  account  for 
the  instances  I  have  seen  of  business  success — money-getting.  It  comes  from 
rather  a  low  instinct.  Certainly  so  far  as  my  observation  goes,  it  is  scarcely 
met  with  in  combination  with  the  finer  or  more  interesting  traits  of  character. 
I  have  known,  and  known  tolerably  well,  a  great  many  "successful"  men — "big" 
financially — men  famous  during  the  last  half  century,  and  a  less  interesting  crowd 
I  do  not  care  to  encounter.  Not  one  that  I  have  ever  known  would  I  care  to 
meet  again  either  in  this  world  or  the  next ;  nor  is  one  associated  in  my  mind  with 
the  idea  of  humor,  thought  or  refinement.  A  set  of  mere  money-getters  and 
traders,  they  were  essentially  unattractive.  The  fact  is  that  money-getting  like 
everything  else  calls  for  a  special  aptitude  and  great  concentration,  and  for  it  I 
did  not  have  the  first  in  any  marked  degree,  while  to  it  I  never  gave  the  last.  So, 
in  now  summing  up,  I  may  account  myself  fortunate  in  having  got  out  of  my 
ventures  as  well  as  I  did.8 

A  similar  opinion  was  expressed  by  Theodore  Roosevelt: 

I  am  simply  unable  to  make  myself  take  the  attitude  of  respect  toward  the 
very  wealthy  men  which  such  an  enormous  multitude  of  people  evidently  really 
feel.  I  am  delighted  to  show  my  courtesy  to  Pierpont  Morgan  or  Andrew  Car- 
negie or  James  J.  Hill,  but  as  for  regarding  any  one  of  them  as,  for  instance,  I 
regard  Prof.  Bury,  or  Peary,  the  Arctic  explorer,  or  Rhodes,  the  historian — why, 
I  could  not  force  myself  to  do  it  even  if  I  wanted  to,  which  I  don't.9 

While  the  great  industrialists  and  financial  leaders  of  modern  capi- 
talism may  have  lacked  a  fine  artistic  sense  themselves,  and  while  they 
have  not  made  any  contributions  to  art  and  civilization  at  all  propor- 
tionate to  their  wealth  and  power,  they  have,  nevertheless,  made  notable  . 
additions  to  our  culture.  They  have  collected  great  paintings  from 
abroad  and  have  endowed  art  museums  in  which  to  store  and  exhibit 
them.  They  have  founded  and  endowed  many  libraries.  They  have 
given  extensively  to  higher  education,  to  scientific  foundations,  and  to 
•  various  research  enterprises.  Though  they  have  seldom  stimulated 
original  work  in  the  arts  and  scholarship,  they  have  done  much  to  make 
publicly  available  already  existing  artistic  work  and  scholarly  achieve- 
ment. But  it  must  not  be  forgotten  that  many  of  their  benefactions  have 
been  dictated  quite  as  much  by  self-interest  as  by  artistic  and  scholarly 
enthusiasm.  As  Horace  Coon  has  made  clear  in  his  penetrating  study  of 
foundations,  Money  to  Burn,  the  wealthy  have  created  their  foundations 
and  endowments  in  part  as  a  defensive  measure.  When  any  reform 
group  proposes  a  change  in  the  economic  system  or  more  drastic  taxation 
of  wealth,  it  is  at  once  alleged  that  such  persons  are  really  trying  to 


™  Lee,  Furman,  Inc.,  publishers,  1938,  p.  156. 
8  Cited  in  Josephson,  op.  cit.,  p.  338« 
»  Ibid.,  p.  337, 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         803 

destroy  art,  culture,  and  scientific  research.  We  may  now  turn  to  further 
developments  in  the  expansion  of  leisure  and  its  responsibilities. 

The  innovation  which  has  worked  by  far  the  greatest  revolution  in  the 
history  of  leisure  has  been  modern  machinery.  For  a  century  or  more 
after  the  Industrial  Revolution  new  lines  of  industry  opened  up  to  absorb 
those  thrown  out  of  work  by  mechanical  inventions.  Moreover,  the 
earlier  machines  did  not  displace  so  many  workmen  as  the  new  and  more 
efficient  machines  which  have  been  devised  since  the  World  War. 

In  1915  there  appeared  the  most  ominous  of  all  developments  in  the 
history  of  material  culture — the  automatic  continuous-process  machine 
and  factory,  capable  of  turning  out  incredible  quantities  of  identical 
products  and  adapted  to  the  production  of  everything  from  cigarettes  to 
dwelling  houses.10  In  the  first  two  industrial  revolutions  man  had  to 
watch  and  run  his  machines.  Now,  in  the  third,  he  can  have,  by  means 
of  the  photo-electric  eye,  machines  which  watch  and  run  other  machines 
or  run  themselves. 

This  colossal  new  reservoir  of  productive  capacity  has  scarcely  been 
recognized,  even  by  economic  historians.  Coupled  with  the  improba- 
bility of  any  vast  new  industries  remaining  to  be  opened  up,  it  makes  the 
probable  technological  unemployment  of  the  future  entirely  out  of  the 
range  of  comparison  with  any  in  the  past.  It  is  as  futile  to  try  to  com- 
pare the  oxcart  to  the  automobile  as  to  bring  into  comparison  technologi- 
cal unemployment  before  and  after  the  rise  of  the  automatic  machine  and 
continuous-process  factory.  Therefore,  while  technological  unemploy- 
ment has  existed  from  the  coup-de-poing  (fist  hatchet)  of  the  early  stone 
age  down  to  one  of  our  modern  match  machines,  that  which  faces  us  in 
the  future  not  only  is  different  in  degree  from  anything  in  the  past;  it 
differs  in  kind.  In  the  light  of  these  facts,  the  propagandistic  character 
of  the  arguments  of  W.  J.  Cameron,  Simeon  Strunsky,  Walter  Lippmann, 
and  others,  to  the  effect  that  the  invention  of  automatic  machinery  only 
creates  new  employment,  is  readily  apparent. 

The  rise  of  the  empire  of  machines  has  produced  a  great  revolution 
with  respect  to  the  character  of  leisure  and  the  numbers  that  participate 
therein.  Before  efficient  machines  revolutionized  industry  a  few  decades 
back,  ten,  twelve  and  even  fourteen-hour  days  were  not  uncommon. 
Only  fifty  years  ago  it  was  customary  for  store  clerks  to  work  twelve 
hours  a  day,  six  days  a  week.  When  one  of  America's  greatest  depart- 
ment stores  opened  about  sixty  years  ago  the  clerks  had  to  work  Sundays 
also,  save  for  four  hours  off  to  go  to  church.  With  the  increasing  effi- 
ciency of  machinery  in  our  day,  even  those  who  must  work  for  a  living 
generally  do  not  work  more  than  a  third  of  the  twenty-four  hours  in  each 
day.  Indeed,  if  we  employed  our  machinery  to  the  limit  of  its  potential 
productivity,  workers  would  not  need  to  be  employed  more  than  four 
hours  a  day.  However,  the  rise  of  automatic  machinery  and  other  novel- 
ties in  mechanical  efficiency,  instead  of  shortening  working  hours  all 


10  See  also  above,  pp.  95-97. 


804          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

around,  have  thrown  more  and  more  persons  out  of  work,  so  that  we  have 
a  vast  army  of  unemployed  persons  who  have  forced  upon  them  an  un- 
welcome but  complete  degree  of  leisure.  Those  not  thrown  out  of  work 
must  still  work  "full  time."  Nevertheless,  all  classes  of  people  enjoy  a 
relatively  great  amount  of  leisure,  compared  with  anything  which  has 
existed  for  the  masses  in  the  past.  And  there  is  every  prospect,  if  civi- 
lization continues,  that  this  leisure  will  grow  in  volume. 

There  is  every  probability  that  we  shall  have  far  more  startling  inven- 
tions in  the  future  than  have  taken  place  in  the  past.  These  will  greatly 
reduce  the  human  effort  needed  in  the  production  of  both  goods  and  food. 
If  we  employed  in  the  most  efficient  way  possible  the  machinery  which  is 
now  available,  we  could  certainly  produce  all  the  goods  and  food  which 
would  be  required  for  a  high  standard  of  living  with  not  more  than  15  or 
20  hours  of  work  each  week.  If  we  preserve  civilization,  we  shall  have 
to  spread  work  among  all  members  of  the  population,  giving  each  one  a 
relatively  short  working  day.  We  cannot  go  on  employing  part  of  the 
population  on  a  relatively  long  working  schedule  each  week,  leaving 
millions  of  others  in  more  or  less  complete  idleness.  A  vast  amount  of 
leisure  is  now  with  us  to  stay.  From  now  on,  one  of  the  major  tasks 
which  civilization  must  tackle  is  the  solution  of  the  problem  of  leisure. 
Thus  far,  a  demoralizing  idleness,  rather  than  a  properly  socialized 
leisure,  has  been  the  result  of  technological  advances.  But  we  must  put 
leisure  to  proper  social  uses,  since  the  majority  of  the  population  can  no 
longer  expect  to  keep  occupied  in  the  task  of  producing  goods  and  food. 

The   Ethics  of  Leisure 

There  was  little  criticism  of  leisure  and  the  leisure  classes  until  the 
end  of  the  Middle  Ages,  though  the  Catholics  did  stress  the  fact  that 
God  condemned  man  to  labor  as  a  penalty  for  original  sin.  As  empha- 
sized by  Max  Weber  and  his  disciples,  criticism  of  leisure  was  primarily 
a  contribution  of  the  Protestant  Revolution. 

One  of  the  major  influences  exerted  by  Protestantism  upon  economic  life 
and  ideas  was  the  impulse  it  gave  to  thrift,  frugality,  and  the  virtues  of 
hard  manual  work.  This  particular  impetus  came  especially  from  Calvin 
and  his  followers.  They  lifted  from  work  both  the  taint  of  servility, 
which  had  been  associated  with  it  in  classical  times,  and  the  penitential 
coloring  attached  to  it  in  medieval  Catholicism.  Calvin  vigorously  con- 
demned idleness:  "For  nothing  is  more  unseemly  than  a  man  that  is  idle 
and  good  for  nothing — who  profits  neither  himself  nor  others,  and  seems 
born  only  to  eat  and  drink.  ...  It  is  certain  that  idleness  and  in- 
dolence are  accursed  of  God."  He  held  up  to  contempt  "idle  bellies  that 
chirp  sweetly  in  the  shade."  Calvin  himself  apparently  approved  of 
work  as  a  preventive  of  sin  and  corporeal  indulgence,  quite  as  much  as  a 
means  to  economic  accumulation.  Thus,  there  sprang  up  that  persistent 
tradition  of  the  moral  and  economic  blessings  of  gruelling  toil  which 
pervaded  modern  times.  When  the  bourgeoisie  later  became  wealthy, 
they  conveniently  found  work  a  virtue  chiefly  for  the  employee  class. 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         805 

It  is  obvious  that  the  Calvinistic  emphasis  upon  the  virtue  of  hard 
work  was  partly  theological  and  partly  economic.  This  attitude  was 
brought  over  into  American  tradition  by  writers  like  Benjamin  Franklin. 
It  gained  wide  acceptance  in  this  country,  not  only  because  of  our 
Protestant  heritage,  but  also  because  the  doctrine  fitted  in  very  well  as  a 
religious  and  ethical  justification  of  the  hard  work  required  to  conquer 
the  American  continent.  That  this  philosophy  of  life  is  still  popular  and 
respectable  in  American  circles  can  be  seen  from  the  following  statement 
by  Gus  W.  Dyer  of  Vanderbilt  University,  taken  from  an  article  syn- 
dicated in  American  newspapers  early  in  1939.  Professor  Dyer  was  issu- 
ing an  implied  warning  that  we  are  reverting  to  paganism  in  our  new 
respect  for  leisure: 

The  Christian  theory  of  life  is  the  very  opposite  of  the  Pagan.  It  puts  the 
emphasis  on  giving,  not  receiving,  on  serving,  not  on  being  served.  Tne  great 
man,  the  man  who  has  found  life  in  the  greatest  abundance  is  the  prime  minister, 
the  greatest  worker.  Work  is  divine.  God  is  revealed  as  the  great  worker,  and 
it  is  through  work  that  men  become  like  God.  It  is  through  work  that  man 
finds  his  life,  and  his  life  is  measured  by  his  work.  Business  is  a  means  by  which 
men  exchange  usefulness.  In  the  exchange  of  commodities  and  services  both 
parties  are  benefited,  both  parties  profit.  The  more  a  man  gives  the  more  he 
receives.  The  abundant  life  is  a  by-product  of  hard  work,  or  services  given  to 
others.  To  run  away  from  work  is  to  run  away  from  life.  To  repudiate  work 
is  to  commit  suicide.  It  is  through  work  that  individuals  and  nations  grow 
strong  and  invincible. 

From  the  beginning  of  our  history  down  to  a  few  years  ago  the  rank  and  file 
of  the  American  citizens  regarded  hard  work  not  only  as  a  duty  but  also  as  an 
honor.  The  hard  worker  was  a  man  of  distinction  in  his  community.  They  had 
little  respect  for  a  man  who  tried  to  avoid  work,  and  had  a  contempt  for  a  man, 
able  to  work,  who  looked  to  the  government  to  support  him.  They  found  their 
lives  and  grew  strong  through  hard  constructive  work,  through  constructive  serv- 
ice to  their  families,  their  communities  and  to  their  country.  They  accepted  it  as 
their  duty  to  support  the  government  from  their  earnings  in  all  of  its  constitu- 
tional, legitimate  activities,  but  they  scorned  the  idea  of  degrading  themselves 
and  sacrificing  their  independence  by  looking  to  the  government  to  give  them  any 
special  aid. 

It  was  the  proud  boast  of  Americans  up  to  a  few  years  ago  that  the  average 
American  working  man  did  a  third  more  work  than  any  other  average  working 
man  in  the  world.  It  was  the  American  ideal  of  work  based  on  the  Christian 
theory  of  life  that  made  us  invincible  in  the  past.  Shall  we  give  it  up,  "lean 
on  the  shovel,"  and  revert  to  the  destructive  theory  of  ancient  paganism? 

In  the  middle  of  the  nineteenth  century  the  notion  that  work  is  virtu- 
ous was  emphasized  from  the  standpoint  of  aesthetics  by  Thomas  Carlyle, 
John  Ruskin,  William  Morris,  and  others.  They  emphasized  the  element 
of  craftsmanship,  holding  that  every  man  should  spend  part  of  each  day 
in  manual  labor  and  find  some  satisfaction  in  turning  out  a  worth-while 
piece  of  work.  In  our  own  day,  writers  on  leisure  have  adopted  this  point 
of  view  as  a  means  of  solving  the  problem  of  leisure  rather  than  as  a 
justification  of  hard  work. 

It  is  quite  obvious  that  hard  manual  work  is  in  itself  no  virtue  what- 
ever. Productive  work,, at  the  best,  can  only  furnish  us  with  the  material 
basis  for  truly  human  achievements  on  the  supra-pig  level.  The  less 


806         LEISURE,  RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

time  we  have  to  devote  to  the  problems  of  making  a  living,  the  more  we 
shall  have  to  give  to  those  things  which  make  living  worth  while.  Some 
writers  on  leisure  today  have  gone  to  the  opposite  extreme  from  the 
attitude  of  Calvin,  Franklin,  and  others,  and  have  frankly  and  enthusi- 
astically defended  the  virtues  of  freedom  from  drudgery.  This  point  of 
view  has  been  forcefully  expressed  by  Lawrence  Conrad  in  an  article  on 
"The  Worthy  Use  of  Leisure,"  in  the  Forum.  Mr.  Conrad  points  out  that 
our  forebears  struggled  to  conquer  work  and  to  gain  freedom  from 
drudgery: 

Our  progenitors  for  thousands  of  years  had  yearned  towards  that  moment 
when  we  could  have  leisure.  The  leisure  they  pictured  was  not  a  turning  from 
band  to  gusset  and  from  gusset  to  seam.  It  was  unalloyed  leisure,  freedom  from 
compulsion.  What  they  had  in  mind  was  a  shedding  of  ball  and  chain;  a  libera- 
tion of  the  fancy  of  humanity;  a  surging  up  of  dreams  and  visions.  They  pic- 
tured man,  the  conqueror,  searching  time  and  space  for  the  signs  of  his  further 
destiny.11 

But  as  we  reach  out  to  profit  by  the  millenniums  of  toil  of  our  ancestors 
in  the  quest  of  freedom  from  drudgery,  we  are  being  captured  by  those 
who  hold  that  we  shall  be  ruined  unless  our  use  of  leisure  is  "worthy": 

At  just  that  moment  another  crowd  came  along  and  said:  "Get  up  and  get 
busy.  Did  you  think  that  you  could  be  idle  during  this  rest  period?  Not  at 
all.  The  factory  is  closed;  we  have  let  you  out  from  there.  But  we  have 
work  for  you  to  do.  You  must  take  piano  lessons,  or  start  a  stamp  collection, 
or  read  the  book-of-the-month,  or  attend  a  lecture.  This  is  for  your  own  good." 

So  goes  modern  life.  Our  educational  leaders  would  march  us  from  the  factory 
to  the  public  library,  then  on  through  the  art  museum  and  the  lecture  hall,  and 
on  to  our  night  school  classes,  and  then  home  to  our  book-of-the-month.  And 
so  to  bed.  So  strong  a  prejudice  has  been  aroused  against  standing  still  or  sitting 
still  that  we  have  all  of  us  come  to  a  place  where  we  start  guiltily  when  we  are 
discovered  doing  nothing.  "What!  No  tools  in  your  hands?  You  ought  to  be 
ashamed!"  And  we  are  ashamed. 

Lincoln,  sitting  on  a  cracker  barrel  in  a  country  store,  would  be  given  some- 
thing important  to  dp.  Daydreaming  has  become  a  grievous  sin.  Dawdling, 
which  is  one  of  the  sweetest  of  all  human  pastimes,  has  been  blotted  out.  You 
never  see  a  whittlcr  in  these  days,  just  plain  whittling.12 

Mr.  Conrad  believes  that  the  movement  for  "worthy"  use  of  leisure  is 
robbing  us  of  the  enjoyment  of  our  new  found  freedom  from  work: 

As  a  people  we  grow  disaffected  and  sour.  Standing  in  front  of  the  polar  bear 
cage  for  the  hundredth  time,  or  in  front  of  the  "Fifteenth  Century  Knight  in 
Armor,"  we  turn  the  thing  over  in  our  minds.  Somehow  we  have  a  feeling  that, 
left  to  ourselves,  we  could  figure  out  a  better  way  to  spend  our  time. 

Unless  human  beings  can  feel  free  to  explore  their  leisure  as  individuals,  each 
one  finding  in  it  his  own  most  gratifying  compensation  for  a  life  of  toil,  then  there 
is  no  good  in  the  fevered  striving  by  which  it  was  earned,  and  there  is  no  use  in 
our  trying  to  increase  it  for  posterity. 

No  two  of  us  would  be  quite  alike  in  our  taste  for  leisure.  Each  person  would 
have  his  own  separate  mode  of  vagrancy.  Should  each  individual  follow  his  own 
bent  and  take  his  own  special  kind  of  reward  for  labor,  our  whole  social  order 

11  November,  1931. 


LEISURE,    RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS          807 

might  come  to  be  sprinkled  through  once  more  with  that  most  priceless  element 
the  world  has  ever  lost — namely,  interesting  human  beings.18 

One  may  not  go  quite  as  far  as  Mr.  Conrad  but  his  position  illustrates 
the  change  of  attitude  which  has  arisen  in  the  present  century.  It  is 
certainly  far  sounder  than  the  Calvinistic  point  of  view  and  more  in 
harmony  with  the  trends  and  requirements  of  our  day.  We  shall  con- 
sider this  problem  of  the  ethics  of  leisure  in  the  next  section,  dealing  with 
some  leading  social  and  psychological  aspects  of  leisure  in  the  machine 
era. 

Some  Outstanding  Social  and  Psychological  Phases 
of  the  Problem  of  Leisure 

There  is  no  dodging  the  immediate  and  vital  significance  of  the  problem 
of  leisure  in  the  twentieth  century.  Before  the  problem  can  be  attacked 
in  an  intelligent  fashion  we  must  bring  about  such  a  reconstruction  of 
our  economic  society  as  will  put  an  end  to  widespread  unemployment  and 
idleness.  Such  work  as  needs  to  be  done  in  a  mechanical  era  must  be 
spread,  so  that  everyone  may  do  his  share,  however  small  the  amount  of 
time  involved  in  actual  manual  effort.  Man  is  so  constituted  that  he 
likes  to  do  some  work  and  be  self-supporting.  Despite  much  banter  to 
the  contrary,  information  collected  on  the  attitudes  of  WPA  and  especially 
CWA  workers  made  it  clear  that  they  hated  to  be  forced  to  dawdle  along 
and  loaf  on  the  job  to  spread  work.  They  preferred  to  be  "overworked" 
in  private  industry.  Social  workers  have  also  frequently  reported  on  the 
slow  physical  and  mental  degeneration  of  heads  of  families  when  forced 
to  remain  idle  on  relief. 

Yet,  even  if  we  do  spread  work  and  bring  about  other  reforms  so  that 
the  full  benefits  of  the  machine  will  go  to  all,  we  shall  still  have  the 
problem  of  leisure  to  solve.  Until  we  deal  with  it  effectively,  the  un- 
precedented amount  of  leisure  time  will,  as  Dr.  L.  P.  Jacks  points  out, 
only  result  in  idleness,  stagnation,  and  the  decay  of  personality  and 
cultural  life: 

Men  have  always  desired  leisure.  They  are  now  threatened  with  more  of  it 
than  their  education  has  fitted  them  for  dealing  with,  more  than  nature  intended 
them  to  have,  more  than  they  are,  as  yet,  capable  of  enjoying  or  making  use 
of.  ... 

The  centre  of  our  social  problem  is  passing  rapidly  to  the  leisure  end  of  life, 
the  end  where  consumption  rather  than  production  is  the  outstanding  feature, 
and  it  is  precisely  in  regard  to  consumption  that  our  lack  of  preparation  for  life, 
or  of  education  for  it,  is  most  pronounced.  The  applications  of  science  are  almost 
entirely  confined  to  the  producing  or  working  end  of  industry;  our  technological 
and  vocational  systems  of  education  have  the  same  objective  and  the  same  appli- 
cations; while  the  consuming  process,  especially  that  part  of  it  which  goes  on  at 
the  leisure  end,  is  abandoned  to  caprice,  to  lawlessness,  to  the  inroad  of  new 
desires  and  fashions  uncontrolled  by  any  sort  of  scientific  guidance.14 


is  Ibid. 

14  The  New  York  Times  Magazine,  July  5,  1931,  p.  6. 


808          LEISURE,   RECREATION,   AND  THE  ARTS 

As  Dr.  Jacks  does  well  to  emphasize,  this  problem  of  leisure  is  no 
superficial  fancy  of  the  social  dilettante,  but  a  vital  issue  upon  which  the 
very  future  of  human  civilization  literally  depends.  Unless  we  work  out 
plans  which  bring  the  uses  of  leisure  into  harmony  with  the  nature  and 
needs  of  man,  the  collapse  of  our  culture  is  inevitable: 

And  the  question  immediately  arises — perhaps  the  most  serious  question  now 
confronting  our  civilization — what  are  people  in  general  going  to  do  with  leisure? 
Will  they  take  as  the  model  for  their  leisure  the  sort  of  life  now  most  favored  by 
the  "idle  rich" — for  there  are  such  people,  though  not  all  who  receive  the  name 
deserve  it — and  get  as  much  of  that  sort  of  thing  as  their  means  enable  them  to 
procure,  display,  luxurious  feeding,  sex  excitement,  gambling,  bridge,  golf,  globe- 
trotting and  the  rest;  the  life  which  gets  itself  portrayed  in  "magazines  of  fash- 
ion" and  furnishes  not  a  few  of  our  people  with  the  only  idea  they  have  of 
heaven?  Or  will  they  spend  it  in  the  way  the  idle  poor,  by  whom  I  moan  the 
unemployed,  are  now  spending  the  leisure  forced  on  them  by  the  industrial  crisis, 
which  consists,  for  the  most  part,  in  just  stagnating,  physically,  mentally  and 
morally?  Or  will  it  be  a  mixture  of  the  two — stagnation  relieved  by  whatever 
doses  of  external  excitement  people  may  have  the  cash  to  purchase? 

If  the  corning  leisure  of  mankind  is  to  be  spent  in  any  one  of  these  ways,  I 
have  no  hesitation  in  predicting  that  our  civilization  will  go  to  the  devil  and  go 
there,  most  probably,  to  the  tune  of  revolution.  Human  beings  are  biologically 
unfitted  for  a  mode  of  existence  framed  on  those  lines  and  inevitably  degenerate 
and  finally  perish,  by  the  process  of  revolutionary  self-destruction,  when  they 
adopt  it.15 

There  are  today  in  current  discussion  of  the  problems  of  leisure  two 
rather  divergent  attitudes  toward  the  problem.  One  is  the  so-called 
biological  theory,  which  defends  the  position  that  a  rational  leisure  must 
be  intimately  'associated  with  productive  work,  which  is  made  pleasant 
and  rational.  This  attitude  toward  the  problem  is  presented  by  Floyd 
H.  Allport,  in  an  article,  "This  Coming  Era  of  Leisure." 16  Professor  All- 
port  thus  expounds  and  defends  his  approach  to  the  problem  of  leisure: 

According  to  the  first  of  these,  which  I  shall  call  the  biological  theory,  work 
and  play  cannot  be  sharply  separated.  Leisure  is  not  so  much  a  time  of  freedom 
from  the  tasks  we  have  to  do,  but  the  lighter  and  more  enjoyable  aspects  of  those 
tasks.  Advocates  of  biological  leisure  are  interested  in  increasing  not  the  amount 
of  time  in  which  our  bodies  shall  be  free  from  all  productive  labor,  but  rather  the 
enjoyment  of  productive  activities  themselves,  once  they  are  released  from  strain, 
monotony,  accident,  and  disease.  Hence  the  advocate  of  biological  leisure  would 
use  machinery  and  applied  science  not  primarily  to  replace  human  work,  but  to 
render  the  organism  as  it  performs  its  tasks  more  healthy  and  secure.  He  aims 
for  a  wholesome  balance  between  expenditure  of  energy  and  the  variety,  rest, 
and  recreation  necessary  to  keep  the  organism  fit.  His  goal  is  not  more  efficient 
machinery,  but  more  efficient  men  and  women;  and  by  this  he  means  greater 
efficiency  not  for  their  employers,  but  for  themselves.  .  .  . 

Now  it  is  the  proposal  of  the  technological  leisurist  to  undermine  all  this 
process  of  learning  and  acquiring  interests  by  satisfying  all  organic  needs  in 
advance  and  with  only  a  minimum  of  routine  action  upon  the  part  of  the  indi- 
vidual. Such  learning  and  work  as  will  be  required  will  be  of  a  listless,  stereo- 
typed sort,  unrelated  to  the  biological  structure  or  the  emotional  equipment  of 


™lbid.    See  also  L.  P.  Jacks,  "The  Saving  Forces  of  Our  Civilization,"  in  The 
New  York  Times  Magazine,  November  8,  1931. 
*6  Harper's,  November,  1931. 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,   AND  THE  ARTS          809 

the  worker.  Work  will  require  only  the  repetitive  running  of  machines  and  not 
the  continuous  and  increasing  development  of  bodily  skills.  Its  pattern  will  be 
laid  down  by  another,  not  planned  by  ourselves.  Except  for  the  few  contrivers 
of  remaining  inventions,  it  will  offer  no  stimulus  of  social  recognition.  There 
will  be  little  likelihood  of  developing  the  natural  gifts  which  are  peculiar  to  indi- 
viduals; for  a  system  which  runs  with  perfect  precision  can  be  no  respecter  of 
persons.  Considered  as  a  means  of  developing  human  potentialities,  the  life- 
supporting  work  of  the  world  will  have  to  be  written  off  as  a  total  loss. 

But  worse  than  that,  since  work,  through  its  connection  with  organic  adjust- 
ment, is  the  primary  activity  through  which  interest  can  be  elicited,  its  separa- 
tion from  the  rest  of  life  would  leave  the  organism  listless  and  cold.  It  would 
not  merely  destroy  the  possibility  of  special  lines  of  interest,  but  would  threaten 
the  experience  of  interest  itself.  The  spoon-feeding  sometimes  practiced  upon 
children  of  wealthy  parents  would  then  be  extended  to  humanity  at  large.  We 
should  be  like  children  for  whom  have  been  provided  a  corps  of  mechanical  serv- 
ants even  more  prompt  and  efficient  than  misguided  parents;  we  should  be  in 
danger  of  becoming  a  race  of  morons  well  fitted  to  enjoy  the  age  of  the  perfect 
labor-saving  machine. 

The  goal  of  the  elimination  of  labor  or  the  separation  of  it  from  the  so-called 
higher  activities,  is,  as  a  working  philosophy,  fundamentally  wrong.  Its  fallacy 
lies  in  the  ignoring  of  human  nature  and  the  assumption  that,  by  sheer  inventive 
genius,  man  can  rise  to  heights  in  which  he  will  be  more  than,  or  at  least  different 
from,  man.  In  conquering  nature  about  us  we  are  on  the  verge  of  denying 
human  nature.17 

At  the  opposite  extreme  from  this  biological  theory  of  work  and  leisure 
presented  by  Professor  Allport,  we  find  the  so-called  technological  or 
sociological  conception  of  leisure  and  its  uses.  According  to  this  point  of 
view,  work,  in  the  sense  of  the  drudgery  necessary  to  produce  the  material 
needs  of  mankind,  is  a  necessary  evil,  a  social  nuisance  which  we  should 
get  rid  of  so  far  as  possible  by  utilizing  machinery.  This  attitude  has 
been  formulated  by  Henry  Pratt  Fairchild  in  an  article,  "Exit  the  Gospel 
of  Work."  18  Professor  Fairchild  calls  attention  to  the  tremendous  trans- 
formation in  the  status  of  work  which  has  come  about  as  a  result  of  the 
mechanical  inventions  of  the  last  50  years: 

For  about  999,950  years  the  chief  preoccupation  of  man  has  been  getting  a 
living.  The  bare  task  of  keeping  soul  and  body  together,  and  providing  himself 
with  a  few  simple  comforts  and  an  occasional  modest  luxury  or  two,  has  en- 
grossed his  entire  time  and  energy.  The  one  imperious  demand  that  Nature 
made  of  him  was  work.  There  was  a  direct  and  conspicuous  relationship  be- 
tween the  amount  of  work  he  did  and  his  chance  of  survival,  not  to  speak  of  any 
positive  enjoyment  or  contentment.  Society  needed  the  full  output  of  produc- 
tive energy  of  every  one  of  its  adult  members,  however  unevenly  the  product 
of  that  energy  may  have  been  distributed.  Starvation  was  never  far  from  the 
lower  classes,  want  from  the  middle  groups,  or  privation  from  the  privileged. 
Famine  was  something  more  than  a  remote  possibility.  During  this  long  period 
the  utility  of  work  was  so  great  that  reverence  for  it  became  so  thoroughly  in- 
grained in  human  nature  as  to  seem  almost  instinctive,  and  social  sanctions  in 
favor  of  work  were  developed  of  the  most  imperious  character. 

Now,  within  the  last  fifty  years,  man  suddenly  finds  himself  possessed  of  a 
productive  mechanism  so  capacious  and  competent  that  if  he  expend^  his  habitual 
amount  of  work  on  it  it  will  swamp  him  with  more  goods  than  he  has  the  ability 


"Loc.  cit.,  pp.  642-643,  64&-650, 
i*  Harper's,  April,  1931, 


610          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

to  grapple  with.  No  wonder  many  of  his  traditional  values  seem  all  awry!  No 
wonder  he  stands  trembling,  bemused,  awestruck  before  his  own  devices,  the  wise 
use  of  which  defies  his  intelligence,  the  power  of  which  far  outstrips  his  ability 
to  control.10 

This  thoroughgoing  revolution  in  the  status  and  necessity  of  work 
renders  necessary  and  desirable  a  comparable  alteration  in  our  perspec- 
tive toward  work  and  leisure  in  the  contemporary  age: 

What  is  needed  is  obviously  a  revolution  in  some  of  our  basic  philosophies  of 
life.  First  of  all,  as  already  intimated,  we  must  have  a  complete  reversal  of  our 
characteristic  attitude  toward  economic  activities.  The  god  of  work  must  be 
cast  down  from  his  ancient  throne,  and  the  divinity  of  enjoyment  put  in  his  place. 
We  must  learn  that  consumption  is  the  only  justification  and  guide  of  production. 
We  must  learn  that  consumption  requires  the  same  scientific  study  and  research 
that  we  have  so  generously  lavished  on  production.  We  must  develop  a  technic 
of  consumption.  .  .  . 

Along  with  this,  we  must  have  a  new  philosophy  of  work.  Work  must  be 
recognized  not  as  a  virtue  or  a  blessing,  but  as  an  intrinsic  evil.  The  only  justifi- 
cation for  work  is  its  product.  .  .  . 

We  must,  most  emphatically  of  all,  have  a  new  philosophy  of  idleness — or 
rather,  we  must  substitute  for  the  present  philosophy  of  idleness  a  sound  and 
comprehensive  philosophy  of  leisure  time.  We  must  come  to  realize  that  leisure 
time,  that  is,  time  spent  in  pleasurable  employment,  is  the  only  kind  of  time  that 
makes  life  worth  living.  All  other  time  is  tolerable  only  as  it  contributes  to  the 
richness  and  developmental  content  of  our  leisure.  But,  of  course,  leisure,  to  be 
itself  tolerable,  must  be  immeasurably  more  than  mere  idleness.  Leisure  time 
should  mean  the  opportunity  for  all  those  pursuits  that  really  contribute  to  the 
realization  and  enlargement  of  personality.20 

The  adoption  of  this  attitude  implies  that  all  socially  unnecessary  work 
should  be  dispensed  with: 

In  the  new  day  work  must  not  only  not  be  encouraged  but  not  permitted  unless 
there  is  some  positive  and  demonstrable  social  good  to  be  derived  from  it.  Work 
is  too  potent  a  thing  to  be  indulged  in  irresponsibly.  We  can't  allow  people  to 
go  about  working  at  their  own  sweet  will.  .  .  . 

When  mechanization  has  been  carried  to  its  ultimate  perfection  there  will  be  so 
little  of  routine  production  left  for  human  hands  and  minds  to  do  that  in  all  prob- 
ability there  will  be  actual  competition  for  the  doing  of  it  for  its  own  sake,  for 
the  interest,  variety,  and  stimulation  that  it  has  to  offer.21 

If  such  changes  are  brought  into  being,  our  leisure  will  no  longer  be 
contaminated  by  any  hangover  of  the  punitive  philosophy  that  stresses 
the  nobility  of  drudgery.  Our  time  will  veritably  be  free  for  creative 
endeavor  on  the  supra-pig  level  of  achievement: 

Thus  the  distinction  between  work  and  recreation  will  at  last  be  wiped  out 
altogether.  Everyone  will  be  left  free  for  genuinely  creative  activities.  Type 
will  still  be  set,  clothes  made,  furniture  built,  gardens  planted,  and  ditches  dug 
by  hand.  But  these  things  will  be  done  in  just  the  same  spirit  as  now  pictures 
are  painted,  songs  sung,  and  doilies  embroidered — for  the  delight  and  pleasure  in 
doing  them,  for  the  expression  and  development  of  personality.  Few  enjoyments 
are  higher  than  those  which  come  from  impressing  one's  own  individuality  upon 


19  Fairchild,  loc.  rit.,  p.  567. 

20  Ibid.,  pp.  570,  571-572. 

.,  pp.  571,  573, 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         811 

a  material  medium,  especially  if  it  be  in  measurably  permanent  form.  Mankind 
is  endowed  with  limitless  capacities  for  creating  beautiful  and  useful  things  in 
varied  and  individual  forms.  The  men  of  the  future — and  not  such  a  distant 
future,  either — will  devote  themselves  to  these  and  kindred  pursuits,  and  will  look 
back  upon  their  ancestors  who  spent  their  time  and  energy  in  the  routine  pro- 
duction of  standardized,  conventional,  and  largely  superfluous  material  objects  in 
much  the  same  attitude  with  which  we  regard  the  savages  who  knock  out  their 
teeth,  brand  their  skin,  or  cut  off  the  joints  of  their  fingers  for  some  traditional 
reason  that  they  do  not  even  think  of  trying  to  understand,  but  just  blindly 
obey.22 

Dr.  Jacks  suggests  an  approach  to  the  problem  of  leisure  which  seeks 
to  effect  a  compromise  between  the  interpretations  offered  by  Professors 
Allport  and  Fairchild: 

Man  is  a  skill-hungry  animal,  hungry  for  skill  in  his  body,  hungry  fqr  skill  in 
his  mind,  and  never  satisfied  until  that  skill-hunger  is  appeased.  After  all,  what 
a  discontented  miserable  animal  man  is  until  he  gets  some  kind  of  satisfaction  for 
this  skill-hunger  that  is  in  him!  Self-activity  in  skill  and  creation  is  the  sum- 
mary mark  of  human  nature  from  childhood  right  on  up  until  man's  arteries 
begin  to  ossify.23 

If  our  solution  of  the  problem  of  leisure  is  to  be  successful  and  a  real 
asset  to  man  and  society,  its  exploitation  must  fully  satisfy  the  basic 
human  drive  for  creative  activity: 

The  happiness  that  man's  nature  demands  and  craves  for  is  impossible  until 
the  creative  part  of  him  is  awakened,  until  his  skill-hunger  is  satisfied.  Man's 
happiness,  the  happiness  for  which  he  was  created,  comes  from  within  himself. 
Till  then,  and  till  his  happiness  begins  to  well  up  from  within  through  this  self- 
active,  creative  life,  man  is  living  on  a  starvation  diet;  he  is  devitalized;  he  is  in 
low  condition;  he  is  wanting  in  mind  and  body.  Created  for  the  enjoyment  of 
happiness,'  yes,  but  on  those  terms  no  amount  of  ready-made  pleasures  purchased 
pn  the  market,  no  intensity  of  external  excitement,  will  ever  compensate  for  the 
loss  of  creative  impulse,  or  for  the  starvation  of  his  essential  nature  as  a  skill- 
hungry  being.  That  is  a  fundamental  truth,  and  to  me  there  is  no  truth  about 
human  nature  that  I  find  more  certain,  more  important,  more  vital,  whenever 
the  education  of  human  beings,  either  of  children  or  adults,  is  in  question.24 

In  an  illuminating  article  on  'The  Problems  of  Leisure," 25  George  A. 
Lundberg  suggests  that  it  is  high  time  that  the  social  sciences  began  to 
devote  attention  to  the  problems  and  activities  of  leisure.  Play  and 
various  types  of  art  must  occupy  our  attention  in  periods  of  leisure,  now 
that  work  is  becoming  increasingly  unnecessary  during  a  considerable 
period  of  time  each  day.  Play  and  art  can  both  take  care  of  our  leisure 
time  needs  and  satisfy  that  craving  for  skill-expression  which  Dr,  Jacks 
has  correctly  emphasized: 

The  social  sciences  are  devoted  to  the  study  of  group  behaviour — what  people 
do.  Now  it  happens  that  among  the  various  activities  in  which  man  engages — 
political,  economic,  etc. — are  certain  activities  which  we  call  play,  recreation, 


22  Ibid.,  p.  573. 

23  L.  P.  Jacks,  Today's  Unemployment  and  Tomorrow's  Leisure   (reprinted  from 
Recreation,  December,  1931),  p.  6. 

24  Ibid. 

25  Sociology  and  Social  Research,  May-June,  1933. 


812         LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

artistic,  or  more  generally,  "leisure"  pursuits.  These  activities  are  present  as 
universally,  have  as  long  a  history,  and  presumably  have  behind  them  as  deep- 
seated  biological  drives  as  any  of  the  others.  All  behaviour  is  the  result  of  the 
organism  struggling  to  make  an  adjustment  of  some  sort.  Play,  painting,  danc- 
ing, and  singing  are  basically  just  as  truly  responses  to  organic  needs  as  are 
hunting,  farming,  or  withdrawing  one's  hand  from  the  fire.  From  this  point  of 
view,  play  and  artistic  behaviour  are  as  proper  subject  matter  for  scientific  study 
as  any  other  phases  of  human  activity.26 

In  the  civilization  which  lies  ahead  of  us,  which  is  bound  to  be  charac- 
terized by  both  greater  leisure  and  a  more  secular  point  of  view,  aesthetics 
may  become  the  chief  objective  of  human  life,  as  theology  was  in  the 
Middle  Ages.  We  shall  be  concerned  primarily  with  becoming  Jiappy 
here  and  now,  rather  than  saving  our  souls  in  a  future  life: 

There  is  no  reason,  therefore,  why  man  in  a  social  order  less  preoccupied  than 
the  present  with  the  maldistribution  of  wealth,  should  not  turn  his  intellectual 
activities  upon,  say,  aesthetics,  just  as  under  other  conditions  he  has  turned  them 
on  theology.  The  starting  points  and  sequences  of  modern  science  have  had,  and 
still  have,  their  justification.  But  other  equally  valid  thought-patterns  might 
conceivably  be  constructed  from  other  starting  points  with  other  sequences  in 
other  directions.  .  .  . 

It  is  conceivable  that  under  another  system  of  ideals  and  education  men  might 
prefer  to  utilize  at  least  part  of  the  leisure  which  the  machine  has  won  for  them 
in  some  form  of  self-activity  which  would  not  greatly  affect  economic  production 
of  profits.  We  might,  for  example,  hold  up  what  men  are  rather  than  what  they 
buy  as  a  standard  of  worth.  On  this  theory  the  greatest  satisfactions  of  life  as 
well  as  the  best  balanced  personalities  come  from  the  acquisition  and  exercise  of 
skills  of  various  sorts  not  necessarily  of  economic  significance.  The  consumption 
of  blue  sky,  sunshine,  and  sylvan  solitude,  or  the  amateur  dabbling  in  the  fine 
arts  is  of  this  nature.  Merely  as  a  method  of  killing  time  and  consuming  ener- 
gies it  may  be  no  more  absorbing  than  the  frantic  game  of  keeping  up  with  the 
Joneses.  The  justification  for  this  substitute,  therefore,  must  be  based  on  other 
grounds.  We  must  show  that  this  substitute  is  in  some  way  more  compatible 
with  man's  biological  nature  and  that  its  indulgence  contributes  more  to  that 
balance  and  integration  of  personality  which  is  generally  recognized  as  desirable 
— the  opposite  of  the  enormous  numbers  of  mental  cases  in  and  out  of  our 
asylums.27 

Leisure  and  Recreation 

We  have  already  suggested  that  play  and  the  arts  will  have  to  provide 
for  most  of  our  activity  in  the  future.  We  have  seen  that  Professor  All- 
port  and  those  who  hold  to  the  biological  theory  of  leisure  contend  that, 
work  and  play  should  remain  closely  interrelated.  There  is  something 
to  be  said  for  this  point  of  view,  especially  along  the  line  of  making 
necessary  work  more  pleasant  to  human  beings  and  less  disastrous  in  its 
effect  on  the  human  personality.  But  the  period  in  which  we  can  work 
at  all  is  bound  to  become  shorter  and  shorter.  So,  even  the  most  pleasur- 
able work  cannot  occupy  much  of  our  time.  The  problem  of  leisure 


28  Loc.  cit.,  p.  5. 
27Lundberg,  "T 
573-574;  and  Leisure:  A  Suburban  Study,  Columbia  University  Press,  1934,  Chap! 


27Lundberg,  "Training  Jor  Leisure,"   Teacher's  College  Record,  April,   1933,  pp. 

i.  I. 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         813 

would  still  remain.  And,  certainly  little  can  be  said  for  the  theory, 
popular  in  some  quarters,  that  play  should  be  made  laborious.  As  Pro- 
fessor Lundberg  has  suggested,  the  very  idea  of  slavish  pleasures  is  a 
misnomer.  Even  though  the  populace  should  take  a  far  greater  interest 
in  artistic  activity  than  it  does  today,  we  are  bound  to  have  more  and 
more  time  which  we  must  devote  to  some  form  of  playful  activity. 
Hence  the  problem  of  play  and  recreation  is  a  significant  one. 

Perhaps  as  good  a  definition  of  play  as  any  is  offered  by  S.  L.  Pressy, 
namely,  that  play  is  "those  things  which  individuals  do  simply  because 
they  want  to."  This  view  of  play  harmonizes  with  both  the  older  notion 
that  play  is  simply  a  natural  form  of  human  expression  and  the  newer 
attempts  to  find  a  definite  psychological  explanation  of  play  and  its 
personal  and  social  functions. 

During  the  nineteenth  century,  various  sociologists,  psychologists,  and 
educators  brought  forward  scientific  theories  of  play.  These  have  been 
summarized  by  Edward  S.  Robinson.28  The  sociologist,  Herbert  Spencer, 
held  that  play  is  a  form  of  activity  which  results  from  the  necessity  of 
discharging  surplus  nervous  energy.  He  also  suggested  that  imitation 
has  a  large  function  in  playful  activities,  a  notion  which  was  more  elabo- 
rately developed  by  the  French  writer  Gabriel  Tarde.  The  psychologist, 
Moritz  Lazarus,  suggested  a  theory  of  play  which  has  received  wide 
acceptance.  He  was  father  of  the  notion  that  play  constitutes  a  funda- 
mental form  of  recreation  for  the  human  being.  It  provides  the  natural 
recovery  from  over-activity  and  fatigue.  It  is  truly  recreative,  in  that 
it  provides  an  alternative  form  of  activity  which  is  more  stimulating  than 
sheer  rest  and  immobility. 

Another  psychologist,  Karl  Groos,  who  made  elaborate  studies  of  the 
play  of  both  animals  and  men,  offered  a  sociological  and  pedagogical 
conception  of  play.  He  held  that  play  is  fundamentally  a  preparation 
for  adult  life,  in  which  the  natural  instincts  in  man  are  socialized  in  such 
a  fashion  as  to  be  adapted  to  the  requirements  of  the  life  of  an  adult  in 
a  social  group.  He  also  emphasized  the  cathartic  function  of  play, 
namely,  that  play  permits  us  to  work  off  pent-up  emotions  and  surplus 
energy.  Lilla  Appleton,  after  making  a  study  of  play  among  both 
savages  and  civilized  mankind,  maintained  that  the  forms  of  play  have  a 
definite  physical  basis,  associated  with  somatic  changes  related  to  the 
growth  of  the  individual. 

The  eminent  educator  and  psychologist,  G.  Stanley  Hall,  adapted  his 
notion  of  play  to  his  general  theory  of  psychological  recapitulation.  He 
held,  in  general,  that  the  mental  life  of  the  individual  reproduces  in  brief 
the  mental  history  of  the  race.  Accordingly,  he  looked  upon  play  as  a 
persistence  of  the  motor  habits  and  mental  traits  of  the  human  race  as 
they  had  existed  in  the  past.  Play  is,  fundamentally,  a  reversion  to  the 
activities  of  our  ancestors,  running  back  into  the  animal  world.  Hall's 
disciple,  George  T.  W.  Patrick,  in  his  Psychology  of  Relaxation,  gave 


28  Article  "Play,"  Encyclopedia  of  the  Social  Sciences,  Macmillan,  Vol.  12. 


814          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

this  idea  greater  precision  by  holding  that  modern  man's  impulse  to 
recreation  is  an  attempt  to  recall  and  reproduce  the  chief  types  of  life, 
habits,  and  occupations  during  the  long  period  of  stone-age  culture.  The 
psychologist,  Alexander  Shand,  presented  an  emotional  theory  of  play. 
He  held  that  play  is  basically  devoted  to  the  maintenance  of  the  emotion 
of  joy.  His  doctrine  was  thus  a  hedonistic  interpretation  of  play.  The 
English  psychologist,  William  McDougall,  contended  that  play  arises 
out  of  the  natural  impulse  of  rivalry.  It  is  produced  by  the  effort  to 
surpass  others. 

Freud  and  the  psychoanalysts  have  laid  much  stress  upon  the  make- 
believe  element  in  play.  It  is  a  manifestation  of  fantasy  and  a  form 
of  substitution  in  human  activity.  Alfred  Adler  relates  play  to  his  theory 
of  the  neurotic  constitution  by  contending  that  play  is  the  child's  com- 
pensation for  his  physical  and  mental  inadequacy. 

These  theories  of  play  are  not  mutually  exclusive.  All  of  them 
make  a  valuable  contribution  to  a  comprehensive  interpretation  of  the 
psychology  of  play  and  its  function  in  society,  such  as  that  presented  by 
Professor  Pressey  in  the  following  paragraph: 

It  is  presupposed,  in  the  first  place,  that  the  individual  is  naturally  active, 
physically  and  mentally.  In  considering  play,  the  question  is  therefore  not  as 
to  why  the  individual  does'  anything,  but  as  to  why  he  indulges  in  the  particular 
activities  called  play.  The  following  factors  seem  outstanding:  (a)  Play  varies 
with  the  physical  and  mental  development  of  the  individual.  There  is  a  gradual 
development  from  the  more  simple  and  tactive  to  the<  more  complex  and  social, 
and  the  play  of  an  individual  at  any  particular  age  is  in  harmony  with  the  stage 
of  development  he  has  reached,  (b)  Play  varies  with  the  physical  environment 
and  opportunity  for  play ;  play  is  activity  which  is  in  accordance  in  one  way  or 
another  with  the  child's  physical  environment.  Finally,  (c)  fads,  fashions  and 
conventions  as  to  play,  among  both  children  and  adults,  are  exceedingly  impor- 
tant influences;  play  is  activity  which  is  in  harmony,  in  one  way  or  another,  with 
the  individual's  social  environment.29 

From  a  sociological  point  of  view,  the  most  fundamental  contributions 
of  play  are  those  which  fall  under  the  educational  and  hygienic  aspects. 
In  an  educational  way,  play  helps  to  socialize  the  individual.  Especially 
is  this  true  of  play  carried  on  in  groups.  The  natural  and  selfish  impulses 
of  the  individual  are  modified  and  held  in  check  by  the  social  restraints 
imposed  by  the  rules  of  the  game.  Not  only  rivalry,  but  the  sense  of 
fair  play,  is  brought  into  being.  It  is  no  accident  that  educational 
sociologists  have  laid  great  stress  upon  the  importance  of  play  in  prepar- 
ing youth  for  intelligent  participation  in  the  responsibilities  of  group  life. 
The  enthusiasm  shown  by  children  and  adults  in  play  has  had  an  im- 
portant influence  upon  educational  theory.  Observers  could  not  help 
marking  the  vast  difference  between  the  gusto  exhibited  £n  play  and  the 
indifference  manifested  by  the  child  in  schools  conducted  according  to 
the  traditional  type  of  punitive  discipline.  Hence  there  has  been  an 
effort  on  the  part  of  progressive  educators  to  devise  new  types  of  educa- 


29  S.  L.  Pressey,  Psychology  and  the  New  Education,  Harper's,  1933,  p.  79. 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         815 

tional  procedure  which  seek  to  produce  in  the  child  the  same  enthusiasm 
for  learning*  that  he  manifests  on  the  playground.  To  a  certain  extent, 
the  more  progressive  educators  have  sought  to  make  the  learning  process 
a  form  of  playful  activity.  The  Progressive  Education  Movement,  in 
particular,  has  endeavored  to  introduce  into  the  schoolroom  some  of  the 
motivation  which  influences  children  in  spontaneous  play. 

The  hygienic  aspects  of  play  have  been  recognized  by  those  interested 
in  both  physical  and  mental  hygiene.  The  recreational  and  restful 
features  of  play,  through  introducing  alternate  forms  of  activity,  have 
been  thoroughly  accepted  in  modern  physical  hygiene.  Gymnastic  ex- 
ercises and  supervised  games  have  been  provided  to  help  build  up  the 
physique  of  youth,  special  forms  being  devised  to  correct  physical  de- 
ficiencies. The  stimulating,  distracting,  and  compensatory  mental 
phases  of  play  have  been  taken  into  account  by  students  of  mental 
hygiene.  The  latter  have  stressed  the  cathartic  and  curative  aspects  of 
playful  endeavor.  These  are  extremely  helpful  to  the  adult  as  well  as 
to  the  child:  Today,  play  occupies  an  important  place  in  educational 
theory  and  mental  hygiene,  as  well  as  in  the  field  of  recreational  endeavor. 

Outstanding   Phases  of  the  History  of  Recreation 

Until  the  rise  of  modern  democracy  and  the  Industrial  Revolution,  play 
and  sports  were  chiefly  a  privilege  and  activity  of  the  upper  classes. 
The  hard  working  and  oppressed  peasants,  serfs,  and  slaves  had  little 
time  or  energy  for  play,  even  when  legally  permitted  to  indulge  in  it. 
The  spprts  of  the  upper  classes  were  long  closely  associated  with  religious 
rites  or  with  the  preparation  for  war.  The  Roman  chariot  races,  the 
tournaments,  jousts,  and  hunting  parties  of  the  Middle  Ages,  and  the 
fox  hunting  of  the  English  gentry  in  modern  times  are  good  illustrations 
of  the  typical  noble  monopoly  of  prevailing  sports.  But  the  yeoman  and 
middle  classes  were  not  entirely  deprived  of  popular  sports.  For  example, 
in  the  Middle  Ages,  they  indulged  in  archery,  quoits,  bear-baiting,  cock- 
fighting,  mock  tournaments,  and  the  like. 

Some  historians  of  sport  have  contended  that  this  social  cleavage  in 
the  sport  world  between  the  nobility  and  the  yeomen  was  what  has  given 
rise  in  our  day  to  the  differentiation  between  the  amateur  and  the  pro- 
fessional. Our  modern  amateur  has  descended  from  the  earlier  aristo- 
crat, and  our  present  professional  from  those  of  the  middle  and  lower 
classes,  whose  sporting  activities  were  looked  upon  as  a  lower  type  and 
were  sometimes  entered  upon  for  self-support.  The  invention  of 
machines  during  the  Industrial  Revolution  ultimately  provided  leisure 
time  for  the  masses  to  indulge  in  sports — iron  slaves  being  substituted 
for  human  slaves  and  serfs.  The  democratic  theory  of  human  equality 
emphasized  the  right  of  all  to  participate  in  play  and  sport,  thus  breaking 
down  the  earlier  doctrines  of  aristocratic  monopoly.  A  special  impetus 
was  given  to  the  democratization  of  sports  by  the  first  World  War. 
Examination  of  recruits  revealed  the  startling  presence  of  physical  de- 


816          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

fects  on  a  national  scale  and  suggested  that  mass  sports  might  help  to 
correct  these.  The  cultivation  of  mass  sports  as  a  means  o'f  promoting 
physical  perfection  in  preparation  for  war  gained  particular  headway  in 
Fascist  countries.  But  the  crowding  of  industrial  populations  in  con- 
gested city  areas  gravely  handicapped  the  direct  participation  of  the 
masses  in  sports;  they  have  usually  had  to  be  content  to  indulge  vi- 
cariously in  the  role  of  spectators. 

In  primitive  and  early  historic  society,  play  and  sports  were  closely 
linked  up  with  religion.  Religious  festivals,  especially  those  associated 
with  fertility  rites,  were  accompanied  by  various  forms  of  play  and 
games,  some  of  which  took  a  form  which  today  would  be  regarded  as 
licentious.  In  ancient  Oriental  society  there  was  a  particularly  close 
relationship  between  religious  festivals  and  such  play  as  existed.  The 
relation  between  Greek  play  and  Greek  religion  has  been  described  by 
Jane  Harrison  in  her  interesting  book  Ancient  Art  and  Ritual.  Other 
religious  celebrations  which  promoted  play,  sports,  and  games  were  those 
which  celebrated  a  military  victory  or  a  deliverance  from  pestilence  or 
some  other  form  of  disaster.  The  close  interrelation  between  religion, 
sex,  and  sports  continued  well  into  the  Middle  Ages.  As  Albert  Parry 
points  out:  "Not  infrequently  during  the  Middle  Ages,  races  in  honor  of 
a  saint  were  followed  by  general  licentiousness  among  the  spectators."  80 
Another  association  of  play  and  sports  with  religion  in  primitive  and 
early  historic  society  was  manifested  by  the  close  relationship  between 
tricks  and  religious  ceremonials.  Such  tricks  as  the  tying  and  untying 
of  knots,  ventriloquism,  and  numerous  fire  tricks  were  performed  in  re- 
ligious ceremonials.  They  were  closely  associated  with  magic.  In 
initiation  rites,  a  great  variety  of  tricks  were  devised  to  deceive  and 
impress  the  uninitiated.  While  play  has  been  sweepingly  secularized  in 
modern  times,  it  is  still  widely  associated  with  religious  auspices  and 
organizations.  The  Y.M.C.A.,  the  Knights  of  Columbus,  the  Y.M.H.A., 
and  the  like,  have  laid  much  stress  upon  gymnasiums,  games,  and  physical 
exercise.  Sunday-school  picnics  are  usually  given  over  to  various  forms 
of  games,  thus  perpetuating  in  a  lesser  degree  the  association  between 
play  and  religion  in  early  society. 

The  history  of  play,  sports,  and  recreation,  like  the  history  of  most 
other  forms  of  culture,  is  in  one  way  a  record  of  its  progressive  seculariza- 
tion. While  religion  still  played  a  large  part  in  Greek  recreation,  espe- 
cially in  the  games  associated  with  religious  festivals,  the  Greeks  were 
the  first  to  give  a  marked  secular  turn  to  recreation  and  physical  exercise. 
The  Greeks  regarded  athletics  as  decisively  a  phase  of  leisure-time  ac- 
tivity executed  on  the  supra-pig  level  of  achievement.  The  Greeks 
looked  upon  recreation  as  a  phase  of  both  hygiene  and  aesthetics.  From 
the  standpoint  of  hygiene,  the  Greeks  jegarded  physical  exercise  and 
games  as  a  means  of  producing  the  perfect  human  body*  Moreover,  the 
Greeks  viewed  athletic  games  as  a  form  of  aesthetic  expression,  and 


80  Encyclopedia  of  the  Social  Sciences,  Macmillan,  Vol.  14,  p.  306. 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         817 

athletics  were  closely  associated  with  music  in  the  Greek  classification  of 
the  arts. 

The  Romans  continued  the  process  of  secularizing  sports  and  games. 
The  Romans,  however,  were  interested  in  producing  a  good  physique  and 
in  encouraging  games  and  sports  primarily  for  the  purpose  of  preparing 
the  Roman  youth,  physically  and  mentally,  for  war.  Roman  politics 
also  contributed  a  secularizing  influence,  since  the  government  tried  to 
placate  the  masses  by  providing  great  public  spectacles,  such  as  chariot 
races  and  gladiatorial  combats.  These  Roman  spectacles  represented 
perhaps  the  first  impressive  example  of  the  vicarious  participation  of  the 
masses  in  public  sports  as  spectators. 

Since  the  nobility  monopolized  most  sports  during  the  Middle  Ages 
and,  since  their  sports  were  of  a  primarily  military  character, 'the  secu- 
larizing influence  was  continued.  But  there  was  also  a  strong  religious 
element  in  medieval  sports  and  recreation.  Medieval  sports  were  chiefly 
military  or  quasi-military  and  designed  to  train  brave  and  hardy  knights. 
But  the  supreme  purpose  of  battle  was  to  promote  the  cause  of  Christ. 
As  Charles  Young  puts  it:  "The  medieval  knight  employed  his  over- 
weening sentiment  of  personal  independence  and  love  of  adventure  in 
defense  of  the  Church.  To  fight  for  Christ  becomes  not  merely  the 
highest  duty  but  the  noblest  ambition  of  one  who  traditionally  regards 
courage  in  battle  as  the  sum  of  all  virtue."  With  the  growing  seculariza- 
tion of  life  since  the  Middle  Ages,  sports  naturally  tended  to  share  in  the 
process.  The  final  secularization  of  sports  and  recreation  was  accom- 
plished as  a  phase  of  the  commercialization  of  sport  in  the  late  nineteenth 
and  the  twentieth  centuries. 

Among  primitive  peoples  we  find  many  examples  of  games  and  sports, 
some  closely  related  to  the  responsibilities  of  daily  life,  such  sts  hunting. 
Much  attention  was  given  to  archery,  when  primitive  peoples  had 
mastered  the  use  of  the  bow  and  arrow.  Blow  guns  were  frequently  used. 
There  were  games  consisting  of  rolling  rings  with  spears.  A  variety  of 
string  games  were  common.  The  Indians  also  had  ball  games,  and  some 
historians  of  sport  derive  the  American  baseball  game  from  a  sport 
originally  common  among  the  American  Indians.  It  is  certain  that  the 
Canadian  gajne  of  lacrosse  was  directly  taken  over  from  one  of  the 
Indian  ball  games.  We  have  already  referred  to  the  various  games  and 
tricks  associated  with  religious  ceremonials  and  magic  in  primitive  times. 
The  children  among  primitive  peoples  indulged  in  games  not  so  far  re- 
moved from  those  common  among  children  today.  They  had  numerous 
toys,  such  as  miniature  boats,  sledges,  reindeer,  and  other  animals.  They 
indulged  in  the  common  make-believe  play  and  mimicry,  such  as  playing 
at  fighting  and  hunting,  playing  house,  playing  chief,  and  the  like.  As  in 
modern  society,  much  of  the  play  of  primitive  children  was  in  anticipation 
of,  and  preparation  for,  the  responsibilities  of  adult  life. 

The  games  and  sports  of  early  historic  peoples  may  be  illustrated  by 
the  example  of  the  ancient  Egyptians.  One  of  the  favorite  sports  among 
the  Egyptian  aristocracy  was  bullfighting,  but  it  was  a  contest  between 


818         LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

bulls  themselves,  and  not  one  between  bulls  and  men.  Acrobatic  feats 
and  games  were  very  popular  with  the  Egyptians.  Other  common  Egyp- 
tian games  and  sports  were  throwing  knives  at  a  target,  rolling  and 
catching  hoops,  wrestling,  and  many  games  with  bones,  nuts,  beans,  and 
shells.  Then  ball  games  were  confined  primarily  to  throwing  and  catch- 
ing. Boxing  was  little  indulged  in  by  the  Egyptians,  but  mock  fights 
with  staves  were  popular.  The  honorable  place  of  woman  in  ancient 
Egyptian  civilization  was  reflected  in  the  fact  that  women  participated 
prominently  in  most  of  the  Egyptian  sports,  actually  predominating  in 
ball  games.  Sports  which  strengthened  the  physique  and  prepared  youth 
for  military  activities  were  especially  popular  in  Assyria  and  Persia. 
Horseback  riding  and  hunting  were  encouraged.  The  kings  and  nobility 
showed  special  enthusiasm  for  big-game  hunting  and  stories  of  royal 
prowess  in  killing  lions  are  fabulous. 

No  people  developed  sports  in  a  more  wholehearted  fashion  than  did 
the  ancient  Greeks.  Among  the  Greeks,  play  and  recreation  was  not  a 
mere  informal  and  sporadic  thing,  but  an  integral  part  of  Greek  educa- 
tion, citizenship,  and  cultural  life.  The  Greeks  made  thorough  provision 
for  compulsory  physical  training,  both  during  school  days  and  in  early 
adulthood.  They  encouraged  the  cultivation  of  physical  sports  through- 
out life.  The  Greeks  had  the  palaistra  and  the  gymnasium  (from  which 
we  derive  the  term  gymnastics) ,  in  which  to  give  systematic  instruction  in 
physical  exercises,  and  various  gymnastic  equipment,  such  as  weights, 
punchballs,  dumbbells,,  boxing  gloves,  discuses,  javelins,  and  the  like. 
Several  types  of  ball  games  were  played.  Wrestling,  boxing,  running 
races,  jumping,  throwing  of  weights,  discuses,  javelins,  and  the  like  were 
popular  forms  of  physical  exercise  and  sports.  Boxing  was  a  particularly 
brutal  and  dangerous  sport,  since  the  gloves  were  merely  strips  of  leather 
wound  around  the  hands,  and  the  Greeks  directed  their  blows  almost  ex- 
clusively at  the  head.  Professional  boxers  had  strips  of  iron ,  under  the 
bands  of  leather.  The  fingers  were  left  free  and  it  was  not  unknown  for 
opponents  to  have  their  eyes  gouged  out.  We  should  not,  of  course,  fail 
to  mention  the  famous  Olympic  games  held  every  four  years,  which  con- 
stituted one  of  the  most  impressive  spectacles  of  ancient  Greek  life. 

In  addition  to  the  games  and  sports  involved  in  Greek  physical  edu- 
cation and  associated  with  formal  athletics,  the  Greeks  indulged  in  vari- 
ous informal  sports.  One  of  the  most  popular  among  the  aristocracy  was 
horseback  riding.  Hunting,  swimming,  and  rowing  were  popular  Greek 
sports,  but  the  Greeks  never  went  in  for  bathing  as  extensively  as  did  the 
Romans.  The  Greek  children  played  with  hoops,  tops,  kites,  swings,  and 
the  like.  Knuckle  bones  provided  a  form  of  practical  entertainment 
among  the  Greek  youngsters  in  helping  to  teach  arithmetic.  All  in  all, 
one  may  safely  say  that  the  Greek  attitude  toward  athletics  and  sports, 
in  offering  training  to  all  in  good  sportsmanship  and  symmetrical  physical 
development,  came  closer  than  any  other  recreational  notion  in  history 
to,  the  ideal  which  \ye  might  well  seek  to  recover  and  apply  in  our  present 
day  efforts  to  solve  the  problem  of  leisure. 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         819 

Though  the  Romans  adopted  many  phases  of  Greek  culture,  they  did 
not  take  over  to  any  marked  degree  the  aesthetic  attitude  of  the  Greeks 
toward  sports.  While  they  provided  for  intensive  and  systematic  physi- 
cal training  of  Roman  youth,  this  was  carried  on  primarily  as  a  phase  of 
military  training,  or  at  least  for  the  purpose  of  promoting  military  effi- 
ciency. As  Charles  V.  P.  Young  puts  it:  "While  the  Romans  were 
intensely  fond  of  physical  exercise,  it  was  originally  and  primarily,  as 
has  been  said,  as  a  means  to  an  end,  viz.,  military  efficiency.  The  scien- 
tific training  of  an  ideal  harmony  of  mind  and  body  had  no  place  in  their 
scheme  of  things."31 

Roman  boys  were  compelled  to  assemble  daily  to  be  put  through 
arduous  physical  exercises  and  training  in  the  use  of  weapons.  They 
were  drilled  in  the  military  step,  compelled  to  carry  heavy  weights,  trained 
to  throw  the  javelin,  and  the  like.  Accessory  exercises  designed  to  im- 
prove physical  and  military  efficiency  were  such  things  as  boxing,  wrest- 
ling, and  running.  These  exercises  were  serious  and  solemn  matters, 
rarely  taking  the  form  of  spontaneous  sports  or  social  amusements. 
Roman  men,  even  prominent  public  officials,  did,  however,  take  a  rather 
unusual  interest  in  certain  gymnastics  and  games  for  the  sake  of  relaxa- 
tion and  recreation.  Boys  also  participated  in  these  games  when  they 
were  not  occupied  in  more  serious  exercises.  Ball  games  were  particularly 
popular  with  the  Romans.  Some  of  these  games  resembled  our  modern 
baseball,  and  others  were  roughly  like  soccer  and  medicine  ball,  as  played 
today.  The  Romans  also  showed  much  enthusiasm  for  sham  fights  in 
which  they  fought  a  dummy  much  as  they  would  a  living  adversary.  It 
hardly  needs  to  be  pointed  out  that  no  other  people  in  history  have  shown 
as  much  enthusiasm  for  public  baths  as  did  the  Romans.  The  opening 
of  the  baths  was  announced  each  day  by  the  ringing  of  a  bell.  The  great 
baths  were  capacious  and  luxurious.  There  were  rooms  and  pools  for 
hot,  warm,  and  cold-water  bathing.  Gymnasiums  and  ball  courts  were 
provided  for  the  more  energetic.  There  were  balconies  on  which  bathers 
of  both  sexes  might  gather  and  gossip.  Libraries  and  art  galleries  were 
often  provided  for  the  more  studious  and  aesthetic.  The  price  of  admis- 
sion was  very  low — about  one  cent  for  a  man,  two  cents  for  a  woman,  and 
free  admission  for  children. 

We  have  already  called  attention  to  the  fact  that  the  Romans  were  the 
first  to  promote  mass  attendance  at  sports,  as  a  phase  of  their  political 
policy  of  bread-and-circuses.  Gladiatorial  fights,  conflicts  between 
gladiators  and  wild  beasts,  fights  between  beasts  themselves,  and  chariot 
races  were  the  more  important  offerings  in  these  great  public  spectacles. 
Associated  with  the  chariot  races  was  the  prototype  of  our  race  track 
gambling,  racketeering,  and  fixing  of  races.  The  Romans  were,  inci- 
dentally, much  given  to  gambling  and  games  of  chance.  The  Roman 
amphitheaters  in  which  these  public  spectacles  were  held  provided  a 
seating  capacity  equal  to  that  of  our  largest  stadiums  today.  Indeed, 


81 C.  V.  P.  Young,  How  Men  Have  Lived,  Stratford,  1931,  p.  163. 


820          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

few  of  our  present  stadiums  equal  the  seating  capacity  of  the  Circus 
Maximus,  which  seated  more  than  150,000  spectators. 

During  the  Middle  Ages,  there  was,  as  we  have  seen,  a  definite  social 
cleavage  in  the  realm  of  play  and  sports.  The  nobility,  whose  life  was 
colored  by  the  ideals  of  the  age  of  chivalry,  followed  sports  supposedly 
suitable  to  the  noble  life.  Some  of  these  noble  sports,  such  as  the  tourna- 
ment and  the  joust,  constituted  training  in  the  art  of  war  in  the  age  of 
knighthood  and  chivalry.  The  tournament  was  a  real  battle  between 
mounted  knights,  which  took  on  the  form  of  a  great  public  spectacle. 
Deaths  were  frequent.  The  church  often  protested  because  of  the  num- 
ber killed  or  injured  at  tournaments.  Jousting  was  somewhat  less 
dangerous,  since  the  combatants  were  separated  by  a  wooden  beam 
which  prevented  the  horses  from  colliding  when  the  knights  rode  head- 
long at  each  other.  Less  dangerous  still  were  the  quintain,  in  which  a 
knight  endeavored  to  pierce  a  manikin  with  his  lance  at  full  speed,  and 
the  behourd  which  was  a  type  of  fencing  on  horseback. 

Aside  from  these  military  sports,  the  most  popular  type  of  noble  recrea- 
tion was  some  form  of  hunting.  The  nobles  had  exclusive  hunting  rights 
in  the  Middle  Ages  and  little  thought  of  the  ruinous  effect  of  their  hunting 
on  the  cultivated  fields  of  the  peasants.  Stag  hunting  and  wild  boar 
hunting  were  popular.  Almost  universal  was  the  sport  of  falconry,  or 
hunting  birds  and  small  game  animals  with  trained  falcons  and  hawks. 
When  inside  their  castles  the  nobility  amused  themselves  chiefly  by 
listening  to  the  songs  and  jokes  of  the  troubadours  and  jesters,  playing 
chess  and  drinking. 

The  medieval  yeomanry  had  their  own  sports,  some  of  which  were  an 
imitation  of  those  of  the  nobles.  Such  were  the  mock  tournaments,  in 
which  the  yeomen  were  seated  on  oxen  and  armed  with  flails  instead  of 
lances.  The  yeomen  also  frequently  had  their  own  quintains,  in  the  form 
of  spearing  figures  mounted  on  posts  in  the  village  common.  Instead  of 
the  noble  hunting  enterprises,  the  yeomen  had  to  content  themselves  with 
archery,  pitching  quoits,  bear-baiting,  cockfighting,  and  the  like.  The 
peasants  and  sejfs  had  fewer  sports  than  the  yeomen,  but  on  manorial 
'holidays  they  might  have  a  chance  to  wrestle,  throw  weights,  watch  a 
cockfight,  or  observe  two  blindfolded  men  trying  to  kill  with  a  club  a 
pig  or  a  goose  let  loose  in  an  enclosure.  Usually,  the  peasants  and  serfs, 
working  from  daylight  until  dark,  had  little  time  or  inclination  to  engage 
in  sports. 

The  rise  of  Protestantism,  and  especially  of  Puritanism,  in  early 
modern  times,  tended  to  exert  a  restraining  influence  upon  sports.  The 
main  leisure  possessed  by  any,  save  the  nobility,  was  on  Sunday,  and  the 
Puritans  revived  the  Sabbatarian  teachings  of  the  Old  Testament  and 
attempted  to  enforce  a  taboo  upon  sports  on  Sunday.  This  definitely 
curtailed  sports  and  amusements  in  those  places  where  the  Puritans  were 
able  to  enact  and  enforce  their  restrictive  legislation.  Moreover,  the 
Puritans  looked  askance  upon  bear  and  bull-baiting,  cockfighting,  and 
the  like,  and  did  their  best  to  discourage  these,  even  when  carried  on 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         821 

during  week  days.  Thus,  while  religion  had  formerly  stimulated  play 
and  sports,  it  became,  for  a  long  time,  a  distinctly  restraining  influence  in 
many  Protestant  countries. 

With  the  invention  of  gunpowder,  knighthood  and  chivalry  came  to  an 
end,  and  the  typical  medieval  amusements  of  the  feudal  nobility  were 
terminated  when  this  social  class  was  finally  ousted  from  power.  Tour- 
naments, jousts,  and  falconry  were  discarded.  The  commoner  was 
gradually  allowed  to  participate  in  hunting  activities.  But  horseback 
riding  still  remained  the  basis  of  the  sport  of  the  upper  classes  which> 
particularly  in  England,  was  transformed  into  hunting  with  the  hounds. 

With  the  termination  of  feudalism,  the  middle  class  rose  in  importance 
and  their  sports  assumed  a  social  importance  quite  equal  to  those  of  the 
country  gentry.  Typical  forms  of  play  and  sport  in  early  modern  times 
are  summarized  in  the  following  statement  from  an  English  newspaper 
of  the  early  eighteenth  century: 

The  modern  sports  of  the  citizens,  besides  drinking,  are  eockfighting,  bowling 
upon  greens,  playing  at  tables  or  backgammon,  cards,  dice,  and  billiards;  also 
musical  meetings  in  the  evening ;  they  sometimes  ride  out  on  horseback,  and  hunt 
with  the  lord-mayor's  pack  of  dogs  when  the  common  hunt  goes  on.  The  lower 
classes  divert  themselves  at  football,  wrestling,  cudgels,  ninepins,  shovelboard, 
cricket,  stowball,  ringing  of  bells,  quoits,  pitching  the  bar,  bull  and  bear  bait- 
ings.82 

Other  sports  mentioned  by  another  writer  of  the  same  era  were  "Sail- 
ing, rowing,  swimming,  archery,  bowling  in  alleys,  and  skittles,  tennis, 
chess,  and  draughts ;  and  in  the  winter  skating,  sliding,  and  shooting." 

We  should  also  in  this  place  say  a  word  or  two  about  the  sports  of  our 
colonial  ancestors  during  this  period.  The  typical  sports  of  the  English 
country  gentry  were  brought  over  and  established  in  the  southern  colonies. 
Pox  hunting  behind  the  hounds  was  particularly  popular  with  the  squires 
of  Virginia  and  some  other  southern  colonies.  The  upper  classes  in  both 
the  South  and  the  North  found  much  pleasure  in  boating  and  yacht  races. 
Horse  racing  was  popular  in  Virginia,  and  it  made  some  headway  even 
in  New  England.  Hunting  and  fishing  were  not  only  popular  but  a  prac- 
tical necessity  throughout  the  whole  colonial  area.  The  middle  and  lower 
classes  amused  themselves  at  such  games  as  skittles,  an  early  form  of 
bowling,  pulling  the  goose,33  cockfighting,  swimming,  and  skating.  Due 
to  the  popularity  of  hunting  and  the  necessity  of  protecting  themselves 
from  the  Indians,  the  colonists  universally  fostered  shooting  matches. 
In  the  rough  life  of  the  frontier  vigorous  sports  such  as  rough-and-tumble 
fights,  wrestling  matches,  and  eyegouging  were  popular. 

The  nineteenth  century  witnessed  a  remarkable  change  in  the  range 
and  character  of  sports  and  recreation.  This  revolution  was  brought 
about  by  the  sweeping  mechanical  and  institutional  changes  which  have 


82  Young,  op.  cit.t  p.  273. 

88  In  this  sport  a  neavily  greased  goose  was  hung  on  a  rope  above  a  road  or  a 
stream  and  a  man  on  horseback  or  in  a  boat  rode  under  the  goose  at  full  speed 
and  tried  to  pull  it  off  the  rope. 


822         LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

come  over  the  world  since  1800.  The  Industrial  Revolution,  the  inven- 
tion of  machines,  and  the  triumph  of  modern  industrialism  gradually 
brought  about  a  greater  amount  of  leisure  time  which  could  be  devoted 
to  sports  and  recreation.  But  most  of  those  who  were  able  to  enjoy  this 
larger  volume  of  leisure  found  themselves  cooped  up  in  cities,  where  the 
facilities  for  recreation  were  very  limited.  This  encouraged  the  creation 
of  mass  spectacles  and  commercial  recreation,  in  which  the  professional 
and  working  classes  could  participate  vicariously  as  spectators.  The 
growth  of  democracy,  which  followed  in  the  wake  of  the  increasing 
strength  of  the  working  classes,  swept  away  most  of  the  exclusiveness 
which  had  dominated  sports.  Sports  became  the  legal  right  of  every- 
body, even  though  the  masses  might  have  a  limited  opportunity  to  engage 
in  such  recreation.  Nationalism  also  exerted  its  influence  upon  the  world 
of  sports.  The  German  patriot,  Friedrich  Ludwig  Jahn,  introduced  the 
idea  of  practicing  gymnastics  as  a  phase  of  the  preparation  of  the  Ger- 
mans for  successful  resistance  to  Napoleon.  His  introduction  of  gym- 
nastic exercises  in  Berlin,  in  1811,  was  widely  imitated  throughout  the 
rest  of  Prussia  and  in  some  of  the  other  German  states.  The  German 
Turnvereine  of  the  nineteenth  century  were  definitely  modeled  on  the 
program  of  "Father"  Jahn. 

Another  important  innovation  in  sports  since  the  opening  of  the  nine- 
teenth century  has  been  the  growing  popularity  of  competitive  games  and 
the  development  of  organized  games  between  matched  teams.  The  latter 
seems  to  have  been,  in  the  beginning,  primarily  an  English  and  American 
development.  This  new  phase  of  sports  may  have  been  due  in  part  to 
environmental  conditions  peculiar  to  the  English  and  Americans,  but 
very  likely  it  also  reflected  the  competitive  character  of  the  economic  life 
and  institutions  of  our  capitalistic  industrialism.  Anyhow,  it  has  been 
one  of  the  most  momentous  innovations  in  the  history  of  sports  and 
recreation.  Its  significance  and  foundations  are  thus  characterized  by 
S.  L.  Pressey: 

Certain  larger  social  influences  upon  play  also  deserve  mention.  The  organ- 
ized team  game  seems  to  be  largely  an  Anglo-Saxon  product.  American  col- 
legians prefer  football,  whereas  the  youthful  intelligentsia  of  Germany  have  a 
special  fondness  for  dueling,  and  the  French  prefer  tennis  to  play  between  groups. 
But  all  this  is  presumably  not  because  German  or  French  youths  lack  some 
mysterious  instinct  or  ability  which  tends  to  make  English  and  American  boys  pe- 
culiarly fond  of  team  games.  Rather  the  explanation  is  to  be  found  in  differences 
in  climate,  in  the  size  and  character  of  the  leisure  class,  and  especially  in  the 
largely  unknown  development  of  the  conventions  of  amusement.  It  must  be 
further  observed  that  these  differences  are  being  rapidly  modified.  The  vogue 
of  tennis  in  France  is  relatively  new,  although  the  game  originated  there.  Amer- 
ican baseball  has  no  very  long  history,  and  its  amazing  popularity  in  Japan  has 
come  about  in  a  short  period  of  time.  The  present  passion  for  golf  in  our  coun- 
try is  largely  a  post-war  phenomenon.  In  short,  there  is  every  evidence  that  the 
form  which  the  play  life  of  a  community  or  a  nation  takes  is  determined  by 
influences  which  are  best  described  as  social;  certain  conventions  are  developed 
with  respect  to  sport  and  amusement. 

The  writer  is  inclined  to  believe  that  the  competitive  character  of  much  Amer- 
ican play  is  to  be  regarded  as  such  a  convention.  After  all,  many  recreational 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         823 

activities,  such  as  fishing,  canoeing,  hiking,  dancing,  and  singing,  are  not  com- 
petitive. The  tendency  to  identify  play  with  competitive  games  and  sports  may 
be  a  product  of  our  highly  individualistic  and  competitive  socio-economic  mode 
of  life.  The  present  emphasis  on  the  competitive  in  recreation  seems  to  be 
relatively  recent,  and,  on  the  whole,  unfortunate.84 

We  may  now  briefly  describe  the  origins  of  characteristic  sports  of  the 
nineteenth  century,  which  have  been  based  upon  the  principle  of  matched 
teams  and  have  lent  themselves  particularly  well  to  the  creation  of  mass 
spectacles  and  commercialized  recreation.  Baseball  has  gained  such  pop- 
ularity that  it  is  usually  described  as  our  "national  game."  Some  attrib- 
ute its  origins  to  the  ball  games  common  among  the  American  Indians. 
But  it  is  more  likely  that  it  is  a  further  development  of  the  numerous  ball 
games  which  were  common  among  the  English  people  in  the  seventeenth 
and  eighteenth  centuries.  The  literal  origin  of  our  present  baseball  game 
can  be  traced  back  to  the  ingenuity  of  Abner  Doubleday,  a  civil  engi- 
neer, who  laid  out  the  modern  baseball  diamond  and  introduced  on  it  the 
game  of  town  ball  in  Cooperstown,  N.  Y.,  in  1839.  The  Doubleday 
system  was  popularized  when  the  Knickerbocker  baseball  club  was  organ- 
ized in  New  York  City,  in  1845,  under  the  leadership  of  Alexander  J. 
Cartwright.  This  took  over  the  Doubleday  system  and  provided  for  a 
team  of  nine  men.  In  the  decade  of  the  fifties,  baseball  teams  were 
formed  in  the  other  larger  cities  of  the  East  and  the  game  was  thoroughly 
launched.  The  first  professional  club  to  be  established  was  the  Cincin- 
nati Red  Stockings,  who  assumed  a  professional  status  in  1869.  The 
game  was  nationalized  when  the  National  League  was  founded  in  New 
York  City,  in  February,  1876.  The  American  League  was  founded  in 
1900.  Numerous  minor  leagues  have  also  been  created.  The  develop- 
ment of  stars,  since  the  advent  of  Adrian  C.  ("Cap")  Anson  in  1877  has 
served  to  add  glamour  and  popularity. 

Football  is  an  old  game,  which  certainly  goes  back  as  far  as  ancient 
Sparta.  It  was  very  popular  in  medieval  England.  Early  American 
football  was  modeled  after  the  English  game,  particularly  as  developed 
at  Rugby.  It  was  played  in  Eastern  universities  with  indifferent  results 
during  the  first  two  thirds  of  the  nineteenth  century.  But  the  American 
football  game,  as  a  conflict  of  regular  matched  teams,  was  launched 
with  the  formation  of  the  Oneida  Football  Club  in  Boston,  in  1867.  The 
guiding  spirit  was  Gerrit  Smith  Miller,  a  native  of  New  York  State.  The 
first  inter-collegiate  contest  was  played  between  Rutgers  and  Princeton 
in  1869,  with  25  players  on  each  side.  The  man  who  was  mainly  respon- 
sible for  transforming  football  from  its  early  crude  manifestations  in  the 
'60's  into  the  present  well-developed  inter-collegiate  and  professional 
game  was  Walter  C.  Camp,  a  member  of  the  Yale  football  team  in  the 
late  seventies,  and  the  leading  adviser  in  all  modifications  of  the  rules 
of  the  game  for  nearly  50  years  thereafter.  Famous  coaches  who  have 
helped  to  develop  and  stabilize  the  game  have  been  Amos  Alonzo  Stagg 


34  Presgey,  Psychology  and, the  Ne^-Educati'On,  Harper's,.  1933,  pp.  74-75. 


824         LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

of  Chicago,  Fielding  H.  Yost  of  Michigan,  Percy  Haughton  of  Harvard, 
and  Glen  Warner  of  the  Carlisle  Indians. 

The  increasingly  popular  game  of  basketball  was  created  in  January, 
1892,  by  James  Naismith  of  the  Y.M.C.A.  Training  College  at  Spring- 
field, Mass.  It  grew  out  of  an  attempt  to  adapt  the  principles  of  lacrosse 
and  association  football  to  indoor  play  on  gymnasium  floors.  Professor 
Naismith  organized  the  first  team  at  Springfield  and  the  game  rapidly 
gained  popularity.  Adopted  as  an  amateur  game  by  the  colleges  and  uni- 
versities in  the  nineties,  professional  teams  became  popular  early  in  the 
present  century.  The  game  has  enormously  increased  its  following  in 
the  last  decade. 

Hockey,  as  a  popular  game,  followed  on  the  heels  of  basketball.  The 
game  of  "shinny"  had  been  played  since  colonial  times,  but  ice  hockey 
as  an  organized  game  was  imported  from  Canada,  where  it  was  already 
popular  in  the  latter  half  of  the  nineteenth  century.  It  was  introduced 
into  the  United  States  by  a  Canadian  student  at  Johns  Hopkins  Univer- 
sity, in  1895.  Its  popularity  spread  quickly,  and  during  the  next  year 
the  American  Amateur  Hockey  League  was  formed.  While  hockey  has 
been  popular  as  an  inter-collegiate  game,  it  has  gained  even  greater  head- 
way among  professionals  during  the  last  15  years.  During  the  winter 
months  it  is  probably  more  widely  supported  than  any  other  professional 
sport,  gathering  together  great  crowds  of  spectators  in  the  numerous 
arenas  provided  for  it  in  American  cities. 

We  should,  perhaps,  mention  certain  other  games  and  sports  which  have 
come  to  enjoy  much  popularity.  Perhaps  the  most  notable  innovation 
has  been  the  game  of  golf.  The  game  was  played  in  Scotland  as  far 
back  as  the  sixteenth  century.  It  became  known,  but  was  not  popular,  in 
the  English  colonies  of  America  in  the  eighteenth  century.  The  game 
was  revived  in  the  United  States  as  a  result  of  the  influence  of  Robert 
Lockhart,  a  resident  of  Yonkers,  N.  Y.,  who  had  been  born  in  Scotland. 
Enthused  over  golf  as  a  result  of  a  visit  to  his  native  land  in  1888,  he 
returned  to  Yonkers  and  enlisted  the  interest  of  his  friend,  John  Reid, 
who  became  the  first  great  American  patron  of  golf.  The  first  outstand- 
ing American  golfer  was  Walter  J.  Travis,  who  won  a  national  amateur 
title  in  1900.  Others  who  gained  eminence  were  Jerome  B.  Travers, 
Harry  H.  Hilton,  Francis  Oumiet,  Walter  C.  Hagen,  Robert  T.  Jones,  Jr., 
Gene  Sarazen,  and  R.  Guldahl.  The  game  has  been  cultivated  by  both 
amateurs  and  professionals.  One  of  the  ablest  of  the  latter  was  "Long 
Jim"  (James)  Barnes.  While  golf  was  widely  established  before  the  first 
World  War,  its  popularization  has  come  chiefly  since  1918.  Between 
1916  and  1930  the  number  of  golf  courses  increased  from  742  to  5,856. 
The  golf  equipment  manufactured  in  1929  was  valued  at  21  million  dol- 
lars, and  the  present  value  of  golf  courses  in  the  United  States  has  been 
estimated  at  over  a  billion  dollars. 

An  interesting  development  in  contemporary  sport  has  been  the  revival 
of  the  principles  of  the  ancient  Olympic  games.  This  was  a  reaction 
against  the  growing  professionalism  and  commercialism  of  sports.  The 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         825 

development  was  also  due  to  the  personal  enthusiasm  of  a  Frenchman, 
Pierre  de  Couvertin,  who  sought  compensation  for  the  defeat  of  France 
in  1870  by  carrying  on  propaganda  for  out-of-door  sports.  He  thought 
that  France  might  triumph  here,  though  defeated  on  the  field  of  battle. 
He  summoned  a  conference  in  Paris,  in  1864,  at  which  the  International 
Olympic  Committee  was  created.  The  first  Olympic  games  were  held  in 
1896  at  Olympia  in  Greece.  Taking  the  form  of  a  great  international 
competition  in  the  realm  of  sport,  the  Olympic  games  have  been  held 
every  four  years  since  1896,84a  constantly  gaining  in  popularity,  and  pres- 
tige. The  competition  has  been  rendered  more  keen  and  severe  by  the 
growth  of  nationalism  since  the  first  World  War,  and  particularly  since 
the  rise  of  Fascism. 

Fascism  has  promoted  mass  sports  and  play  in  Italy  and  Germany  not 
only  to  provide  recreation  and  insure  physical  fitness  but  also  to  promote 
national  unity  and  patriotic  sentiment.  Not  since  Greek  days  has  so 
much  attention  been  given  to  mass  sports  by  any  important  political 
community.  But  the  spirit  of  fascist  play  is  markedly  different  from  that 
of  the  Attic  Greeks.  It  is  a  sort  of  cross  between  Spartan  military  dis- 
cipline and  the  Roman  circuses. 

We  should,  perhaps  in  this  place,  say  a  word  about  the  increasing 
popularity  of  gymnastics.  We  have  already  noted  that  gymnastics  in 
modern  times  had  their  origin  as  a  phase  of  nationalism  under  Father 
Jahn  in  Prussia  early  in  the  last  century.  From  his  movement  there 
developed  the  Turnverein,  which  became  very  popular  in  Germany  and 
among  German-Americans.  The  disciples  of  Jahn  relied  primarily 
upon  heavy  apparatus.  Two  other  influences  were  particularly  impor- 
tant in  the  growth  of  the  gymnasium  in  the  United  States.  One  was  the 
medical  point  of  view,  set  forth  forcefully  by  Dr.  Edward  M.  Hartwell 
in  1885,  which  stressed  the  desirability  of  physical  training  from  the 
standpoint  of  physical  and  mental  hygiene.  The  other  was  the  influence 
which  came  from  religion  and  social  reform  and  led  to  the  introduction 
of  gymnasiums  in  settlement  houses,  the  Y.M.C.A.  and  Y.W.C.A.,  and 
the  like. 

While  the  first  American  gymnasiums  generally  adopted  the  heavy 
apparatus  of  the  Jahn  system,  calisthenics,  introduced  in  the  Hartford 
Seminary  by  Catherine  E.  Beecher,  became  more  popular.  It  laid  much 
stress  upon  setting-up  exercises,  and  posture  exercises.  This  innovation 
was  popularized  by  Dr.  Dio  Lewis,  who  was  also  indebted  to  the  Swedish 
system  of  free  gymnastics.  The  man  most  influential  in  developing  the 
American  system  of  gymnastic  exercises,  taking  the  best  from  both  Euro- 
pean and  American  practice,  was  Dudley  A.  Sargent,  who  became  profes- 
sor of  physical  training  at  Harvard  University  in  1878.  The  Young 
Men's  Christian  Association,  under  the  leadership  of  Robert  Burny, 
J.  Gardner  Smith,  and  Luther  H.  Gulick,  pl&yed  a  very  important  part  in 
popularizing  the  gymnasium  and  American  gymnastics.  A  training 
school,  under  Y.M.C.A.  auspices,  was  created  at  Springfield,  Mass. 


Except  for  the  war  years  1916  and  1940. 


826          LEISURE,  RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

Gulick  originally  had  charge  of  this.  The  aim  of  the  Y.M.C.A.  was  to 
develop  a  "muscular  Christianity/'  The  gymnasium  movement  was  pop- 
ularized by  the  development  of  competition  between  gymnastic  teams 
following  1899.  The  gymnasium  has  promoted  not  only  gymnastic  exer- 
cises but  also  such  sports  as  swimming,  basketball,  handball,  and  the 
like. 

Perhaps  the  most  remarkable  development  in  the  whole  history  of 
sports  has  been  the  rise  of  commercialized  sports  and  amusements,  mainly 
since  the  first  World  War.  This  has  been  due,  first  and  foremost,  to  the 
growth  of  urban  populations.  Since  restrictions  of  space  have  made  it  im- 
possible for  many  city  dwellers  to  participate  directly  in  play  and  sports, 
there  has  been  a  natural  tendency  to  provide  great  mass  spectacles  which 
thousands  of  spectators  may  watch  and  in  which  they  may  participate 
vicariously.35  Then,  the  first  World  War  gave  a  strong  impetus  to  sports 
and  to  vicarious  mass  participation  therein.  The  strongest  influence  here 
was  a  combination  of  patriotism  and  hygiene.  Sports  were  believed  to 
bring  about  more  perfect  physique,  which  was  desirable  in  potential  sol- 
diers. 

Mass  production  methods  tended  to  enter  into  sports  themselves,  in 
order  to  meet  the  need  for  public  spectacles  and  the  health  training  of 
the  multitude.  Acquisitive  impulses  also  played  their  part,  since  busi- 
nessmen quickly  detected  the  possibility  of  profits  in  the  sale  of  admis- 
sions to  public  spectacles  and  in  the  marketing  of  various  forms  of 
sporting  goods.  And  the  gambling  spirit  was  not  without  influence  in 
this  development.  It  has  been  an  especially  strong  force  in  promoting 
the  development  of  horse  racing  and  racetrack  gambling. 

While  the  commercialization  of  sports  has  had  certain  benefits,  such  as 
making  possible  the  very  existence  of  mass  spectacles,  it  has  carried  with 
it  certain  abuses,  especially  when  racketeers  and  gamblers  have  been  able 
to  get  control  of  some  of  these  sports  and  "fix"  the  results,  so  as  to  pro- 
mote their  gambling  earnings.  Baseball  has  been  unusually  free  from 
this  abuse,  but  even  here  the  racketeers  were  able  to  fix  the  World  Series 
between  the  Chicago  White  Sox  and  the  Cincinnati  Reds  in  1919.  There 
has  been  a  considerable  amount  of  well-warranted  suspicion  about  the 
integrity  of  boxing  matches,  and  professional  wrestling  is  shot  through 
with  corruption  and  manipulation.  It  is  not  taken  seriously  by  many 
sport  lovers.  It  is  more  a  phase  of  comedy  than  of  sport.  But  horse 
racing  has  been  most  thoroughly  victimized  by  the  gamblers  and  rack- 
eteers. Not  only  is  much  of  the  racetrack  betting  dishonestly  conducted 
and  designed  to  line  the  pockets  of  gamblers,  but  at  times  even  the  races 
themselves  are  fixed  through  the  bribery  of  jockeys  or  the-  doping  of 
horses.  The  operations  of  the  racetrack  gamblers  and  racketeers  repre- 
sent the  most  extreme  pathological  aspects  of  commercialized  sports. 

The  manufacture  and  sale  of  various  forms  of  sporting  and  athletic 
goods,  firearms,  ammunition,  and  the  like,  have  become  a  major  busi- 


35  On  spectator  sports  and  vicarious  participation,  see  J.  B.  Nash,  Spectatoritis, 
Sears,  1932, 


LEISURE,  RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         827 

ness  in  the  United  States.  It  is  estimated  that,  in  1929,  when  the  sale  of 
these  goods  reached  the  maximum  point,  it  totaled  approximately 
half  a  billion  dollars.  But  even  this  is  only  a  small  fraction  of  the  total 
cost  of  all  recreation  in  the  United  States,  which  was  estimated  to  have 
been,  in  1929,  approximately  10  billion  dollars. 

Recreation   in  the  United  States  in  the 
Twentieth  Century 

Since  the  turn  of  the  present  century,  the  major  trends  in  recreation 
have  been  the  popularization  of  play  and  sports,  the  institutionalization 
of  both  as  a  phase  of  social  planning,  the  promotion  of  games  and  sports 
by  private  business  enterprise,  and  the  growth  of  great  commercialized 
public  spectacles.  E.  C.  Worman  thus  summarizes  some  of  the  major 
forces  that  have  brought  about  the  expansion  of  recreational  activities 
and  the  facilities  therefor: 

Many  factors  have  been  responsible  for  this  widespread  development.  Much 
of  it  has  grown  out  of  the  nature  of  our  times.  Technological  advances  in  indus- 
try, the  growth  of  cities,  the  great  hazards  of  motor  transportation,  the  new 
freedom  of  women,  changing  religious  conceptions,  the  selfish  exploitation  of 
natural  resources,  and  the  pollution  of  streams  and  ocean  waters  have  played 
their  part  in  recent  years  to  make  the  provision  of  recreation  a  practical  necessity 
for  young  and  old  of  all  classes.86 

But  even  the  rapid  development  of  mass  recreation  in  the  last  genera- 
tion has  not  kept  pace  with  the  increased  need  for  such  physical  and 
mental  outlets  as  recreation  provides.  The  increased  attention  given  to 
recreation  in  the  twentieth  century  has  been  ably  justified  by  Jesse  F. 
Steiner: 

The  modern  recreational  movement  is  so  firmly  entrenched  in  American  life 
and  its  positive  social  results  so  decidedly  outweigh  its  negative  that  it  is  no 
longer  difficult  to  justify  the  increasing  financial  outlays.  The  present  genera- 
tion hardly  needs  a  reminder  of  the  fact  that  wholesome  recreation  leads  to  both 
bodily  and  mental  health.  It  also  breaks  the  monotony  of  labor  and  the  exhaust- 
ing routine  and  regimen  of  our  mechanized  industrial  system.  For  thousands 
recreation  is  now  a  kind  of  cult  aiming  at  physical,  mental  and  moral  efficiency. 
For  additional  thousands  it  opens  the  doors  to  a  new  world  where  during  hours 
of  pleasurable  leisure  the  onerous  drudgeries  of  life  are  forgotten.  Of  an  equal 
if  not  greater  importance  is  the  outlet  given  our  pent-up  emotions.  The  theory 
of  emotional  catharsis,  first  developed  from  the  public  games  and  spectacles  of 
ancient  Greece,  offers  a  psychological  basis  for  the  prevailing  belief  that  recrea- 
tion tends  to  reduce  crime  and  delinquency.  The  large  variety  of  sports  and 
amusements  are,  on  this  basis,  more  than  mere  diversions  for  hours  of  leisure; 
they  are  vital  factors  in  the  progress  of  civilization.  One  of  society's  important 
functions,  therefore,  is  the  cultivation  of  mass  amusements,  activities  and  diver- 
sions appealing  to  all  age  groups  from  the  preadolescent  to  the  far  advanced 
in  life.  It  is  an  insurance  of  social  health.87 


80  E.  C.  Worman,  article  "Recreation,"  Social  Work  Year  Book,  1989,  pp.  361-362. 
87  W.  F.  Ogburn,  et  al.,  Recent  Social  Trends  in  the  United  States,  McGraw-Hill, 
1933,  p.  913. 


828          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

Inventions  and  new  types  of  games  have  helped  to  revolutionize  recrea- 
tion in  the  twentieth  century.  The  profit  motive  has  also  had  full  play 
in  stimulating  recreation.  It  was  authoritatively  estimated  in  1940  that 
we  were  spending  between  three  and  four  billion  dollars  for  commercial- 
ized recreation.  This  gave  industry  a  powerful  vested  interest  in  sup- 
porting and  expanding  this  field  of  recreational  activity.  The  most 
notable  of  the  new  forms  of  commercial  amusement  are  moving  pictures 
and  the  radio.  Radio  manufacturers,  broadcasting  stations,  and  the  gen- 
eral public  spend  millions  to  bring  the  radio  into  the  homes.  Also,  broad- 
casting companies  have  advertisers  who  spend  relatively  lavishly  to  pro^ 
duce  the  programs  which  tliQ  public  enjoys.  The  automobile,  by  putting 
the  nation  on  wheels,  has  promoted  many  and  varied  forms  of  recreation?, 
especially  travel,  camping,  hunting,  fishing,  and  the  like. 

Among  the  non-professionalized  games  in  which  the  public  participates, 
probably  the  most  notable  trend  has  been  the  growth  in  the  popularity 
of  golf  and  tennis.  Golf  still  remains,  partly  on  account  of  the  expense 
involved  in  belonging  to  golf  and  country  clubs,  pretty  much  of  a  class 
game,  with  no  marked  mass  participation.  But  tennis  has  become  one  of 
the  more  popular  sports.  A  large  number  of  tennis  courts  are  provided 
by  the  American  Lawn  Tennis  Association;  there  are  many  class  courts 
associated  with  golf  clubs;  and  many  more  public  tennis  courts  have  been 
provided  by  the  cities  of  the  United  States.  The  greater  availability 
of  tennis  to  the  masses,  as  compared  with  golf,  may  be  seen  from  the  fact 
that,  in  1939,  there  were  only  358  public  golf  courses,  while  11,667  public 
tennis  courts  were  provided  by  American  cities. 

The  increased  interest  in  recreation  and  its  social  significance  are 
reflected  in  the  expansion  of  public  facilities  for  recreation  and  sports, 
both  in  country  and  city  areas.  National  parks  and  forests  have  been 
opened  up  to  travelers,  and  made  available  by  the  automobile.  In  1940, 
there  were  some  20,817,228  acres  of  national  parks,  154  in  number.  In 
1940,  approximately  16,735,000  persons  visited  these  national  parks,  over 
90  per  cent  of  them  in  private  cars.  Under  the  New  Deal  adminis- 
tration an  effort  was  made  to  improve  the  facilities  for  visitors  to  our 
national  parks.  Some  46  new  national  park  projects  have  been  set  up  in 
24  states.  Camping  facilities  are  provided  for  visitors  from  metropolitan 
areas.  The  CCC  and  the  WPA  have  taken  a  leading  part  in  the  prepara- 
tion of  these  recreational  demonstration  projects.  Closely  associated 
with  national  parks  are  our  national  forests,  which  now  have  about  175,- 
000,000  acres  under  the  Forest  Service.  Many  of  these  forests  contain 
extensive  recreational  facilities.  The  increasing  popularity  and  accessi- 
bility of  the  national  forests  may  be  seen  from  the  fact  that,  in  1916,  they 
were  visited  by  only  3,000,000  persons,  while  in  1939  they  were  visited 
by  approximately  33,000,000  persons,  not  including  those  who  merely 
passed  through  them  on  their  way  to  other  destinations. 

Besides  national  parks  and  forests  there  are  many  state,  county,  and 
municipal  parks.  There  are  now  about  two  million  acres  in  state 
parks.  In  1935,  there  were  reported  to  be  some  526  county  parks,  em- 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         829 

bracing  160,000  acres,  and  15,000  municipal  parks  occupying  about  380,- 
000  acres.  The  municipal  parks  are  especially  useful  for  our  crowded 
city  populations.  It  was  estimated,  in  1930,  that  the  capital  invested  in 
municipal  parks  amounted  to  considerably  more  than  a  billion  dollars, 
and  that  over  $100,000,000  is  spent  annually  to  maintain  and  operate 
them.  A  recent  trend  has  been  the  acquisition  by  cities  of  park  areas 
outside  the  corporate  limits  of  municipalities.  There  are  about  130,000 
acres  of  such  parks  at  present. 

A  notable  recent  development  has  been  the  growth  of  public  play- 
grounds, especially  in  connection  with  school  and  community  recreation 
centers.  The  most  potent  force  promoting  this  trend  has  been  the  Na- 
tional Recreation  Association,  created  in  1906.  It  was  then  known  as 
the  Playground  Association  of  America.  In  1910,  there  were  only  about 
1,300  public  playgrounds;  the  number  had  increased  to  7,240  in  1930,  and 
to  9,749  in  1939.  The  extent  and  variety  of  public  recreation  facilities 
provided  by  American  cities  today  is  shown  in  the  following  table  from 
the  1940  yearbook  of  the  National  Recreation  Association,  giving  the 
data  for  1939: 

PUBLIC  RECREATION  FACILITIES  IN  THE  UNITED  STATES  1939 

Facilities  Number  of  Cities 

Supervised  playgrounds,  9,749  792 

Indoor  community  recreation  centers,  4,123  444 

Recreation  buildings,  1,666 395 

Athletic  fields,  875     422 

Baseball  diamonds,  3,846   704 

Public  bathing  beaches,  548 253 

Nine-hole  golf  courses,  146 114 

Eighteen-hole  golf  courses,  212  135 

Indoor  swimming  pools,  315  122 

Outdoor  swimming  pools,  866  399 

Public  tennis  courts,  11,617   716 

Wading  pools,  1,545  426 

Archery  ranges,  455   257 

Bowling  greens,  217   77 

Handball  courts,  1,983  173 

Horseshoe  courts,  9,326  646 

Ice-skating  areas,  2,968   427 

Picnic  areas,  3,511   476 

Play  streets,  298   46 

Shuffleboard  courts,  2,299  259 

Ski  jumps,  116  64 

Softball  diamonds,  8,995  736 

Stadiums,  244   176 

Theaters,  110 70 

Toboggan  slides,  301    114 

The  most  thoroughly  revolutionized  phase  of  recreation  has  been 
travel,  mainly  as  a  result  of  the  production  of  low  priced  cars  and  the 
building  of  better  highways  on  which  these  cars  may  be  operated.  Good 
roads  have  been  extended  into  mountain,  forest,  and  national  park  areas. 
In  1930,  some  92  per  cent  of  the  visitors  to  the  national  forests  and  85 
per  cent  of  the  visitors  to  national  parks  used  automobiles.  In  1916, 
about  15,000  automobiles  entered  the  national  parks,  while  by  1931  the 


830         LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

number  had  increased  to  approximately  900,000.  Motor  tours  have  be- 
come increasingly  popular  as  a  method  of  taking  a  vacation.  The  Amer- 
ican Automobile  Association  estimated  that,  in  1929,  about  45,000,000 
persons  took  vacation  trips  by  automobile  in  the  United  States.  The 
AAA  estimated  that  in  1940  some  5  billion  dollars  were  spent  on  motor 
vacations.  Perhaps  most  significant  are  the  short  automobile  rides  taken 
within  the  community  or  to  near-by  places  during  leisure  hours  each  day. 
The  automobile  has,  of  course,  facilitated  forms  of  recreation  other  than 
travel,  since  it  is  used  for  fishing,  hunting,  going  to  the  movies,  and  any 
number  of  sports  removed  some  distance  from  the  home. 

Closely  related  to  motor  travel  in  general  has  been  the  development  of 
outdoor  camping.  The  American  Camping  Association  has  devoted 
much  effort  to  raising  the  standards  of  camping  equipment  and  leader- 
ship. The  federal  government,  through  the  WPA  and  the  CCC,  has 
labored  to  increase  camping  facilities.  Approximately  10,000,000  per- 
sons camp  somewhere  in  the  national  forests  each  year.  The  hostel 
movement  of  European  youth  was  introduced  to  this  country  in  1935, 
being  especially  popular  in  New  England.  This  provides  attractive 
camping  facilities  for  young  persons  visiting  scenic  areas.  There  were 
227  youth  hostels,  with  11,000  members,  in  1940.  Automobile  travel  and 
camping  have  been  more  closely  combined  than  ever  with  the  advent  of 
automobile  trailers.  Many  of  these  are  on  the  road  today,  as  well  as  in 
the  numerous  tourist  camps  which  are  available  along  all  the  good  high- 
ways. Trailers  concentrate  near  resorts  and  form  veritable  trailer  cities, 
especially  in  areas  like  Florida  and  California  during  the  winter  season. 

The  better  facilities  for  travel  and  camping  have  encouraged  hunting 
and  fishing.  In  average  years  over  7,000,000  hunting  and  fishing  licenses 
are  issued,  and  millions  of  dollars  are  spent  for  hunting  and  fishing 
equipment. 

Water  sports  have  increased  in  recent  years.  The  number  of  public 
bathing  beaches  maintained  by  American  cities  increased  from  127  in 
1923  to  548  in  1939.  In  Chicago,  during  the  summer  of  1930,  some 
7,000,000  persons  used  the  public  bathing  beaches.  The  number  of  pub- 
lic swimming  pools  has  also  increased  more  than  100  per  cent  since  1923, 
some  1,181  being  reported  in  1939.  It  has  been  estimated  that  there  are 
over  3,500  private  and  public  swimming  pools  in  the  United  States.  In 
1937,  some  124  cities  reported  an  attendance  of  over  100,000,000  at  bath- 
ing beaches  and  swimming  pools. 

The  increased  popularity  of  the  automobile  on  land  has  been  paralleled 
by  the  use*  of  motor  boats  for  recreation.  In  1930  there  were  250,000 
registered  motor  boats,  at  least  three-quarters  of  which  were  used  for 
pleasure. 

Skiing,  formerly  a  recreation  chiefly  limited  to  Alpine  and  other  Euro- 
pean resorts,  has  attracted  an  ever  greater  number  of  Americans  in  areas 
where  there  is  snow.  Owing  to  the  relative  difficulty  of  motor  travel  in 
winter  weather,  the  railroads  have  cooperated  in  bringing  skiers  to  suitable 
locations.  Special  cars  for  skiers  are  added  to  regular  trains,  and  special 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         831 

ski  trains  are  run  from  city  centers  to  highlands  and  mountain  areas. 
Airplanes  are  also  widely  used  by  the  more  opulent  skiers. 

Americans  are  notable  organizers  and  joiners;  hence,  it  is  not  surprising 
to  find,  besides  local  organizations  devoted  to  the  promotion  of  sports,  na- 
tional organizations  which  have  formulated  rules,  stimulated  activities, 
and  endeavored  to  raise  the  general  level  of  sportsmanship  in  various 
fields.  Among  these  are  The  United  States  Golf  Association,  the  Amer- 
ican Lawn  Tennis  Association,  Amateur  Athletic  Union  of  the  United 
States,  National  Amateur  Athletic  Federation,  American  Olympic  Asso- 
ciation, Amateur  Fencers'  League  of  America,  National  Association  of 
Amateur  Oarsmen,  Amateur  Billiard  Association  of  America,  American 
Skating  Union  of  the  United  States,  American  Canoe  Association,  Amer- 
ican Snow  Shoe  Union,  National  Association  of  Scientific  Angling  Clubs, 
National  Cycling  Association,  National  Horse  Shoe  Pitchers'  Association, 
National  Ski  Association,  National  Amateur  Casting  Association,  Na- 
tional Collegiate  Athletic  Association,  and  United  States  Football  Asso- 
ciation. 

By  all  odds  the  most  important  organization  promoting  an  interest  in 
recreation  and  raising  the  standards  therein  has  been  the  National 
Recreation  Association.  This  grew  out  of  the  devotion  and  enthusiasm 
of  Joseph  Lee  (1862-1937),  of  Boston.  In  1894,  Lee  learned  in  a  news- 
paper that  boys  had  been  arrested  for  playing  ball  in  a  street.  He 
indignantly  protested  that  "those  boys  were  arrested  for  living."  From 
that  time  onward,  he  devoted  himself  to  the  playground  movement,  with 
the  text  that  "the  boy  without  a  playground  is  the  father  to  the  man 
without  a  job."  Important  social  workers,  like  Jane  Addains  and  Jacob 
A.  Rii£,  encouraged  Lee.  President  Theodore  Roosevelt  enthusiastically 
supported  the  program. 

The  first  meeting  was  called  together  in  New  York  in  the  winter  of 
1904-05  by  Dr.  Henry  S.  Curtis,  the  most  notable  members  of  the  orig- 
inal group  being  Lee  and  Dr.  Luther  H.  Gulick.  A  number  of  meetings 
were  held  in  the  next  few  months,  and,  in  November,  1905,  the  name  of 
the  Playground  Association  of  America  was  chosen  for  the  new  organ- 
ization. The  organization  was  formally  launched  on  April  12,  1906,  with 
the  warm  approval  of  President  Roosevelt.  Lee,  one  of  our  leading 
authorities  on  recreation,  became  president  of  the  organization  in  1910, 
and  remained  at  its  head  until  1935.  The  name  was  later  changed  to  the 
National  Recreation  Association.  Lee  was  a  wealthy  man  and  generously 
endowed  the  recreation  movement,  giving  some  $360,000  to  the  Play- 
ground Association.  He  was  rewarded  by  seeing  the  number  of  play- 
grounds in  the  country  increase  by  more  than  tenfold  between  1910  and 
1935.  The  National  Recreation  Association  not  only  has  labored  vigor- 
ously to  increase  interest  in  sports  and  play ;  it  has  done  more  than  any 
other  organization  to  promote  the  growth  of  playgrounds  and  to  emphasize 
the  necessity  of  supervised  play  and  recreation.  It  has  tried  to  make  the 
latter  a  source  of  personality-building  as  well  as  of  physical  exercise  and 
emotional  outlet. 


832          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

Mainly  as  a  result  of  the  work  of  the  National  Recreation  Associa- 
tion, there  has  been  a  remarkable  expansion  of  community  recreational 
facilities,  a  matter  which  we  have  already  mentioned.  Though  the  public 
playgrounds  are  almost  exclusively  an  American  institution,  the  play- 
ground movement  was  really  introduced  into  this  country  from  Europe. 
In  1885,  Dr.  Marie  Zakrzewska  visited  Berlin  and  witnessed  children 
playing  on  sandpiles  in  the  public  parks  of  that  city.  Upon  her  return, 
she  opened  a  sand  garden  in  Boston.  These  early  play  centers  for  small 
children  later  grew  into  model  playgrounds,  equipped  with  the  customary 
apparatus.  The  social  settlements  also  encouraged  the  early  growth  of 
playgrounds,  Hull  House  in  Chicago  opening  one  in  1893,  and  the  Henry 
Street  Settlement  in  New  York,  another  in  1895. 

By  the  beginning  of  the  present  century,  New  York,  Chicago,  Philadel- 
phia, Pittsburgh,  Baltimore,  New  Haven,  Providence,  San  Francisco  and 
other  large  cities  had  begun  to  provide  public  playgrounds.  The  move- 
ment gained  rapid  headway  after  the  formation  of  the  National  Recrea- 
tion Association  in  1906.  In  some  27  states,  cities  now  have  the  right  to 
set  up  public  recreation  systems.  By  1939,  some  792  cities  provided 
9,749  public  playgrounds,  together  with  4,123  indoor  community  recrea- 
tion centers,  and  1,666  recreation  buildings.  There  were  about  100,- 
000,000  participants  in  the  recreation  centers  and  recreation  buildings. 
In  1939,  no  less  than  1,204  urban  communities  were  supplying  organized 
public  recreation  facilities,  at  a  total  annual  cost  of  approximately  $57,- 
000,000.  The  degree  to  which  supervised  play  has  developed  is  shown 
by  the  fact  that  in  1939  these  1,204  urban  communities  hired  some  25,- 
042  recreation  workers  to  supervise  playground  activities.  Along  with 
these  were  some  18,000  supplementary  supervisors,  paid  out  of  emergency 
funds  supplied  mainly  by  the  federal  government.  And  in  addition  to 
both  of  these  were  some  10,000  volunteer  supervisors.  The  growth  of  the 
supervised  play  movement  may  be  noted  from  the  fact  that,  in  1912,  there 
were  only  5,320  paid  supervisors  of  recreation,  and  the  total  amount  ex- 
pended for  public  community  recreation  was  only  $4,000,000. 

Even  private  industry  has  extensively  fostered  recreation  to  improve 
.the  health  and  morale  of  employees.  In  a  survey  of  2,700  concerns,  cov- 
ered by  the  investigation  of  the  National  Industrial  Conference  Board,  it 
was  found  that  552  provided  athletic  facilities  and  411  had  clubhouses  for 
such  activities. 

A  remarkable  development  in  recreation  and  the  extension  of  recrea- 
tional facilities  has  been  the  generous  aid  rendered  by  the  federal  govern- 
ment under  various  New  Deal  auspices.  E.  C.  Worman  thus  summarizes 
the  extent  of  this  government  aid  to  community  recreation: 

By  1938  the  emergency  relief  agencies  of  the  federal  government,  including  the 
WPA,  the  National  Youth  Administration  (NYA)  and  the  Resettlement  Admin- 
istration (now  the  Farm  Security  Administration)  had  spent  one  billion  dollars 
for  recreation  purposes.  At  one  time  there  were  49,000  persons  employed  by  the 
Recreation  Division  of  the  WPA  and  a  similar  number  by  the  NYA.  Literally 
thousands  of  recreation  facilities,  such  as  camps,  picnicking  grounds,  trails,  swim- 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         833 

ming  pools,  and  so  forth,  have  been  built.  The  Department  of  the  Interior 
through  the  National  Park  Service  and  the  Office  of  Education;  the  Department 
of  Agriculture  through  the  Forest  Service,  the  Bureau  of  Agricultural  Economics, 
the  Bureau  of  Biological  Survey,  and  the  Bureau  of  Home  Economics;  and  32 
other  bureaus  or  offices  are  related  in  some  way  to  recreation  service,  much  of 
which  has  developed  during  the  depression.88 

To  be  more  specific,  to  June,  1939,  WPA  workers  had  built  7,621  new 
recreation  buildings,  2,394  athletic  fields,  2,078  playgrounds,  1,164  new 
swimming  and  wading  pools,  and  6,347  tennis  courts,  and  had  cleared 
332,618  acres  of  new  park  projects.  The  federal  government  contributed 
$26,000,000  to  support  supervised  play  in  1939. 

This  revolutionary  increase  in  recreational  facilities  has  been  accom- 
panied by  a  more  dynamic  philosophy  with  respect  to  play.  There  has 
been  a  shift  of  interest  from  mere  play  itself  to  an  ever  greater  considera- 
tion of  the  effects  of  play  upon  participants.  Physical  hygiene  has  been 
supplemented  by  mental  hygiene.  There  is  no  longer  a  tendency  to 
believe  that,  once  a  playground  is  set  up  and  supervisors  supplied,  the 
process  will  take  care  of  itself.  A  serious  research  interest  in  the  nature 
and  effects  of  play  has  been  developed.  This  new  philosophy  and  the 
new  objectives  of  play  and  recreation  have  been  well  summarized  by 
Dr.  V.  K.  Brown: 

Our  objectives  are  moving  over  into  new  ground.  Where  we  once  were  con- 
tent to  issue  medals  of  award  for  signal  accomplishment,  and  to  consider  victory 
a  sufficient  end  in  itself,  in  view  of  the  striving  and  the  sacrifice  which  made  the 
victory  possible,  now  we  are  concerned  far  more  with  the  spiritual  significances 
of  that  victory  to  the  victor  himself,  to  the  steadying  fact  it  represents  to  him — 
the  fact,  however  later  life  may  buffet  him,  that  once,  at  least,  in  a  contest  where 
he  threw  his  whole  self  into  the  issue,  in  spite  of  opposition,  fatigue,  and  difficulty, 
he  fought  through  to  triumph,  and  stood  at  the  end  unconquered  and  uncon- 
querable. Long  ago,  we  passed  the  point  where  we  were  interested  exclusively  in 
what  people  do  in  recreation ;  the  trend  is  now  to  consider,  as  more  vital,  rather 
what  the  thing  done  itself  does,  in  turn,  to  the  doer  of  it.39 

The  development  of  recreational  facilities  in  rural  areas  has  lagged 
behind  the  progress  in  cities  and  the  larger  village  communities.  A  care- 
ful survey  in  1935  showed  that  rural  communities  had  a  96  per  cent  defi- 
ciency in  personnel  for  recreational  supervision  and  an  even  greater  lack 
of  recreational  facilities.  The  very  nature  of  rural  life  provides  plenty 
of  outdoor  activity,  but  organized  and  supervised  recreation  in  the  coun- 
try has  been  only  slightly  developed.  A  number  of  organizations  have 
endeavored  to  overcome  this  deplorable  backwardness  of  rural  recrea- 
tion. The  extension  service  of  the  United  States  Department  of  Agri- 
culture has  promoted  rural  recreation  through  the  4-H  Clubs  and  has 
encouraged  camping  by  rural  women.  The  National  Recreation  Associa- 
tion has  held  systematic  rural  institutes  for  more  than  a  decade  and  has 
trained  about  60,000  rural  recreation  leaders,  drawn  from  schools, 
churches,  the  Grange,  4-H  Clubs,  and  the  like.  Some  of  the  emergency 


38  "Recreation,"  Social  Work  Year  Book,  1989,  pp.  371-372. 

89  V.  K.  Brown,  "Trends  in  Recreation  Service,"  Recreation,  May,  1931,  p.  63. 


834          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

relief  work  carried  on  by  the  WPA  has  befen  devoted  to  the  improvement 
of  rural  recreational  facilities. 

But  far  and  away  the  most  important  practical  advance  in  rural  recre- 
atipnal  facilities  has  been  the  appearance  and  growth  of  consolidated  and 
centralized  schools.  These  merge  and  concentrate  the  resources  of  the 
rural  community  and  provide  playground  facilities  accessible  to  rural 
youth.  All  the  better  schools  of  this  sort  have  paid  supervisors  of  ath- 
letics. But  even  here  the  facilities  favor  the  participation  of  the  children 
who  reside  in  the  village  where  the  centralized  school  is  located.  The 
rural  children  can  normally  use  these  facilities  only  during  noon  and 
recess  hours,  since  the  buses  bring  them  to  the  schools  at  the  moment 
school  begins  and  takes  them  home  as  soon  as  the  period  of  instruction  is 
over.  Most  of  the  new  mechanical  facilities  for  recreation  and  amuse- 
ment, notably  the  automobile,  movies,  and  radio,  are  enjoyed  by  the 
rural  population. 

In  spite  of  the  remarkable  development  of  recreational  facilities,  we 
have  as  yet  only  scratched  the  surface  in  the  way  of  providing  thor- 
oughly adequate  playground  facilities  for  American  youth,  to  say  nothing 
of  American  adults.  In  1930  it  was  estimated  that  only  5,000,000  out 
of  approximately  32,000,000  children  between  the  ages  of  6  and  18  were 
served  by  public  playgrounds.  Even  in  1938,  it  was  estimated  that  at 
least  8,000,000  urban  children  and  12,000,000  rural  children  had  no  pub- 
lic playground  facilities.  There  is  also  a  shortage  of  park  acreage  to 
meet  the  needs  of  the  present  urban  population.  Notwithstanding  the 
growth  of  parks  and  better  automobile  transportation,  most  young  people 
living  in  cities  still  have  to  depend  upon  motion  pictures,  dance  halls,  pool 
rooms,  and  the  like  for  most  of  their  diversion.  One  of  the  most  notori- 
ous inadequacies  of  our  day  has  been  the  failure,  as  yet,  to  force  the 
public  school  system  to  cooperate  intelligently  and  completely  in  the 
creation  of  a  well-rounded  municipal  recreation  program. 

Despite  their  inadequacy,  recreation  and  leisure-time  activities  already 
constitute  a  big  business  in  themselves.  They  involve  annual  expendi- 
tures greater  than  any  New  Deal  budget  before  1940.  In  1930,  it  was 
estimated  that  the  total  cost  of  recreation,  broadly  interpreted,  amounted 
to  a  little  more  than  $10,000,000,000,  nearly  two  thirds  of  which  could  be 
attributed,  directly  and  indirectly,  to  the  use  of  automobiles  and  motor 
boats  for  recreational  purposes.  Professor  Steiner  has  compiled  the 
table  on  page  835,  itemizing  the  expenditures  for  recreation,  in  the  year 
1930. 

An  outstanding  leisure-time  phenomenon  has  been  the  development  of 
athletic  sports  as  public  spectacles  and  the  commercialization  of  the  lat- 
ter. Millions  attend  these  spectacles  in  person;  many  more  millions 
participate  in  them  vicariously  through  the  newspapers,  moving  pictures, 
and  radio  broadcasts.  Almost  everything  else  is  forced  out  of  public 
attention  at  the  time  of  radio  broadcasts  of  championship  boxing  matches, 
World  Series  ball  games,  and  leading  inter-collegiate  football  games. 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         835 

ESTIMATED  ANNUAL  COST  OF  RECREATION  *o 

(In  thousands  of  dollars) 

Amount  of  Expenditures 

A.  Governmental  expenditures: 

1.  Municipalities    $   147,179 

2.  Counties    8,600 

3.  Federal  9,300 

4.  States    28,331 

Total    $     193,410 

B.  Travel  and  mobility: 

1.  Vacation  travel  in  U.  S. 

(a)  Automobile    touring    $3,200,000 

(b)  Travel  by  rail  750,000 

(c)  Travel  by  air  and  water  25,000 

2.  Vacation  travel  abroad 

(a)  To   Canada    266,283 

(b)  To    Mexico    55,642 

(c)  To    countries    overseas    391,470 

(d)  To   insular  possessions    1,326 

( e )  Alien   American    tourists   abroad    76,000 

3.  Pleasure-use  of  cars,  boats,  etc. 

(a)  Automobiles  (except  touring)    1,246,000 

(b)  Motor  boats    460,000 

(c)  Motor   cycles    10,796 

(d)  Bicycles   9,634 

Total     6,492,151 

C.  Commercial  amusements: 

1.  Moving  pictures   $1,500,000 

2.  Qther  admissions    166,000 

3.  Cabarets  and  night  clubs   23,725 

4.  Radios  and  radio  broadcasting  525,000 

Total  ~7777TT  2,214,725 

D.  Leisure  time  associations: 

1.  Social  and  athletic  clubs  $125,000 

2.  Luncheon   clubs    7,500 

3.  Lodges 175,000 

4.  Youth  service  and  similar  organizations  75,000 

Total 382,500 

E.  Games,  sports,  outdoor  life,  etc.: 

1.  Toys,  games,  playground  equipment  $113,800 

2.  Pool,  billiards,  bowling  equipment   12,000 

3.  Playing   cards    20,000 

4.  Sporting  and  athletic  goods  500,000 

5.  Hunting  and  fishing  license  12,000 

6.  College  football    21,500 

7.  Resort  hotels  75,000 

8.  Commercial  and  other  camps  47,000 

9.  Fireworks 6,771 

10.  Phonographs  and  accessories  75,000 

Total  883,071 

Total  annual  cost  of  recreation  $10,165,857 


Recent  Social  Trends,  McGraw-Hill,  Vol.  II,  p.  949. 


836          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

Baseball  still  remains  the  great  "national  game,"  though  it  is  now  being 
hard  pressed  by  inter-collegiate  and  professional  football.  In  1941  each 
of  the  major  leagues  drew  an  attendance  of  over  5,000,000,  the  American 
League  having  an  attendance  of  5,220,519  and  the  National  League  of 
5,029,689. 

The  greatest  attendance  comes  at  the  time  of  the  World  Series  games. 
This  reached  its  maximum  in  1926,  when  328,051  saw  the  series  between 
the  St.  Louis  National  League  team  and  the  New  York  American  League 
team.  The  receipts  in  this  year  were  $1,207,064.  The  nearest  to  a 
duplication  of  these  figures  came  in  1936  when  302,924  persons  witnessed 
the  series  between  the  New  York  National  League  and  the  New  York 
American  League  teams,  the  receipts  being  $1,204,399. 

Inter-collegiate  football  also  grew  into  a  big  business.  In  1930,  some 
3,289,000  persons  attended  these  games,  the  receipts  being  $8,363,674,  a 
gain  of  210  per  cent  over  the  figures  of  1921.  Seating  facilities  grew  from 
929,000  in  1920  to  2,307,000  in  1930.  The  figures  for  1930  were  based 
upon  the  reports  of  49  institutions  as  to  attendance,  and  65  institutions  as 
to  receipts.  It  has  been  estimated  that  the  total  attendance  at  all  inter- 
collegiate football  games  in  1930  was  over  10  million  with  receipts  of 
over  21  million  dollars.  The  increasing  commercialization  of  inter- 
collegiate football  has  brought  serious  criticism  from  educators,  who  feel 
that  this  development  has  distracted  attention  from  learning.41 

There  has  been  a  notable  growth  in  the  popularity  of  professional  foot- 
ball, especially  in  the  larger  cities  of  the  East.  The  teams  are  recruited 
chiefly  from  the  stars  of  former  inter-collegiate  teams.  The  attendance 
at  these  games  has  come  to  rival  seriously  the  figures  in  the  most  thrilling 
and  exciting  inter-collegiate  games.  This  popularity  of  professional 
football  has  become  most  marked  in  the  years  since  1930.  Official  organ- 
izations of  professional  football  leagues  were  instituted  in  1941. 

Boxing,  particularly  in  the  heavy-weight  class,  has  produced  a  greater 
attendance  and  larger  receipts  than  any  other  type  of  commercialized 
sporting  spectacle.  A  generation  ago,  men  like  Corbett  and  Fitz- 
simmons  fought  for  a  purse  of  a  few  thousand  dollars,  but  a  million-dollar 
gate  was  produced  in  1921,  at  the  Dempsey-Carpentier  fight  at  Boyle's 
Thirty  Acres  in  Jersey  City.  The  high  point  in  professional  boxing 
came  in  1927,  when  the  return  engagement  between  Dempsey  and  Tunney 
drew  a  gate  of  $2,650,000.  The  inferior  quality  of  heavy-weight  boxers 
in  the  decade  which  followed  produced  smaller  gates,  though  the  most 
perfunctory  engagement  brought  an  income  which  would  have  seemed 
mythical  in  the  days  of  John  L.  Sullivan.  Even  the  fight  between  Jack 
Sharkey  and  Tommy  Loughran  in  1929  paid  $320,335,  as  against  $270,755 
for  the  dramatic  Johnson-Jefferies  fight  in  1910,  which  marked  the  larg- 
est gate  ever  known  down  to  that  time.  The  unusual  fistic  prowess  of 
Joe  Louis,  and  his  unprecedented  willingness  to  defend  his  heavyweight 
"crown"  frequently,  have  stimulated  interest  in  boxing  in  the  last  few 


41  See  above,  pp.  761-763. 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         837 

years,  but  even  here  the  game  has  suffered  for  lack  of  competent  oppo- 
nents for  Louis.  There  has  been  less  popular  interest  in  the  far  more 
exciting  fights  between  lighter  weight  pugilists,  though  the  remarkable 
achievements  of  Henry  Armstrong  in  1938-1940  brought  about  a  consid- 
erable following  for  this  class  of  fighters. 

Professional  wrestling  has  not  attained  the  prestige  or  popularity  of 
commercialized  boxing.  The  sport  has  not  been  as  thoroughly  regulated 
as  boxing,  championships  are  always  in  dispute,  and  the  sport  is  not 
unfairly  suspected  of  much  dishonesty  and  the  "fixing  of  bouts."  How- 
ever, wrestling  has  become  ostensibly  more  rough  and  brutal  in  recent 
years,  perhaps  thus  seeking  to  increase  popular  following.  Some  major 
bouts  do  attract  large  crowds,  but  nothing  comparable  to  those  at  cham- 
pionship boxing  matches. 

Despite  efforts  to  curb  racetrack  gambling,  horse  racing  has  become 
an  important  commercialized  sport,  though  by  no  means  attracting  the 
attendance  of  baseball  and  football  games.  Large  sums  are  paid  to  own- 
ers of  winning  horses.  In  1920,  the  earnings  were  approximately  $7,775,- 
000.  By  1930,  they  had  almost  doubled.  But  the  sums  involved  in 
the  stakes  won  by  horses  are  insignificant  when  compared  to  the  gam- 
bling bill  associated  with  horse  racing.  It  has  been  estimated  by  experts 
that  the  annual  losses  by  those  betting  on  horse  races  in  the  United  States 
amounts  to  at  least  one  and  a  half  billion  dollars. 

This  brief  discussion  of  the  development  of  recreation  in  the  twentieth 
century  will  suffice  to  demonstrate  the  vast  increase  of  interest  and 
the  enormous  growth  of  receipts.  Nevertheless,  the  majority  of  Ameri- 
cans p-re  not  provided  in  any  adequate  manner  with  opportunities  for 
wholesome  recreation.  Further,  the  increasing  stress  upon  victory  and 
championships,  at  whatever  cost,  rather  than  the  enjoyment  of  sport  for 
its  own  sake,  destroys  the  intellectual  and  cultural  effects  of  a  great  deal 
of  our  recreational  activity.  The  latter  is  also  degraded  through  the 
excessive  commercialization  of  sports,  with  occasional  overt  dishonesty 
and  exploitation  by  gamblers.  However,  we  may  expect  the  revolution- 
ary growth  of  recreational  interests,  activity  and  expenditures  to  con- 
tinue, and  we  may  hope  for  an  ever  increased  control  of  this  development 
by  sound  psychological,  sociological,  and  aesthetic  principles.  Professor 
Steiner  has  well  summarized  the  outstanding  trends  in  contemporary 
recreation: 

This  brief  survey  of  recent  recreational  developments  gives  some  conception 
of  the  magnitude  of  the  leisure  time  field,  as  well  as  its  growing  importance  in 
present  day  affairs.  The  trends  that  stand  out  most  prominently  and  seem  to 
be  characteristic  of  the  whole  movement  may  be  summarized  as  follows :  interest 
in  active  participation  in  games  and  sports;  the  nationwide  vogue  of  automobile 
touring  and  pleasure  travel;  the  development  of  outdoor  life  and  vacation  activi- 
ties; acceptance  of  governmental  responsibility  for  providing  public  recreational 
facilities;  expansion  of  the  field  of  commercial  amusements;  the  desire  for  amuse- 
ments that  provide  thrills  and  excitement;  preoccupation  with  the  outcome  of 
competitive  games  and  sports;  popularity  of  forms  of  creation  that  promote 
social  relations  between  the  sexes;  and  the  development  of  organizations  that 


838          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

facilitate  recreational  interests.  More  briefly,  the  two  most  important  trends  in 
modern  recreation  in  this  country  have  been  the  widespread  development  of 
commercialized  facilities  for  the  enjoyment  of  passive  amusements,  and  the  rapid 
growth  of  private  and  public  facilities  for  participation  in  a  large  variety  of 
games  and  sports  and  other  active  recreational  activities.  From  the  point  of 
view  of  numbers  reached,  commercial  amusements,  largely  because  of  motion 
pictures  and  the  radio,  seem  to  occupy  the  leading  position,  but  when  costs  are 
taken  into  consideration,  the  bulk  of  our  recreational  expenditures  must  be 
charged  against  active  rather  than  passive  forms  of  leisure  time  pursuits.  .  .  . 
However  difficult  their  solution,  modern  forms  of  recreation  have  become  so 
deeply  rooted  in  our  social  fabric  that  there  can  be  no  thought  of  going  back 
to  the  simpler  pleasures  of  an  earlier  generation.  To  a  degree  hitherto  unknown, 
sports,  games  and  amusements  have  gained  recognition  as  a  vital  part  of  human 
living  and  are  acceptecl  as  a  necessity  for  which  provision  must  be  made.  The 
depression  is  temporarily  curtailing  some  of  these  activities  but  there  is  no  evi- 
dence of  any  declining  interest.  During  the  next  few  years  the  curve  of  recrea- 
tional growth  may  not  rise  as  rapidly  as  in  the  immediate  past,  but  there  seems 
to  be  no  doubt  that  it  will  continue  to  move  upward.  What  is  needed  is  a  larger 
degree  of  statesmanlike  planning  than  has  yet  been  attempted  in  order  that  the 
further  development  of  the  recreation  movement  may  be  as  much  as  possible 
in  the  interests  of  the  general  welfare.42 

Art  as  a   Phase  of  Leisure-Time  Activity 

Along  with  play  and  recreation,  we  must  surely  consider  art  as  an  out- 
standing expression  of  the  leisure-time  activity  of  man.  In  our  discus- 
sion of  art  we  shall  interpret  it  in  the  broadest  sense  as  including  archi- 
tecture, sculpture,  painting,  music,  the  drama,  literature,  and  all  phases 
of  aesthetic  expression. 

There  is  no  sharp  break  or  wide  gulf  between  play  and  art.  Indeed, 
art  is  a  sort  of  racial  expression  of  the  play  motive  in  the  individual. 
As  Irwin  Edrnan  puts  it: 

The  arts  serve  in  an  important  sense  the  same  function  in  the  race  that  play 
does  in  the  individual.  On  the  part  of  the  artist,  despite  the  fact  that  the  arts 
involve  technical  difficulties  and  that  their  pursuance  often  entails  social  sacrifices, 
they  have  something  of  the  quality  of  play  and  they  constitute  a  type  of  spon- 
taneous action  which  any  polity  might  well  wish  to  insure  for  all  its  citizens.4211 

In  briefly  summarizing  the  role  of  the  arts  in  leisure  time  activities  we 
shall  deal  only  with  the  social  aspects  of  art,  making  no  pretense  what- 
ever to  giving  a  technical  analysis  of  the  history  and  nature  of  art. 

Perhaps  as  good  an  introductory  definition  of  art  as  any  we  could 
offer  is  suggested  by  Alfred  D.  F.  Hamlin,  who  says  that  "art,  in  its 
broadest  sense,  is  the  purposeful  exercise  of  human  activities  for  the 
accomplishment  of  some  predetermined  end  of  use  or  pleasure.  Art  is 
thus  set  apart  from  Nature  which  exists  and  operates  outside  of  man,  and 
which  can  enter  the  domain  of  art  only  when  and  insofar  as  man  calls 
her  into  his  service  by  employing  her  powers  for  his  own  purposed 
ends." 43  The  deliberate  element  in  art  is  more  directly  related  to  the 
practical  arts  than  to  the  fine  arts.  The  latter  have  no  function  other 


42  Recent  Social  Trends,  McGraw-Hill,  Vol.  II,  pp.  954,  957. 

*2a  Article  "Art,"  Encyclopaedia  of  the  Social  Sciences,  Vol.  2,  pp.  225-226. 

48  Article  "Art,"  Encyclopaedia  Americana,  Vol.  2,  p.  335. 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         839 

than  to  provide  enjoyment  and  they  are  mainly  the  product  of  sponta- 
neous creative  activity  on  the  part  of  the  artist. 

In  discussing  the  arts  a  sharp  distinction  is  usually  made  between  the 
fine  arts,  and  the  useful  or  practical  arts.  The  fine  arts  are  characterized 
^primarily  by  the  fact  that  they  have  little  practical  utility  but  are  capa- 
ble of  bringing  spontaneous  and  immediate  enjoyment  to  the  artist  and 
the  observer.  In  the  broadest  sense,  the  practical  arts  include  all  indus- 
tries and  the  techniques  for  producing  food,  shelter,  and  clothing.  Often 
the  term  is  given  a  more  limited  application,  describing  objects  that  are 
both  useful  and  beautiful,  such  as  Indian  baskets,  beautiful  vases,  and 
decorative  iron  work.  The  distinction  between  the  fine  arts  and  the 
practical  arts  is  not  always  clearly  drawn.  In  primitive  times,  tools  and 
weapons  were  a  matter  of  artistic  effort  as  well  as  of  utilitarian  value, 
and  even  ostensibly  artistic  products  had  a  practical  value  through  their 
relation  to  religion  and  magic.  Pictures  of  animals,  for  example,  were 
thought  to  give  some  magical  control  over  them  and  to  facilitate  the 
process  of  hunting.  Among  the  Greeks,  and  again  in  the  medieval  craft 
gilds,  there  was  such  a  pride  in  workmanship  that  even  utilitarian  prod- 
ucts were  turned  out  with  something  of  the  artist's  pride  and  seriousness. 
The  industrial  arts,  especially  the  handmade  metal  work,  of  colonial 
America  were  probably  the  outstanding  art  products  of  that  era. 

Since  the  Industrial  Revolution  and  the  rise  of  mechanical  industry,  a 
real  gulf  seems  to  have  appeared  between  the  fine  arts  and  the  practical 
arts.  However,  recently  an  effort  has  been  made  to  give  some  artistic 
flavor  to  objects  of  utility.  We  see  this  in  the  artistic  design  of  sky- 
scrapers, in  the  attention  given  to  the  beautification  of  automobiles,  in 
the  decoration  of  buildings,  and  in  the  design  of  furniture.  The  drab 
standardization  of  former  days  is  passing  away. 

The  fine  arts  may  be  regarded,  in  a  fundamental  way,  as  a  product  of 
our  emotions.  Sex,  the  play  impulse,  and  other  phases  of  the  drive 
for  self-expression  seem  to  lie  at  the  foundation  of  art.  But  this  fact 
should  not  obscure  the  outstanding  element  in  the  origin  of  art,  namely 
that  art  is  a  social  product.  The  emotions  which  underlie  art  are  called 
forth  mainly  by  social  situations  and  needs,  such  as  religion,  war,  sex 
and  family  activities,  ritual,  and  group  play.  Art  serves  a  definite  social 
function  in  providing  sources  of  spontaneous  enjoyment  for  social  groups. 
Art  provides  expression  for  social  values.  The  changes  in  artistic  ideals 
and  methods  are  closely  related  to  underlying  social  transformations. 
However  individualized  may  be  the  emotional  experiences  of  the  artist, 
it  remains  a  fact  that  art  is  socially  conditioned  in  its  origins,  functions, 
and  manifestations. 

Landmarks  in  the  Development  of  Art 

There  are  several  outstanding  elements  to  be  emphasized  in  describ- 
ing primitive  art.44  Since  religion  dominates  all  phases  of  primitive  life, 

44  T/.  E.  A.  Parkyn,  Prehistoric  Art,  Longmans,  1915. 


840          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

it  is  not  surprising  that  it  exerted  a  great  influence  over  primitive  art. 
Many  authorities  believe,  for  example,  that  the  marvelous  cave  paint- 
ings of  the  stone  age  were  produced  because  of ,  the  belief  that  they  would 
give  the  hunters  a  magical  control  over  the  animals  drawn.  Some  author- 
ities question  this  interpretation,  but  there  is  no  doubt  of  the  importance 
of  magic  in  primitive  art.  The  great  stone  monuments  of  the  Neolithic 
age  attest  the  degree  to  which  religion  could  bring  forth  social  effort  of  a 
fundamentally  artistic  character.  The  totem  poles  of  the  American 
Indians  admirably  illustrate  the  fusion  of  the  social  and  religious  in 
primitive  art.  Another  phase  of  primitive  art  was  its  practicality. 
Much  of  primitive  artistic  effort  and  design  had  a  utilitarian  basis  and 
was  connected  with  the  development  of  weapons,  tools,  textiles,  and 
pottery.  There  were  relatively  few  products  of  primitive  art  which  did 
not  have  some  utility,  real  or  imaginary,  of  a  magical  or  industrial  sort. 
A  third  characteristic  of  primitive  art  lay  in  the  use  of  symbolism, 
wherein  a  part  was  made  to  stand  for  the  whole,  and  conventionalization, 
which  might  go  so  far  that  the  original  figures  and  objects  would  be 
unrecognizable.  Decorative  tendencies  tended  to  crowd  out  realism.  In 
some  cases,  primitive  decorative  art  attained  an  elaborate  technique,  as 
in  the  Maya  art  of  Yucatan  and  Guatemala. 

In  the  ancient  Near  East,  art  became  far  more  divorced  from  the  com- 
mon people  than  in  primitive  times.  In  primitive  society,  almost  every- 
body participated  in  artistic  activity  in  one  way  or  another.  But  with  the 
rise  of  a  rich  leisure  class  of  kings  and  nobles,  art  became  limited  mainly 
to  this  group,  though  the  people  might  view  it  from  afar.  The  religioufe 
motive  was  still  powerful.  The  sculptures  of  gods,  guardian  animals  and 
monsters,  and  the  temples,  tombs,  and  pyramids  attest  the  strength  of 
the  religious  motive  in  art.  The  ruling  classes  exploited  art  to  glorify 
their  status  and  prestige.  This  tendency  is  shown  in  the  remains  of  their 
elaborately  decorated  palaces.  Assyrian  art  expressed  and  glorified  the 
war  motive  more,  perhaps,  than  has  been  the  case  in  any  other  period  of 
history.  Since  sex  and  reproduction  were  prominent  in  oriental  re- 
ligion, it  is  not  surprising  that  they  were  conspicuous  in  oriental  art.  This 
was  especially  true  of  the  art  of  the  Hittities,  Cretans,  and  Philistines. 

No  other  people  have  been  as  profoundly  influenced  by  or  devoted  to 
art  as  were  the  ancient  Greeks,  especially  the  Greeks  of  ancient  Athens. 
With  most  of  us  in  the  United  States,  art  is  something  apart  from  our 
daily  life.  It  does  not  in  any  large  sense  pervade  our  very  being  and 
order  our  reactions  toward  life.  But  this  was  exactly  what  it  did  with 
the  cultured  Greeks  of  Periclean  Athens.  To  them,  art  was  not  some- 
thing to  look  at  in  bored  fashion  in  a  museum  on  a  Sunday  afternoon,  but 
it  was  a  vital  aspect  of  their  existence.  Such  things  as  rhythm,  propor- 
tion, balance,  order,  and  taste  were  as  important  to  the  cultivated  Greeks 
as  bank  balances,  stock-exchange  reports,  baseball  scores,  and  fashion 
plates  are  to  us  today.  The  artist  then  was  regarded  as  one  of  the  most 
honored  and  respected  members  of  the  community.  The  Greeks  never 
regarded  a  work  of  art  as  a  "good"  existing  in  a  void,  Plato  seems  to 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         841 

have  regarded  such  an  idea  as  inimical  to  social  well-being  and  looked 
askance  upon  "pure"  aesthetics. 

Since  the  Greeks  possessed  a  high  degree  of  civic  devotion  and  com- 
munity spirit,  the  artists'  works  often  depicted  the  more  notable  civic 
activities  or  achievements.  The  influence  of  religion  on  Greek  art  cannot 
be  ignored.  While  the  cultivated  Greeks  were  free  from  gross  and  brutal 
superstition,  they  reveled  in  a  rich  and  suggestive  mythology  which  fur- 
nished many  and  varied  themes  for  art. 

Amotig  the  Greeks  art  became,  for  the  first  time,  a  subject  of  philosoph- 
ical speculation.  Plato  and  Aristotle  discussed  the  nature  and  desirable 
qualities  of  art  and  its  role  in  life.  They  thus  created  that  branch  of 
philosophy  which  we  call  aesthetics.  Art  exerted  an  important  influence 
on  the  Greek  theories  of  morals.  Aristotle  held  that  the  good  life  is  one 
controlled  by  the  ideals  of  the  disciplined  artist  and  consists  in  steering  a 
happy  mean  between  self-denial  and  indulgence. 

So  profound  was  the  artistic  influence  among  the  Greeks  that  it  even 
affected  their  industrial  life.  It  produced  an  ideal  of  craftsmanship  that 
was  virtually  artistic.  There  was  a  narrow  borderline  between  the 
Greek  workman  and  the  Greek  artist.  Indeed,  some  of  the  great  Greek 
temples  and  other  works  of  art  were  made  in  part  by  Greek  craftsmen 
drawn,  from  everyday  industrial  pursuits.  While  the  slaves  and  some  of 
the  lower  order  of  workmen  may  not  have  had  much  part  in  making  or 
appreciating  Greek  art,  it  is  probable  that  Greek  art  dominated  the  whole 
populace  of  Athens  to  a  greater  degree  than  has  ever  been  the  case  before 
or  since.  The  more  backward  and  warlike  of  the  Greek  city-states  were 
little  interested  in  art,  and  Greek  art  really  means  the  artistic  ideals  and 
achievements  of  ancient  Athens  and  Alexandria. 

The  Romans  added  little  in  the  way  of  original  contributions  to  art. 
They  mainly  adopted  Greek  ideals  and  models  in  art.  The  wealth  of 
Rome,  at  its  height,  produced  elaborate  works  of  art  based  on  Greek  prec- 
edents. But  the  extent  of  the  Empire  permitted  the  Romans  to  gather 
artistic  and  architectural  inspiration  from  other  sources  than  Hellas. 
Many  oriental  elements  entered  into  Roman  art,  especially  into  Roman 
architecture,  with  its  wide  use  of  the  arch  and  dome  construction.  The 
rebuilding  of  Rome  by  Trajan  and  Hadrian  represented  the  culmination 
of  Roman  artistic  achievements.  Even  here  the  chief  artists  were  Hel- 
lenistic, and  Trajan's  chief  city-planner  was  a  Syrian  architect. 

The  Greeks  and  Romans  were  chiefly  interested  in  things  of  this  world 
and,  while  the  religious  motive  was  strong  in  classical  art,  the  purposes 
and  results  of  Greek  and  Roman  art  were  primarily  secular.  Hence  it 
was  inevitable  that  the  rise  of  Christianity  would  work  a  marked  revolu- 
tion in  the  arts.  The  Greeks  were  perfectly  frank  in  making  an  appeal 
to  the  senses;  The  Christians  regarded  this  as  sinful,  and  the  new  atti- 
tude had  its  effect  in  suppressing  nudity  in  art  and  in  otherwise  lessening 
its  sensuous  appeal.  But  as  soon  as  the  Christians  became  established, 
they  became  deeply  impressed  with  the  services  which  art  might  render 
to  the  glorification  of  God.  So)  it  was  not  long  before  the  richest  and 


842         LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

most  civilized  of  the  early  Christians,  those  in  the  Eastern  or  Byzantine 
Empire,  were  erecting  churches  more  magnificent  and  more  elaborately 
decorated  than  any  temples  of  pagan  antiquity.  Such,  for  example,  was 
the  great  church  of  Sancta  Sophia  built  by  the  Emperor  Justinian  in 
Constantinople,  in  the  first  half  of  the  sixth  century.  Soon  the  western 
Christians  were  erecting  the  impressive  Romanesque  and  Gothic  cathe- 
drals of  the  Middle  Ages.  These  were  never,  however,  as  elaborately 
decorated  as  the  Byzantine  churches.  The  erection  of  medieval  cathe- 
drals almost  matched  the  building  of  the  Greek  temples  as  a  matter  of 
community  effort  and  pride.  A  medieval  archbishop  thus  describes, 
somewhat  lyrically,  the  building  of  the  cathedral  of  Chartres  in  France: 

The  inhabitants  of  Chartres  have  combined  to  aid  in  the  contruction  of  their 
church  by  transporting  the  materials.  .  .  .  Since  then  the  faithful  of  our  diocese 
and  of  other  neighboring  regions  have  formed  associations  for  the  same  object; 
they  admit  no  one  into  the  company  unless  he  has  been  to  confession.  .  .  .  They 
elect  a  chief  under  whose  direction  they  conduct  their  wagons  in  silence  and  with 
humility.  Who  has  ever  seen?  Who  has  ever  heard  tell,  in  times  past,  that 
powerful  princes  of  the;  world,  that  men  brought  up  in  honors  and  in  wealth,  that 
nobles,  men  and  women,  have  bent  their  proud  and  haughty  necks  to  the  harness 
of  carts,  and  that,  like  beasts  of  burden,  they  have  dragged  to  the  abode  of 
Christ  these  wagons,  loaded  with  wines,  grains,  oil,  stone,  timber,  and  all  that  is 
necessary  for  the  construction  of  the  church?  .  .  .  They  march  in  silence  that 
not  a  murmur  is  heard.  .  .  .  When  they  halt  on  the  road  nothing  is  heard  but 
confession  of  sins,  and  pure  and  suppliant  prayer.  .  .  .  When  they  have 
reached  the  church  they  arrange  the  wagons  about  it  like  a  spiritual  camp,  and 
during  the  whole  night  they  celebrate  the  watch  by  hymns  and  canticles.  On 
each  wagon  they  light  tapers.45 

Inasmuch  as  the  medieval  cathedral  was  a  real  community  center  for 
secular  as  well  as  religious  life,  the  populace  of  medieval  cities  were  thus 
able  to  participate  directly  in  enjoying  the  chief  products  of  medieval 
art.  In  the  craft  gilds  we  find  a  devotion  to  fine  workmanship  as 
notable  as  that  which  characterized  the  Greek  craftsmen.  Indeed,  the 
craft  gilds  imposed  severe  penalties  on  workers  who  turned  out  inferior 
products.  And,  just  as  the  better  Greek  workmen  helped  in  the  con- 
struction of  Greek  temples,  so  the  medieval  craftsmen  did  most  of  the 
Work  in  the  building  of  the  medieval  cathedrals.  The  intimate  relation 
between  craftsmanship  and  art  is  also  well  illustrated  by  the  beautiful 
illuminated  manuscripts  and  tapestries  of  the  Middle  Ages. 

The  most  notable  outburst  of  artistic  enthusiasm  and  productivity  be- 
tween Greek  days  and  our  own  came  in  the  period  of  the  so-called  Renais- 
sance, which  fell  roughly  in  the  three  centuries  between  1350  and  1650. 
There  are  a  number  of  reasons  for  this.  There  was  a  great  revival  of 
interest  in  Greek  and  Roman  culture.  As  a  result,  the  pagan  enthusiasm 
for  art  gained  respectability.  A  sort  of  adjustment  between  Christianity 
and  the  pagan  point  of  view  was  achieved  in  what  is  called  the  cult  of 
beauty.  Beauty  was  believed  to  provide  man  with, a  glimpse  into  the 


45  J.  W.  Thompson,  Economic  and  Social  History  of  the  Middle  Ages,  Appleton- 
Ceutury,  1928,  p.  672. 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         843 

higher  world  of  the  spirit.  It  connected  the  mundane  with  the  eternal. 
With  the  revival  of  the  pagan  outlook  more  importance  was  attached  to 
man  as  man,  and  human  experience  came  to  be  regarded  as  the  practical 
measure  of  all  things.  While  most  early  Renaissance  art  was  highly 
religious  in  theme  and  much  Renaissance  art  always  remained  so,  there 
was  a  gradual  secularization  of  art.  This  reached  its  highest  develop- 
ment in  Dutch  painting,  where  something  resembling  a  return  to  the 
humanity  of  paganism  was  manifested.  Another  tendency  during  the 
Renaissance  was  the  marked  growth  of  individuality.  This  reacted 
upon  art  in  the  way  of  stimulating  artistic  activity  and  producing  a 
number  of  world-famed  individual  artists  in  every  field  of  artistic  ac- 
tivity. Never  before  or  since  in  western  Europe  has  art  enjoyed  such 
popularity  or  brought  forth  such  notable  products  as  during  the  era  of 
the  Renaissance. 

The  Catholic  Church  approved  of  Renaissance  art  and  did  little  to 
combat  the  pagan  and  secular  trends.  But  Puritanism,  born  of  the 
Protestant  Reformation,  was  highly  hostile  to  many  forms  of  art.  It 
revived  the  ascetic  tendencies  of  early  Christianity  and  was  violently 
opposed  to  any  appeal  to  the  senses.  It  did  much  either  to  suppress 
art  in  Protestant  countries  or  to  divert  it  into  forms  of  expression  in 
which  an  appeal  to  the  senses  could  not  be  regarded  as  in  any  way 
sinful.40  Of  course,  not  all  Protestants  were  Puritans  and  not  all  Prot- 
estant art  was  blighted  by  puritanism. 

The  secularization  of  art,  which  had  been  aided  by  the  Dutch,  was 
carried  further  by  the  reaction  of  overseas  discoveries  upon  art.  Ocean 
scenes,  ships,  sailors,  adventurers,  and  idealized  Indian  maidens  in  part 
displaced  priests,  martyrs,  and  the  Virgin  as  pictorial  subjects.  This 
secularizing  influence  was  also  aided  by  the  Rationalism  of  the  period  of 
the  Enlightenment.  The  court  life  of  the  time,  especially  in  France,  pro- 
moted a  sort  of  nco-pagan  realism  in  depicting  the  eroticism  and  voluptu- 
ousness of  the  era.  Venus  became  more  popular  than  the  Virgin  with 
the  artists  of  the  day.  A  new  enthusiasm  for  the  study  and  the  practice 
of  art  was  generated  by  the  Romantic  movement  of  the  first  half  of  the 
nineteenth  century.  Romanticism  especially  emphasized  the  importance 
of  the  emotions  as  a  guide  to  life  and  its  values.  This  directly  stimulated 
artistic  expression. 

The  Industrial  Revolution  of  the  eighteenth  and  nineteenth  centuries 
had  an  important  reaction  upon  art.  Hitherto,  industry  had  been 
carried  on  by  handicraft  methods  and  there  was  some  opportunity  for 
art  to  express  itself  through  work  in  fine  craftsmanship.  The  mass 
production  of  the  factory  system  did  not  permit  personal  joy  and  artistic 
satisfaction  in  work.  John  Ruskin  and  William  Morris  in  the  middle  of 
the  nineteenth  century  came  forward  to  stress  the  need  for  artistic  ex- 
pression among  the  mass  of  the  people.  They  vigorously  condemned 
the  drab  dreariness  and  drudgery  of  factory  production.  Both  empha- 


46  For  a  more  favorable  view  of  the  Reformation  and  art,  see  G.  G.  Coulton,  Art 
and  the  Reformation,  Knopf,  1928. 


844          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

sized  the  desirability  of  reviving  the  handicrafts  and  manual  arts  and 
giving  greater  play  to  the  motive  of  craftsmanship.  An  American  echo 
of  this  attitude  was  seen  in  the  work  of  Elbert  Hubbard  and,  more 
recently,  in  that  of  Ralph  Borsodi.  The  economist,  Thorstein  Veblen, 
reemphasized  what  he  called  the  instinct  of  workmanship  and  condemned 
its  extinction  by  the  factory  system. 

The  rise  of  capitalism  and  the  growth  of  a  class  of  wealthy  men  repre- 
sented another  influence  on  art  arising  from  the  Industrial  Revolution. 
Many  of  these  new  plutocrats,  while  they  had  little  personal  knowledge 
or  appreciation  of  art,  became  collectors  of  art  as  a  phase  of  their  leisure- 
class  activity.  It  gave  them  social  prestige  and  ministered  to  their 
zeal  for  display.  They  not  only  collected  art  for  their  own  personal 
galleries  but  also  founded  art  museums.  In  this  way,  they  contributed 
to  art  appreciation  and  education.  This  was  offset  in  some  degree  by 
the  elaborate  and  costly  monstrosities  which  they  all  too  often  erected 
for  private  dwellings.  Capitalism  in  art  also  tended  to  revive,  to  a 
certain  extent,  puritanical  standards.  For  protective  purposes,  the 
capitalists  had  adopted  the  puritanical  notion  that  sin  and  immorality 
are  purely  a  matter  of  sexual  behavior.  Hence  capitalism  tended  to 
frown  upon  nudity  and  other  forms  of  appeal  to  the  senses.  It  was  no 
accident  that  the  leader  of  American  capitalism  was  also  the  chief  finan- 
cial supporter  of  Anthony  Comstock,  who  is  still  remembered  for  his 
suppression  of  "September  Morn,"  a  picture  which  now  seems  superbly 
innocent. 

In  our  day,  there  has  been  a  revived  interest  in  art  and  a  great  variety 
in  the  forms  of  its  expression.  Modernism  in  art  was  launched  by 
Cezanne  and  van  Gogh,  who  led  the  revolt  against  tradition  and  con- 
vention. Modernism  has  extended  all  the  way  from  sound  realism  to 
such  bizarre  trends  as  Cubism.  Despite  the  vagaries  of  extremists,  the 
works  of  the  leading  modernists,  Cezanne,  van  Gogh,  Seurat,  Gauguin, 
Rousseau,  Renoir,  Matisse,  Picasso,  Manet,  and  Derain  exhibit  "true 
artistic  genius.  Private  support  for  art  has  been  supplemented  by  an 
ever  increasing  government  subsidy.  Under  the  Roosevelt  administra- 
tion various  artistic  enterprises  were  subsidized  to  provide  work  for  un- 
employed artists.  In  totalitarian  states,  art  has  been  exploited  as  a 
means  of  propaganda  for  the  new  regime.  A  new  proletarian  art  has 
arisen  in  Russia  and  Mexico  which  glorifies  the  worker  in  modern  life. 

The  Growth  of  Art  in  the  United  States 

Let  us  now  review  briefly  some  of  the  factors  that  have  brought  about 
increased  interest  and  activity  in  the  field  of  art  in  the  United  States. 
Colonial  civilization  flourished  in  the  period  before  the  Industrial  Revolu- 
tion, and  the  element  of  fine  craftsmanship  which  was  present  in  the 
handicraft  stage  is  evident  in  the  furniture  and  metal  work  of  colonial 
times.  Colonial  architecture  also  had  a  severe  simplicity,  especially  in 
New  England,  which  constituted  a  definite  artistic  trend.  It  has  been 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         845 

revived  with  enthusiasm  in  our  own  century.  Some  of  the  better  trends 
in  European  art,  especially  English  art,  were  reproduced  in  the  Southern 
colonies.  By  and  large,  however,  the  more  notable  colonial  contributions 
to  art  were  exhibited  in  interior  decoration  and  in  the  handicraft  activities 
of  daily  life.  The  country  was  relatively  poor,  and  the  Puritanism  which 
prevailed  in  many  of  the  colonies  was  antagonistic  to  art. 

Nor  did  the  appreciation  and  exploitation  of  beauty  make  much  head- 
way in  the  first  three  quarters  of  the  nineteenth  century.  Our  isolation 
from  Europe  after  the  War  of  1812  brought  a  repudiation  of  English  as 
well  as  most  continental  European  cultural  influences.  We  were  a 
pioneer  country,  and  the  poverty  and  seriousness  of  pioneer  life  led  to  the 
idea  that  art  is  an  effeminate  waste  of  time  on  trivialities.  As  industrial 
expansion  set  in,  we  became  primarily  absorbed  in  business  and  making 
money.  The  remarkable  growth  of  the  evangelical  religions  between  the 
Revolutionary  War  and  the  Civil  War  gave  a  new  impetus  to  Puritanism. 
The  latter  was  strongly  opposed  to  art  as  a  manifestation  of  the  sensuous 
and  the  sinful.  The  middle  of  the  century  was  notable  as  the  period  of 
the  flowering  of  democracy,  and  democracy,  born  in  part  on  the  frontier, 
looked  askance  at  the  refinement  which  art  expresses  and  encourages. 
The  destruction  of  Southern  culture  by  the  Civil  War  was  a  serious  blow 
to  art.  Though  some  writers  like  Ralph  Waldo  Emerson  raised  their 
voices  against  the  anti- aesthetic  trends  in  American  culture,  they  were 
not  able  to  make  much  headway  against  such  tendencies  in  American 
life. 

Nevertheless,  the  United  States  did  make  certain  important  contribu- 
tions to  artistic  life  in  this  period.  Major  Charles  Pierre  L 'Enfant 
brought  over  Continental  ideas  of  architecture  and  city  planning  and 
laid  out  plans  for  the  new  capitol  at  Washington,  as  well  as  for  a  number 
of  public  buildings  and  private  homes.  Thomas  Jefferson  combined 
Renaissance  and  classical  styles  at  Monticello,  the  University  of  Vir- 
ginia, and  the  state  capitol  at  Richmond.  The  architect  Charles  Bui- 
finch  (1763-1844)  has  been  called  the  Christopher  Wren  of  the  United 
States.  He  introduced  Renaissance  architectural  styles  into  this  country 
in  such  buildings  as  the  original  State  House  in  Boston.  There  was  a 
widespread  imitation  of  classical  Greek  architecture  in  this  country  as  a 
result  of  the  influence  of  Benjamin  H.  Latrobe  (1764-1820),  who  was 
once  described  as  "the  man  who  brought  the  Parthenon  to  America  in  his 
gripsack."  An  excellent  example  of  this  type  of  architecture  is  the 
Treasury  Building  in  Washington. 

Musical  appreciation  and  some  musical  performance  got  under  way 
before  the  end  of  the  Civil  War.  The  Handel  and  Haydn  Society  was 
founded  in  Boston  in  1815,  and  this  and  other  choral  societies  promoted 
an  interest  in  vocal  music.  The  New  York  Philharmonic  Orchestra  was 
founded  in  1842.  The  first  grand  opera  was  performed  in  New  York  in 
1825,  and  an  opera  house  was  built  there  in  1833.  The  Boston  Academy 
of  Music,  opened  in  the  same  year,  launched  capable  musical  instruction. 
Distinguished  foreign  artists,  such  as  Ole  Bull,  Jenny  Lind,  and  Adelina 


846         LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

Patti,  were  warmly  welcomed.  Towards  the  end  of  this  period  Stephen 
Foster  composed  his  immortal  American  folksongs. 

For  a  time  after  the  Civil  War  artistic  tastes  seemed  to  grow  worse. 
We  had  a  generation  of  mushroom  millionaires,  with  a  great  urge  for 
display,  unrestrained  by  taste  and  unguided  by  education.  The  country 
was  flooded  with  the  new  machine  products  of  which  we  were  so  proud  at 
the  time.  We  even  insisted  on  bringing  in  atrocities  from  England,  like 
the  Eastlake  and  Queen  Anne  houses.  This  was  the  nadir  period,  known 
as  "the  Black  Walnut"  or  President  Grant  era. 

In  the  'seventies  and  'eighties,  however,  there  was  a  slow  awakening  of 
interest  in  art  in  this  country.  The  new  leisure  class  of  wealthy  busi- 
nessmen and  bankers,  in  spite  of  their  frequent  bad  taste,  helped  to  endow 
art  by  founding  a  number  of  art  museums  and  subsidizing  such  worthy 
institutions  as  the  Metropolitan  Opera  House  and  the  New  York  Phil- 
harmonic Society.  Their  private  art  collections  also  gave  some  favorable 
publicity  to  artistic  interest.  One  of  the  greatest  of  American  architects, 
Henry  H.  Richardson  (1838-1886),  did  his  work  in  this  period.  He 
revived  interest  in  Romanesque  styles,  well  illustrated  by  Trinity  Church 
in  Boston.  The  other  outstanding  architect  of  the  day  was  Richard 
Morris  Hunt  (182&-1895),  who  inclined  towards  French  Renaissance 
styles  and  is  best  known  for  building  magnificent  homes  for  the  new 
millionaires  of  the  period,  the  Tribune  Building  in  New  York,  the  Fogg 
Museum  at  Harvard,  and  the  Capitol  extension  in  Washington.  Charles 
Eliot  Norton  (1827-1908)  took  a  chair  in  the  history  and  theory  of  art 
at  Harvard  in  1875  and  had  great  influence  in  promoting  art  education 
and  in  making  it  a  respectacle  department  of  higher  learning.  When 
the  Roeblings  built  the  Brooklyn  Bridge,  completed  in  1883,  they  showed 
that  engineering  enterprise  could  produce  a  work  of  beauty  as  well  as  of 
utility. 

The  World's  Columbian  Exposition  in  Chicago,  in  1893,  gave  a  great 
impetus  to  the  popular  appreciation  of  art.  It  brought  together  such 
able  architects  as  Richard  M.  Hunt,  Charles  F.  McKim,  Stanford  White, 
Louis  Sullivan,  Daniel  H.  Burnham,  and  Charles  B.  Atwood.  They 
designed  many  of  the  important  buildings  in  artistic  fashion.  The 
classical  style  dominated,  and  perhaps  the  best  piece  of  designing  was 
done  by  Atwood  for  the  Palace  of  Fine  Arts.  Burnham  later  had  a  great 
deal  of  influence  on  the  artistic  renaissance  in  the  Midwest  through  his 
work  on  the  Chicago  planning  commission. 

As  the  wealthy  grew  richer,  they  devoted  more  of  their  riches  to  the 
collection  and  support  of  art.  Led  by  Andrew  Carnegie,  they  continued 
to  establish  and  endow  art  museums  and  galleries.  They  brought  over 
millions  of  dollars  worth  of  European  art  treasures.  The  lack  of  true 
artistic  sensibilities  on  the  part  of  some  of  them  is  well-illustrated  by  the 
annoyed  surprise  of  Senator  William  Clark  of  Montana,  the  copper  king, 
when  the  Dresden  Museum  refused  to  sell  him  the  Sistine  Madonna  at 
any  price  they  pleased  to  name. 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         847 

The  marked  increase  in  immigration  from  southern  Europe,  especially 
from  Italy,  provided  a  new  element  in  our  population  which  was  tradi- 
tionally devoted  to  every  form  of  artistic  expression.  This  laid  the  basis 
for  greater  popular  interest  in  art  in  generations  to  come.  • 

The  turn  of  the  century  brought  with  it  a  sort  of  outburst  of  American 
art,  unprecedented  in  our  history.  This  was  the  product  of  a  combination 
of  European  influences  and  new  internal  developments,  such  as  we  have 
described  above.  Richardson,  Hunt,  and  their  leading  successors  in 
architecture  were  trained  abroad.  The  immigrant  influence  was  im- 
portant. The  Chicago  Fair  galvanized  the  new  artistic  impulses.  Louis 
Sullivan  established  a  new  school  of  architecture  which  provided  an 
unprecedented  fusion  of  utility  and  beauty.  It  was  Sullivan's  basic  dic- 
tum that  form  should  follow  function  in  architecture.4611  He  created  the 
first  modern  office  building  of  real  distinction.  Sullivan  and  Cass  Gilbert 
also  transformed  the  new  skyscraper  architecture  into  works  of  art.  One 
of  the  first  great  triumphs  in  the  field  was  the  Woolworth  Building,  de- 
signed by  Gilbert. 

The  mam  American  achievements  in  painting  during  this  period  were 
in  the  field  of  landscape  painting,  in  which  Americans  led  the  world. 
Probably  the  ablest  of  our  landscape  painters  was  George  Innes,  but 
others  like  Winslow  Homer  and  Alexander  Wyant  did  highly  competent 
work.  Excellent  portrait  painting  was  done  by  the  expatriate  John 
Singer  Sargent  and  by  Abbot  Thayer  and  George  Bellows,  among  others. 
John  La  Farge  and  Edwin  Abbey  produced  creditable  mural  decoration, 
and  Frederick  Remington  and  Charles  Dana  Gibson  led  in  brilliant  illus- 
tration. In  the  field  of  sculpture,  the  genius  of  the  period  was  Augustus 
Saint-Gaudens  (184&-1907),  America's  greatest  sculptor,  known  for  such 
masterpieces  as  the  statue  of  "Grief"  in  the  Rock  Creek  cemetery  in 
Washington  and  the  Shaw  Memorial  in  Boston. 

American  interest  in  music  grew  during  this  period,  and  substantial 
contributions  were  made  to  musical  composition.  The  fame  of  the 
New  York  Philharmonic  Orchestra  grew  under  its  able  conductor, 
Theodore  Thomas.  Leopold  Damrosch  founded  the  New  York  Sym- 
phony Society  in  1881,  and  most  of  the  other  large  American  cities  fol- 
lowed suit  before  the  end  of  the  century.  German  choral  societies  stimu- 
lated the  interest  in  vocal  music.  Competent  composers  appeared  in  the 
persons  of  Edward  A.  McDowell,  Dudley  Buck,  John  K.  Paine,  Horatio 
Parker,  Arthur  Foote,  and  G.  W.  Chadwick.  John  Philip  Sousa  popu- 
larized band  music  and  contributed  many  compositions  of  his  own. 
Foreign  artists  were  welcomed  in  greater  numbers,  especially  in  grand 
opera,  and  better  facilities  were  created  for  musical  instruction. 

In  the  period  since  the  first  World  War,  artistic  interest  and  activity 


46a  On  Sullivan  and  the  Chicago  school  of  architecture,  which  also  included  William 
L.  Jenney  and  John  Root,  see  Sigfried  Giedion,  Space,  Time  and  Architecture, 
Harvard  University  Press,  1941. 


848         LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

have  been  further  increased.  As  the  United  States  became  richer,  we 
imported  even  more  of  the  European  art  treasures  than  in  early  decades. 
It  has  been  estimated  that  the  objects  of  art  now  in  private  and  public 
collections  in  the  United  States  are  worth  approximately  2  billion  dollars, 
if  their  value  can  be  measured  in  money.  More  and  more  of  these  art 
treasures  are  being  given  to  public  museums.  It  is  estimated  that,  in  the 
year  1931  alone,  the  art  gifts  to  the  public  amounted  to  more  than  135 
million  dollars.  Art  education  assumed  a  new  importance  and  the  great 
foundations  have  given  ever  more  liberally  to  promote  the  study  and 
appreciation  of  the  arts.  The  revival  of  interest  in  the  Colonial  period 
and  the  restoration  of  Williamsburg,  Va.,  by  John  D.  Rockefeller,  Jr., 
have  stimulated  our  appreciation  of  early  American  art  and  architecture. 

The  influence  of  the  government  has  been  favorable  to  artistic  activity. 
Especially  notable  here  have  been  the  various  art  projects  subsidized  by 
the  Roosevelt  Administration.  City  planning  has  made  marked  head- 
way. The  most  notable  achievement  here  ha&  been  the  astonishing  work 
of  Robert  Moses  on  the  parks  and  parkways  of  Greater  New  York.  The 
World  Fairs  in  Chicago  in  1933  and  1934  and  in  New  York  in  1939  and 
1940  did  much  to  acquaint  the  public  with  modern  trends  in  art.  But  it 
was  no  less  than  a  national  scandal  that  the  foremost  architect  of  our  day, 
Frank.  Lloyd  Wright,  was  not  employed  to  contribute  designs  to  the 
New  York  exposition. 

Even  business  and  industry  have  made  their  contribution  to  the  arts. 
The  New  York  city  zoning  law  introduced  the  "set-back"  style  in  sky- 
scraper architecture,  good  examples  of  which  are  the  New  York  Telephone 
Building  designed  by  Ralph  Walker  and  the  Hotel  Shelton  designed  by 
Arthur  Harmon.  The  evolution  of  the  automobile  in  the  last  two  decades 
well  illustrates  the  evolution  of  artistic  considerations  in  industry  and 
engineering.  Modernistic  furniture  has  shown  how  artistry  and  effi- 
ciency may  be  combined  in  objects  of  utility.  The  movies  and  the  radio 
have  helped  to  popularize  art  and  music.  Greater  emphasis  upon  the 
manual  arts  in  education  is  working,  though  unconsciously  and  often 
in  awkward  fashion,  towards  the  ideal  expressed  by  Ruskin  and  Morris. 
'  There  was  important  progress  in  American  art  between  the  two  World 
Wars.  In  architecture,  the  main  developments  were  the  further  expan- 
sion of  skyscraper  architecture  and  the  extension  of  modern  trends  in 
every  field,  even  into  ecclesiastical  architecture.  In  the  skyscraper  field, 
the  influence  af  Sullivan  and  Gilbert  continued,  but  Harmon,  Walker, 
Raymond  Hood,  and  others  took  up  the  earlier  tradition  and  expanded 
it.  Eliel  Saarinen  was  more  influential  than  any  other  in  promoting 
modernism  in  skyscraper  architecture.  The  outstanding  architect  of 
both  America  and  the  world  in  this  period  was  Frank  Lloyd  Wright 
(1868-  ),  who  developed  a  daring  functional  modernism.  He  intro- 
duced functional  utility  in  his  buildings,  related  the  design  of  a  given 
building  to  its  surroundings,  and  experimented  extensively  with  new 
building  materials,  especially  steel  and  glass.  He  had  even  more  influ- 
ence and  prestige  in  Europe  and  the  Orient  than  in  the  United  States, 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         849 

where  traditionalism  was  strong  enough  to  delay  recognition  of  his  genius 
for  a  time.46b 

In  painting,  the  landscape  tradition  was  continued  by  able  and  original 
artists,  such  as  Rockwell  Kent,  who  is  also  noted  for  his  skill  with  wood- 
cuts and  murals.  John  Marin  exhibited  genius  with  his  brilliantly  colored 
marine  landscapes,  mainly  watercolors  and  miniatures.  Georgia  O'Keefe 
captivated  the  discerning  with  her  symbolic  paintings  of  flowers.  Vari- 
ous American  artists,  such  as  Arthur  Dove,  Marsden  Hartley,  and 
Charles  Demuth,  flirted  with  various  phases  of  modernism,  but  the  out- 
standing development  in  American  painting  in  the  period  was  to  be  found 
in  realistic  and  colorful  murals,  free  from  the  stiffness  and  conventionality 
of  the  academic  school.  Leaders  in  this  class  were  Thomas  H.  Benton, 
William  Gropper,  George  Biddle,  Howard  Cook,  and  others.  Mural 
painting  was  still  further  "brought  down  to  earth"  and  adapted  to  a 
democratic,  proletarian  public  in  the  work  of  two  Mexicans,  Diego 
Rivera  and  Jose  Orozco.  Rivera  is  a  deadly  earnest  apostle  of  the 
working  class,  while  Orozco  satirizes  the  leisure  class  and  their  academic 
servants.  Alfred  Stieglitz  has  not  only  raised  photography  to  the  level 
of  an  art,  but  has  probably  been  the  most  potent  and  persistent  personal 
force  in  promoting  native  American  art  and  artists. 

The  most  dramatic  innovation  in  the  appreciation  of  painting  in  the 
United  States  between  the  two  wars  was  the  establishment  of  a  respec- 
table status  for  modernistic  art  in  this  country,  almost  a  single-handed 
achievement  of  Albert  C.  Barnes  of  Merion,  Pennsylvania.  Making  a 
large  fortune  as  the  discoverer  of  a  valuable  antiseptic,  argyrol,  he 
devoted  himself  to  the  collection  and  promotion  of  modern  art,  of  which 
he -has 'by  far  the  greatest  collection  in  the  world.  His  wealth,  persist- 
ence, and  pugnacity,  as  well  as  his  genius  for  art  appreciation,  enabled 
Barnes  to  overcome,  to  some  degree,  the  prejudices  of  the  classicists  and 
purists  and  enormously  to  increase  the  standing  of  modern  art,  not  only 
in  America  but  in  Europe  itself.47 

In  sculpture  there  were  a  number  of  able  artists  in  this  period,  even 
though  none  reached  the  stature  of  Saint-Gaudens.  Perhaps  closest  to 
the  tradition  of  the  latter  is  the  work  of  Daniel  Chester  French.  Lorado 
Taft  is  well  known  for  his  fountains.  George  Grey  Barnard  has  been 
called,  with  good  reason,  the  American  Rodin.  The  leading  American 
eclectic  was  Paul  Manship,  best-known  for  his  bronzes  and  his  versatility 
in  decorative  design.  Carl  Milles,  a  Swede,  has  exerted  a  considerable 
influence  upon  American  sculpture,  especially  in  the  design  of  fountains. 

One  of  the  more  original  achievements  of  the  United  States  in  the  fine 
arts  between  the  two  World  Wars  was  in  music.  For  the  first  time, 
American  composers  showed  more  originality  than  Europeans.  Jazz 
music  was  perhaps  the  most  original  American  contribution.  It  is  char- 


4flb;Oh  Frank  Lloyd  Wright  and  his  work,  see  H.  R.  Hitchcock,  In  the  Nature  of 
Materials,  Duell,  Sloan  &  Pearce,  1942. 

47  See  the  four  articles  by  Carl  W.  McCardle,  "The  Terrible-Tempered  Dr. 
Barnes,"  Saturday  Evening  Post,  March  21-April  11,  1942. 


850          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

acterized  by  emphatic  syncopated  rhythm,  repetition,  and  moving  emo- 
tional appeal.  Its  sources  are  many  and  contrasting — Negro  and  Spanish 
rhythm,  melodic  idioms,  "blues"  harmonies,  and  even  classic  harmony 
and  melody.  Among  the  American  composers  who  have  combined  the 
conventional  and  the  modernistic  are  Henry  Hadley,  John  Alden  Car- 
penter, Arthur  Shepherd,  Deems  Taylor,  Philip  James,  and  Howard 
Hanson.  Leading  American  modernists  in  composition  have  been  Aaron 
Copland,  Roy  Harris,  Roger  Sessions,  Leo  Ornstein,  and  William  Grant 
Still.  George  Gershwin  and  Paul  Whiteman  raised  jazz  to  the  level  of  an 
art.  Jerome  Kern  and  Cole  Porter  elevated  the  lyric  level  of  musical 
comedy.  The  United  States  has,  of  late,  produced  able  performing 
artists  in  music,  especially  vocalists.  The  Metropolitan  Opera  Com- 
pany has,  on  occasion,  put  on  performances  of  European  grand  opera 
with  a  full  cast  of  American  singers. 

Trends   in  Contemporary  American  Art 

We  may  now  consider  some  developments  in  art  and  art  appreciation 
since  the  first  World  War.  A  number  of  agencies  have  furthered  popular 
interest  in  art.  Prominent  here  have  been  the  art  museums,  many  of 
which  are  under  private  control.  The  art  museum  acquires  and  assembles 
objects  of  art,  makes  possible  an  increase  in  our  knowledge  of  the  history 
and  nature  of  art,  and  contributes  to  public  enjoyment  by  making  it 
possible  for  large  numbers  of  people  to  view  outstanding  examples  of 
artistic  achievement.  In  1890,  there  were  76  art  museums  in  the  country. 
By  1929,  they  had  increased  to  167.  Some  41  were  added  in  the  decade 
from  1920  to  1929.  There  is  an  art  museum  in  every  city  in  the  United 
States  with  a  population  of  250,000  or  over.  The  capital  invested  in  art 
museums  in  1929  was  approximately  60  million  dollars,  exclusive  of  art 
treasures.  While  most  of  the  larger  museums  are  in  the  great  cities  of 
the  East,  a  greater  per  capita  interest  is  shown  in  the  art  museums  of 
cities  in  the  Middle  West  and  the  Far  West.  In  the  last  two  decades 
much  progress  has  been  made  in  linking  up  the  museums  with  art  educa- 
tion. Art  classes  make  use  of  the  resources  and  facilities  of  the  museums, 
and  this  tendency  is  encouraged  by  most  museums. 

Despite  their  valuable  social  and  educational  service,  our  art  museums 
have  been  sharply  criticized  for  their  alleged  conservatism  and  sterility 
and  their  lack  of  democratic  spirit  and  virility.  Such  were  the  charges 
made  by  Park  Commissioner  Robert  Moses  of  New  York  City  in  the 
winter  of  1940-41.  The  American  painter  Thomas  H.  Benton  presents 
the  extreme  of  critical  attitudes  toward  our  art  museums: 

A  graveyard  run  by  a  pretty  boy  with  delicate  wrists  and  a  swing  in  his 
gait.  .  .  .  Do  you  want  to  know  what  is  the  matter  with  the  art  business  in 
America?  It's  the  third  sex  and  the  museums.  Even  in  Missouri  we're  full 
of  'em.  Our  museums  are  full  of  ballet  dancers,  retired  businessmen  and  boys 
from  the  Fogg  Institute  at  Harvard  where  they  train  museum  directors  and  art 
artists.  I'd  have  people  buy  the  paintings  and  hang  them  in  privies  or  anywhere 
anybody  had  time  to  look  at  them.  Nobody  looks  at  them  in  museums.  Nobody 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         851 

goes  to  museums.    I'd  like  to  sell  mine  to  saloons,  bawdy  houses,  Kiwanis  and 
Rotary  Clubs  and  Chambers  of  Commerce — even  women's  clubs.48 

Architecture  has  been  another  important  agency  in  bringing  art  before 
the  public.  In  every  field  of  construction  greater  attention  is  being  given 
to  artistic  considerations  in  the  erection  of  buildings.  Frank  Lloyd 
Wright  has  done  more  than  any  other  architect  to  urge  the  combination 
of  beauty  with  functional  utility  in  the  design  of  public  buildings,  busi- 
ness plants,  hotels  and  private  homes.  Wright  and  Eliel  Saarinen  have 
even  introduced  highly  modernistic  design  into  church  buildings  in  such 
structures  as  the  Christian  Church  in  Columbus,  Indiana,  and  the  Com- 
munity Church  in  Kansas  City.  Public  buildings  are  usually  designed 
by  skillful  architects  and  not  only  their  exterior  but  their  interior,  as  well, 
shows  an  increasing  concern  with  art.  Art  figures  more  prominently 
than  ever  before  in  the  interior  decoration  of  buildings.  It  was  not  so 
long  ago  that  murals  of  distinction  were  limited  to  a  few  public  buildings 
like  the  Boston  Public  Library  or  the  Library  of  Congress.  Today,  even 
great  office  buildings  like  Rockefeller  Center  have  extensive  mural  decora- 
tions. Business  buildings,  which  formerly  were  all  too  often  monstrosii 
ties,  are  now  very  generally  designed  with  an  eye  to  artistic  appeal. 
Skyscrapers,  in  particular,  have  been  so  beautifully  designed  that  they 
have  been  aptly  called  "the  cathedrals  of  commerce."  The  private  dwell- 
ings of  the  rich  were  once  notorious  for  their  drab  monotony  or  their 
monstrous  and  lavish  decoration.  Most  of  the  great  apartment  houses 
which  have  replaced  them  are  far  more  pleasingly  and  artistically  de- 
signed. This  is  especially  true  where  city  planning  and  large  housing 
projects  have  dominated  the  construction  picture.  It  is  rare  to  find  a 
large  ugly  building  of  recent  construction.  Even  factories,  which  were 
once  a  blot  on  the  landscape,  are  now  often  laid  out  with  due  considera- 
tion for  architectural  appeal  and  landscaping  possibilities. 

It  is  where  city  planning  and  large  building  projects  have  been  executed 
that  we  find  the  fullest  rein  given  to  considerations  of  aesthetic  appeal 
and  to  housing  utility.  Since  there  is  every  probability  that  city  plan- 
ning and  large  scale  housing  developments  will  be  far  more  marked  in  the 
future  than  they  have  been  in  the  past,  we  may  expect  much  more  of 
an  artistic  impulse  from  such  tendencies.  Unless  our  civilization  col- 
lapses, there  is  every  probability  that  the  cities  of  the  future  will  be 
examples  of  planned  beauty  as  well  as  of  service  and  convenience. 

Of  all  forms  of  art,  it  is  probable  that  music  has  had  the  greatest 
popular  appeal  since  1918.  A  complete  revolution  has  been  worked  here 
by  the  radio,  exclusively  in  the  last  two  decades.  Today  over  26  million 
families  own  radio  sets.  While  much  of  the  radio  music  is  the  intolerably 
banal  crooning  and  commercial  jazz,  there  is  a  residual  element  of 
high-grade  performance.  Such  is  the  weekly  program  of  the  New  York 
Philharmonic  Society  and  the  Metropolitan  Opera  Company,  and  the  sus- 
taining programs  provided  by  the  great  broadcasting  chains.  In  the 


48  Quoted  in  Time,  April  14,  1941,  p.  70;  see  also  Thomas  Craven,  "Our  Decadent 
Museums,"  in  The  American  Mercury,  December,  1941. 


852         LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

summer,  a  number  of  excellent  programs  are  provided  by  stadium  con- 
certs and  other  community  projects.  Important  regional  music  festivals 
are  also  usually  put  on  the  air.  Radio  lectures  on  music  have  increased 
popular  musical  appreciation. 

Far  more  attention  is  given  to  music  in  the  colleges  and  schools  than 
ever  before,  a  matter  which  we  shall  comment  upon  later,  in  connection 
with  art  education.  There  are  school  and  college  glee  clubs,  orchestras, 
and  bands.  Many  music  contests  are  conducted  in  public  schools.  In 
1931,  it  was  estimated  that  at  least  73,000  high  school  students  played  in 
some  form  of  instrumental  competition.  The  number  is  much  larger 
today.  The  introduction  of  consolidated  or  centralized  community 
schools  in  rural  areas  has  greatly  facilitated  the  extension  of  musical 
instruction  and  activities  in  our  schools.  Community  singing  has  been 
more  actively  promoted  during  thd  last  twenty  years  than  ever  before, 
and  regional  music  festivals  are  more  numerous  and  better  attended. 
Both  vocal  and  instrumental  concerts  of  high  merit  are  being  brought  to 
smaller  cities. 

One  deplorable  trend  in  musical  activity,  which  has  been  especially  a 
result  of  the  radio  and  the  phonograph,  has  been  the  marked  falling  off 
in  the  amount  of  individual  music  performed  in  the  home.  For  example, 
by  1929,  the  total  value  of  musical  instruments  produced  in  the  United 
States  had  dropped  to  less  than  one  half  the  figure  for  1925.  This  trend 
has  continued.  Many  professional  musicians  have  also  been  deprived 
of  work. 

The  old  monopoly  over  the  drama  once  possessed  by  the  legitimate 
theatre  has  been  undermined  by  the  movies.  Nevertheless,  the  conven- 
tional theatre  is  by  no  means  a  dying  art,  though  the  movies  have  all  but 
destroyed  the  road  companies,  except  for  performances  of  smash  hits  in 
the  larger  cities.  This  loss  has  been  somewhat  offset  by  the  growth  of 
the  little  theatre  movement  and  the  summer  theatre  movement,  which 
bring  a  superior  type  of  dramatic  production  to  non-metropolitan  dis- 
tricts. 

Among  those  who  have  made  the  modern  theatre  a  work  of  art  in 
something  more  than  the  acting,  the  leading  place  must  be  assigned  to 
Edward  Gordon  Craig,  an  English-born  actor  and  stage  director.  He 
declared  war  on  artificial  stage-settings  and  scenery  and  insisted  on 
introducing  realism  and  beauty  into  stage  equipment.  He  held  that  a 
good  play  must  be  an  all-round  artistic  production  in  which  actors, 
musicians,  and  stage  technicians  must  cooperate.  Lavish  spectacle  plays 
were  introduced  on  the  American  stage  by  Max  Reinhardt  and  Norman 
Bel-Geddes.  Conspicuous  among  such  Reinhardt  productions  have  been 
"The  Miracle"  and  "The  Eternal  Road."  Others  who  have  promoted 
beauty  and  realism  in  stage  decoration  and  management  have  been 
Robert  Edmond  Jones  and  Lee  Simonson.  Not  all  novelty  in  stage 
design  has  been  in  the  direction  of  lavishness.  There  have  been  trends 
towards  simplicity,  as  well,  and  some  cases  of  extreme  simplicity,  as  in 
Orson  Welles'  "Caesar,"  and  Thornton  Wilder's  "Our  Town,"  were  well 
received. 


LEISURE,    RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         853 

It  can  hardly  be  said  that  the  movies  have  elevated  our  artistic  per- 
spective and  sensibilities,  but  they  have  undoubtedly  increased  aesthetic 
appreciation  on  the  part  of  the  masses,  many  millions  of  whom  have  never 
seen  a  legitimate  drama  performed  by  a  first-class  company.  And  some 
movie  productions,  especially  those  reproducing  the  plays  of  Shakespeare, 
have  been  works  of  art,  not  only  in  regard  to  the  acting  but  also  with 
respect  to  the  scenic  settings.  The  animated  cartoons  of  Walt  Disney 
and  his  productions  of  "Snow  White  and  the  Seven  Dwarfs,"  and  "Fan- 
tasia" have  notably  promoted  art  on  the  screen.  No  doubt  the  total 
impact  of  the  movies  has  been  a  marked  positive  contribution  to  art 
education  for  the  masses. 

Pageantry,  which  is  perhaps  the  most  social  of  the  arts,  has  definitely 
gained  ground  in  the  last  two  decades.  Norman  Bel-Geddes  and  Max 
Reinhardt  have  introduced  elaborate  pageantry  in  the  theatre.  It  is 
especially  exploited  in  portraying  scenes  of  regional  historical  and  cul- 
tural development.  Closely  related  is  the  interest  created  in  rhythmic 
dancing,  in  which  the  number  of  participants  has  increased  rapidly  since 
the  first  World  War.  Isadora  Duncan,  Ruth  St.  Denis,  Martha  Graham, 
and  Doris  Humphrey  have  been  mainly  responsible  for  introducing 
naturalistic  rhythmic  dancing.  Among  other  things,  they  studied  and 
adapted  the  dances  of  Egypt,  India,  and  Greece. 

World  Fairs  have  become  more  frequent  and  more  lavish.  The 
Chicago  Exposition  of  1933-34  and  the  New  York  and  San  Francisco 
Expositions  of  1939-40  did  much  to  popularize  recent  artistic  develop- 
ments, especially  in  the  field  of  modernistic  architecture  and  furniture 
and  mural  decoration. 

Regional  and  racial  monopoly  in  the  field  of  art  have  been  under- 
mined. While  the  great  museums  and  theatres  in  the  Eastern  metro- 
politan centers  still  dominate  the  artistic  scene  in  the  United  States,  they 
are  now  being  rivaled  by  those  in  the  Midwest  and  on  the  Pacific  coast. 
Artistic  interest  and  achievement  are  now  taking  on  a  national  character. 
This  trend  has  been  notably  forwarded  by  the  government  art  projects, 
and  by  the  radio  and  the  movies.  And  the  artistic  products  of  the  white 
race  are  now  supplemented  by  those  of  the  Negro,  the  American  Indian, 
and  the  Mexicans.  The  Negroes  have  been  especially  successful  in  the 
field  of  music. 

Another  mode  of  promoting  art  as  a  social  force  has  been  the  increas- 
ingly artistic  character  of  those  things  which  touch  our  daily  lives.  The 
city  homes  of  a  few  generations  back,  even  those  of  the  rich,  were  for  the 
most  part  terrible  to  behold.  Today  the  tendency  is  toward  more  con- 
venient and  sanitary  housing  and  also  more  artistry  in  the  construction 
of  apartments  and  individual  dwellings.  This  has  reached  its  highest 
form  of  expression  in  the  projects  associated  with  city  planning.  Much 
more  attention  than  ever  before  has  been  given  to  landscaping  in  con- 
nection with  home  construction.  The  increasing  amount  of  suburban 
life  has  forwarded  and  facilitated  this  development.  A  great  deal  more 
care  has  also  been  given  to  artistic  considerations  inside  our  homes. 
Electric  fixtures  have  become  more  artistic  as  well  as  more  efficient. 


854          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

Household  furnishings  are  simpler  and  more  beautiful.  Nothing  reflects 
the  progress  of  artistic  interest  and  achievement  in  the  home  more  com- 
pletely than  the  improvement  in  bathroom  designs  and  decorations.  Even 
kitchen  stoves  and  sinks  can  now  be  a  work  of  art.  A  modern  kitchen 
has  contributed  as  much  to  the  improved  appearance  of  the  home  as  it 
has  to  increased  household  efficiency.  Our  clothes  unquestionably  also 
reveal  the  progress  of  artistic  values,  though  this  is  contaminated  by  the 
profit  motive  in  commercialized  fashions,  which  often  decrees  bizarre 
monstrosities  that  can  make  no  claim  to  artistic  merit. 

Since  ours  is  a  business  civilization,  we  cannot  ignore  the  relation  of 
recent  trends  in  business  and  industry  to  artistic  considerations  and 
interests. 

Business  buildings  and  factories,  as  we  have  seen,  are  built  with  more 
of  an  eye  for  art  and  beauty  than  ever  before.  Among  the  artist- 
engineers  who  have  helped  to  make  factories  and  factory-products  beau- 
tiful have  been  Joseph  Sinel,  Norman  Bel-Geddes,  George  Sakier,  Henry 
Dreyfuss,  Raymond  Loewy,  and  Harold  Van  Doren.  Some  business 
plants,  especially  in  suburban  areas,  have  taken  the  lead  in  the  com- 
munity for  architectural  beauty  and  skillful  landscaping. 

Many  products  of  industry  have  become  ever  more  attractive.  We 
have  already  made  reference  to  better  housing  and  interior  decoration 
and  equipment.  The  almost  incredible  improvement  in  automobile  de- 
sign has  reflected  artistic  advance  as  much  as  anything  else  in  our  genera- 
tion. Nor  can  we  overlook  the  services  of  writers  like  Lewis  Mumford 
in  stressing  the  possibilities  of  art  within  the  modern  industrial  frame- 
work, in  such  books  as  Technics  and  Civilization;  The  Culture  of  Cities; 
Sticks  and  Stones;  and  The  Golden  Day. 

Probably  nothing  has  more  directly  reflected  the  increasing  interest  in 
artistic  appeal  than  competitive  commercial  advertising.  All  big  com- 
panies today  have  art  directors,  and  advertising  itself  has  become  as 
much  a  matter  of  art  as  of  commerce.  While  advertising  has  certainly 
done  little  to  promote  creative  originality  in  art,  it  has  surely  helped  to 
make  the  masses  art-conscious.  Dr.  Frederick  P.  Keppel  has  fairly 
stated  the  position  of  commercial  advertising  in  current  artistic  trends: 

Granting  that  advertising  has  its  full  share  of  the  general  failings  of  our  age, 
plus  a  few  special  crimes  of  its  own,  one  cannot  escape  the  conviction  that  it  is 
today  exercising  a  very  powerful  and,  on  the  whole,  a  wholesome  influence  on 
our  aesthetic  standards.40 

Another  phase  of  modern  business  which  has  made  its  contribution  to 
an  increase  of  artistic  appeal  has  been  the  publication  of  our  leading 
"class"  and  popular  magazines.  They  have  become  ever  more  artistic 
in  layout,  format,  typography,  illustrations,  and  color  work.  The  most 
notable  achievements  along  this  line  have  been  the  sumptuous  magazines 
like  Fortune  and  Esquire  but  many  less  pretentious  publications  show  a 


*»  Recent  Social  Trends,  McGraw-Hill,  Vol.  II,  p.  978. 


LEISURE,  RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS       sss 

great  aesthetic  improvement  over  the  periodicals  before  the  first  World 
War. 

We  have  been  talking  about  the  contributions  of  business  to  art;  but 
art  has  also  contributed  to  business.  Even  if  we  exclude  the  radio  and 
the  movies,  the  various  branches  of  artistic  activity  constitute  a  large 
financial  investment  and  provide  employment  for  hundreds  of  thousands 
of  persons.  If  we  include  radio  and  movies,  it  is  evident  that  art  today 
constitutes  a  business  enterprise  of  tremendous  proportions. 

The  increase  of  interest  in  the  field  of  art  since  the  turn  of  the  century 
has  not  been  wholly  spontaneous.  To  a  great  extent,  it  has  been  pro- 
moted by  direct  and  indirect  art  education,  though  it  still  remains  true 
that  artistic  interest  is  developing  more  rapidly  than  the  facilities  in 
formal  art  education. 

Until  the  present  century,  there  was  little  provision  for  systematic  art 
instruction  in  this  country.  Individual  painters  and  musicians  might 
study  privately  under  great  masters  at  home  and  abroad,  but  there  was 
slight  interest  in  systematic  art  education  even  in  private  schools.  We 
have  already  pointed  out  how  Charles  Eliot  Norton  founded  art  education 
at  Harvard  in  1875,  but  his  example  was  not  widely  imitated.  In  col- 
leges, art  was  regarded,  particularly  by  the  men,  as  a  "sissy  subject" 
suitable  only  for  girls. 

A  strong  impulse  to  art  education  in  the  schools  grew  out  of  the  Pro- 
gressive Education  Movement  in  the  elementary  schools.  Art  education 
is  today  generally  a  part  of  the  curriculum  in  public  schools.  There  has 
been  a  marked  increase  in  art  courses  in  men's  colleges  as  well  as  in  co- 
educational and  women's  colleges.  Art  is  no  longer  regarded  as  effemi- 
nate. The  American  Institute  of  Architects  launched  a  strong  drive  in 
1923  to  encourage  art  education  in  the  colleges.  Most  college  art  courses 
still  remain,  however,  those  in  the  history  and  appreciation  of  art. 

At  the  same  time  that  general  and  untechnical  art  education  in  the 
schools  and  colleges  is  increasing,  there  have  also  been  marked  gains  in 
professional  art  and  music  schools.  In  the  18  outstanding  art  schools  of 
the  country,  the  attendance  increased  from  10,000  to  18,000  between 
1920  and  1930.  Art  and  music  training  today  are  less  narrow  and 
specialized,  and  make  an  effort  to  provide  broad  all-round  training. 

In  addition  to  direct  education  in  the  arts  there  is  much  indirect  art 
education,  implicit  in  the  artistic  trends  which  we  have  already  noted. 
The  graphic  arts  are  brought  constantly  to  our  attention  in  the  form  of 
photography,  wood  engraving,  etching,  lithography  and  the  like.  The 
periodical  press  is  an  important  source  of  indirect  art  education,  as  is 
also  the  daily  press.  Art  exhibitions  and  art  lectures  are  a  source  of 
competent  instruction  to  many.  Especially  important  are  the  traveling 
exhibitions  which  bring  both  art  treasures  and  current  artistic  productions 
to  small  communities.  The  wide  circulation  of  books  on  art  such  as 
those  by  Hendrik  Van  Loon  and  Thomas  Craven,  has  contributed  to 
popular  education  in  this  field. 

Viewing  artistic  developments  in  the  United  States  since  the  first  World 


856          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

War,  one  may  discern  not  only  greater  interest  in  the  arts  but  also  a 
tendency  toward  direct  participation  in  creative  artistic  endeavor.  This 
important  transformation  is  summarized  by  Dr.  Keppel: 

Taking  the  evidence  as  a  whole,  however,  there  seems  no  question  that  it 
indicates  a  definite  trend  toward  the  belief  that  beauty,  its  creation,  reproduc- 
tion, its  passive  enjoyment  has  an  essential  place  in  normal  human  life.  Today 
people  by  the  tens  of  thousands  will  look  at  exhibitions  in  museums  and  fairs,  in 
hotels  and  office  buildings.  They  will  listen  by  the  millions  to  good  music  on  the 
radio  and  at  the  summer  concert.  Perhaps  as  many  take  real  pleasure  in  the 
design  of  articles  in  daily  use,  from  safety  razor  to  motor  car,  and  in  the  play  of 
color  and  light  and  shade.  Few  relatively,  but  still  an  increasing  number,  do 
something  besides  look  and  listen;  they  participate  in  the  little  theater,  in  school 
and  community  orchestras,  in  businessmen's  sketch  clubs.50 

Some  of  the  outstanding  tendencies  in  the  artistic  scene  since  the  first 
World  War  are  the  following:  Primarily  as  the  result  of  increased  leisure, 
art  has  received  more  attention  from  the  public  than  ever  before.  Art 
has  become  more  dynamic  and  may  be  entering  into  a  new  period  of 
creation  and  expansion.  Industry  is  putting  out  its  products  with  an  eye 
for  artistry  as  well  as  utility.  There  has  never  been  so  much  concern  for 
design  and  landscaping  for  dwellings,  office  buildings,  and  factories.  Ad- 
vertising is  becoming  more  expensive,  ingenious,  and  artistic.  The 
United  States  is  producing  far  more  original  art  than  ever  before  and  is 
less  content  to  rest  satisfied  with  merely  viewing  foreign  masterpieces. 
There  has  been  a  remarkable  expansion  of  interest  and  facilities  in  every 
phase  of  art  education.  There  is  an  increasing  amount  of  governmental 
interest  in,  and  support  of,  art.  Finally,  mere  passivity  is  being  sup- 
plemented by  a  greater  degree  of  creative  participation  in  every  field  of 
art. 

The  New  Deal  Art  Projects 

The  federal  government  was  not  entirely  a  newcomer  in  the  field  of 
art  in  1935  when  the  WPA  Art  Projects  were  created.  At  the  close  of 
the  eighteenth  century  Major  L 'Enfant,  a  famous  French  architect, 
'was  brought  over  to  lay  out  the  city  of  Washington.  His  plan  was 
followed  roughly  in  the  building  of  the  city.  In  1803,  Jefferson  appointed 
Latrobe  Surveyor  of  Public  Buildings  and  commissioned  him  to  carry  on 
work  on  the  federal  capitol.  This  building  as  it  stands  today  is  a  sort 
of  recapitulation  of  the  artistic  history  of  the  country.  In  some  ways 
more  distinguished  is  the  new  Library  of  Congress  with  its  famous  murals. 
A  Commission  of  Fine  Arts  had  been  appointed  in  1859,  but  was  abolished 
a  year  later.  In  1910  a  National  Fine  Arts  Commission  was  provided 
for,  made  up  of  seven  members  appointed  by  the  President.  Its  func- 
tion was  purely  advisory  and  it  did  not  receive  a  salary. 

Another  example  of  governmental  patronage  of  the  arts  is  the  Chamber 
Music  Foundation  established  by  Elizabeth  Sprague  Coolidge  and  housed 


5°  Recent  Social  Trends,  McGraw-Hill,  Vol.  II,  p.  1003. 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         857 

in  a  special  hall  in  the  Library  of  Congress.  At  the  other  extreme  in 
musical  expression  are  the  Army,  Navy,  and  Marine  bands,  of  which 
the  last  is  the  oldest.  The  government  also  supports  some  national 
galleries,  such  as  that  in  the  Smithsonian  Institute  and  the  Freer  Gallery. 
On  the  whole,  however,  federal  support  of  art  before  1935  was  slight  and 
unimpressive.  The  gift  of  a  great  national  art  museum  in  Washington 
by  Andrew  Mellon,  together  with  his  art  treasures,  was  probably  the 
most  notable  private  benefaction  for  national  art  interest.  The  museum 
was  opened  with  appropriate  ceremonies  in  the  spring  of  1941. 

The  excursion  of  the  federal  government  into  the  role  of  Art  Sponsor 
Number  One  was,  like  the  conservation  program,  stimulated  by  the  un- 
employment and  relief  situation.  It  began  with  the  creation  of  a  small 
experimental  unit  known  as  the  Public  Works  Art  Project  in  December, 
1933.  Thisv  lasted  until  June,  1934,  and  gave  work  to  about  3,000  paint- 
ers and  sculptors.  In  1934,  a  Section  of  Painting  and  Sculpture  was 
created  in  the  Treasury  Department  and  employed  about  a  thousand 
artists.  In  October,  1938,  it  was  changed  to  the  Section  of  Fine  Arts 
and  made  permanent.  The  Section  of  Painting  and  Sculpture,  though 
ill-housed  and  working  under  considerable  handicaps,  did  accomplish 
some  good  work,  the  best  of  which  has  been  put  in  government  buildings. 

But  the  art  enterprise  which  attained  impressive  proportions  was 
the  four  Art  Projects  created  in  August,  1935,  under  the  general  super- 
vision of  the  Works  Progress  Administration.  These  projects  were  the 
Federal  Arts  Project,  the  Federal  Music  Project,  the  Federal  Theatre 
Project,  and  the  Federal  Writers  Project.  While  these  projects  were 
under  the  formal  supervision  of  Harry  Hopkins,  as  head  of  WPA,  the 
actual- supervision  was  handed  over  to  his  assistant  administrator,  Ellen 
S.  Woodward.  Competent  directors  were  selected  for  the  several  Projects 
by  R.  J.  Baker,  then  assistant  to  Mr.  Hopkins.  Holger  Cahill  was  ap- 
pointed director  of  the  Arts  Project,  Nikolai  Sokoloff  of  the  Music  Project, 
Hallie  Flanagan  of  the  Theatre  Project,  and  Henry  C.  Alsberg  of  the 
Writers  Project. 

These  four  art  projects  reached  their  peak  in  1936,  when  they  employed 
about  42,500  persons.  Some  5,330  were  enrolled  in  the  Arts  Project, 
15,629  in  the  Music  Project,  12,477  in  the  Federal  Theatre,  and  6,500  in 
the  Writers  Project.  The  personnel  was  cut  rather  sharply  thereafter 
and,  by  January,  1938,  only  27,000  were  employed.  The  projects  tapered 
off  and  were  pretty  much  closed  by  the  end  of  1939.  War  crowded  out 
art  in  federal  interests.  By  January,  1938,  about  $87,000,000  had  been 
expended  on  these  projects.  The  revolutionary  character  of  the  federal 
art  enterprise  has  been  well  stated  by  Fortune: 

What  the  government's  experiments  in  music,  painting,  and  the  theatre  actually 
did,  even  in  their  first  year,  was  to  work  a  sort  of  cultural  revolution  in  America. 
They  brought  the  American  audience  and  the  American  artist  face  to  face  for 
the  first  time  in  their  respective  lives.  And  the  result  was  an  astonishment 
needled  with  excitement  such  as  neither  the  American  artist  nor  the  American 
audience  had  ever  felt  before. 


858          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

Down  to  the  beginning  of  these  experiments  neither  the  American  populace 
nor  the  American  artist  had  ever  guessed  that  the  American  audience  existed. 
The  American  audience  as  the  American  artist  saw  it  was  a  small  group  of 
American  millionaires  who  bought  pictures  not  because  they  liked  pictures  but 
because  the  possession  of  certain  pictures  was  the  surest  and  most  cheaply 
acquired  sign  of  culture.  Since  all  pictures,  to  qualify,  must  necessarily  have 
been  sold  first  for  a  high  price  at  Christie's  in  London  this  audience  did  not  do 
much  for  American  painters.  The  same  thing  was  true  of  the  American  audience 
as  the  American  composer  saw  it.  The  American  audience  as  the  American  com- 
poser saw  it  was  something  called  the  concertgoer:  a  creature  generally  female 
and  ordinarily  about  sixty  years  of  age  who  believed  everything  Waiter  Dam- 
rosch  said  and  prided  herself  on  never  hearing  anything  composed  more  recently 
than  1900  or  nearer  than  Paris,  France.  This  audience  also  was  little  help  to  the 
American  composer.  From  one  end  of  the  range  to  the  other,  American  artists, 
with  the  partial  exception  of  the  popular  novelists  and  the  successful  Broadway 
playwrights,  wrote  and  painted  and  composed  in  a  kind  of  vacuum,  despising  the 
audience  they  had,  ignoring  the  existence  of  any  other. 

It  was  this  vacuum  which  the  Federal  Arts  Projects  exploded.  In  less  than  a 
year  from  the  time  the  program  first  got  under  way  the  totally  unexpected 
pressure  of  popular  interest  had  crushed  the  shell  which  had  always  isolated 
painters  and  musicians  from  the  rest  of  their  countrymen  and  the  American 
artist  was  brought  face  to  face  with  the  true  American  audience.51 

The  work  of  the  Arts  Project  was  varied  and  voluminous.  Architects 
were  put  to  work  on  WPA  building  projects.  Painters  and  sculptors 
produced  works  that  were  loaned  to  tax-supported  institutions  or  ex- 
hibited throughout  the  country.  Other  artists  were  given  work  to  do  in 
art  education.  A  searching  history  of  American  decorative  art  before  the 
twentieth  century,  "An  Index  of  American  Design,"  was  compiled.  The 
extent  and  variety  of  the  accomplishments  of  the  Arts  Project  through 
the  year  1938  are  well  summarized  in  the  following  paragraph  from  an 
official  bulletin: 

A  total  of  13,458  tax-supported  public  institutions  have  received  allocations 
of  project  work  for  which  they  have  contributed  the  material  and  other  nonlabor 
costs.  On  the  walls  of  schools,  hospitals,  armories,  and  other  public  buildings 
all  over  the  country  hang  the  works  of  project  artists.  A  total  of  more  than 
100,000  works  of  art  created  by  Works  Progress  Administration  artists  in  the 
fields  of  painting,  sculpture,  and  graphic  arts  have  been  allocated  to  these 
institutions.  Other  art  workers  have  created  550  dioramas  and  models,  450,000 
posters,  35,000  map  drawings  and  diagrams,  45,000  arts  and  crafts  objects, 
350,000  photographs,  10,000  lantern  slides  and  various  types  of  visual  aids,  and 
10,000  Index  of  American  Design  drawings,  making  a  grand  total  of  about  a 
million  works  of  all  kinds  allocated  by  the  project  to  tax-supported  institutions 
during  the  past  3  years.  In  addition  to  these  allocations  there  are  another 
25,000  works  circulating  in  traveling  exhibitions  throughout  the  country,  which 
will  be  included  in  future  allocations.  This  means  that  for  every  worker  now 
employed  on  the  program  the  public  has  received  200  works  in  creative  and 
applied  art.  Over  1,200  artists  who  are  not  producing  work  for  allocation  are 
engaged  in  the  art  educational  and  teaching  program.52 

In  popularizing  art  and  carrying  it  to  areas  which  had  had  little  previ- 
ous opportunity  to  appreciate  art,  the  most  important  work  of  the  Federal 


01  Fortune,  May,  1937. 

^--Report  on  the  Federal  Arts  Project,  January,  1939,  p.  5, 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         859 

Arts  Project  was  its  cooperation  with  local  communities  in  setting  up  some 
62  community  art  centers  and  galleries  throughout  the  country.  By 
January,  1939,  over  4%  million  persons  had  visited  the  community  gal- 
leries, listened  to  government-paid  lecturers  on  art  appreciation  or  par- 
ticipated in  the  art  classes  which  were  established.  The  appreciation 
and  enthusiasm  of  the  communities  is  well  demonstrated  by  the  fact  that 
they  themselves  contributed  over  $300,000  to  the  support  of  these  com- 
munity art  projects.  The  nature  and  variety  of  the  services  of  these 
community  projects  to  January,  1939,  were  well  described  by  Thomas  (X 
Parker,  assistant  director  of  the  Federal  Arts  Project: 

Like  our  thousands  of  fine  libraries  throughout  the  country,  the  community 
art  centers  endeavor  to  reach  and  serve  average  American  communities  in  fields 
of  art  and  its  application  to  everyday  life.  There  are  changing  exhibitions  of 
various  types  of  art,  both  local  and  national,  giving  a  fresh  selection  every  three 
weeks.  There  are  docents  and  artist-teachers  in  constant  attendance  who  give 
to  questioning  visitors  of  all  ages,  races  and  classes  a  friendly  and  human  in- 
troduction to  the  meaning  of  art.  There  are  afternoon  and  evening  classes 
ministering  both  to  the  needs  of  exuberant  youngsters  who  must  have  an  outlet 
for  their  aburidant  energy,  and  to  the  problems  of  adults  who  find  a  new  source 
of  interest  and  service  in  the  fine  arts.  There  are  demonstration  talks  in  which 
the  processes  of  print-making,  of  fresco  painting,  of  poster  making,  and  sculp- 
ture are  removed  from  the  mysterious  technical  jargon  in  which  they  have  long 
been  veiled  and  brought  to  the  understanding  of  Mr.  and  Mrs.  Average  American. 
Thus,  through  the  opportunity  of  actually  seeing  the  artist  at  work,  and  through 
carefully  prepared  exhibits  of  materials,  tools  and  progress  stages  of  the  creation 
of  a  work  of  art,  people  in  all  sections  of  the  country  are  feeling  the  desire  both 
to  possess  art  and  to  participate  in  painting,  print-making,  sculpture  or  arts  and 
crafts,  according  to  their  talents.53 

So  far  as  artistic  achievement  is  concerned,  the  most  notable  work 
of  the  Arts  Project  has  been  that  done  in  murals  and  sculpture.  Over 
1,200  murals  and  mosaics  have  been  completed  and  installed  in  public 
institutions.  About  1,800  works  of  sculpture  have  also  been  turned  out 
for  public  buildings,  parks,  battlefields,  and  other  historical  sites.  The 
demand  for  the  products  of  the  Arts  Project  by  hospitals,  schools,  and  the 
like  was  far  greater  than  could  be  supplied  by  the  personnel  of  the  Arts 
Project.  All  in  all,  the  work  of  the  Arts  Project  justifies  the  comment 
of  Lawrence  Coleman,  the  director  of  the  American  Association  of  Mu- 
seums, to  the  effect  that  "the  Federal  Arts  Project  is  one  of  the  most  im- 
portant things  that  has  happened  to  American  art  in  a  hundred  years." 

The  Federal  Music  Project  reached  more  Americans  than  any  other 
WPA  art  project.  It  put  on  more  than  100,000  programs  and  it  has 
been  estimated  that  they  reached  100  million  persons.  The  Music 
Project  had  little  opportunity  to  do  creative  work,  but  it  did  make  exten- 
sive u$e  of  interpretative  artists.  Director  Solokoff  showed  that  orches- 
tras could  produce  the  music  of  the  great  masters  in  competent  fashion 
without  having  world-famous  directors.  The  Music  Project  also  proved 


58  Quotation  from  typewritten  manuscript  furnished  to  the  author  by  the  Federal 
Art  Project. 


860          LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS 

that  music  is  more  important  than  the  names  of  its  performers,  which  was 
a  good  lesson  for  American  musical  audiences  to  learn.  Dr.  Sokoloff  also 
rendered  an  important  service  in  giving  proper  attention  to  American 
composers  who  have  been  quite  generally  slighted  in  American  music. 
The  "Index  of  American  Composers"  prepared  by  the  Music  Project  gave 
us  for  the  first  time  a  full  comprehension  of  the  extent  of  American 
musical  composition.  The  educational  work  of  the  Music  Project  was 
also  impressive.  In  December,  1936,  over  200,000  persons  were  enrolled 
in  music  classes,  with  some  1,300  qualified  musicians  as  teachers.  Classes 
were  held  everywhere  from  metropolitan  slum  districts  to  the  most  re- 
mote reaches  of  rural  America. 

The  Federal  Theatre  Project  also  attained  great  popularity.  Over 
1,700  performances  were  given  between  February,  1936,  and  January, 
1938.  They  were  played  before  audiences  that  totaled  over  30,000,000 
persons.  It  is  estimated  that  at  least  half  of  those  who  attended  these 
performances  had  never  before  seen  an  actor  on  the  stage.  Perhaps  the 
outstanding  performance  was  the  play  "The  Living  Newspaper."  Other 
important  plays  were  "Prologue  to  Glory/'  "Triple-A  Plowed  Under," 
"One  Third  of  a  Nation/'  and  "It  Can't  Happen  Here,"  which  was  barred 
from  the  movies.  The  marionette  shows  in  New  York  City  and  else- 
where were  viewed  by  at  least  5  million  school  children. 

In  addition  to  its  dramatic  performances,  every  Federal  Theatre  group 
in  the  country  offered  courses  in  dramatic  art  to  train  actors  for  more 
competent  performance.  All  in  all,  one  may  safely  say  that  the  Federal 
Theatre  represented  the  most  remarkable  renaissance  of  the  legitimate 
stage  since  it  was  challenged  by  the  rise  of  the  movies. 

The  most  important  work  of  the  Federal  Writers  Project  was  the 
"American  Guide  Series/'  admirable  handbooks  of  practical  information 
on  each  of  the  forty-eight  states  and  Alaska,  Hawaii,  and  Puerto  Rico. 
Guides  were  also  prepared  for  certain  important  American  cities.  Sup- 
plemental volumes  on  folklore,  local  culture,  and  racial  groups  were  pre- 
pared. Sponsors  put  up  over  $400,000  for  these  guides. 

Closely  related  to  the  Writers  Project  was  the  Historical  Record  Sur- 
vey, which  made  a  careful  record  of  documents  in  public  offices,  libraries, 
and  historical  association  files. 

There  has  been  much  criticism  of  the  fact  that  over  100  million  dollars 
was  spent  on  the  various  Federal  Art  Projects.  But  it  is  doubtful  if  any 
public  money  was  more  fruitfully  expended.  One  of  the  greatest  defi- 
ciencies in  our  national  culture  has  been  our  backwardness  in  the  field  of 
art.  The  Federal  Art  Projects  constituted  an  impressive,  if  temporary, 
effort  to  remedy  this  deficiency.  The  total  cost  was  less  than  the  cost  of 
two  great  modern  battleships. 

That  we  have  a  long  road  to  travel  before  we  appreciate  the  true  value 
of  art  in  American  life  is  evident  from  the  fact  that  one  of  the  first  things 
to  be  dismantled  in  the  economy  drive  of  1939  were  the  Federal  Art 
Projects.  And  the  very  people  who  most  bitterly  criticized  these  expend- 
itures were  the  ones  who  most  enthusiastically  supported  the  expenditures 


LEISURE,   RECREATION,  AND  THE  ARTS         861 

of  billions  for  the  armaments  which  may  ultimately  destroy  any  civiliza- 
tion capable  of  appreciating  art. 

American  states  have  not  done  so  much  to  subsidize  art  projects  as  have 
the  American  municipalities,  which  appear  to  be  increasing  the  extenl 
of  their  support.  In  1823  the  Brooklyn  Museum  was  founded  and  haj 
been  supported  by  taxation.  The  St.  Louis  Art  Museum,  founded  in  th( 
'seventies,  is  also  supported  by  taxation.  The  Metropolitan  Museum  o: 
Art  in  New  York  City  receives  large  municipal  appropriations.  Othei 
important  museums  and  galleries  which  get  aid  from  taxation  are  th( 
Detroit  Institute  of  Art,  the  Chicago  Art  Institute,  the  Newark  City  An 
Museum,  the  DeYoung  Memorial  Museum  in  San  Francisco,  city  gal- 
leries in  Los  Angeles,  Oakland,  Sacramento,  and  San  Diego,  the  galleries 
in  San  Antonio,  Houston,  and  Dallas,  Texas,  the  galleries  in  Indianapolis 
Evansville,  and  Fort  Wayne,  Indiana,  and  the  civic  galleries  in  Buffalo 
Albany,  and  Yonkers.  There  are  other  publicly  supported  museums  anc 
galleries  but  these  are  the  more  important  ones. 

Baltimore  and  San  Francisco  are  the  two  cities  that  support  municipa 
symphony  orchestras.  The  Baltimore  Symphony  was  established  ir 
1916;  that  of  San  Francisco  in  1935.  We  read  about  civic  opera  com- 
panies in  various  American  cities,  but,  almost  without  exception,  thes< 
are  privately  supported.  The  first  municipal  grant  for  an  opera  in  the 
United  States  was  made  by  Philadelphia  in  1923,  but  the  move  was  pre- 
mature, as  there  does  not  seem  to  be  enough  demand  for  opera  as  yd 
to  warrant  public  financing. 

Government  aid  to  the  arts  is  heartily  to  be  welcomed,  so  long  as  ii 
does  not  assume  to  dictate  artistic  standards  and  coerce  individual  artist* 
in  their  creative  activity.  Indeed,  public  support  of  art,  along  with  th< 
preservation  of  freedom,  is  an  indispensable  phase  of  any  true  civilization 

Whether  the  state's  participation  in  the  affairs  of  art  is  a  power  for  evil  o: 
for  good  may  depend,  first  of  all  upon  the  degree  of  liberality  inherent  in  th< 
form  of  government  itself.  Second,  it  is  in  large  part  a  matter  of  the  direc 
administering  of  the  art  activities.  In  a  democracy,  a  sensible  and  just  ar 
administration  is  not  beyond  the  limits  of  possibility;  indeed,  it  is  well  withii 
the  range  of  hope. 

It  is  important,  however,  that  the  permanent  fine  arts  system  now  definite!) 
in  the  making  in  our  country,  avoid  prescribing  the  policies  or  usurping  the  ar 
activities  of  the  nation ;  that  the  government  provide  a  center  for  tne  arts,  bui 
leave  ample  opportunity  for  independent  effort  outside;  that  it  strive  to  keej 
the  product  of  the  country's  creative  workers  free  from  the  label,  "governmeni 
art.'f ... 

The  problem  of  "government  interference,"  as  it  may  accompany  state  subsidy 
of  the  arts,  was  once  discussed  by  the  late  John  Drinkwater  in  connection  wit! 
the  moot  question  of  England's  national  theatre.  His  epigrammatic  conclusion 
which  might  serve  as  a  motto  for  any  government  in  its  relationship  to  art  wai 
simply  this:  "The  state  should  pay  the  piper,  but  should  not  call  the  tune."5 


64  Grace  Overmyer,  Government  and  the  Arts,  Norton,  1939,  pp.  216-217.  For  i 
good  discussion  of  the  effect  of  the  two  World  Wars  on  recreation  and  the  arts,  se< 
R.  B.  Fosdick,  "Leisure  Time  in  the  Army  and  Navy,"  in  Survey  Graphic,  June,  1942 


CHAPTER  XX 
Summary  Appraisal  of  Our  Institutional  Crisis 

LET  us  gather  together  the  main  threads  of  the  argument  we  have 
presented  in  this  book.  We  made  it  clear,  at  the  outset,  that  social  organ- 
ization is  an  outgrowth  of  the  natural  sociability  of  mankind  and  indis- 
pensable for  the  development  of  human  culture.  In  spite  of  his  superior 
intelligence,  man,  in  isolation,  is  a  relatively  weak  and  helpless  animal. 
In  association  with  his  fellowmen,  however,  he  finds  strength  for  defense 
and  for  dynamic  achievements.  Through  cooperative  endeavor,  social 
groups  have  brought  about  division  of  labor  and  industrial  specializa- 
tion. These  facilitate  the  provision  of  the  necessities  of  life  and  help 
to  create  a  surplus,  thereby  making  possible  further  achievements  in 
cultural  evolution.  Moreover,  group  life  has  enabled  man  to  use  the 
special  talents  of  individual  members.  As  culture  develops,  social  or- 
ganization becomes  more  complex,  and,  if  the  society  is  an  efficient  one, 
its  growing  social  complexity  contributes  to  further  progress. 

The  advantages  of  group  life  and  social  organization  are  not  obtained 
without  a  price.  This  price  is  the  discipline  imposed  upon  the  individual 
by  the  group  and  the  loss  of  liberty  which  this  involves.  For  a  long 
time  in  the  experience  of  mankind,  the  question  of  group  discipline  was  a 
purely  automatic  and  spontaneous  affair.  There  was  no  philosophic 
reflection  on  the  problem  of  how  much  discipline  might  be  good  for  the 
individual  and  as  to  how  far  excessive  regimentation  might  hamper 
progress.  Reflection  of  this  sort  began  with  the  Greeks.  There  is  no 
doubt  that,  for  many  thousands  of  years,  the  potential  progress  of  the 
race  has  been  slowed  down  through  the  excessive  regimentation  of  the 
mass  of  mankind.  The  supreme  problem  of  social  philosophy  is  to  out- 
line a  society  which  will  assure  just  enough  discipline  to  secure  orderly 
social  life  and  yet  provide  enough  liberty  and  independence  to  encourage 
individual  invention  and  freedom  of  speculation.  It  is  easy  enough  thus 
to  state  the  issue  theoretically,  but  it  is  desperately  difficult  to  solve  the 
problem  in  the  actual  operations  of  mankind  'and  the  control  of  human 
society. 

We  made  it  clear  that  institutions  are  the  chief  means  by  which  group 
life  is  carried  on.  These  institutions  have  been  built  up  to  control  the 
main  problems  of  organized  existence.  They  have  governed  our  rela- 
tions with  the  supernatural  world,  the  problems  of  sex  and  procreation, 
the  gaining  of  a  livelihood,  the  enforcement  of  group  discipline  through 
government,  the  transmission  of  folkways  and  knowledge  from  genera- 

862 


APPRAISING  OUR   INSTITUTIONAL  CRISIS       863 

tion  to  generation,  the  modes  of  communication  between  groups  and  re- 
gions, the  relations  between  social  classes,  our  attitudes  towards  strangers, 
the  contacts  between  groups,  and  the  like.  The  security  and  well-being 
of  mankind  depend  very  directly  upon  the  efficiency  of  our  social  institu- 
tions. 

In  their  origins,  institutions  are  rarely  the  product  of  conscious 
thought  or  deliberate  choice.  They  are  the  outcome  of  man's  blundering 
efforts  to  satisfy  the  various  drives  inherent  in  human  nature.  If  these 
efforts  are  successful  enough  to  allow  the  group  to  maintain  itself,  they 
take  on  a  permanent  character  as  institutions.  Since  primitive  man 
attributes  causation  mainly  to  the  supernatural  world,  our  early  institu- 
tions were  usually  regarded  as  of  divine  origin  and  accorded  a  suitable 
reverence.  This  has  made  it  very  difficult  to  alter  institutions,  except 
through  the  shock  of  war,  revolution,  and  other  violent  forms  of  impact 
on  the  life  and  culture  of  the  group.  Even  after  we  have  given  up  any 
formal  belief  in  the  divine  origin  of  our  institutions,  the  vested  interests 
in  society  are  able  to  provide  rationalizations  which  confer  a  large  amount 
of  sanctity  upon  our  institutions  and  make  it  almost  as  difficult  to 
change  them  as  in  primitive  times. 

Institutions  can  operate  efficiently  only  when  they  are  in  reasonable 
adjustment  to  the  basic  conditions  of  life,  especially  the  state  of  tech- 
nology and  industry.  An  acute  cultural  crisis  always  arises  when  insti- 
tutions get  out  of  adjustment  with  fundamental  life  conditions.  If  the 
latter  have  changed  markedly  since  the  period  when  institutions  arose, 
we  have  a  social  maladjustment  which  bodes  ill  for  the  future  of  society. 
This  failure  of  institutions  to  keep  pace  with  life  conditions  is  known 
among  -social  scientists  as  cultural  lag.  It  is  the  foremost  problem  with 
which  organized  society  must  cope.  It  is  especially  serious  in  contem- 
porary times,  when  material  conditions  are  changing  rapidly  while  insti- 
tutions maintain  a  stubborn  reluctance  to  change  with  anything  like 
comparable  rapidity  and  rationality. 

The  institutional  crisis  of  our  day  is  far  more  marked  and  serious  than 
in  any  earlier  period  in  the  history  of  mankind.  In  the  last  hundred 
years,  our  science  and  technology  have  made  more  rapid  strides  than  in 
the  million  years  preceding  the  middle  of  the  nineteenth  century.  We 
have  an  extremely  impressive  body  of  scientific  knowledge  and  tech- 
nological equipment.  But  we  continue  to  try  to  control  this  empire 
of  laboratories  and  machines  through  basic  institutions  which  were  fully 
developed  by  the  time  of  George  Washington.  In  many  of  of  them  there 
are  definite  strains  from  the  culture  of  the  caveman.  In  this  way,  we 
are  veritably  trying  to  control  an  airplane  era  by  means  of  oxcart  insti- 
tutions, and  the  experiment  is  not  succeeding. 

In  earlier  days,  institutions  tended  to  keep  pace  with  the  slight  body  of 
scientific  knowledge  and  a  handicraft  technology.  But  today  they  lag 
sadly  behind  scientific  research  and  mechanical  invention. 

A  vast  gulf  has  developed  between  our  archaic  institutions  and  our 
highly  advanced  science  and  technology.  This  creates  the  basic  social 


864       APPRAISING  OUR  INSTITUTIONAL  CRISIS 

problem  of  our  day.  All  of  our  other  social  problems — the  waste  of  nat- 
ural resources,  starvation  in  the  midst  of  plenty,  the  crisis  in  democratic 
government,  international  enmity  and  war,  religious  disintegration,  the 
futility  of  education,  the  breakdown  of  morals,  the  disintegration  of 
family  life,  the  crisis  in  property  rights,  the  losses  due  to  crime,  mental 
instability,  the  sense  of  insecurity,  and  the  like — are  primarily  subordi- 
nate and  incidental  results  of  the  gulf  between  machines  and  institutions. 
We  shall  solve  none  of  these  social  problems  satisfactorily  until  we  bring 
our  institutions  up  to  date  and  make  them  as  efficient  as  our  technology. 

If  we  can  modify  our  institutions  so  that  our  science  and  machinery 
work  efficiently  for  the  benefit  of  mankind,  a  material  Utopia  will  be 
within  our  grasp,  and  we  shall  also  be  able  to  rid  ourselves  of  that  su- 
preme menace — international  war.  If,  however,  we  continue  to  sabotage 
our  new  science  and  technology  through  archaic  institutions,  we  face 
inevitable  economic  collapse  and  international  anarchy.  Our  science  and 
machinery  are  assets  only  if  they  are  used  wisely  and  efficiently.  If  we 
continue  to  use  them  as  we  do  today,  they  will  only  provide  us  with  an 
effective  short-cut  to  oblivion.  Mankind,  very  literally,  has  the  choice 
in  our  day  between  utopia  and  chaos.  Upon  our  success  in  bringing  our 
institutions  up  to  date  will  depend  the  outcome. 

In  treating  of  industry,  we  made  it  clear  that  most  of  the  human  effort 
in  getting  a  living  before  the  rise  of  modern  industrialism  was  bestowed 
upon  hunting,  pastoral  life,  and  agriculture.  Our  present-day  industrial 
and  manufacturing  era  is  a  very  recent  episode  in  human  evolution. 
Even  today,  the  majority  of  those  on  the  planet  are  still  engaged  in 
hunting,  herding,  or  farming.  Down  to  the  Industrial  Revolution,  most 
manufacturing  activity  was  carried  on  within  the  home.  However,  there 
were  some  central  shops  in  ancient  Babylonia,  and  small  factories  in 
Egypt,  Greece,  and  Rome.  In  the  Middle  Ages,  a  great  deal  of  industry 
was  carried  on  under  the  supervision  of  the  guilds  and  the  monasteries. 
The  putting-out  system,  which  became  popular  in  early  modern  times, 
has  often  been  called  the  domestic  system  because  it  was  located  pri- 
marily in  the  homes  of  workers.  The  factory  system,  which  followed  on 
the  heels  of  the  Industrial  Revolution,  has  been  a  very  late  arrival  in  the 
evolution  of  manufacturing. 

From  the  earliest  stone  ages  to  the  eighteenth  century  of  the  Christian 
era,  the  prevailing  technique  of  production  was  that  of  handicraft  meth- 
ods. Man  relied  upon  his  hands  and  upon  tools  which  extended  his 
manual  power.  Mechanical  production  began  to  appear  in  the  seven- 
teenth century.  By  the  nineteenth  it  dominated  manufacturing  in  civi- 
lized states.  The  evolution  of  the  empire  of  machines  has  passed  through 
three  stages  in  modern  times.  First  came  the  development  of  machines 
for  making  cloth,  the  introduction  of  the  steam  engine  for  power  services, 
and  cheaper  methods  of  making  iron  and  steel  through  the  use  of  coke 
furnaces.  Next,  came  the  rise  of  large-scale  industry  and  improved 
methods  of  factory  administration.  Finally,  in  the  twentieth  century, 
we  have  witnessed  the  widespread  introduction  of  electrical  power,  of 


APPRAISING  OUR   INSTITUTIONAL  CRISIS       865 

mass  production,  and  automatic  machinery.  All  of  this  may  be  the 
prelude  to  even  more  striking  and  momentous  mechanical  advances. 

We  now  have  the  technological  equipment  to  produce  enough  food  and 
goods  to  provide  everybody  with  a  high  standard  of  living  with  a  minimum 
of  physical  effort.  But  we  have  not  realized  any  such  benefit,  because 
our  protential  productivity  has  been  curtailed  and  sabotaged  by  an  eco- 
nomic system  which  arose  in  the  period  of  handicraft  industry  and  is 
consecrated  to  the  limitation  of  production  and  linked  to  the  economy  of 
scarcity.  The  technology  of  abundance  cannot  long  coexist  with  a 
scarcity  economy  and  philosophy.  We  must  either  put  our  machines  to 
work  directly  for  human  service  in  an  efficient  manner  or  be  resigned  to 
the  collapse  of  both  our  economic  order  and  our  technological  equipment. 
Every  year  that  passes  gives  greater  evidence  of  the  incompatibility  be- 
tween our  technological  prowess  and  our  archaic  economic  ideas  and 
practices.  Many  believe  that  the  only  solution  lies  in  handing  over  the 
control  of  our  economic  life  to  trained  industrial  engineers,  who  can  set 
up  a  planned  and  efficient  economy. 

We  have  become  so  accustomed  to  capitalism  as  a  method  of  economic 
control  that  we  are  wont  to  imagine  that  it  has  always  dominated  eco- 
nomic ideals  and  practices.  As  an  actual  matter  of  fact,  it  is  a  product 
of  modern  times  and  was  not  highly  developed  until  the  nineteenth  cen- 
tury. Greek  and  Roman  philosophers  were  highly  critical  of  even  rudi- 
mentary capitalistic  ideals  and  practices.  Medieval  church  ethics  prac- 
tically outlawed  them.  They  did  not  become  popular  until  the  rise  of 
Protestantism.  Even  then,  it  required  a  couple  of  centuries  to  accumu- 
late enough  financial  reserves  and  to  develop  enough  commercial  enter- 
prise to  give  capitalism  a  firm  foothold  in  the  modern  economic  order. 
Capitalism  may  have  its  virtues  or  defects,  but  it  can  scarcely  be  re- 
garded as  a  universal  institution,  coexistent  with  the  entire  economic 
experience  of  mankind. 

We  traced  the  various  stages  through  which  capitalism  has  developed. 
It  started  out  as  commercial  capitalism,  under  the  leadership  of  the  mer- 
chant classes,  after  the  discovery  of  America  and  the  expansion  of  Europe. 
The  coming  of  machinery  and  the  factory  system  brought  into  being 
industrial  capitalism,  then  controlled  by  the  rising  class  of  factory 
owners.  As  factories  grew  larger  and  the  great  industrialists  became 
richer  and  more  powerful,  industrial  capitalism  moved  on  into  monopoly 
capitalism,  with  control  centered  in  a  few  powerful  individuals  and 
groups.  They  sought  to  increase  profits  through  reducing  waste,  restrict- 
ing output,  and  maintaining  high  prices.  In  the  twentieth  century,  capi- 
talism passed  out  of  the  control  of  industrialists,  save  in  the  case  of  a  few 
exceptions  like  Henry  Ford,  and  came  to  be  dominated  by  the  great  in- 
vestment banking  interests.  The  latter  were  chiefly  interested  in  making 
profits  through  speculative  financial  manipulations,  often  at  the  expense 
of  sound  industry  and  trade.  The  excesses  of  this  type  of  capitalism, 
which  we  know  as  finance  capitalism,  brought  on  the  great  depression  of 
1929  and  the  years  following. 


866       APPRAISING  OUR   INSTITUTIONAL  CRISIS 

The  depression  may  prove  the  undoing  of  private  capitalism,  since  the 
efforts  to  recover  from  it  have,  almost  without  exception,  stimulated  the 
growth  of  state  capitalism  or  state  socialism.  The  second  World  War 
seems  to  have  hastened  such  developments.  Prior  to  the  war,  it  seemed 
as  though  economic  problems  might  be  solved  by  means  of  the  so-called 
"middle-way7'  system,  so  successfully  applied  in  Scandinavian  countries 
and  Finland.  Here,  private  and  state  capitalism  were  combined  success- 
fully with  cooperative  enterprise.  But  the  strains  and  stresses  of  the 
second  World  War  seem  likely  to  wreck  this  promising  development  and 
to  favor  the  progress  of  an  ever  more  rigorous  collectivism. 

Perhaps  the  most  sacred  of  our  economic  institutions  is  private  prop* 
erty.  While  there  have  been  certain  types  of  private  property  since 
primitive  times  and  tribal  society,  the  rise  of  property  to  a  position  of 
institutional  sanctity  is  as  recent  a  development  as  that  of  mechanical 
production.  Property  rights  and  usages  were  strictly  controlled  in  an- 
cient pagan  times  and  during  the  Middle  Ages.  Private  property  was, 
in  theory  at  least,  subordinated  to  religious  and  moral  conceptions  of 
social  welfare.  The  sanctification  of  private  property  was  a  rationaliza- 
tion provided  by  the  philosophical  apologists  for  the  rise  of  capitalism 
and  industrialism.  Being  the  spokesmen  for  those  who  accumulated  the 
most  property,  they  portrayed  its  accumulation  as  a  divinely-approved 
process  and  sought  to  protect  property  against  assault  by  proclaiming 
it  to  be  indispensable  to  social  well-being.  Their  arguments  possessed 
some  validity  in  early  modern  times.  At  that  time,  the  possessors  of 
property  dominated  economic  enterprise  and  were  responsible  for  the 
majority  of  economic  achievements.  The  urge  to  accumulate  property 
then  undoubtedly  stimulated  industrial  enterprise.  Property  owners  di- 
directly  controlled  and  managed  commercial  and  manufacturing  projects 
in  those  days. 

In  recent  times,  the  relation  of  property  owners  to  economic  enterprise 
has  changed  greatly.  Through  the  rise  of  corporations  and  holding  com- 
panies and  the  resulting  ascendancy  of  finance  capitalism,  the  ownership 
of  property  had  been  widely  divorced  from  the  control  and  management 
of  economic  enterprises.  Those  who  own  securities  in  our  great  indus- 
trial concerns  actually  have  little  or  nothing  to  do  with  the  policies  and 
practices  through  which  they  are  operated.  Those  who  do  control  them 
are  frequently  more  interested  in  making  money  out  of  financial  specula- 
tion, at  the  expense  of  stockholders,  than  they  are  in  efficient  methods  of 
operating  the  plants.  Property,  in  our  economic  age,  has  tended  more 
and  more  to  become  passive  and  parasitical.  The  arguments  for  its 
sanctity  become  yearly  more  musty  and  more  lacking  in  validity. 

At  the  very  moment  when  private  property  was  becoming  a  less 
dynamic  factor  in  industrial  progress,  property  owners  and  their  lawyer 
retainers  extended  the  conception  of  property  beyond  all  precedent,  espe- 
cially in  the  United  States.  The  Fourteenth  Amendment  and  the  "due 
process  of  law"  clause  therein  has  permitted  a  reactionary  Supreme  Court 
to  confer  essential  sanctity  upon  private  property.  Therefore,  the  pow- 


APPRAISING  OUR   INSTITUTIONAL  CRISIS       867 

4          * 

erful  vested  economic  interests; in  the  country  sought  to  christen  their 
every  selfish  policy  and  practice  as  property  and  thus  to  place  it  beyond 
the  reach  of  the  law.  Almost  every  effort  to  promote  social  reform,  eco- 
nomic justice,  and  public  decency  was  vigorously  opposed,  on  the  ground 
that  it  invaded  the  sanctity  of  property.  Such  things  as  the  open  shop, 
dangerous  and  atrocious  working  conditions,  dishonest  weights  and  meas- 
ures, shoddy  products,  exposure  to  mutilation  and  death  in  factories  and 
mines,  and  gigantic  financial  larcenies,  were  all  defended  as  property 
interests,  and  this  defense  was  usually  upheld  by  the  supreme  tribunal 
of  our  land.  Not  until  President  Roosevelt's  attack  upon  the  Supreme 
Court  in  the  late  'thirties  was  this  enormous  extension  and  distortion  of 
property  rights  seriously  checked.  In  the  Old  AVorld,  the  growth  of  state 
capitalism  and  war  measures  have  seriously  restricted  private  property 
rights. 

In  spite  of  the  tremendous  prestige  of  property  rights  and  the  stubborn 
defense  of  property  by  the  courts,  there  have  been  serious  inroads  upon 
private  property  in  recent  times,  even  in  the  United  States.  Paradoxically 
enough,  the  most  serious  undermining  of  property  and  the  greatest  losses 
to  property  owners  have  been  the  result  of  the  policies  and  practiced  of  the 
great  financial  moguls  who  control  our  economy  and  have  been  most 
active  in  defending  property  rights  through  the  courts.  The  same  corpo- 
ration lawyers  who  have  argued  in  behalf  of  property  rights  before  the 
courts  have  guided  their  corporate  employers  in  those  policies  which  have 
brought  billions  of  dollars  in  losses  to  bondholders  and  stockholders.  It 
is  doubtful  if  the  taxes  imposed  upon  property  by  public  agencies  have 
exceeded  the  waste  and  larcenies  carried  out  by  those  in  control  of  corpo- 
rations at  the  expense  of  security  holders,  who  are  the  chief  property- 
owning  classes  in  the  community. 

The  breakdown  of  private  capitalism  and  the  increase  of  state  capital- 
ism have  enormously  increased  the  taxes  laid  upon  private  property  and 
income.  The  unemployment  associated  with  a  declining  capitalism  has 
thrown  far  greater  expenditures  upon  governmental  agencies,  which  have 
had  to  assume  responsibility  for  relief  and  employment.  Further,  the 
greater  complexities  of  our  society  have  led  to  new  governmental  respon- 
sibilities. All  of  this  has  increased  public  expenditures  and  made  higher 
taxes  necessary.  These  restrict  and  lessen  the  amount  of  property  that 
can  be  accumulated  by  any  generation  and  handed  on  to  the  next.  The 
most  direct  attack  of  our  tax  system  upon  private  property  probably  lies 
in  our  heavy  estate  and  inheritance  taxes.  These  are  being  ever  in- 
creased, and  to  evade  them  is  becoming  more  and  more  difficult. 

As  the  state  intrudes  more  and  more  into  economic  and  financial  enter- 
prises, the  area  open  to  private  property  dominion  and  operations  is  being 
constantly  restricted.  World  war  is,  perhaps,  more  menacing  to  private 
property  than  any  other  factor  in  our  generation.  War  leads  to  an 
enormous  increase  in  the  amount  of  state  activity,  at  the  expense  of  pri- 
vate property  and  enterprise.  Less  and  less  freedom  is  left  to  private 
agencies  and  the  profit  system.  Taxes  become  ever  higher,  and  less  and 


868       APPRAISING  OUR   INSTITUTIONAL  CRISIS 

less  profits  and  other  forms  of  income  are  available  to  property  owners. 
It  is  not  at  all  unlikely  that  the  second  World  War  will  mark  the  termi- 
nation of  the  economic  order  which  has  been  based  primarily  upon  private 
enterprise  and  devoted  to  the  accumulation  and  transmission  of  private 
property. 

We  traced  the  stages  through  which  the  public  control  of  society  by 
government  and  politics  has  passed.  For  thousands  of  years,  there  was 
little  government  other  than  that  exerted  by  fathers  in  the  family  and 
by  powerful  individuals  in  small  groups  of  hunters  and  fishermen.  In 
the  later  stages  of  primitive  society,  we  find  a  form  of  government  based 
upon  blood  relationship,  real  or  alleged.  This  is  diversely  known  as 
gentile  or  tribal  society.  Government  in  this  stage  of  human  develop- 
ment was  vested  mainly  in  a  group  of  elders  or  chieftains,  frequently 
elected  by  tribesmen.  In  some  cases,  a  chief  might  rise  to  the  status  of 
a  rudimentary  king.  Representative  government  and  a  considerable 
amount  of  personal  liberty  usually  prevailed  in  primitive  governments. 

In  due  time,  powerful  chieftains  and  their  tribal  followers  were  able  to 
overcome  other  tribes  and  to  impose  their  power  on  them.  When  they 
did  so  they  usually  created  little  city-states.  The  latter  have  usually 
been  the  first  definite  type  of  civil  society,  in  which  territorial  residence 
and  property  rights,  rather  than  kinship,  real  or  alleged,  were  the  domi- 
nating features  of  political  life.  It  was  very  usual  for  a  stage  of  feud- 
alism, based  upon  personal  relations,  rather  than  either  kinship  or 
residence,  to  intervene  between  tribal  society  and  the  well  consolidated 
city-state.  In  Egypt,  Babylonia,  Greece,  and  Rome,  the  city-states  were 
the  earliest  historical  examples  of  civil  government.  When  one  city-state 
succeeded  in  conquering  others,  it  set  up  a  kingdom  or,  if  more  successful 
in  conquest,  a  patriarchal  empire.  The  culmination  of  ancient  political 
development  was  the  Roman  Empire.  In  the  history  of  Rome  we  can 
trace  political  evolution  from  tribal  society  through  feudalism,  a  republi- 
can city-state,  and  kingdoms,  to  the  greatest  empire  the  world  ever  knew 
prior  to  the  rise  of  the  British  Empire. 

In  the  Middle  Ages,  we  find  a  recapitulation  of  all  the  stages  of  politi- 
cal evolution  before  the  medieval  period.  The  Middle  Ages  started  with 
tribal  society.  Then  there  were  centuries  of  feudalism,  characterized  also 
by  an  attempt  to  revitalize  the  ghost  of  the  Roman  Empire,  followed  by 
the  rise  of  city-states  and  national  kingdoms. 

In  modern  times,  we  come  upon  the  rise  of  the  national  state,  the  most 
characteristic  political  institution  of  modern  society.  The  national  state 
was  most  frequently  created  by  absolute  monarchs  out  of  the  ruins  of 
feudalism.  In  time,  the  absolute  monarchs  were  overthrown  and  repre- 
sentative government  was  set  up  under  middle-class  auspices.  In  many 
countries  in  the  nineteenth  century,  a  more  radical  and  aggressive  type 
of  government,  known  as  democracy,  was  brought  into  being.  Patriotism 
and  nationalistic  sentiment  were  more  vigorous  in  democracies  than  they 
had  been  in  absolute  monarchies. 

The  national  state  of  our  day  is  a  dual  challenge  to  human  civilization. 


APPRAISING  OUR   INSTITUTIONAL  CRISIS       869 

It  has  become  so  overgrown  and  top-heavy  that  the  problems  of  govern- 
ment have  become  ever  more  difficult  to  solve  through  democratic  meth- 
ods, and  the  resulting  crisis  invites  the  institution  of  dictatorship.  Fur- 
ther, the  warlike  character  and  bellicose  patriotism  of  national  states 
constitute  a  special  menace  in  our  day  of  ever  more  efficient  armament 
and  mechanized  warfare. 

War,  under  modern  conditions,  is  economically  more  expensive  than 
ever  before,  and  it  is  far  more  destructive  to  life  and  property.  Unless 
some  method  can  be  devised  for  peacefully  resolving  the  disputes  which 
now  give  rise  to  warfare,  and  for  creating  an  international  army  powerful 
enough  to  curb  war  between  national  states,  it  seems  unlikely  that  orderly 
human  civilization  can  endure  for  many  more  decades.  Logical  and 
powerful  federations  of  adjoining  states  may  serve  as  the  first  step  in 
the  creation  of  international  political  control. 

It  is  thought  by  some  that  the  problem  of  the  top-heavy  belligerent 
national  state  will  be  solved  as  the  result  of  the  creation  of  the  next  stage 
in  political  evolution.  It  is  held  that  the  territorial  national  states,  based 
on  the  representation  of  geographical  districts,  must  be  replaced  by  the 
functional  state,  in  which  government  will  be  administered  by  elected 
representatives  of  vocations,  professions,  and  occupations.  This  may 
prove  true.  In  fact,  since  the  first  World  War  there  have  been  some 
developments  along  the  line  of  vocational  representation. 

The  technique  of  government  which  has  prevailed  since  absolutism 
was  supplapted  by  representation  is  what  has  been  called  party  gov- 
ernment. Parties  have,  thus  far,  constituted  the  only  agency  through 
which  representative  government  can  be  operated.  While  governments 
have  been  able  to  exist  under  the  party  system,  the  latter  has  been 
weighed  down  by  such  basic  defects  that  party  government  is  proving 
ever  more  inadequate  as  a  mode  of  handling  the  complex  problems  of 
modern  life.  Though  party  government  is  supposed  to  be  an  agency  of 
democracy,  it  is  fundamentally  undemocratic  in  its  organization  and 
operation.  Parties  fall  under  the  control  of  machines  and  leaders  which 
become  as  oligarchical  as  any  feudal  oligarchy.  Parties  come  to  be  oper- 
ated more  for  the  benefit  of  the  machine  and  its  leaders  than  for  the  serv- 
ice of  the  public  weal.  Moreover,  whereas  the  complicated  problems  of 
modern  government  demand  expertness  and  superb  rationality,  party 
government  is  fundamentally  anti-rational  and  tends  to  exclude  experts 
in  favor  of  irresponsible  and  untrained  rabble-rousers.  The  most  suc- 
cessful party  is  the  one  that  can  appeal  most  potently  to  emotions,  pas- 
sions, and  prejudices.  And  a  conscienceless  party  orator  or  propa- 
gandist can  command  far  more  votes  than  the  most  highly  trained  and 
public-spirited  expert  on  government  affairs.  Unless  vocational  repre- 
sentation can  remedy  the  evils  of  representative  government  under  the 
party  system,  the  world  is  likely  to  head  rapidly  for  dictatorship,  under 
which  there  is  only  one  party  and  no  real  party  government. 

Democracy  is  now  in  a  most  critical  situation.  It  has  already,  at  least 
temporarily,  disappeared  from  the  majority  of  the  countries  of  the  world. 


370       APPRAISING  OUR   INSTITUTIONAL  CRISIS 

It  worked  very  well  in  small  communities  in  a  simple  agricultural  society. 
But  it  has  proved  incompetent  and  wasteful  in  large  industrialized  states. 
It  has  been  able  to  persist  in  the  United  States  mainly  because  we  have 
been  so  big  and  rich  that  we  could  withstand,  for  a  time,  an  unusual 
amount  of  graft,  corruption,  and  incompetence.  If  there  is  to  be  any  hope 
of  democracy  surviving  in  large  states,  we  must  introduce  drastic  reforms. 
We  must  extend  the  civil  service  to  cover  both  legislative  and  judicial  de- 
partments, as  well  as  the  administrative  side  of  government.  Only  com- 
petent and  trained  persons  should  be  allowed  to  be  candidates  for  any 
public  office.  Some  voting  system  must  be  developed  which  will  accord 
mpre  voting  power  to  an  able  and  educated  person  than  can  be  claimed 
by  an  illiterate  moron.  Vocational  and  proportional  representation  must 
bo  introduced  to  provide  just  and  efficient  representative  government. 
Unless  such  reforms  are  introduced,  there  is  little  prospect  that  the  demo- 
cratic era  will  survive  the  present  generation. 

Law  and  legal  practices  are  among  the  most  important  institutions  of 
society,  and  they  illustrate  to  a  rather  unusual  degree  the  fact  of  cultural 
lag.  Only  orthodox  religion  and  conventional  morality  are  as  far  out 
pf  line  with  the  realities  of  contemporary  life  as  is  the  law.  In  many 
ways,  ours  is  a  law-controlled,  if  not  a  law-made,  civilization.  The  law- 
yers occupy  a  place  in  contemporary  life  comparable  to  that  held  by  the 
medicine  men  in  primitive  society  and  by  the  theologians  in  the  Middle 
Ageg.  And  the  law,  today,  has  as  little  relation  to  either  fact  or  justice 
as  magic  in  the  stone  age  or  theology  in  the  medieval  period. 
.  In  the  first  place,  we  are  swamped  with  an  excess  of  overcomplicated 
Jaws.  There  are  a  vast  number  of  laws  that  grew  out  of  earlier  condi- 
tions of  society  and  have  little  relation  to  contemporary  conditions. 
Then,  our  legislatures  have  passed  swarms  of  laws,  as  a  result  of  the 
growing  tendency  of  government  to  interfere  in  all  phases  of  modern  life 
and  to  regulate  even  the  details  of  personal  life.  The  laws  themselves 
are  further  complicated  by  a  vast  body  of  technical  and  often  contra- 
dictory judicial  decisions  and  legal  opinions.  Not  even  the  most  learned 
lawyer  can  be  familiar  with  more  than  a  small  portion  of  extant  law.  If 
he  is  honest  and  clear-sighted,  he  usually  confesses  that  the  law  which  he 
does  know  has  little  bearing  upon  the  facts  of  life  which  the  law  is  sup- 
posed to  regulate.  Legal  language  is  an  archaic  and  barbarous  collec- 
tion of  technical  jargon,  which  is  far  more  helpful  to  the  lawyers  in  con- 
cealing their  ignorance  than  it  is  to  the  cause  of  promoting  justice  or 
handling  contemporary  realities.  Yet,  this  jargon  has  taken  on  a  quasi- 
sanctified  character  and  the  most  respected  lawyer  is  the  one  who  is 
most  facile  in  its  manipulation.  The  average  lawyer  has  far  more  respect 
for  the  technicalities  of  legal  procedure  than  he  has  for  the  administration 
pf  justice.  The  rules  of  legal  evidence  and  the  methods  of  legal  procedure 
are  almost  the  reverse  of  the  rules  followed  in  presenting  scientific  evi-^ 
dence  to  establish  facts. 

In  the  execution  of  law  today,  the  whole  set-up  favors  the  rich,  at  the 
gxpense  of  the  poor.    Lawyers  and  judges  are  usually  prejudiced  in  favor 


APPRAISING  OUR   INSTITUTIONAL  CRISIS       871 

of  the  vested  interests  of  society,  and  only  the  wealthy  can  normally 
secure  legal  aid  competent  to  cope  with  the  technicalities  of  law  or  meet 
the  expense  of  legal  procedure.  The  technicalities  and  delays  in  the  law 
almost  always  operate  in  the  favor  of  the  wealthy.  The  poor  man  has 
great  difficulty  in  securing  justice  Jin  criminal  procedure  and  he  is  usually 
at  even  more  of  a  disadvantage  in  civil  cases.  The  main  exception  is 
where  juries  may,  at  times,  be  partial  to  poor  persons  who  are  parties  to 
negligence  cases.  But  even  here  the  advantage  usually  lies  with  the 
party  who  can  afford  to  hire  a  lawyer  who  is  competent  in  "tear- jerking" 
antics  before  a  jury. 

It  has  been  said  that  legal  practice  today,  outside  of  criminal  law,  falls 
into  the  big  and  the  little  legal  racket.  The  big  legal  racket  is  the  prac- 
tice of  corporation  law,  in  which  the  most  expensive  counsel  available 
tell  corporations  how  they  may  evade  the  laws  through  which  the  gov- 
ernment has  endeavored  to  control  their  operations  in  the  interest  of 
society.  The  main  instrument  used  has  been  constitutional  law,  because 
of  the  solicitude  shown  by  constitutions  and  courts  for  the  sanctity  of 
property  and  property  rights.  We  have  already  seen  how  the  remarkable 
extension  of  property  rights  to  cover  nearly  all  business  practices,  espe- 
cially corporate  practices,  has  made  it  possible  for  great  corporations  to 
protect  themselves  through  appeals  to  constitutional  law. 

The  little  legal  racket  encompasses  all  the  frantic  efforts  of  the  rank- 
and-file  lawyers  to  get  enough  legal  business  to  make  a  living.  Their 
chief  salvation  lies  in  negligence  cases.  The  coming  of  the  automobile 
has  been  a  godsend  in  this  respect.  A  goodly  portion  of  the  cases  in  our 
courts  today  arise  out  of  automobile  accidents  and  the  injuries,  real  or 
alleged,,  which  come  therefrom.  A  considerable  racket  has  literally  de- 
veloped out  of  purely  faked  negligence  cases,  where  no  accident  at  all  has 
taken  place.  It  has  often  been  asserted  by  competent  lawyers  that,  in 
their  mad  search  for  business,  more  litigation  is  created  by  lawyers  than 
arises  from  any  other  single  source. 

Our  criminal  law,  while  superficially  sophisticated  and  impressively 
complicated,  actually  gets  little  closer  to  the  truth  and  justice  than  the 
criminal  procedure  of  primitive  peoples.  The  jury  trial,  for  example,  is 
little  more  scientific  or  reliable  than  the  ancient  ordeal  or  trial  by  battle* 
Even  when  justice  is  actually  done  in  a  courtroom,  the  result  may  be  for- 
feited through  setting  aside  a  verdict  on  the  basis  of  hair-splitting  tech- 
nicalities. 

Through  obstructing  justice  and  frustrating  normal  progress,  the  law 
not  only  injures  society,  but  also  places  the  law  itself  in  jeopardy.  If 
progress  is  so  delayed  as  to  bring  revolution  and  dictatorship,  conven- 
tional law  and  legal  procedure  are  invariably  suppressed  and  the  decrees 
of  the  dictator  are  substituted  therefor.  Hence,  the  lawyers  should  take 
warning  and  clean  house  while  the  opportunity  still  remains  for  them  to 
do  so  in  the  few  democracies  that  are  left. 

One  of  the  most  novel  and  up-to-date  aspects  of  our  institutional  life 
are  those  techniques  associated  with  contemporary  transportation  and 


872       APPRAISING  OUR   INSTITUTIONAL  CRISIS 

the  communication  of  information.  Most  of  these  are  highly  novel,  a 
product  of  the  last  half-century  or  so.  To  a  considerable  extent,  they 
have  been  created  on  the  basis  of  the  remarkable  discoveries  in  electro- 
mechanics.  Streamlined  trains  on  railroads,  automobile  buses,  airplanes, 
and  transoceanic  clippers  have  facilitated  and  quickened  transportation. 
They  have  also  extended  and  speeded  up  the  postal  service.  The  tele- 
phone, telegraph,  wireless  telegraphy,  the  radio,  the  movies  and  television, 
and  the  press  have  given  us  a  new  and  impressive  equipment  for  the  trans- 
mission of  information.  Together  these  have  all  but  conquered  time  and 
space,  so  far  as  travel  and  communication  are  concerned. 

The  fact  that  the  agencies  of  transportation  and  communication  have 
been  thoroughly  commercialized  has  greatly  extended  their  service  to  our 
material  life.  Otherwise,  they  would  have  remained  chiefly  scientific 
curiosities.  But  we  have  paid  a  price  for  this  commercialization.  The 
fact  th&t  they  have  been  brought  under  the  control  of  business  has  in- 
evitably meant  that  they  reflect  conventional  business  ideals  and  prej- 
udices. This  becomes  of  practical  significance  chiefly  in  connection  with 
the  press,  radio,  and  the  movies.  Our  railroads  and  airplanes  carry 
radicals  as  well  as  conservatives,  provided  the  radicals  can  raise  the 
money  to  pay  their  fares  and  behave  themselves  while  on  board.  But 
the  press,  radio,  and  the  movies  reveal  no  such  hospitality  to  progressives, 
to  say  nothing  of  radicals.  With  only  sufficient  exceptions  to  prove  the 
rule,  their  intellectual  message  reflects  the  economic  interests  which  have 
built  them  up  and  receive  the  revenue  that  they  produce. 

Thus  even  the  agencies  of  communication  show  the  incongruities  grow- 
ing out  of  the  gulf  between  science  and  institutions.  Perhaps  the  most 
advanced  and  impressive  phases  of  applied  science,  they  become  means 
of  disseminating  ancient  ideas  and  outworn  institutions.  Even  astrology 
broadcasts'  have  proved  popular.  As  Clifford  Kirkpatrick  observes:  "It 
is  amazing  that  primitive  conceptions  of  the  universe,  developed  some 
three  thousand  years  ago  in  Arabia,  are  spoken  with  greater  conviction 
than  ever  into  a  tiny  microphone  and  sent  winging  their  way  into  thou- 
sands of  homes." 

Outside  the  dictatorships  and  war-regimented  democracies,  most  of 
the  censorship  of  the  agencies  of  communication  is  still  voluntary,  though 
often  very  extensive.  Censorship  exists  mainly  for  two  purposes:  (1)  to 
exclude  progressive  and  radical  notions  which  threaten  the  existing  social 
order  and .  (2)  to  exclude  material,  whether  radical  or  not,  that  might 
offend  the  prejudices  of  the  mass  of  newspaper  readers,  movie  fans,  and 
radio  listeners.  The  result  is  inevitably  the  intellectual  debasement  of 
the  product,  as  well  as  the  promotion  of  conservative  propaganda.  Be- 
cause the  liberal  and  radical  attitudes  are  severely  curtailed  in  the  press, 
movies  and  radio  broadcasts,  our  agencies  of  communications  can  be 
labeled  anti-democratic,  even  though  these  agencies  may  fervently  bally- 
hoo a  desperate  world  war  in  behalf  of  democracy. 

In  their  general  cultural  effects,  we  may  readily  concede  that  modern 
agencies  of  communication  have  greatly  enriched  the  material  available 


APPRAISING  OUR   INSTITUTIONAL  CRISIS       873 

to  the  common  man.  But  the  efforts  to  get  mass  appeal,  and  thereby 
realize  the  maximum  profits,  have  suppressed  artistic  originality  and  any 
spirit  of  intellectual  adventure. 

The  lesson  of  revolution  and  dictatorship  abroad  should  be  clear  enough 
to  those  who  control  our  agencies  of  communication  so  that  they  can  liter- 
ally read  it  while  running.  If  essential  reforms  are  delayed  to  the  point 
where  revolution  and  dictatorship  are  inevitable,  the  press,  movies,  and 
the  radio  are  taken  over  by  the  state  and  become  obedient  agents  of  dic- 
tatorial propaganda.  Insofar  as  censorship  and  other  anti-progressive 
policies  on  the  part  of  these  agents  of  communication  weaken  and  destroy 
democracy,  their  owners  and  custodians  are  only  digging  their  own  eco- 
nomic graves.  If  they  are  wise  they  will  mend  their  ways  before  it  is 
too  late. 

Despite  the  great  advances  in  knowledge  and  experience  in  the  twen- 
tieth century,  our  culture  is  still  weighed  down  with  prejudices  which 
handicap  democracy,  threaten  liberty,  and  lessen  the  desirable  spirit  of 
tolerance.  The  main  prejudices  of  our  time  are  economic,  in  the  same 
way  that  they  were  religious  and  theological  in  the  Middle  Ages  and 
early  modern  times.  They  grow  chiefly  out  of  the  efforts  to  defend  and 
perpetuate  the  capitalistic  system  and  private  property.  The  economic 
prejudice,  which  arises  in  this  fashion,  colors  most  of  the  prejudices  ex- 
hibited in  other  fields,  like  politics,  law,  and  the  propaganda  executed  by 
the  agencies  of  communication.  But  even  radical  countries  like  Russia 
have  not  been  able  to  free  themselves  from  economic  prejudices  which, 
in  such  countries,  take  the  form  of  anti-capitalism.  In  some  dictatorial 
> countries  in  Europe  we  have  witnessed,  in  recent  years,  an  amazing  devel- 
opment of  racial  prejudices  which  are  likely  to  get  worse  before  they 
are  subdued. 

The  social  conflicts  of  our  day,  together  with  the  remarkable  develop- 
ment of  new  agencies  of  communication,  have  greatly  encouraged  land 
facilitated  the  growth  of  propaganda.  This  now  dominates  every  field 
of  communication.  Owing  to  the  fact  that  the  agencies  of  communication 
are  overwhelmingly  in  the  hands  of  the  wealthy,  present-day  propaganda 
favors  the  classes  rather  than  the  masses.  As  we  have  just  pointed  out, 
this  makes  contemporary  propaganda  overwhelmingly  anti-democratic. 
Since  most  of  the  information  of  the  common  man  comes  from  this  propa- 
ganda, it  is  becoming  ever  more  difficult  for  the  mass  of  mankind  to  par- 
ticipate intelligently  in  public  life  and  democratic  government. 

The  chief  protective  device  against  misleading  propaganda  is  a  wide- 
spread knowledge  of  the  devices  of  propaganda.  But  it  is  difficult  to 
spread  any  such  knowledge  effectively  because  the  agencies  that  would 
have  to  be  used  are  all  controlled  by  the  propaganda  mongers.  Public 
education  should  have  as  one  of  its  main  objects  the  exposure  of  propa- 
ganda and  propaganda  agencies.  But  education  itself  still  remains 
chiefly  under  the  control  of  the  same  social  classes  and  forces  which 
disseminate  reactionary  propaganda  through  our  agencies  of  communi- 
cation. Such  valuable  organizations  as  the  Institute  for  Propaganda 


874       APPRAISING  OUR   INSTITUTIONAL  CRISIS 

Analysis  are  nearly  helpless  in  the  face  of  the  avalanche  of  propaganda 
which  overwhelms  the  man  on  the  street. 

Censorship  threatens  the  free  play  of  ideas  which  is  essential  to  democ- 
racy and  social  progress.  Censorship  which  grows  out  of  puritanical 
prejudices  is  annoying  and  is  disastrous  to  both  art  and  literature.  But 
it  is  less  menacing  than  the  censorship  produced  by  reactionary  economic 
forces.  This  latter  type  of  censorship  is  what  obstructs  the  most  essen- 
tial reforms  and  heads  us  towards  economic  collapse,  revolution,  dictator- 
ship, and  collectivism.  The  most  extreme  form  of  censorship  is  produced 
by  war.  Now  that  the  entire  planet  is  being  involved  in  war,  we 
face  the  gloomy  prospect  of  nearly  complete  global  censorship.  It  is 
doubtful  whether  even  the  return  of  peace  will  put  an  end  to  a  censorship 
which  has  been  so  extreme  and  become  so  habitual. 

We,  in  this  country,  should  learn  the  lessons  of  the  danger  of  censorship 
from  the  experience  with  it  overseas.  If  we  persist  in  censorship  to  such 
an  extent  that  we  prevent  reforms  under  democratic  auspices,  we  shall 
turn  the  country  over  to  a  dictatorship  which  will  censor  ideas  as  ruth- 
lessly as  any  in  existence  in  the  Old  World. 

The  human  family  is  the  most  basic,  most  ancient,  and  most  persistent 
of  our  institutions.  The  authoritarian  rural  family,  which  has  dominated 
the  social  scene  in  the  West  since  the  fall  of  the  Roman  Empire,  is  now 
being  undermined.  There  are  a  number  of  reasons  for  this,  the  most 
important  of  which  are  economic.  The  rise  of  industrialism  and  the 
growth  of  city  life  have  produced  a  social  situation  vastly  different  from 
the  conditions  of  rural  life  which  favored  and  supported  the  old  type  of 
family.  The  city  home  is  no  longer  so  vital  a  social  cell  as  was  the  rural1 
home.  Children  are  no  more  so  great  an  asset  as  they  were  on  the  farm. 
Social  and  recreational  interests  no  longer  center  in  the  home.  Women 
can  freely  enter  industry  and  the  professions  and  are  not  as  dependent 
upon  a  male  partner  for  their  support.  Intellectual  factors  also  play 
their  part  in  undermining  the  family,  most  notably  in  the  breakdown  of 
conventional  morality  and  the  growth  of  sexual  enlightenment. 

As  the  result  of  these  new  factors  and  forces,  the  old  type  of  family 
life  is  becoming  progressively  more  unstable.  In  the  United  States,  at 
bhe  present  time,  about  one  marriage  in  every  six  ends  in  divorce. 
However,  though  the  family  may  be  unstable,  there  is  no  prospect  that 
marriage  will  disappear.  Indeed,  the  marriage  rate  is  increasing,  though 
not  so  rapidly  as  the  divorce  rate. 

There  is  every  probability  that  the  family  can  adjust  itself  to  the  new 
conditions  of  modern  life.  We  are  fairly  safe  in  predicting  that,  in  the 
new  form  of  family  which  will  emerge,  the  mother  will  be  more  important 
than  she  was  in  the  period  of  the  authoritarian  rural  family.  It  is  also 
fairly  certain  that  the  state  will  take  over  many  responsibilities  which 
have  been  executed  by  the  family. 

A  number  of  reforms  may  be  suggested  as  means  of  checking  the  grow- 
ing instability  of  the  family.  Economic  reforms,  which  will  produce  an 
adequate  income  and  economic  security,  will  do  much  to  give  cohesive* 


APPRAISING  OUR   INSTITUTIONAL  CRISIS       875 

ness  to  family  life.  The  growth  of  sex  education  and  adjustment  will 
eliminate  many  of  the  causes  of  divorce.  Social  workers  and  psychia- 
trists can  contribute  much  to  solving  problems  of  marital  discord. 

None  of  our  institutions  finds  itself  in  a  more  critical  situation  than 
does  organized  religion.  Religion  has,  thus  far,  represented  man's  re- 
action to  a  hypothetical  supernatural  world.  The  decline  of  belief  in 
supernaturalism  has  inevitably  undermined  religion.  Earlier  crises  in 
religion  have  not  been  based  upon  any  scientific  assault  upon  super- 
naturalism.  They  have  represented  nothing  more  than  the  substitution 
of  one  form  of  supernaturalism  for  another.  It  is  the  current  scientific 
questioning  of  the  whole  supernatural  hypothesis  which  renders  the  re- 
ligious revolution  of  our  day  so  unique  and  so  devastating. 

The  liberal  friends  of  religion  have  endeavored  to  readjust  religion  to 
the  newer  outlook  and  have  sought  to  establish  religion  on  a  secular  and 
human  basis.  They  have  endeavored  to  make  religion  serve  man  rather 
than  to  execute  the  supposed  will  of  the  gods.  There  is  little  doubt  that 
an  enlightened  secular  religion,  supporting  social  justice  and  world  peace, 
could  render  many  important  services  to  humanity.  But  it  is  very 
difficult  to  get  an  adequate  mass  following  for  a  secular  religion,  divorced 
from  any  fear  of  a  supernatural  world  or  of  the  tortures  of  hellfire.  Re- 
ligious scepticism  and  indifference  in  our  day  unusally  lead  to  an  aban- 
donment of  all  forms  of  religious  interests. 

Far  more  menacing  to  religion  today  than  scientific  scrutiny  or  scepti- 
cal assault  is  the  intervention  of  the  new  secular  interests  which  tend  to 
crowd  out  the  attention  formerly  given  to  religion.  The  automobile,  the 
movies,  the  radio,  golf,  commercialized  sports,  and  the  like,  have  done 
more  to  produce  religious  indifference  among  the  masses  than  all  the 
results  of  scientific  research  and  all  the  attacks  of  sceptics. 

Many  believe  that  a  substitute  for  the  old  supernatural  religion  will  be 
found  in  new  economic  and  political  cults.  It  is  readily  apparent  that 
Bolshevism  in  Russia  and  Fascism  in  Germany  and  Italy  have  many 
affinities  with  the  older  religious  emotions  and  practices.  Service  clubs 
have  taken  on  a  quasi-religious  cast  in  this  country. 

Since  the  older  morality  is  directly  linked  with  supernatural  religion, 
the  decline  of  the  latter  has  naturally  undermined  the  conventional  moral 
codes  which  rested  upon  a  supernatural  basis.  It  is  now  difficult  to  pro- 
mote good  behavior  solely  through  an  appeal  to  the  fear  of  the  gods  or 
the  penalty  of  damnation  in  the  world-to-come.  But  the  complicated 
nature  of  contemporary  life  creates  a  greater  need  than  ever  for  a  sound 
moral  code.  It  is  evident  to  all  enlightened  students  of  ethics  that  such 
a  moral  code  must  be  erected  on  secular  foundations.  It  must  grow  out 
of  prolonged  and  profound  research  into  the  nature  of  man  and  his 
social  obligations.  The  current  mental  hygiene  program  is  generally 
believed  to  represent  the  best  substitute  at  hand  for  the  old  supernatural 
morality,  and  to  point  the  way  to  the  type  of  studies  and  attitudes  upon 
which  we  must  rely  for  the  creation  of  an  adequate  code  of  secular 
morality. 


876       APPRAISING  OUR   INSTITUTIONAL  CRISIS 

Education  offers  the  only  possibility  of  bringing  about  social  change 
in  orderly  fashion  without  running  the  risk  of  violence  and  revolution. 
Unfortunately,  education  today  is  not  adapted  to  execute  this  responsi- 
bility. We  have  made  education  available  for  the  masses,  but  we  have 
not  adapted  the  content  of  education  to  the  realities  of  modern  life.  We 
go  on  with  a  curriculum  which  was  designed  to  train  children  in  the 
declining  days  of  feudalism.  We  seem  to  think  that  such  subject  matter 
will  prepare  people  to  run  a  twentieth-century  democracy.  We  are 
shocked  when  it  fails  to  do  so. 

Our  elementary  and  grammar  schools  are  clogged  with  archaic  material 
and  make  too  little  allowance  for  mental  differences  in  children.  Our 
high  schools  train  pupils  to  enter  college  rather  than  to  enter  life.  Our 
colleges  and  universities  are  hampered  by  the  fact  that  we  have  the  same 
institutions  and  instruction  for  the  mass  of  students,  who  go  to  college  as 
a  matter  of  fad  and  fashion,  and  for  the  able  and  serious  few  who  go  to 
college  to  get  an  education. 

Education  cannot  guide  social  change  until  we  give  far  more  attention 
to  the  social  studies  and  teach  them  much  more  realistically.  To  do  so 
safely,  teachers  will  be  compelled  to  organize  to  assure  stability  of  tenure. 
Owing  to  the  seriousness  of  the  social  crisis  which  is  upon  us,  many  believe 
that  the  only  hope  of  using  education  to  direct  social  change  lies  in  an 
enormous  extension  of  adult  education.  Some  feeble  steps  are  being 
taken  to  promote  this  movement. 

Our  new  empire  of  machines  has,  for  the  first  time,  now  made  possible 
leisure  and  security.  If  we  use  these  machines  wisely  and  efficiently  in 
the  service  of  society,  we  shall  be  able  to  get  on  what  Plato  described  as 
the  supra-pig  level  of  culture  and  to  create  a  truly  human  civilization. 

One  of  the  most  important  fields  of  social  science  in  the  future  must  be 
that  devoted  to  a  scientific  study  of  leisure.  We  must  know  the  full  im- 
plications of  leisure  and  how  to  cultivate  it  most  effectively  for  the  good 
of  the  human  race.  Otherwise,  our  increased  leisure  may  only  result  in 
degeneracy  and  confusion. 

An  important  phase  of  leisure-time  activity  is  play  or  recreation.  Play 
has  become  enormously  diversified  and  extremely  popular.  As  the  result 
of  various  social  agencies,  it  is  now  more  efficiently  administered  and 
supervised.  But,  even  yet,  recreational  facilities  are  miserably  inade- 
quate for  those  who  dwell  in  city  slums  and  in  rural  regions.  Under  the 
influence  of  the  profit  sysem,  play  has  been  thoroughly  commercialized;  it 
constitutes  a  phase  of  American  big  business.  The  invention  and  ex- 
ploitation of  the  automobile  has  been  the  most  important  factor  in  the 
extension  of  recreation  in  recent  times. 

If  we  cultivate  leisure  in  a  civilized  fashion,  we  must  make  far  greater 
provision  for  the  popular  appreciation  of  art  and  participation  in  it.  Art 
must  enter  definitely  into  the  life  of  the  whole  people.  It  must  no  longer 
remain  an  exhibition  for  the  favored  few.  The  movies  and  the  radio  have 
done  much  of  late  to  popularize  interest  in  the  arts,  especially  music. 

Especially  important  and  promising  has  been  the  government  support 


APPRAISING  OUR   INSTITUTIONAL  CRISIS       877 

of  art  in  revolutionary  countries  and  in  the  United  States  under  the 
Roosevelt  administration.  The  latter  has  done  more  than  anything  else 
to  bring  art  directly  to  the  people  of  our  country.  But  the  expenditures 
for  art  have  been  the  merest  triviality  compared  with  what  will  be  neces- 
sary to  make  art  a  vital  factor  in  modern  life. 

We  may  conclude  with  a  theme  that  has  oft  been  repeated  in  this 
book;  namely,  that  our  social  institutions  are  in  a  most  critical  period, 
owing  to  the  great  gulf  between  them  and  our  material  culture.  Until  we 
close  this  gulf  by  bringing  our  institutions  up  to  date,  there  will  be  no 
hope  of  solving  our  social  problems.  Indeed,  our  whole  civilization  will 
remain  in  grave  jeopardy.  The  present  total  and  global  war  has  already 
placed  it  in  a  state  of  unprecedented  fluidity  and  uncertainty.  We  may 
well  close  with  a  recent  pronouncement  of  the  British  Labor  Party: 

The  Labour  Party  asks  that  we  register  now,  as  a  nation,  our  recognition 
that  this  war  has  already,  socially  and  economically,  effected  a  revolution  in  the 
world  as  vast,  in  its  ultimate  implications,  as  that  which  marked  the  replacement 
of  Feudalism  by  Capitalism.  All  over  the  world,  the  evidence  is  abundant  that 
this  revolution  has  deeply  affected  men's  minds;  our  central  problem  is  to  dis- 
cover its  Appropriate  institutions,  above  all,  if  we  can,  to  discover  them  by 
consent. 


Selected  References 


Selected  References 


*  Note :  Publisher  and  date  are  given  only  in  the  first  listing  of  any  book. 

CHAPTER  1 

Atteberry,  G.  C.,  Auble,  J.  L.,  and  Hunt,  E.  F.,  Introduction  to  Social  Science, 
2  vols.,  Macmillan,  1941. 

Ballard,  L.  V.,  Social  Institutions,  Appleton-Century,  1936. 

Balz,  A.  G.  A.,  The  Basis  of  Social  Theory,  Knopf,  1924. 

Barnes,  H.  E.,  An  Economic  History  of  the  Western  World,  Harcourt,  Brace, 
1938. 

,  History  of  Western  Civilization,  2  Vols.,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1935. 

/  Sociology  and  Political  Theory,  Knopf,  1924. 

,  The  Twilight  of  Christianity,  Vanguard,  1929. 

Boodin,  J.  E.,  The  Social  Mind,  Macmillan,  1939. 

Bossard,  J.  H.  S.,  cd.,  Man  and  His  World,  Harper,  1932. 

Bristol,  L.  M.,  Social  Adaptation,  Harvard  University  Press,  1915. 

Burgess,  E.  W.,  ed.,  Personality  and  the  Social  Group,  University  of  Chicago 
Press,  1929. 

Chapin,  F.  S.,  Cultural  Change,  Appleton-Century,  1928. 

Coker,  F.  S.,  Organismic  Theories  of  the  State,  Columbia  University  Press,  1910. 

Coolcy,  C.  H.,  Human  Nature  and  the  Social  Order,  Scribner,  1902. 

: ,  Social  Organization,  Scribner,  1909. 

,  Social  Process,  Scribner,  1918. 

Dixon,  R.  B.,  The  Building  of  Cultures,  Scribner,  1928. 

Dorsey,  J.  M.,  The  Foundations  of  Human  Nature,  Longmans,  1935. 

Durkheim,  Emile,  The  Division  of  Labor  in  Society  (translated  by  George  Simp- 
son), Macmillan,  1933. 

Eldridge,  Seba,  Political  Action,  Lippincott,  1924. 

Ellwood,  C.  A.,  Sociology  in  Its  Psychological  Aspects,  Appleton-Century,  1914. 

,  The  Psychology  of  Human  Society,  Appleton-Century,  1925. 

Faris,  Ellsworth,  The  Nature  of  Human  Nature,  McGraw-Hill,  1937. 

Folsom,  J.  K.,  Culture  and  Social  Progress,  Longmans,  1928. 

Gesell,  Arnold,  Wolfchild  and  Human  Child,  Harper,  1941. 

Giddings,  F.  H.,  The  Elements  of  Sociology,  Macmillan,  1898. 

Groves,  E.  R.,  Personality  and  Social  Adjustment,  Longmans,  1923. 

,  An  Introduction  to  Sociology,  Longmans,  1928. 

Hankins,  F.  H.,  The  Racial  Basis  of  Civilization,  Knopf,  1926. 

Hart,  Hornell,  The  Science  of  Social  Relations,  Holt,  1927. 

Hertzler,  J.  0.,  Social  Institutions,  McGraw-Hill,  1929. 

Hetherington,  H.  J.  W.,  and  Muirhead,  J.  H.,  Social  Purpose,  Allen  &  Unwin, 
1918. 

Hobhouse,  L.  T.,  Social  Development,  Holt,  1924. 

,  Social  Evolution  and  Political  Theory,  Columbia  University  Press, 

1913. 

881 


882  SELECTED  REFERENCES 

Jenks,  Edward,  The  State  and  the  Nation,  Button,  1919. 

Keller,  A.  G.,  Man's  Rough  Road,  Macmillan,  1932. 

Kropotkin,  Peter,  Mutual  Aid:  A  Factor  of  Evolution,  Knopf,  1925. 

Lurnley,  F.  E.,  Means  of  Social  Control,  Appleton-Century,  1925. 

Maclver,  R.  M.,  Society:  Its  Structure  and  Changes,  Farrar  &  Rinehart,  1936. 

,  Community:  A  Sociological  Study,  Macmillan,  1917. 

Mackenzie,  J.  S.,  Introduction  to  Social  Philosophy,  Glasgow,  1895. 
Martin,  E.  D.,  The  Behavior  of  Crowds,  Harper,  1920. 
Mecklin,  J.  M.,  Introduction  to  Social  Ethics^  Harcourt,  Brace,  1920. 
Monroe,  Paul,  A  Textbook  in  the  History  of  Education,  Macmillan,  1912. 
Miiller-Lyer,  Franz,  The  History  of  Social  Development,  Knopf,  1921. 
Ogburn,  W.  F.,  and  Nimkoff,  M.  F.,  Sociology,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1940. 
Panunzio,  Constantino,  The  Major  Social  Institutions,  Macmillan,  1939. 
Ricgel,  R.  E.,  ed.,  Introduction  to  the  Social  Sciences,  2  Vols.,  Appleton-Century, 

1941. 

Robinson,  T.  H.,  et  al.,  Men,  Groups  and  the  Community,  Harper,  1940. 
Ross,  E.  A.,  Social  Control,  Macmillan,  1901. 

,  Social  Psychology,  Macmillan,  1908. 

,  Principles  of  Sociology,  Appleton-Century,  1920. 

Sait,  E.  M.,  Political  Institutions,  Appleton-Century,  1938. 

Schmidt,  E.  P.,  ed.,  Man  and  Society,  Prentice-Hall,  1938. 

Storck,  John,  Man  and  Civilization,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1927. 

Thomas,  Franklin,  The  Environmental  Basis  of  Society,  Appleton-Century,  1925. 

Zanc,  J.  M.,  The  Story  of  Law,  Ives,  Washburn,  1927. 

Zimmermann,  E.  W.,  World  Resources  and  Industries,  Harper,  1933. 


CHAPTER  2 

Allport,  F.  H.,  Institutional  Behavior,  Duke  University  Press,  1933. 

Ballard,  Social  Institutions. 

Jiarnes,  H.  E.,  History  of  Western  Civilization. 

Barnes,  H.  E.,  and  Becker,  Howard,  Social  Thought  from  Lore  to  Science,  2  Vols.* 

Heath,  1938. 

Campbell,  C.  M.,  Human  Personality  and  the  Environment,  Macmillan,  1934. 
Chapin,  Cultural  Change. 

- ~,  Contemporary  American  Institutions,  Harper,  1935. 

Cole,  G.  D.  H.,  Social  Theory,  Stokes,  1920. 

Cooley,  Social  Organization. 

Dampier-Whetham,  W.  C.  D.,  A  History  of  Science,  Macmillan,  1930. 

Davie,  M.  R.,  The  Evolution  of  War,  Yale  University  Press,  1929. 

Dorsey,  The  Foundations  of  Human  Nature. 

Dunlap,  0.  E.,  The  Story  of  Radio,  Dial  Press,  1935. 

Edman,  Irwin,  Human  Traits,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1920. 

Ellwood,  C.  A.,  Cultural  Evolution,  Appleton-Century,  1927. 

Faris,  The  Nature  of  Human  Nature. 

Fosdick,  R.  B.,  The  Old  Savage  in  the  New  Civilization,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1929. 

Gardner,  Helen,  Art  through  the  Ages,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1926. 

Goldenweiser,  Alexander,  Robots  or  Gods,  Knopf,  1931. 

Gore,  Charles,  ed.,  Property:  Its  Rights  and  Duties,  Macmillan,  1922. 

Haddon,  A.  C.,  Evolution  in  Art,  Scott,  1895. 

Hamilton,  Walton,  "Institutions,"  Encyclopaedia  of  the  Social  Sciences. 


SELECTED   REFERENCES  883 

Hertzler,  Social  Institutions. 

Hibben,  Thomas,  The  Sons  of  Vulcan,  Lippincott,  1940. 

Jenks,  The  State  and  the  Nation. 

Jennings,  H.  S.,  The  Biological  Basis  of  Human  Nature,  Norton,  1930. 

Judd,  C.  H.,  The  Psychology  of  Social  Institutions,  Macmillan,  1926. 

Keller,  A.  G.,  Societal  Evolution,  Macmillan,  1931. 

,  Man's  Rough  Road. 

Laguna,  T.  de,  The  Factors  of  Social  Evolution,  Crofts,  1926. 

Lang,  P.  H.,  Music  in  Western  Civilization,  Norton,  1941. 

Lee,  Joseph,  Play  in  Education,  Macmillan,  1915. 

Lowie,  R.  H.,  Primitive  Society,  Boni  &  Liveright,  1920. 

Marshall,  L.  C.,  The  Story  of  Human  Progress,  Macmillan,  1925. 

McMurtie,  D.  C.,  The  Book,  Covici-Friede,  1937. 

Monroe,  Textbook  in  the  History  of  Education. 

Montross,  Lynn,  War  through  the  Ages,  Harper,  1940. 

Moore,  G.  F.,  A  History  of  Religion,  2  Vols.,  Scribner,  1919. 

Morgan,  L.  H.,  Ancient  Society,  Holt,  1877. 

Miiller-Lyer,  History  of  Social  Development. 

Mumford,  Lewis,  Technics  and  Civilization,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1934. 

Nef,  Karl,  An  Outline  of  the  History  of  Music,  Columbia  University  Press,  1935. 

Ogden,  C.  K.,  The  Meaning  of  Psychology,  Harper,  1926. 

Panunzio,  Major  Social  Institutions. 

Robinson,  J.  H.,  The  Human  Comedy  y  Harper,  1937. 

Robinson,  Victor,  The  Story  of  Medicine,  Boni,  1931. 

Rugg,  Harold,  The  Great  Technology,  Day,  1933. 

Schoen,  Max,  Human  Nature,  Harper,  1931. 

Schwesinger,  G.  C.,  Heredity  and  Environment,  Macmillan,  1933. 

Stern,  B.  J.,  Lewis  Henry  Morgan:  Social  Evolutionist,  University  of  Chicago 

Press,  1931. 

Strecher,  E.  A.,  and  Appel,  K.  E.,  Discovering  Ourselves,  Macmillan,  1931. 
Sumner,  W.  G.,  Folkways,  Ginn,  1907. 

Sumner  and  Keller,  The  Science  of  Society,  4  Vols.,  Yale  University  Press,  1927. 
Tansley,  A.  G.,  The  New  Psychology,  Dodd,  Mead,  1920. 
Thomas,  The  Environmental  Basis  of  Society. 

Thorndike,  E.  L.,  Human  Nature  and  the  Social  Order,  Macmillan,  1940. 
Todd,  A.  J.,  Theories  of  Social  Progress,  Macmillan,  1918. 
Vagts,  Alfred,  The  History  of  Militarism,  Norton,  1937. 
Warden,  C.  J.,  The  Evolution  of  Human  Behavior,  Macmillan,  1932. 
Webster,  H.  H.,  Travel  by  Air,  Land  and  Sea,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1933. 
Wells,  F.  L.,  Pleasure  and  Behavior,  Appleton-Century,  1924. 
Willson,  Beckles,  The  Story  of  Rapid  Transit,  Appleton-Century,  1903. 
Winston,  Sanford,  Culture  and  Human  Behavior,  Ronald  Press,  1933. 
Woodworth,  R.  S.,  Dynamic  Psychology,  Columbia  University  Press,  1918. 


CHAPTER  3 

Ballard,  Social  Institutions. 

Barnes,  H.  E.,  Can  Man  Be  Civilizedf  Brentano,  1932. 

,  Society  in  Transition,  Prentice-Hall,  1939. 

Beard,  C.  A.,  ed.,  Whither  Mankind?  Longmans,  1929. 
,  Towards  Civilization,  Longmans,  1930. 


884  SELECTED   REFERENCES 

Borsodi,  Ralph,  This  Ugly  Civilization,  Harper,  1933. 

Bossard,  J.  H.  S.,  Social  Change  and  Social  Problems,  Harper,  1938. 

Burnham,  James,  The  Managerial  Revolution,  Day,  1941. 

Case,  C.  M.,  Social  Process  and  Human  Progress,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1931; 

Chapin,  Cultural  Change. 

Chase,  Stuart,  Men  arid  Machines,  Macmillan,  1929. 

Crawford,  M.  D.  C,,  The  Conquest  of  Culture,  Greenberg,  1938. 

Dixon,  The  Building  of  Cultures. 

Edwards,  L.  P.,  The  Natural  History  of  Revolution,  University  of  Chicago  Press, 

1927. 

Ellwood,  Cultural  Evolution. 

Fodor,  M.  W.,  The  Revolution  Is  On,  Houghton  Miffllin,  1940. 
Fosdick,  The  Old  Savage  in  the  New  Civilization. 
Gilfillan,  S,  C.,  The  Sociology  of  Inventions,  Follett,  1935. 

,  Social  Effects  of  Inventions,  Government  Printing  Office,  1937. 

Goldenweiser,  Robots  or  Gods. 

Hart,  Hornell,  The  Technique  of  Social  Progress,  Holt,  1931. 

Hertzler,  Social  Institutions. 

,  Social  Progress,  Appleton-Century,  1928. 

Huberman,  Leo,  Man's  Worldly  Goods,  Harper,  1936. 
Keller,  Societal  Evolution. 

,  M an's  Rough  Road. 

Loeb,  Harold,  Life  in  a  Technocracy,  Viking  Press,  1933. 
Lynd,  R.  S.  and  H.  M.,  Middletown,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1926. 

,  Middletown  in  Transition,  1937. 

Lynd,  R.  S.,  Knowledge  for  What?  Princeton  University  Press,  1939. 
Mannheim,  Karl,  Man  and  Society  in  an  Age  of  Reconstruction,  Harcourt,  Brace, 

1940. 

Marshall,  L.  C.,  The  Story  of  Human  Progress,  Macmillan,  1925. 
Mumford,  Technics  and  Civilization. 
Ogburn,  W.  F.,  Social  Change,  Huebsch,  1922. 

,  Sociology. 

Panunzio,  The  Major  Social  Institutions. 

Randall,  J.  H.,  Our  Changing  Civilization,  Stokes,  1929. 

Robinson,  The  Human  Comedy. 

Rugg,  The  Great  Technology. 

Sims,  N.  L.,  The  Problem  of  Social  Change,  Crowell,  1939. 

Smith,  J.  R.,  The  Devil  of  the  Machine  Age,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1931. 

Sorokin,  P.  A.,  The  Sociology  of  Revolution,  Lippincott,  1925. 

Stamp,  Josiah,  The  Science  of  Social  Adjustment,  Macmillan,  1937. 

Thornton,  J.  E.,  ed.,  Science  and  Social  Change,  Brookings  Institution,  1939. 

Todd,  Theories  of  Social  Progress. 

Udmark,  J.  A.,  The  Road  We  Have  Covered,  Modern  Age,  1940. 

Wallis,  W.  D.,  Culture  and  Progress,  McGraw-Hill,  1930. 

Warden,  C.  J.,  The  Emergence  of  Human  Culture,  Macmillan,  1936. 

CHAPTER  4 

Ashley,  P.  W.  L.,  Modern  Tariff  History,  Dutton,  1920. 

Barnes,  Economic  History  of  the  Western  World. 

Baxter,  W.  J.,  Chain  Store  Distribution  and  Management,  Harper,  1931. 

Beard,  Miriam,  A  History  of  the  Business  Man,  Macmillan,  1938. 


SELECTED   REFERENCES  885 

Bent,  Silas,  Slaves  by  the  Billion,  Longmans,  Green,  1938. 

Birnie,  Arthur,  An  Economic  History  of  the  British  Isles,  Crofts,  1936. 

Boissonnade,  Prosper,  Life  and  Work  in  Medieval  Europe,  Knopf,  1927. 

Bowden,  Witt,  Industrial  Society  in  England  toward  the  End  of  the  Eighteenth 
Century,  Macmillan,  1925. 

Bruck,  W.  F.,  Social  and  Economic  History  of  Germany,  1888-1988,  Oxford, 
Press,  1938. 

Burlingame,  Roger,  March  of  the  Iron  Men,  Scribner,  1938. 

,  Engines  of  Democracy,  Scribner,  1940. 

Carcopino,  Jerome,  Daily  Life  in  Ancient  Rome,  Yale  University  Press,  1940. 

Clapham,  J.  H.,  The  Economic  Development  of  France  and  Germany,  1815-191^ 
Macmillan,  1923. 

,  and  Power,  Eileen,  eds.,  The  Agrarian  Life  of  the  Middle  Ages,  Mac- 
millan, 1941. 

Clough,  S.  B.,  and  Cole,  C.  W.,  The  Economic  History  of  Europe,  Heath,  1942. 

Coulton,  G.  G.,  The  Medieval  Village,  Macmillan,  1925. 

Crawford,  M.  D.  C.,  The  Heritage  of  Cotton,  Putnum,  1931. 

Day,  Clive,  History  of  Commerce,  Longmans,  1922. 

,  Economic  Development  in  Modern  Europe,  Macmillan,  1933. 

Ely,  R.  T,,  Studies  in  the  Evolution  of  Industrial  Society,  Macmillan,  1903. 

Erman,  Adolf,  Life  in  Ancient  Egypt,  Macmillan,  1894. 

Faulkner,  H.  U.,  American  Economic  History,  Harper,  1924. 

Frank,  Tenney,  Economic  History  of  Rome,  Johns  Hopkins  Press,  1927. 

Fraser,  H.  F.,  Foreign  Trade  and  World  Politics,  Knopf,  1921. 

Giddins,  P.  H.,  The  Birth  of  the  Oil  Industry,  Macmillan,  1938. 

Glotz,  Gustave,  Ancient  Greece  at  Work,  Knopf,  1926. 

Gras,  N.  S.  B.,  A  History  of  Agriculture  in  Europe  and  America)  Crofts,  1940. 

Guillebaud,  C.  W.,  The  Economic  Recovery  of  Germany,  1933-1938,  Macmillan, 
1939. 

Hammond,  J.  L.  and  B.,  The  Village  Labourer,  Longmans,  1911. 

,  The  Town  Labourer,  Longmans,  1925. 

The  Skilled  Labourer,  Longmans,  1920. 


-,  The  Rise  of  Modern  Industry,  Methuen,  1925. 


Hawks,  Ellison,  The  Book  of  Electrical  Wonders,  Dial  Press,  1936. 

Hayward,  W.  S.,  and  White,  Percival,  Chain  Stores,  McGraw-Hill,  1928. 

Heaton,  Herbert,  Economic  History  of  Europe,  Harper,  1936. 

Heckscher,  E.  F.,  Mercantilism,  2  Vols.,  Macmillan,  1935. 

Herskovits,  M.  J.,  The  Economic  Life  of  Primitive  Peoples,  Knopf,  1940. 

Hibben,  Sons  of  Vulcan. 

Hobson,  J.  A.,  Incentives  in  the  New  Industrial  Order,  Seltzer,  1925. 

Horrocks,  J.  W.,  Short  History  of  Mercantilism,  Brentano,  1925. 

Jastrow,  Morris,  The  Civilization  of  Babylonia  and  Assyria,  Lippincott,  1915. 

Kirkland,  E.  C.,  A  History  of  American  Economic  Life,  Crofts,  1932. 

Laut,  A.  C.,  The  Romance  of  the  Rails,  McBride,  1929. 

Loeb,  Life  in  a  Technocracy. 

,  ed.,  National  Survey  of  Potential  Product  Capacity,  New  York  City 

Housing  Authority,  1935. 
Mantoux,  Paul,  The  Industrial  Revolution  of  the  Eighteenth  Century,  Harcourt, 

Brace,  1928. 

Marshall,  L.  C.,  The  Story  of  Human  Progress,  Macmillan,  1937. 
McVey,  F.  L.,  Modem  Industrialism,  Appleton-Century,  1923. 
Meakin,  Walter,  The  New  Industrial  Revolution,  Brentano,  1929. 


886  SELECTED   REFERENCES 

Merz,  Charles,  And  Then  Came  Ford,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1929. 

Miller,  J.  A.,  Master  Builders  of  Sixty  Centuries,  Appleton-Century,  1938. 

Mitchell,  H.,  The  Economics  of  Ancient  Greece,  Cambridge  University  Press, 

1940. 

Morgan,  0.  S.,  ed.,  Agricultural  Systems  of  Middle  Europe,  Macmillan,  1933. 
Miiller-Lyer,  A  History  of  Social  Development. 
Mumford,  Technics  and  Civilization. 
Nussbaum,  F.  L.,  A  History  of  the  Economic  Institutions  of  Modern  Europe, 

Crofts,  1933. 
Ogg,  F.  A.,  and  Sharp,  W.  R.,  Economic  Development  of  Modern  Europe,  Mac- 

millan,  1926. 

Person,  H.  S.,  ed.,  Scientific  Management  in  American  Industry,  Harper,  1929. 
Pirenne,  Henri,  Economic  and  Social  History  of  Medieval  Europe,  Routledge, 

1936. 

Pitigliani,  Fausto,  The  Italian  Corporative  State,  Macmillan,  1934. 
Preston,  H.  W.,  and  Dodge,  Louise,  The  Private  Life  of  the  Romans,  Sanborn, 

1930. 

Pro  the  ro,  R.  W.,  English  Farming,  Past  and  Present,  Longmans,  1922. 
Renard,  G.  F.,  Life  and  Work  in  Prehistoric  Times,  Knopf,  1929. 

,  Guilds  in  the  Middle  Ages,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1919. 

,  Life  and  Work  in  Modern  Europe,  Knopf,   1926   (with  Georges 

Weulersse) . 

Rogers,  Agnes,  From  Machine  to  Man,  Little,  Brown,  1941. 
Sayce,  R.  U.,  Primitive  Arts  and  Crafts,  Macmillan,  1933. 
Taussig,  F.  W.,  The  Tariff  History  of  the  United  States,  Putnam,  1923. 
Thompson,  J.  W.,  Economic  and  Social  History  of  the  Middle  Ages,  Appleton- 
Century,  1928. 

•  '•'  •-,  Economic  and  Social  History  of  Europe  in  the  Later  Middle  Ages, 

Appleton-Century,  1931. 

Thurnwald,  Richard,  Economics  in  Primitive  Communities,  Oxford  Press,  1932. 
Toutain,  J.  F.,  Economic  Life  of  the  Ancient  World,  Knopf,  1930. 
Tyler,  J.  M.,  The  New  Stone  Age  in  Northern  Europe,  Scribner,  1921. 
Unwin,  George,  Industrial  Organization  in  the  16th  and  17th  Centuries,  Oxford 

Press,  1904. 
Usher,  A.  P.,  An  Introduction  to  the  Industrial  History  of  England,  Houghton 

Mifflin,  1920. 
Veblen,  Thorstein,  The  Instinct  of  Workmanship  and  the  State  of  the  Industrial 

Arts,  Macmillan,  1914. 

Walton,  Perry,  The  Story  of  Textiles,  Tudor,  1936. 
Ward,  H.  F.,  In  Place  of  Profit,  Scribner,  1933. 
Weber,  Max,  General  Economic  History,  Greenberg,  1927. 
Webster,  Travel  by  Air,  Land  and  Sea. 

Westerbrook,  F.  A.,  Industrial  Management  in  this  Machine  Age,  Crowell,  1932. 
Westerfield,  R.  B.,  Middlemen  in  English  Business,  Yale  University  Press,  1915. 
Willson,  The  Story  of  Rapid  Transit. 
Wolf,  Howard  and  Ralph,  Rubber:  A  Story  of  Glory  and  Oreed,  Covici,  Friede, 

1936. 

CHAPTER  5 

Anderson,  Nels,  The  Hobo,  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1923. 

•  •  ,  Men  on  the  Move,  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1940. 


SELECTED  REFERENCES  887 

Arnold,  T.  W.,  The  Folklore  of  Capitalism,  Yale  University  Press,  1937. 

,  The  Bottlenecks  of  Business,  Reynal  &  Hitchcock,  1940. 

Baake,  E.  W.,  The  Unemployed  Man,  Dutton,  1934. 

Barnes,  H.  E.,  The  Money  Changers  versus  the  New  Deal,  Long  &  Smith,  1934. 

Beaglehole,  Ernest,  Property,  Macmillan,  1932. 

Berle,  A.  A.,  and  Means,  G.  C.,  The  Modern  Corporation  and  Private  Property, 

Commerce  Clearing  House,  1932. 
Blair,  John,  Seeds  of  Destruction,  Covici-Friede,  1938. 

Bonbright,  J.  C.,  and  Means,  G.  C.,  The  Holding  Company,  McGraw-Hill,  1932. 
Bowers,  E.  L.,  Is  It  Safe  to  Work?  Houghton  Mifflin,  1930. 
Brandeis,  L.  B.,  Other  People's  Money  and  How  the  Bankers  Use  It,  Stokes, 

1932. 

Brooks,  R.  R.,  When  Labor  Organizes,  Yale  University  Press,  1937. 
Chase,  Stuart,  The  Tragedy  of  Waste,  Macmillan,  1925. 

,  A  New  Deal,  Macmillan,  1932. 

— ,  The  Economy  of  Abundance,  Macmillan,  1934. 

,  Idle  Money,  Idle  Men,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1940. 

Clark,  Evans,  et  al.,  The  Internal  Debts  of  the  United  States,  Macmillan,  1933. 

,  More  Security  for  Old  Age,  Twentieth  Century  Fund,  1937. 

Corey,  Lewis,  The  House  of  Morgan,  Watt,  1930. 

Coyle,  D.  C.,  Roads  to  a  New  America,  Little,  Brown,  1938. 

Daugherty,  C.  R.,  Labor  Problems  in  American  Industry,  Houghton,  Mifflin,  1938. 

Davis,  Forrest,  What  Price  Wall  Street,  Godwin,  1932. 

Davis,  Jerome,  Capitalism  and  Its  Culture,  Farrar  &  Rinehart,  1935. 

Dennis,  Lawrence,  7s  Capitalism  Doomed?  Harper,  1932. 

,  The  Coming  American  Fascism,  Harper,  1936. 

Doane,  R.  R.,  The  Measurement  of  American  Wealth,  Harper,  1933. 

,  The  Anatomy  of  American  Wealth,  Harper,  1940. 

Dobb,  M.  H.,  Capitalist  Enterprise  and  Social  Progress,  Lpndon,  1925. 
Douglas,  P.  H.,  Social  Security  in  the  United  States,  McGraw-Hill,  1939. 

,  Controlling  Depressions,  Norton,  1935. 

,  and  Director,  Aaron,  The  Problem  of  Unemployment,  Macmillan, 

1931. 

Douglas,  W.  0.,  Democracy  and  Finance,  Yale  University  Press,  1941. 
Epstein,  Abraham,  Insecurity :  A  Challenge  to  America,  Smith  &  Haas,  1933. 
Flynn,  J.  T.,  Investment  Trusts  Gone  Wrong,  New  Republic  Press,  1930. 

,  Graft  in  Business,  Vanguard,  1931. 

,  Security  Speculation,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1934. 

Foster,  W.  Z.,  Towards  a  Soviet  America,  Coward  McCann,  1932. 

Fuller,  R.  G.,  Child  Labor  and  the  Constitution,  Crowell,  1923. 

Gill,  Corrington,  Wasted  Manpower,  Norton,  1939. 

Goldberg,  R.  M.,  Occupational  Diseases,  Columbia  University  Press,  1931. 

Goldmark,  Josephine,  Fatigue  and  Efficiency,  Russell  Sage  Foundation,  1917. 

Gras,  N.  S.  B.,  Business  and  Capitalism,  Crofts,  1939. 

Hacker,  L.  M.,  American  Problems  of  Today,  Crofts,  1938. 

,  The  Triumph  of  American  Capitalism,  Simon  &  Schuster,  1940. 

Hacket,  J.  D.,  Health  Maintenance  in  Industry,  Shaw,  1925. 

Hamilton,  Alice,  Industrial  Poisons  in  the  United  States,  Macmillan,  1925. 

Hansen,  A.  H.,  Fiscal  Policy  and  Business  Cycles,  Norton,  1940. 

Hart,  A.  G.,  et  al.,  Debts  and  Recovery,  Twentieth  Century  Fund,  1938. 

Jones,  Bassett,  Debt  and  Production,  Day,  1933. 

Josephson,  Matthew,  The  Robber  Baronsf  Harcourt,  Brace,  1935. 

Kemnitzer,  W.  J.,  The  Rebirth  of  Monopoly,  Harper,  1938. 


888  SELECTED   REFERENCES 

Kennedy,  E.  D.,  Dividends  to  Pay,  Reynal  &  Hitchcock,  1940. 

Kcynes,  J.  M.,  et  al.,  Unemployment  as  a  World  Problem,  University  of  Chicago 
Press,  1931. 

Kuznets,  Simon,  National  Income  and  Its  Composition,  191 9-1 938 f  2  Vols.,  Na- 
tional Bureau  of  Economic  Research,  1942. 

Laidler,  H.  W.,  Concentration  in  American  Industry,  Crowell,  193L 

Leven,  Maurice,  The  Income  Structure  of  the  United  States,  Brookings  Institu- 
tion, 1938. 

Lowenthal,  Max,  The  Investor  Pays,  Knopf,  1933. 

Lundberg,  Ferdinand,  America's  Sixty  Families,  Vanguard,  1937. 

MacDonald,  Lois,  Labor  Problems  and  the  American  Scene,  Harper,  1938. 

MacDougall,  E.  D.,  ed.,  Crime  for  Profit,  Stratford,  1933. 
-,  Speculation  and  Gambling,  Stratford,  1936. 

Mallon,  G.  W.,  Bankers  versus  Consumers,  Day,  1933. 

Mangold,  G.  B.,  Problems  of  Child  Welfare,  Macmillan,  1936. 

Melvin,  Bruce,  Youth — Millions  Too  Many,  Association  Press,  1940. 

Moiilton,  H.  G.,  The  Formation  of  Capital,  Brookings  Institution,  1935. 

Myers,  Gustavus,  History  of  Great  American  Fortunes,  3  Vols.,  Kerr,  1909. 

Myers,  M.  G.,  Monetary  Proposals  for  Social  Reform,  Columbia  University 
Press,  1940. 

Newcomer,  Mabel,  Taxation  and  Fiscal  Policy,  Columbia  University  Press,  1940. 

Noyes,  A.  D.,  The  Market  Place,  Little,  Brown,  1938. 

O'Leary,  P.  M.,  Corporate  Enterprise  and  Modern  Economic  Life,  Harper,  1933. 

Perlman,  Selig,  Theory  of  the  Labor  Movement,  Macmillan,  1928. 

Rautenstrauch,  Walter,  Who  Gets  the  Money?  Harper,  1934  (new  ed.  1939). 

Ripley,  W.  Z.,  Main  Street  and  Wall  Street,  Little,  Brown,  1927. 

Rochester,  Anna,  Rulers  of  America,  International  Publishers,  1936. 

Rogers,  J.  H.,  Capitalism  in  Crisis,  Yale  University  Press,  1938. 

Rorty,  James,  Our  Master's  Voice:  Advertising,  Day,  1934. 

Rosenfarb,  Joseph,  The  National  Labor  Policy,  Harper,  1940. 

Rubinow,  I.  M.,  The  Quest  for  Security,  Holt,  1934. 

Scherman,  Harry,  The  Promises  that  Men  Live  By,  Random  House,  1938. 

Simons,  A.  J.,  Holding  Companies,  Pitman,  1927. 

Simpson,  Kemper,  The  Margin  Trader,  Harper,  1938. 

,  Big  Business,  Efficiency  and  Fascism,  Harper,  1941. 

Snyder,  Carl,  Capitalism  the  Creator,  Macmillan,  1940. 

Stewart,  P.  W.,  and  Dewhurst,  J.  F.,  Does  Distribution  Cost  Too  Much?  Twen- 
tieth Century  Fund. 

Tannenbaum,  Frank,  The  Labor  Movement,  Putnam,  1921. 

Tawney,  R.  H.,  The  Acquisitive  Society,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1920. 

Veblen,  Thorstein,  The  Theory  of  Business  Enterprise,  Scribner,  1904. 

Webb,  Sidney  and  Beatrice,  The  Decay  of  Capitalist  Civilization,  Harcourt, 
Brace,  1921. 

Weber,  Max,  The  Protestant  Ethic  and  the  Spirit  of  Capitalism,  Scribner,  1930. 

Wickwire,  A.  M.,  The  Weeds  of  Wail  Street,  Newcastle  Press,  1932. 

Winthrop,  Alden,  Are  You  a  Stockholder?  Covici,  Friede,  1937. 

Wormser,  I.  M.,  Frankenstein  Incorporated,  McGraw-Hill,  1931. 

CHAPTER  6 

Arnold,  The  Bottlenecks  of  Business. 
,  The  Folklore  of^  Capitalism. 


SELECTED   REFERENCES  889 

Babson,  R.  W.,  //  Inflation  Comes,  Stokes,  1937. 

Barnes,  The  Money -Changers  versus  the  New  Deal. 

Beaglehole,  Property. 

Berle  and  Means,  The  Modern  Corporation  and  Private  Property. 

Borsodi,  Ralph,  Prosperity  anod  Security,  Harper,  1938. 

Boudin,  L.  B.,  Government  by  Judiciary,  2  Vols.,  Godwin,  1932. 

Brailsford,  H.  N.,  Property  or  Peace,  Covici,  Friede,  1934. 

Bremer,  C.  D.,  American  Bank  Failures,  Columbia  University  Press,  1935. 

Briefs,  G.  A.,  The  Proletariat,  McGraw-Hill,  1937. 

Brown,  H.  G.,  The  Economic  Basis  of  Tax  Reform,  Lucas,  1932. 

Bye,  R.  T.,  and  Blodgett,  R.  H.,  Getting  and  Spending,  Crofts,  1937. 

Calhoun,  A.  W.,  The  Social  Universe,  Vanguard,  1932. 

Clark,  The  Internal  Debts  of  the  United  States. 

,  The  National  Debt  and  Government   Credit,  Twentieth  Century 

Fund,  1937. 
Clay,  Henry,  Property  and  Inheritance,  Daily  News  Co.  (London),  1923. 

,  The  Problem  of  Industrial  Relations,  Macmillan,  1929. 

Coker,  F.  W.,  Democracy,  Liberty  and  Property,  Macmillan,  1942. 

Coon,  Horace,  Money  to  Burn,  Longmans,  1939. 

Coyle,  D.  C.,  Why  Pay  Taxes  f  National  Home  Library,  1937. 

Davis,  Capitalism  and  Its  Culture. 

Delaporte,  L.  J.,  Mesopotamia,  Knopf,  1925. 

Doane,  The  Measurement  of  American  Wealth. 

Ely,  R.  T.,  Property  and  Contract,  2  Vols.,  Macmillan,  1914. 

Emden,  P.  II.,  The  Money  Powers  of  Europe,  Applcton-Century,  1938. 

Epstein,  Abraham,  "Do  the  Rich  Give  to  Charity?"  American  Mercury,  May, 

1931. 
Flynn,  J.  T.,  Investment  Trusts  Gone  Wrong,  New  Republic  Press,  1930. 

: ,  Security  Speculation,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1924. 

Glotz,  Ancient  Greece  at  Work. 

Gore,  Property:  Its  Duties  and  Rights. 

Greenwood,  Ernest,  Spenders  All,  Appleton-Century,  1935. 

Hamilton,  W.  H.,  "Property,"  Encyclopaedia  of  the  Social  Sciences,  Vol.  12. 

Hardy,  C.  0.,  Tax-Exempt  Securities  and  the  Surtax,  Macmillan,  1926. 

Haxey,  Simon,  England's  Money  Lords,  Harrison-Hitton,  1939. 

Hazelett,  C.  W.,  Incentive  Taxation,  Dutton,  1936. 

Helton,  Roy,  Sold  Out  to  the  Future,  Harper,  1935. 

Herskovits,  The  Economic  Life  of  Primitive  Peoples. 

Hobson,  J.  A.,  The  Evolution  of  Modern  Capitalism,  Scribner,  1926. 

,  Incentives  in  the  New  Industrial  Order. 

Jackson,  R.  H.,  The  Struggle  for  Judicial  Supremacy,  Knopf,  1941. 
Jones,  A.  W.,  Life,  Liberty  and  Property,  Lippincott,  1940. 
Keller,  A.  G.,  Social  Science,  Ginn,  1925. 

: ,  Man's  Rough  Road. 

Kelley,  F.  C.,  How  to  Lose  Your  Money  Prudently,  Swain,  1933. 

Kennedy,  Dividends  to  Pay. 

Kimmel,  L.  II.,  The  Taxation  of  Banks,  National  Industrial  Conference  Board, 

1934. 

Larkin,  Paschal,  Property  in  the  Eighteenth  Century,  Dublin,  1930. 
Lindeman,  E.  C.,  Wealth  and  Culture,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1935. 
Louis,  Paul,  Ancient  Rome  at  Work,  Knopf,  1927. 
Lowie,  Primitive  Society. 


890  SELECTED   REFERENCES 

Lundberg,  America's  Sixty  Families, 

Moret,  Alexandra,  The  Nile  and  Egyptian  Civilization,  Knopf,  1927. 

Moulton,  The  Formation  of  Capital. 

Nussbaum,  A  History  of  the  Economic  Institutions  of  Modern  Europe. 

Palm,  F.  C.,  The  Middle  Classes:  Then  and  Now,  Macmillan,  1936. 

Ramsay,  M.  L.,  Pyramids  of  Power,  Bobbs-Merrill,  1937. 

Rautenstrauch,  Who  Gets  the  Money  f 

Rignano,  Eugene,  The  Social  Significance  of  the  Inheritance  Tax,  Knopf,  1924. 

Schcrman,  The  Promises  Men  Live  By. 

Schultz,  W.  J.,  The  Taxation  of  Inheritance,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1926. 

Sinclair,  Upton,  Upton  Sinclair  Presents  William  Fox,  Sinclair,  1933. 

Snyder,  Capitalism  the  Creator. 

Studenski,  Paul,  ed.,  Taxation  and  Public  Policy,  R.  R.  Smith,  1936. 

Taussig,  F.  W.,  Inventors  and  Money-Makers,  Macmillan,  1915. 

Tawney,  R.  H.,  The  Acquisitive  Society,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1920. 

-,  Religion  and  the  Rise  of  Capitalism,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1926. 

Thompson,  Economic  and  Social  History  of  the  Middle  Ages. 

,  Economic  and  Social  History  of  the  Later  Middle  Ages. 

Tilden,  Freeman,  A  World  in  Debt,  Funk  &  Wagnalls,  1936. 

Untereiner,  R.  E.,  The  Tax  Racket,  Lippincott,  1933. 

Veblen,  Thorstein,  The  Theory  of  the  Leisure  Class,  Macmillan,  1899. 

,  Absentee  Ownership,  Huebsch,  1923. 

,  The  Theory  of  Business  Enterprise. 

Wallis,  Louis,  Safeguard  Productive  Capital,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1935. 
Ward,  C.  O.,  The  Ancient  Lowly,  2  Vols.,  Kerr,  1907. 
Weber,  The  Protestant  Ethic  and  the  Spirit  of  Capitalism. 
Wedgwood,  Josiah,  The  Economics  of  Inheritance,  Routledge,  1929. 
Winthrop,  Alden,  Are  You  a  Stockholder?  Covici,  Friede,  1937. 


CHAPTER  7 

Barnes,  H.  E.,  History  and  Social  Intelligence,  Knopf,  1926. 
Beard,  C.  A.,  The  Open  Door  at  Home,  Macmillan,  1934. 

-,  The  Idea  of  National  Interest,  Macmillan,  1934. 


-,  The  Economic  Basis  of  Politics,  Knopf,  1932. 


Bennett,  H.  A.,  The  Constitution  in  School  and  College,  Putnam,  1935. 

Borgeaud,  Charles,  The  Rise  of  Modern  Democracy  in  Old  and  New  England, 
Scribner,  1894. 

,  The  Adoption  and  Amendment  of  Constitutions  in  Europe  and 

America,  Macmillan,  1895. 

Brant,  Irving,  Storm  Over  the  Constitution,  Bobbs-Merrill,  1936. 

Elliott,  W.  Y.,  The  Need  for  Constitutional  Reform,  McGraw-Hill,  1935. 

Gellerman,  William,  The  American  Legion  as  Educator,  Teachers  College  Pub- 
lications, 1938. 

Gibbons,  H.  A.,  Nationalism  and  Internationalism,  Stokes,  1930. 

Greenberg,  L.  S.,  Nationalism  in  a  Changing  World,  Greenberg,  1937. 

Hamilton,  W.  H.,  and  Adair,  Douglass,  The  Power  to  Govern,  Norton,  1937. 

Hayes,  C.  J.  H.,  Essays  on  Nationalism,  Macmillan,  1926. 

,  Historical  Evolution  of  Modern  Nationalism,  Long  &  Smith,  1931. 

Holcombe,  A.  N.,  The  Foundations  of  the  Modern  Commonwealth,  Harper,  1923. 

Jenks,  Edward,  The  State  and  the  Nation,  Button,  1919. 


SELECTED   REFERENCES  891 

Jensen,  Merrill,  The  Articles  of  Confederation,  University  of  Wisconsin  Press, 

1940. 

Levy,  B.  H.,  Our  Constitution,  Tool  or  Testament?  Knopf,  1940. 
Lowie,  R.  H.,  The  Origin  of  the  State,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1937. 
Lyon,   Hastings,   The   Constitution  and   the   Men   Who   Made   It,    Houghton 

Mifflin,  1936. 

MacDonald,  William,  A  New  Constitution  for  a  New  America,  Huebsch,  1921. 
MacLeod,  W.  C.,  The  Origin  and  History  of  Politics,  Wiley,  1931. 
McBain,  H.  L.,  The  Living  Constitution,  Macmillan,  1927. 
Mcllwain,  C.  H.,  Constitutionalism,  Ancient  and  Modern,  Cornell  University 

Press,  1940. 

,  Constitutionalism  and  the  Changing  World,  Macmillan,  1939. 

Merriam,  C.  E.,  The  Making  of  Citizens,  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1931. 

,  The  Written  Constitution  and  the  Unwritten,  Smith,  1931. 

Miller,  H.  A.,  Races,  Nations  and  Classes,  Lippincott,  1926. 

,  The  Beginnings  of  Tomorrow,  Stokes,  1933. 

Morey,  W.  C.,  The  First  State  Constitutions,  Annals  of  the  American  Academy, 

1893. 

Muir,  Ramsay,  Nationalism  and  Internationalism,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1917. 
Partridge,  G.  E.,  The  Psychology  of  Nations,  Macmillan,  1919. 
Pillsbury,  W.  B.,  The  Psychology  of  Nationality  and  Internationalism,  Applcton- 

Century,  1919. 

Riegel,  0.  W.,  Mobilizing  for  Chaos,  Yale  University  Press,  1934. 
Robinson,  J.  H.,  The  Human  Comedy,  Harper,  1937. 
Rose,  J.  H.,  Nationality  in  Modern  History,  Macmillan,  1916. 
Sait,  Political  Institutions. 
Smith,  J.  Allen,  The  Growth  and  Decadence  of  Constitutional  Government,  Holt, 

1930. 


CHAPTER  8 

Adams,  S.  H.,  The  Incredible  Era,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1940. 

Barnes,  Sociology  and  Political  Theory. 

Beman,  L.  T.,  The  Direct  Primary,  Wilson,  1926. 

Bentley,  A.  F.,  The  Process  of  Government,  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1908. 

Brooks,  R.  C.,  Corruption  in  American  Politics  and  Life,  Dodd,  Mead,  1910. 

,  Political  Parties  and  Electoral  Problems,  Harper,  1923. 

Bruce,  H.  R.,  American  Parties  and  Politics,  Holt,  1927. 

Buck,  A.  E.,  The  Budget  in  Governments  Today,  Macmillan,  1934. 

Buehler,  A.  G.,  ed.,  Billions  for  Defense,  Annals  of  the  American  Academy,  1941. 

Carpenter,  W.  S.,  and  Stafford,  P.  T.,  State  and  Local  Government  in  the  United 

States,  Crofts,  1936. 

Chamberlain,  J.  P.,  Legislative  Processes,  Appleton-Century,  1936. 
Childs,  H.  L.,  Labor  and  Capital  in  National  Politics,  Ohio  State  University  Press, 

1930. 

Dinneen,  J.  F.,  Ward  Eight,  Harper,  1936. 

Dobyns,  Fletcher,  The  Underworld  in  American  Politics,  Kingsport  Press,  1932. 
Douglas,  P.  H.,  The  Coming  of  a  New  Party,  McGraw-Hill,  1932. 
Durham,  Knowlton,  Billions  for  Veterans,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1932. 
Fine,  Nathan,  Labor  and  Farmer  Parties  in  the  United  States,  Rand  School,  1928. 
Fish,  C.  R.,  Civil  Service  and  the  Patronage,  Longmans,  1905. 


892  SELECTED   REFERENCES 

Friedrich,  C.  J.,  et  al.,  Problems  of  American  Public  Service,  McGraw-Hill,  1935. 

Garrigues,  C.  H.,  You're  Paying  for  It,  Funk  &  Wagnalls,  1936. 

Greenwood,  Ernest,  Spenders  All,  Appleton-Century,  1935. 

Harding,  T.  S.,  T.N.T.  Those  National  Tax  Eaters,  Long  &  Smith,  1934. 

Harris,  J.  P.,  Election  Administration  in  the  United  States,  Brookings  Institution, 

1934, 

Haynes,  F.  E.,  Third  Party  Movements,  Iowa  State  Historical  Society,  1916. 
Helm,  W.  P.,  Washington  Swindle  Sheet,  Boni,  1932. 
Herring,  E.  P.,  Group  Representation  Before  Congress,  Johns  Hopkins  Press, 

1929. 

"  >  The  Politics  of  Democracy,  Norton,  1940. 
Holcombe,  A.  N.,  Political  Parties  of  Today,  Harper,  1924. 

,  The  New  Party  Politics,  Norton,  1933. 

-,  The  Middle  Classes  in  American  Politics,  Harvard  University  Press, 


1940. 

Key,  V.  O.,  Politics,  Parties  and  Pressure  Groups,  Crowell,  1942. 
Laswcll,  H.  D.,  Politics,  McGraw-Hill,  1936. 
Logan,  E.  B.,  ed,,  The  American  Political  Scene,  Harper,  1938. 
Luce,  Robert,  Legislative  Problems,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1935. 
Ludlow,  Lewis,  America  Go  Bust,  Stratford,  1933. 
Lundbcrg,  America's  Sixty  Families. 

Mayo,  Katherine,  Soldiers  What  Next?  Houghton  Mifflin,  1934. 
McKean,  D.  D.,  The  Boss:  Machine  Politics  in  Action,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1940. 
Merriam,  C.  E.,  The  American  Party  System,  Macmillan,  1940. 
tylichels,  Robert,  Political  Parties,  Hearst's  International  Library,  1915. 
Myers,  Gustavus,  A  History  of  Tammany  Hall,  Boni  &  Liveright,  1917. 
Northrop,  W.  B.  and  J.  B.,  The  Insolence  of  Office,  Putnam,  1932. 
Odegard,  P.  H.,  and  Helms,  E.  A.,  American  Politics,  Harper,  1938. 
Overacker,  Louise,  The  Presidential  Primary,  Macmillan,  1926. 
Powell,  Talcott,  Tattered  Banners,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1933. 
Ray,  P.  O.,  An  Introduction  to  Political  Parties  and  Practical  Politics,  Scribner, 

1917. 

Sait,  E.  M.,  American  Parties  and  Elections,  Appleton-Century,  1939. 
Salter,  J.  T.,  Boss  Rule,  McGraw-Hill,  1935. 

,  The  Pattern  of  Politics,  Macmillan,  1940. 

3ikes,  E.  R.,  State  and  Federal  Corrupt  Practices  Legislation,  Duke  University 

Press,  1928. 

Wallas,  Graham,  Human  Nature  in  Politics,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1909. 
WTallis,  J.  H.,  The  Politician,  Stokes,  1935. 
Werner,  M.  R.,  Privileged  Characters,  McBride,  1935. 

Willoughby,  W.  F.,  The  National  Budget  System,  Brookings  Institution,  1927. 
,  Financial  Conditions  and  Operations  of  the  National  Government, 

1921-1930,  Brookings  Institution,  1931. 


CHAPTER  9 

Agar,  Herbert,  The  People's  Choice,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1933. 
Albig,  William,  Public  Opinion,  McGraw-Hill,  1939. 
Anastasia,  Anne,  Differential  Psychology,  Macmillan,  1937. 
Anshen,  R.  A.,  ed.,  Freedom:  Its  Meaning,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1940. 
Ascoli,  Max,  Intelligence  in  Politics,  Norton,  1938. 


SELECTED   REFERENCES  893 

Barnes,  H.  E.,  Living  in  the  Twentieth  Century,  Bobbs-Merrill,  1928. 
Bates,  E.  S.,  This  Land  of  Liberty,  Harper,  1930. 
Beard,  William,  Government  and  Technology,  Macmillan,  1934. 
Becker,  C.  L.,  Modern  Democracy,  Yale  University  Press,  1941. 

,  New  Liberties  for  Old,  Yale  University  Press,  1941. 

Bennett,  J.  L.,  The  Essential  American  Tradition,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1925. 
Bonn,  M.  J.,  The  Crisis  of  European  Democracy,  Yale  University  Press,  1925. 
Brigham,  C.  C.,  A  Study  of  American  Intelligence,  Princeton  University  Press, 

1923. 

Brooks,  R.  C.,  Deliver  Us  from  Dictators,  University  of  Pennsylvania  Press,  1935. 
Bryce,  James,  Modern  Democracies,  2  Vols.,  Macmillan,  1921. 
Buck,  The  Budget  in  Governments  of  Today. 
Burnham,  The  Managerial  Revolution. 
Burns,  C.  D.,  Challenge  to  Democracy,  Norton,  1935. 
Calkins,  Clinch,  Spy  Overhead,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1937. 
Chafee,  Zechariah,  Free  Speech  in  the  United  States,  Harvard  University  Press, 

1941. 

Coker,  F.  W.,  Recent  Political  Thought,  Appleton-Century,  1934. 
Counts,  G.  S.,  The  Prospects  of  American  Democracy,  Day,  1938. 

,  The  Schools  Can  Teach  Democracy,  Day,  1941. 

Cousins,  Norman,  ed.,  A  Treasury  of  Democracy,  Coward-McCann,  1942. 

Craven,  Avery,  Democracy  in  American  Life,  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1941. 

Dennis,  The  Coming  American  Fascism. 

Dos  Passes,  John,  The  Ground  We  Stand  On,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1941. 

Durant,  W.  J.,  Mansions  of  Philosophy,  Simon  &  Schuster,  1929. 

Edman,  Irwin,  ed.,  Fountain  Heads  of  Freedom,  Reynal  &  Hitchcock,  1941. 

Eldridge,  Seba,  Public  Intelligence,  University  of  Kansas  Press,  1935. 

Ellis,  R.  S.,  The  Psychology  of  Individual  Differences,  Appleton-Century,  1928. 

Ernst,  M.  L.,  and  Lindey,  Alexander,  The  Censor  Marches   On,  Doubleday, 

Doran,  1940. 

Everett,  Samuel,  Democracy  Faces  the  Future,  Columbia  University  Press,  1935. 
Forman,  S.  E.,  A  Good  Word  for  Democracy,  Appleton-Century,  1937. 
Fosdick,  Dorothy,  What  Is  Liberty?  Harper,  1939. 
Friedrich,  Problems  of  the  American  Public  Service. 
Garrison,  W.  E.,  Intolerance,  Round  Table  Press,  1934. 
Gilliland,  A.  R.,  and  Clark,  E.  L.,  The  Psychology  of  Individual  Differences, 

Prentice-Hall,  1939. 

Glover,  T.  R.,  Democracy  in  the  Ancient  World,  Macmillan,  1927. 
Gracchus,  G.  S.,  The  Renaissance  of  Democracy,  Pegasus,  1937. 
Hallgren,  M.  A.,  The  Landscape  of  Freedom,  Howell,  Soskin,  1941. 
Hamilton  and  Adair,  The  Power  to  Govern. 
Hattersley,  A.  F.,  Short  History  of  Democracy,  Macmillan,  1930. 
Hays,  A.  G.,  Let  Freedom  Ring,  Boni  &  Liveright,  1928. 

,  Trial  by  Prejudice,  Covici,  Friede,  1933. 

,  Democracy  Works,  Random  House,  1940. 

Herring,  The  Politics  of  Democracy. 

Hoag,  C.  G.,  and  Hallett,  G.  H.,  Proportional  Representation,  Macmillan,  1926. 

Holcombe,  A.  N.,  Government  in  a  Planned  Democracy,  Norton,  1935. 

Huberman,  Leo,  The  Labor  Spy  Racket,  Modern  Age,  1937. 

Hudson,  J.  W.,  Why  Democracy?  Appleton-Century,  1936. 

Huxley,  J.  S.,  Democracy  Marches,  Harper,  1941. 

James,  H.  G.,  Principles  of  Prussian  Administration,  Macmillan,  1913. 


894  SELECTED   REFERENCES 

Joad,  C.  E.  M.,  Liberty  Today,  Dutton,  1935. 

Kallen,  H.  M.,  ed.,  Freedom  in  the  Modern  World,  Coward-McCann,  1928. 

Kingsley,  J.  D.,  and  Petegorsky,  D.  W.,  Strategy  for  Democracy,  Longmans, 

Green,  1942. 
Laski,  H.  J.,  Liberty  in  the  Modern  State,  Harper,  1930. 

;  Democracy  in  Crisis,  University  of  North  Carolina  Press,  1933. 

,  The  Rise  of  Liberalism,  Harper,  1936. 

Lasswell,  H.  D.,  Democracy  through  Public  Opinion,  Banta,  1941. 

Loeb,  Life  in  a  Technocracy. 

Martin,  E.  D.,  Liberty,  Norton,  1930. 

Marx,  F.  M.,  Public  Management  in  the  New  Democracy,  Harper,  1940. 

Mencken,  H.  L.,  Notes  on  Democracy,  Knopf,  1926. 

Merriam,  C.  E,,  The  Role  of  Politics  in  Social  Change,  New  York  University 

Press,  1936. 

,  The  New  Democracy  and  the  New  Despotism,  McGraw-Hill,  1939. 

,  What  Is  Democracy?  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1941. 

,  On  the  Agenda  of  Democracy,  Harvard  University  Press,  1941. 

Minis,  Edwin,  The  Majority  of  the  People,  Modern  Age,  1941. 

Mosher,  W.  E.,  and  Kingsley,  J.  D.,  Public  Personnel  Administration,  Harper, 

1941. 

Norton,  T.  J.,  Losing  Liberty  Judicially,  Macmillan,  1928. 
Odegard,  P.  H.,  et  al.,  Democracy  in  Transition,  Appleton-Century,  1937. 
Overstreet,  H.  A.,  Our  Free  Minds,  Norton,  1941. 
Palm,  F.  C.,  The  Middle  Classes  Then  and  Now,  Macmillan,  1936. 
Penman,  J.  S.,  The  Irresistible  Movement  of  Democracy,  Macmillan,  1923. 
Pink,  M.  A.,  A  Realist  Looks  at  Democracy,  Stokes,  1931. 
Sait,  E.  M.,  Democracy,  Appleton-Century,  1929. 
Salter,  The  Pattern  of  Politics. 
Sejdes,  George,  You  Can't  Print  That,  Payson  &  Clarke,  1929. 

,  You  Can't  Do  That,  Modern  Age,  1938. 

Shalloo,  J,.  P.,  Private  Police,  Annals  of  the  American  Academy,  1933. 

Smith,  Bernard,  The  American  Spirit,  Knopf,  1941. 

Soule,  George,  The  Coming  American  Revolution,  Macmillan,  1934. 

,  The  Future  of  Liberty,  Macmillan,  1936. 

Stout,  II.  M.,  Public  Service  in  Great  Britain,  University  of  North  Carolina  Press, 

1938. 

Strunsky,  Simeon,  The  Living  Tradition,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1939. 
Swancara,  Frank,  The  Obstruction  of  Justice  by  Religion,  Courtright,  1936. 
Swing,  R.  G.,  Forerunners  of  American  Fascism,  Messner,  1935. 
Tead,  Ordway,  The  Case  for  Democracy,  Association  Press,  1938. 
Wallace,  W.  K,  The  Passing  of  Politics,  Macmillan,  1924. 
Wallis,  The  Politician. 
Whipple,  Leon,  Our  Ancient  Liberties,  Wilson,  1927. 

,  The  Story  of  Civil  Liberty  in  the  United  States,  Vanguard,  1927. 

White,  L.  D.,  and  Smith,  T.  V.,  Politics  and  Public  Service,  Harper,  1939. 


CHAPTER  10 

Ackermann,  Wolfgang,  Are  We  Civilized?  Covici,  Friede,  1936. 

Adams,  R.  E.,  War  and  Wages,  Primrose,  1935. 

Background  of  War,  By  the  Editors  of  Fortune,  Knopf,  1937. 


SELECTED   REFERENCES  895 

Bakeless,  John,  The  Origin  of  the  Next  War,  Viking,  1926. 
Baldwin,  H.  W.,  The  Caissons  Roll,  Knopf,  1938. 

,  United  We  Stand,  McGraw-Hill,  1941. 

Barnes,  H.  E.,  The  Genesis  of  the  World  War,  Knopf,  1926. 

,  World  Politics,  Knopf,  1930. 

Beard,  C.  A.,  The  Navy:  Defense  or  Portent?  Harper,  1932. 

Bernstein,  Herman,  Can  We  Abolish  War?  Broadview,  1935. 

Brinton,  H.,  ed.,  Does  Capitalism  Cause  Warf  Brinton,  1935. 

Brodie,  Bernard,  Sea  Power  in  the  Machine  Age,  Princeton  University  Press, 

1941. 

Buehler,  Billions  for  Defense. 

Butler,  Harold,  The  Lost  Peace,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1942. 

Clarkson,  J.  D.,  and  Cochran,  T.  C.,  War  as  a  Social  Institution,  Columbia  Uni- 
versity Press,  1941. 

Curti,  M.  E.,  Peace  or  War,  Norton,  1936. 
Davie,  The  Evolution  of  War. 

Dell,  Robert,  The  Geneva  Racket,  1920-1939,  Hale  (London),  1941. 
Dennis,  Lawrence,  The  Dynamics  of  War  and  Revolution,  Weekly  Foreign  Letter, 

1940. 

DeWilde,  J.  C.,  et  al.,  Handbook  of  the  War,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1939. 
Dodson,  Leonidas,  ed.,  The  Shadow  of  War,  Annals  of  the  American  Academy, 

1934. 

Dupuy,  R.  E.,  and  Eliot,  G.  F.,  //  War  Comes,  Macmillan,  1937. 
Einzig,  Paul,  Economic  Warfare,  Macmillan,  1941. 
Eliot,  G.  F.,  The  Ramparts  We  Watch,  Reynal  &  Hitchcock,  1940. 

,  Bombs  Bursting  in  Air,  Reynal  &  Hitchcock,  1940. 

,  The  Defense  of  the  Americas,  Reynal  &  Hitchcock,  1941. 

Engelbrecht,  H.  C.,  One  Hell  of  a  Business,  McBride,  1934. 

,  Revolt  against  War,  Dodd,  Mead,  1937. 

Engelbrecht,  H.  C.,  and  Hanighen,  F.  C.,  Merchants  of  Death,  Dodd,  Mead, 

1934. 

Hamlin,  C.  H.,  The  War  Myth  in  American  History,  Vanguard,  1927. 
Hart,  Liddell,  Europe  in  Arms,  Random  House,  1937. 
Herring,  Pendleton,  The  Impact  of  War,  Farrar  &  Rinehart,  1941. 
Jameson,  Storm,  ed.,  Challenge  to  Death,  Dutton,  1935. 
Jennings,  W.  I.,  A  Federation  for  Western  Europe,  Macmillan,  1940. 
Kleinschmid,  R.  B.  von,  and  Martin,  C.  E.,  War  and  Society,  University  of 

Southern  California  Press,  1941. 
Knight,  B.  W.,  How  to  Run  a  War,  Knopf,  1936. 
LaMotte,  E.  N.,  The  Backwash  of  War,  Putnam,  1934. 
Lehmann-Russbuldt,  Otto,  War  for  Profits,  King,  1930. 
Lewinsohn,  Richard,  The  Profits  of  War,  Dutton,  1937. 
Lorwin,  L.  L.,  The  Economic  Consequences  of  the  Second  World  War,  Random 

House,  1942. 

Major,  R.  H.,  Fatal  Partners:  War  and  Disease,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1941. 
Montross,  War  through  the  Ages. 
Munk,  Frank,  The  Economics  of  Force,  Stewart,  1940. 
Nearing,  Scott,  War,  Vanguard  Press,  1930. 
Neumann,  Robert,  Zaharoff :  the  Armaments  King,  Knopf,  1936. 
Nichols,  Beverly,  Cry  Havoc,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1933. 
Nickerson,  Hoffman,  Can  We  Limit  Warf  Stokes,  1934. 
,  The  Armed  Horde,  Putnam,  1940. 


896  SELECTED   REFERENCES 

Nicolai,  G.  F.,  The  Biology  of  War,  Appletoii-Century,  1918. 

Noel-Baker,  Philip,  The  Private  Manufacture  of  Armaments,  Oxford  Press,  1937. 

Palmer,  Frederick,  Our  Gallant  Madness,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1937. 

Porritt,  Arthur,  ed.,  The  Causes  of  War,  Macmillan,  1932. 

Pratt,  Fletcher,  America  and  Total  War,  Smith  &  Durrell,  1941. 

Raushenbush,  Stephen  and  Joan,  War  Madness,  National  Home  Library,  1937. 

Seldes,  George,  Iron,  Blood  and  Profits,  Harper,  1934. 

Shapiro,  Harry,  What  Every  Young  Man  Should  Know  about  War,  Knight,  1937. 

Sorokin,  P.  A.,  Social  and  Cultural  Dynamics,  3  Vols.,  American  Book  Co.,  1937, 

Vol.  Ill,  Part  II. 

Sprier,  Hans,  and  Kahler,  Alfred,  War  in  Our  Time,  Norton,  1939. 
Spiegel,  H.  W,,  The  Economics  of  Total  War,  Applcton-Century,  1942. 
Spykman,  N.  K,  America's  Strategy  in  World  Politics,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1942. 
Stein,  Emanuel  and  Bachman,  Jules,  War  Economics,  Farrar  and  Rinehart,  1941. 
Stein,  R.  M,,  M-Day:  the  First  Day  of  War,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1936. 
Steiner,  H.  A.,  Principles  and  Problems  of  International  Relations,  Harper,  1940. 
Stockton,  Richard,  Inevitable  War,  Perth,  1932. 
Taylor,  Edmund,  The  Strategy  of  Terror,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1940. 
Tuttle,  F.  G.,  ed.,  Alternatives  to  War,  Harper,  1931. 
Vagts,  Alfred,  The  History  of  Militarism,  Norton,  1937. 

Van  Kleffens,  E.  N.,  Juggernaut  Over  Holland,  Columbia  University  Press,  1941. 
Waldman,  Seymour,  Death  and  Profits,  Brewer,  Warren  &  Putnam,  1932. 
Waller,  Willard,  ed.,  War  in  the  Twentieth  Century,  Dryden,  1939. 
Werner,  Max,  Battle  for  the  World,  Modern  Age,  1941. 
Wright,  Quincy,  The  Causes  of  War  and  the  Conditions  of  Peace,  Longmans, 

1935. 


CHAPTERS  11-12 

Arnold,  T.  W.,  The  Symbols  of  Government,  Yale  University  Press,  1935. 

,  The  Folklore  of  Capitalism. 

Barnes,  H.  E.,  The  Repression  of  Crime,  Doran,  1926. 

Bates,  E.  S.,  The  Story  of  the  Supreme  Court,  Bobbs-Merrill,  1937. 

Berle,  A.  A.,  Articles  "Legal  Profession,"  and  "Legal  Education"  in  Encyclo- 
paedia of  the  Social  Sciences. 

Berle  and  Means,  The  Modern  Corporation  and  Private  Property. 

Berolzheimer,  Fritz,  The  World's  Legal  Philosophies,  Macmillan,  1912. 

Best,  Harry,  Crime  and  the  Criminal  Law  in  the  United  States,  Macmillan,  1930. 

Black,  F.  R.,  Ill-Starred  Prohibition  Cases,  Badger,  1931. 

Bok,  Curtis,  Backbone  of  the  Herring,  Knopf,  1941. 

Boorstin,  D.  J.,  The  Mysterious  Science  of  the  Law,  Harvard  University  Press, 
1941. 

Borchard,  E.  M.,  Convicting  the  Innocent,  Yale  University  Press,  1932. 

Boudin,  Government  by  Judiciary. 

Bradway,  J.  S.,  ed.,  Frontiers  of  Legal  Aid  Work,  Annals  of  the  American  Acad- 
emy, 1939. 

Cairns,  Huntington,  Law  and  the  Social  Sciences,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1935. 

Christian,  E.  B.  V.,  Solicitors:  An  Outline  of  their  History,  London,  1925. 

Cohen,  J.  H.,  The  Law:  Business  or  Profession?  Jennings,  1924. 

Corwin,  E.  S.,  The  Twilight  of  the  Supreme  Court,  Yale  University  Press,  1934. 

,  Court  Over  Constitution,  Princeton  University  Press,  1938. 


SELECTED   REFERENCES  897 

Cushman,  R.  E.,  Leading  Constitutional  Decisions,  Crofts,  1940. 

Darrow,  Clarence,  The  Story  of  My  Life,  Scribners,  1932. 

Feinstein,  Isidor,  The  Court  Disposes,  Covici,  Friede,  1937. 

Frank,  Jerome,  Law  and  the  Modern  Mind,  Brentano,  1930. 

Gisnet,  Morris,  A  Lawyer  Tells  the  Truth,  Concord  Press,  1931. 

Glueck,  S.  S.,  Crime  and  Justice,  Little,  Brown,  1936. 

Goldberg,  L.  P.,  and  Levenson,  Eleanore,  Lawless  Judges,  Rand  School  Press, 

1935. 

Green,  Leon,  Judge  and  Jury,  Vernon  Law  Book  Co.,  1930. 
Gurvitch,  Georges,  The  Sociology  of  Law,  Philosophical  Library,  1942. 
Haines,  C.  G.,  The  Revival  of  Natural  Law  Concepts,  Harvard  University  Press, 

1930. 

Harrison,  C.  Y.,  Clarence  Darrow,  Cape  &  Smith,  1931. 
Hays,  Trial  by  Prejudice. 

Herbert,  A.  P.,  Uncommon  Law,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1936. 
Hopkins,  E.  J.,  Our  Lawless  Police,  Viking  Press,  1931. 
Jackson,  Percival,  Look  at  the  Law,  Button,  1940. 
Jackson,  R.  H.,  The  Struggle  for  Judicial  Supremacy,  Knopf,  1941. 
Kelley,  How  to  Lose  Your  Money  Prudently. 
Lavine,  Emafcuel,  The  Third  Degree,  Vanguard,  1930. 
Levy,  Our  Constitution:  Tool  or  Testament? 

Maguire,  J.  M.,  The  Lance  of  Justice,  Harvard  University  Press,  1928. 
Moley,  Raymond,  et  al.,  The  Missouri  Crime  Survey,  Macmillan,  1926. 

,  Our  Criminal  Courts,  Minton,  1930. 

Mortenson,  Ernest,  You  Be  the  Judge,  Longmans,  1940. 

Myers,  Gustavus,  History  of  the  Supreme  Court,  Kerr,  1925. 

Parker,  J.  R.,  Attorneys  at  Law,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1941. 

Parsons,  Frank,  Legal  Doctrine  and  Social  Progress,  Huebsch,  1911. 

Partridge,  Bellamy,  Country  Lawyer,  McGraw-Hill,  1939. 

Pearson,  Drew,  and  Allen,  R.  S.,  The  Nine  Old  Men,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1936. 

Pound,  Roscoe,  Interpretations  of  Legal  History,  Macmillan,  1923. 

,  et  al.,  Criminal  Justice  in  Cleveland,  Cleveland  Foundation,  1922. 

Raby,  R.  C.,  50  Famous  Trials,  Washington  Law  Book  Co.,  1932. 

Radin,  Max,  The  Law  and  Mr.  Smith,  Bobbs-Merrill,  1940. 

Ripley,  Main  Street  and  Wall  Street. 

Robinson,  E.  S.,  Law  and  the  Lawyers,  Macmillan,  1935. 

Robson,  W.  A.,  Civilization  and  the  Growth  of  Law,  Macmillan,  1935. 

Rodell,  Fred,  Woe  unto  You,  Lawyers,  Reynal  &  Hitchcock,  1940. 

Schlosser,  A.  H.,  Lawyers  Must  Eat,  Vanguard,  1933. 

Seagle,  William,  There  Ought  to  Be  a  Law,  Macaulay,  1933. 

,  The  Quest  for  Law,  Knopf,  1941. 

Sinclair,  Upton  Sinclair  Presents  William  Fox. 

Smith,  Munroe,  The  Development  of  European  Law,  Columbia  University  Press, 

1928. 

Smith,  R.  H.,  Justice  and  the  Poor,  Carnegie  Foundation,  Bulletin  13,  19,19. 
,  Growth  of  Legal  Aid  Work  in  the   United  States,  Government 

Printing  Office,  1926. 

Stalmaster,  Irving,  What  Price  Jury  Trials?  Stratford,  1931. 
Stone,  Irving,  Clarence  Darrow  for  the  Defense,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1941. 
Swancara,  The  Obstruction  of  Justice  by  Religion. 
Taft,  H.  W.,  Witnesses  in  Court,  Macmillan,  1934. 
Waite,  J.  P.,  Criminal  Law  in  Action,  Sears,  1934. 


898  SELECTED  REFERENCES 

Warren,  Charles,  A  History  of  the  American  Bar,  Little  Brown,  1911. 

Wellman,  F.  L.,  Gentlemen  of  the  Jury,  Macmillan,  1925. 

,  ed.,  Success  in  Court,  Macmillan,  1942. 

Wickersham,  G.  W.,  et  al,  National  Commission  on  Law  Observance  and  En- 
forcement, Reports,  Government  Printing  Office,  1931. 

Wigmore,  J.  H.,  Panorama  of  the  World's  Legal  Systems,  Washington  Law  Book 
Company,  1936, 

,  A  Pocket  Code  of  the  Rules  of  Evidence,  Little  Brown,  1910. 

Williams,  E.  H.,  The  Doctor  in  Court,  Williams  &  Wilkins,  1929. 

,  The  Insanity  Plea,  Williams  &  Wilkins,  1931. 

Wood,  A.  E.,  and  Waite,  J.  B.,  Crime  and  Its  Treatment,  American  Book  Co., 
1941. 

Wormser,  Frankstein  Incorporated. 

Wright,  B.  F.,  The  Contract  Clawe  of  the  Constitution,  Harvard  University 
Press,  1938. 

,  The  Growth  of  American  Constitutional  Law,   Rcynal   &  Hitch- 
cock, 1942. 

-,  American  Interpretations  of  Natural  Law,  Harvard  University  Press, 


1931. 
Zane,  The  Story  of  Law. 


CHAPTER  13 


Archer,  G.  L.,  History  of  Radio  -to  1926,  American  Historical  Society,  1938. 

,  Big  Business  and  Radio,  American  Historical  Co.,  1939. 

Bakeless,  John,  Magazine  Making,  Viking  Press,  1931. 

Barrett,  J.  W.,  Joseph  Pulitzer  and  His  World,  Vanguard,  1941. 

Bickel,  K.  A.,  New  Empires,  Lippincott,  1930. 

Bird,  G.  L.  and  Merwin,  F.  E.,  The  Newspaper  and  Society,  Prentice-Hall,  1942. 

Black,  Archibald,  The  Story  of  Flying,  McGraw-Hill,  1940. 

Blumer,  Herbert,  Movies  and  Conduct,  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1933. 

*,  and  Hauser,  P.  M.,  Movies,  Delinquency  and  Crime,  University  of 

Chicago  Press,  1933. 

Brindze,  Ruth,  Not  to  Be  Broadcast,  Vanguard,  1937. 
Bruno,  Harry,  Wings  Over  America,  McBride,  1942. 

Carlson,  Oliver,  and  Bates,  E.  8.,  Hearst:  Lord  of  San  Simeon,  Vanguard,  1936. 
Chase,  Stuart,  The  Tyranny  of  Words,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1939. 
Clark,  Delbert,  Washington  Dateline,  Stokes,  1941. 

Clarke,  Tom,  My  Northcliffe  Diary,  Cosmopolitan  Book  Corporation,  1931. 
Cochran,  N.  D,,  E.  W.  Scripps,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1933. 
Coon,  Horace,  American  Tel  and  Tel,  Longmans,  1939. 
Crawford,  N.  A.,  The  Ethics  of  Journalism,  Knopf,  1924. 
Davis,  H.  O.,  The  Empire  of  the  Air,  Ventura  Free  Press,  1932. 
Desmond,  P.  W.,  The  Press  and  World  Affairs,  Appleton-Century,  1937. 
Dilts,  M.  M.,  The  Telephone  in  a  Changing  World,  Longmans,  1940. 
Drewry,  J.  E.,  Contemporary  American  Magazines,  University  of  Georgia  Press, 

1938. 
Dunlap,  0.  E.,  Radio  in  Advertising,  Harper,  1931. 

1 -,  The  Story  of  Radio,  Dial  Press,  1935. 

Fechet,  J.  E.,  Flying,  Williams  <fe  Wilkins,  1933. 

Filler,  Louis,  Crusaders  for  American  Liberalism,  Harcourt,  Brace,  19^9. 
Forman,  H.  J.,  Our  Movie  Made  Children,  Macmillan,  1933. 
Franklin.  H.  B..  Motion  Picture  Theatre  Management,  Doran,  1927. 


SELECTED  REFERENCES  899 

Gardner,  Gilson,  Lusty  Scripps,  Vanguard,  1932. 

Gauvreau,  Emile,  My  Last  Million  Readers,  Button,  1941. 

Goldstrom,  John,  Narrative  History  of  Aviation,  Macmillan,  1930. 

Gramling,  Oliver,  A. P.:  the  Story  of  News,  Farrar  &  Rinehart,  1940. 

Hampton,  B.  B.,  History  of  the  Movies,  Covici,  Friede,  1931. 

Harley,  J.  E.,  World-Wide  Influence  of  the  Cinema,  University  of  Southern  Cali- 
fornia Press,  1942. 

Hawks,  Ellison,  Book  of  Electrical  Wonders,  Dial  Press,  1936. 

Hayakawa,  S.  L,  Language  in  Action,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1941. 

Hettinger,  H.  S.,  ed.,  New  Horizons  in  Radio,  The  Annals,  1941. 

Howe,  Quincy,  The  News  and  How  to  Understand  It,  Simon  &  Schuster,  1940. 

Hughes,  Hatcher,  What  Shocked  the  Censors,  American  Civil  Liberties  Union, 
1933. 

Hylander,  C.  T.  and  Harding,  Robert,  Introduction  to  Television,  Macmillan, 
1941. 

Ickes,  H.  L.,  America's  House  of  Lords,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1939. 

,  ed.,  Freedom  of  the  Press  Today,  Vanguard,  1941. 

Ireland,  Alleyne,  Adventures  with  a  Genius,  Dutton,  1937. 

Irwin,  Will,  Propaganda  and  the  News,  McGraw-Hill,  1936. 

Johnston,  S.  P.,  Horizons  Unlimited,  Duell,  Sloan  &  Pearce,  1941. 

Keezer,  D.  M.,  article  "Press,"  Encyclopaedia  of  the  Social  Sciences. 

Kocnigsberg,  M.,  King  News,  Stokes,  1942. 

Korzybski,  Alfred,  Science  and  Sanity  (new  ed.),  Science  Press,  1941. 

Laine,  Elizabeth,  Motion  Pictures  and  Radio,  McGraw-Hill,  1938. 

Lazarsfeld,  P.  F.,  Radio  and  the  Printed  Page,  Duell,  Sloan  &  Pearce,  1941. 

Lewis,  H.  T.,  articles  "Motion  Pictures"  and  "Radio,"  Encyclopaedia  of  the  Social 
Sciences. 

Lee,  A.  M.,  The  Daily  Newspaper  in  America,  Macmillan,  1937. 

Lee,  J.  M.,  History  of  American  Journalism,  Houghton  MifHin,  1933. 

Lee,  I.  J.,  Language  Habits  in  Human  Affairs,  Harper,  1941. 

Lundberg,  Ferdinand,  Imperial  Hearst,  Equinox,  1936. 

Lyons,  Eugene,  ed.,  We  Cover  the  World,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1937. 

MacDougall,  C.  D.,  Newsroom  Problems  and  Policies,  Macmillan,  1941. 

Mavity,  N.  B.,  The  Modern  Newspaper,  Holt,  1930. 

May,  M.  A.,  and  Shuttleworth,  Frank,  Relation  of  .Motion  Pictures  to  the  Char- 
acter and  Attitudes  of  Children,  Macmillan,  1933. 

,  Social  Conduct  and  Attitudes  of  Movie  Fans,  Macmillan,  1933. 

McEvoy,  J.  P.,  Are  You  Listening?  Houghton  Mifflin,  1932. 

McKelwey,  St.  Clair,  Gossip:  the  Life  and  Times  of  Walter  Winchell,  Viking, 
1940. 

Merz,  Charles,  And  then  Came  Ford,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1929. 

Morell,  Peter,  Poisons,  Potions  and  Profits:  the  Antidote  to  Radio  Advertising, 
Knight,  1937. 

Mott,  F.  L.,  History  of  American  Magazines,  3  Vols.,  Harvard  University  Press, 
1939. 

,  American  Journalism,  Macmillan,  1941. 

,  ed.,  Headlining  America,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1937. 

,  and  R.  D.  Casey,  eds.,  Interpretations  of  Journalism,  Grofts,  1937. 

Ogden,  C.  K.,  and  Richards,  I.  A.,  The  Meaning  of  Meaning,  Routledge,  1936. 

Page,  A.  W.,  et  aL,  Modern  Communication,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1932.     : ' 

Payne,  G.  H.,  History  of  Journalism  in  the  United  States,  Appleton-Century, 
1930.  '  , 


900  SELECTED  REFERENCES 

Pound,  Arthur,  The  Turning  Wheel,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1934. 

Regier,  C.  C.;  The  Era  of  the  Muckrakers,  University  of  North  Carolina  Press, 

1932. 

Rolo,  C.  J.,  Radio  Goes  to  War,  Putnam,  1942. 
Rose,  C.  B.,  National  Policy  for  Radio  Broadcasting,  Harper,  1940. 
Rosewater,  Victor,  History  of  Cooperative  Newsgathering  in  the  United  States, 

Appleton-Century,  1930. 

Rosten,  L.  C.,  The  Washington  Correspondents,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1937. 
,  Hollywood — the    Movie    Colony,    the    Movie    Makers,    Harcourt, 

Brace,  194L 

Rotha,  Paul,  The  Film  Till  Now,  Peter  Smith,  1931. 
Schechter,  A.  A.,  and  Anthony,  Edward,  /  Live  on  Air,  Stokes,  1941. 
Seitz,  D.  C.,  Joseph  Pulitzer,  Simon  &  Schuster,  1934. 
Seldes,  George,  Freedom  of  the  Press,  Bobbs-Merrill,  1935. 

,  Lords  of  the  Press,  Messner,  1939. 

Sinclair,  Upton  Sinclair  Presents  William  Fox. 

Smith,  H.  L.,  Airways,  Knopf,  1942. 

Squicr,  G.  W.,  Telling  the  World,  Williams  &  Wilkins,  1933. 

Summers,  H.  B.,  Radio  Censorship,  Wilson,  1939. 

Tassin,  A.  V.,  The  Magazine  in  America,  Dodd,  Mead,  1916. 

Terman,  F.  E.,  Radio  Engineering,  McGraw-Hill,  1932. 

Thompson,  J.  S.,  The  Mechanism  of  the  Linotype,  Inland  Printer  Co.,  1928. 

Villard,  O.  G.,  Fighting  Years,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1939. 

Waples,  Douglas,  ed.,  Print,  Radio  and  Film  in  a  Democracy,  University  of 

Chicago  Press,  1942. 

Walpole,  Hugh,  Semantics,  Norton,  1941. 

Webster,  H.  H.,  Travel  by  Air,  Land  and  Sea,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1934. 
Willey,  M.  M.  and  Casey,  R.  D.,  eds.,  The  Press  in  the  Contemporary  Scene, 

Annals  of  the  American  Academy,  1942. 
Willey,  M,  M.  and  Rice,  S.  A.,  "Communication,"  American  Journal  of  Sociology, 

May,  1931. 

,  Communication  Agencies  and  Social  Life,  McGraw-Hill,  1933. 

Willson,  Beckles,  Story  of  Rapid  Transit^  Appleton,  1903. 
Wood,  J.  W.,  Airports,  Coward-McCann,  1940. 

CHAPTER  14 

Albig,  Public  Opinion. 

Barnes,  H.  E.,  In  Quest  of  Truth  and  Justice,  National  Historical  Society,  1028. 

Bartlett,  F.  C.,  Political  Propaganda,  Cambridge  University  Press,  1940. 

Barzun,  Jacques,  Race:  A  Study  in  Modern  Superstition,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1937. 

Bates,  This  Land  of  Liberty. 

Bennett,  The  Essential  American  Tradition. 

Bent,  Silas,  Ballyhoo,  the  Voice  of  the  Press,  Boni  &  Liveright,  1927. 

Bernays,  E.  L.,  Crystallizing  Public  Opinion,  Liveright,  1934. 

,  Propaganda,  Liveright,  1928. 

Billington,  R.  A.  The  Protestant  Crusade,  1800-1860,  Macmillan,  1938. 

Black,  Ill-Starred  Prohibition  Cases. 

Brindze,  Not  to  Be  Broadcast. 

Brock,  H.  L,  Meddlers:  Uplifting  Moral  Uplifters,  Washburn,  1930. 

Broun,  Heywood,  and  Leech,  Margaret,  Anthony  Comstock,  Roundsman  of  the 

Lord,  Boni,  1927. 
Cantrill,  Hadley,  The  Invasion  from  Mars,  Princeton  University  Press,  1940. 


SELECTED   REFERENCES  901 

Childs,  Labor  and  Capital  in  National  Politics. 

,   ed.,   Propaganda   and  Dictatorship,   Princeton   University   Press, 

1936. 

-,  A  Reference  Guide  to  the  Study  of  Public  Opinion,  Princeton  Uni- 


versity Press,  1934. 

Clarke,  E.  L.,  The  Art  of  Straight  Thinking,  Appleton-Century,  1929. 

Clinchy,  E.  R.,  AU  in  the  Name  of  God,  Day,  1934. 

Creel,  George,  How  We  Advertised  America,  Harper,  1920. 

Davidson,  Philip,  Propaganda  in  the  American  Revolution,  1763—1783,  Uni- 
versity of  North  Carolina  Press,  1941. 

Dennett,  M.  W.,  Who's  Obscene?  Vanguard,  1930. 

Desmond,  R.  W.,  The  Press  and  World  Affairs,  Appleton-Century,  1937. 

Doob,  L.  W.,  Propaganda:  Its  Psychology  and  Technique,  Holt,  1935. 

Duffus,  R.  L.,  "Where  Do  We  Get  Our  Prejudices?"  Harper's  Magazine,  Sept., 
1936. 

Engclbrecht  and  Hanighen,  Merchants  of  Death. 

Ernst,  M.  L.,  and  Lindey,  Alexander,  Hold  Your  Tongue:  Adventures  in  Libel 
and  Slander,  Morrow,  1932. 

,  The  Censor  Marches  On. 

Ernst,  M.  L.,  and  Lorentz,  Pare,  Censored:  the  Private  Life  of  the  Movie,  Cape 
and  Smith,  1930. 

Ernst,  M.  L.,  and  Seagle,  William,  To  the  Pure;  a  Study  in  Obscenity  and  the 
Censor,  Viking,  1928. 

Freeman,  Ellis,  Conquering  the  Man  in  the  Street,  Vanguard,  1940. 

Garrison,  Intolerance. 

Graves,  W.  B.,  Readings  in  Public  Opinion,  Appleton,  1928. 

Gruening,  Ernest,  The  Public  Pays,  Vanguard,  1931. 

Hankins,  F.  H.,  The  Racial  Basis  of  Civilization,  Knopf,  1926. 

Hargreave,  John,  Words  Win  Wars,  Wells  Gardner,  Darton,  1940. 

Hays,  Let  Freedom  Ring. 

Herring,  Group  Representation  Before  Congress. 

Holmes,  R.  W.,  The  Rhyme  of  Reason,  Appleton-Century,  1939. 

Howe,  The  News  and  How  to  Understand  It. 

Huxley,  J.  S.,  and  Haddon,  A.  C.,  We  Europeans,  Harper,  1936. 

Irwin,  Propaganda  and  the  News. 

Jastrow,  Joseph,  The  Betrayal  of  Intelligence:  A  Preface  to  Debunking,  Green- 
berg,  1938. 

Johnston,  H.  A.,  What  Rights  Are  Left,  Macmillan,  1930. 

Keith,  Arthur,  The  Place  of  Prejudice  in  Modern  Civilization,  Day,  1931. 

Key,  Politics,  Parties  and  Pressure  Groups. 

Larson,  Cedric,  Official  Information  for  America  at  War,  Rudge,  1942. 

Lass  well,  H.  D.,  Propaganda  Technique  in  the  World  War,  Peter  Smith,  1938. 

,  Democracy  through  Public  Opinion,  Banta,  1941. 

,  and  Blumenstock,  D.,  World  Revolutionary  Propaganda,  Knopf, 

1939. 

Lavine,  Harold  and  Wechsler,  James,  War  Propaganda  and  the  United  States, 
Yale  University  Press,  1940. 

Lee,  Ivy,  Publicity,  Industries  Publishing  Co.,  1925. 

Lee,  A.  M.,  The  Fine  Art  of  Propaganda,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1940. 

Levin,  Jack,  Power  Ethics,  Knopf,  1931. 

Lippmann,  Walter,  Public  Opinion,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1922. 

,  American  Inquisitors,  Macmillan,  1928. 

Long,  J.  C.,  Public  Relations,  McGraw-Hill,  1925. 


902  SELECTED  REFERENCES 

Lumley,  Means  of  Social  Control. 

,  The  Propaganda  Menace,  Appleton-Century,  1925. 

Lundberg,  George,  Social  Research,  Longmans,  1929. 

McCormick,  R.  R.,  The  Freedom  of  the  Press,  Appleton-Century,  1936. 

Mercer,  F.  A.,  and  Fraser,  G,  L.,  eds.,  Modern  Publicity  in  War,  Studio  Publi- 
cations, 194L 

Mcrriam,  C.  E.,  The  Making  of  Citizens,  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1931. 

Michael,  George,  Handout,  Putnam,  1935. 

Mock,  J.  R.,  Censorship,  1917,  Princeton  University  Press,  1941. 

,  and  Larson,  Cedric,  Words  That  Won  the  War,  Princeton  Uni- 
versity Press,  1939. 

Munson,  Gorham,  Twelve  Decisive  Battles  of  the  Mind,  Greystone  Press,  1942. 

Nevins,  Allan,  ed.,  American  Press  Opinion,  Heath,  1928. 

Noel-Baker,  Philip,  The  Private  Manufacture  of  Armaments,  Oxford,  1937. 

Norton,  Loosing  Liberty  Judicially. 

Odegard,  P.  H.,  Pressure  Politics,  Knopf,  1928. 

,  The  American  Public  Mind,  Columbia  University  Press,  1930. 

O'Higgins,  Harvey,  The  American  Mind  in  Action,  Harper,  1924. 

Parshley,  H.  M.,  Science  and  Good  Behavior,  Bobbs-Mcrrill,  1928. 

Pierce,  B.  L.,  Public  Opinion  and  the  Teaching  of  History,  Knopf,  1926. 

Peterson,  H.  C.,  Propaganda  for  War,  University  of  Oklahoma  Press,  1939. 

Playrie,  C.  E.,  Society  at  War,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1931. 

Ponsonby,  Arthur,  Falsehood  in  Wartime,  Dutton,  1929. 

Post,  Louis,  The  Deportations  Delirium,  Kerr,  1923. 

Read,  J.  M.,  Atrocity  Propaganda,  1914-1919,  Yale  University  Press,  1941. 

Riegel,  Mobilizing  for  Chaos. 

Rorty,  Our  Master's  Voice. 

Rosten,  The  Washington  Correspondents. 

Russell,  Bertrand,  Free  Thought  and  Official  Propaganda,  Viking,  1922. 

Sargent,  Porter,  Getting  US  into  War,  Sargent,  1941. 

Scott,  J.  F.  Patriots  in  the  Making,  Appleton-Century,  1916. 

The  Menace  of  Nationalism  in  Education,  Macmillan,  1926. 


Seldes,  George,  You  Can't  Print  That,  Payson  and  Clarke,  1929. 
Iron,  Blood  and  Profits. 
Freedom  of  the  Press. 
You  Can't  Do  That. 
Lords  of  the  Press. 
Witch  Hunt,  Modern  Age,  1941. 


Samuel,  Maurice,  Jews  on  Approval,  Liveright,  1932. 

Sanger,  Margaret,  My  Fight  for  Birth  Control,  Farrar  &  Rinehart,  1931. 

Shipley,  Maynard,  The  War  on  Modern  Science,  Knopf,  1927. 

Smith,  C.  W.,  Public  Opinion  in  a  Democracy,  Prentice-Hall,  1942. 

Soule,  The  Future  of  Liberty. 

Starr,  Mark,  Lies  and  Hate  in  Education,  Hogarth,  1929. 

Sumner,  Folkways. 

Tenenbaum,  Joseph,  Races,  Nations  and  Jews,  Bloch,  1934. 

Thompson,  C.  D.,  Confessions  of  the  Power  Trust,  Dutton,  1932. 

Throop,  P.  A.,  Criticism  of  the  Crusade:  A  Study  of  Public  Opinion  and  Crusade 

Propaganda,  Swets  &  JZeitlinger,  1940. 
Valentin,  Hugo,  Anti-Semitism,  Historically  and  Critically  Examined,  Viking, 

1936. 
Van  Loon,  Hendrik,  Tolerance,  Boni  &  Liveright,  1925. 


SELECTED  REFERENCES  903 

Viereck,  G.  S.,  Spreading  Germs  of  Hate,  Liveright,  1930. 

Walker,  S.  H.,  and  Sklar,  Paul,  "Business  Finds  Its  Voice,"  Harper's  Magazine, 

January-March,  1938. 
Whipple,  Our  Ancient  Liberties. 

,  The  Story  of  Civil  Liberty  in  the  United  States. 

White,  Walter,  Rope  and  Faggot,  Knopf,  1928. 

Willis,  I.  C.,  England's  Holy  War,  Knopf,  1928. 

Wolf,  Lucien,  The  Myth  of  the  Jewish  Menace  in  World  Affairs,  Macmillan,  1921. 

Wolfe,  A.  B.,  Conservatism,  Radicalism  and  Scientific  Method,  Macmillan,  1923. 

Wood,  Mary,  The  Stranger,  Columbia  University  Press,  1934. 

Woodward,  Helen,  It's  An  Art,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1938. 

Young,  E.  J.,  Looking  Behind  the  Censorships,  Lippincott,  1938. 

Young,  Kimball,  Bibliography  for  Propaganda  and  Censorship,  University  of 

Oregon  Press,  1928. 

CHAPTER  15 

Abbott,  Edith,  Women  in  Industry,  Appleton,  1910. 

Apstein,  T.  E.,  The  Parting  of  the  Ways,  Dodge,  1935. 

Baber,  R.  E.,  Marriage  and  the  Family,  McGraw-Hill,  1939. 

Bartlett,  George  A.,  Men,  Women  &  Conflict,  Putnam,  1932. 

Beard,  Mary,  Woman:  Co-maker  of  History,  Longmans,  1940. 

Bernard,  Jessie,  American  Family  Behavior,  Harper,  1942. 

Binkley,  R.  C.,  What  Is  Right  With  Marriage,  Appleton-Century,  1929. 

Bowman,  H.  A.,  Marriage  for  Moderns,  McGraw-Hill,  1942. 

Briffault,  Robert,  The  Mothers,  3  Vols.,  Macmillan,  1927. 

Burgess,  E.  W.,  and  Cottrell,  L.  S.,  Predicting  Success  or  Failure  in  Marriage, 
Prentice-Hall,  1940. 

Butterfield,  Oliver,  Sex  Life  in  Marriage,  Emerson  Books,  1937. 

Calhoun,  A.  W.,  A  Social  History  of  the  American  Family,  Clark,  1917. 

Calverton,  V.  F.,  The  Bankruptcy  of  Marriage,  Macaulay,  1928. 

Cavan,  R.  S.,  The  Family,  Crowell,  1942. 

Colcord,  J.  S.,  article,  "Family  Desertion,"  Encyclopaedia  of  the  Social  Sciences. 

,  Broken  Homes,  Russell  Sage  Foundation,  1919. 

Davis,  K.  B.,  Factors  in  the  Sex  Life  of  2,200  Women,  Harper,  1921. 

Dickinson,  R.  L.,  and  Beam,  Laura,  The  Single  Woman,  Williams  &  Wilkins, 
1934. 

Elmer,  M.  C.,  Family  Adjustment  and  Social  Change,  Long  &  Smith,  1932. 

Fiske,  G.  W.,  The  Changing  Family,  Harper,  1928. 

Goodsell,  Willystine,  History  of  the  Family  as  a  Social  and  Educational  Institu- 
tion, Macmillan,  1915. 

— • • ,  Problems  of  the  Family,  Appleton-Century,  1928. 

Groves,  E.  R.,  Social  Problems  of  the  Family,  Lippincott,  1927. 

,  The  Marriage  Crisis,  Longmans,  Green,  1928. 

,  Wholesome  Marriage,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1927. 

,  Marriage,  Holt,  1933. 

,  Sex  in  Marriage,  Emerson  Books,  1940. 

,  The  American  Woman,  Greenberg,  1936. 

,  and  Ogburn,  W.  F.,  American  Marriage  and  Family  Relationships, 

Holt,  1928. 

Groves,  G.  H.,  and  Ross,  R.  A.,  The  Married  Woman,  Blue  Ribbon  Books,  1939. 

Gwynne,  W.,,  Divorce  in  America  under  State  and  Church,  Macmillan,  1925. 


904  SELECTED   REFERENCES 

Hamilton,  G.  V.,  A  Research  in  Marriage,  Boni,  1929. 

• ,  and  Macgowan,  Kenneth,  W hat  Is  Wrong  With  Marriage,  Boni, 

1929. 

Hankins,  F.  H.,  "Divorce/'  Encyclopaedia  of  the  Social  Sciences.  "Illegitimacy," 
Ibid. 

Hayden,  J,  F.,  The  Art  of  Marriage,  Union  Library  Association,  1938. 

Holmes,  J.  H.,  Marriage  and  Divorce,  Huebsch,  1913. 

Howard,  G.  E.,  A  History  of  Matrimonial  Institutions,  3  Vols.,  University  of 
Chicago  Press,  1904. 

llutchiris,  Grace,  Women  Who  Work,  International  Publishers,  1934. 

Jung,  Moses,  Modern  Marriage,  Crofts,  1940. 

Keczer,  F.  II.,  A  Treatise  on  the  Law  of  Marriage  and  Divorce,  Bebbs-Merrill, 
1923. 

Kitchin,  S.  B.,  A  History  of  Divorce,  London,  1912. 

Knox,  S.  T.,  The  Family  and  the  Law,  University  of  North  Carolina  Press,  1941. 

LaFollette,  Suzanne,  Concerning  Women,  Boni,  1926. 

Levy,  John,  and  Munroe,  Ruth,  The  Happy  Family,  Knopf,  1940. 

Lichtenberger,  J.  P.,  Divorce,  McGraw-Hill,  193L 

Lindsey,  Cornpanionate  Marriage. 

Mangold,  G.  B,,  Children  Born  Out  of  Wedlock,  University  of  Missouri  Press, 
1921. 

May,  Geoffrey,  Marriage  Laws  and  Decisions  in  the  United  States,  Russell  Sage 
Foundation,  1929. 

Mencken,  H.  L.,  In  Defense  of  Women,  Garden  City  Pub.  Co.,  1931. 

Messer,  M.  B.,  The  Family  in  the  Making,  Putnam,  1925. 

Morgan,  W.  L.,  The  Family  Meets  the  Depression,  University  of  Minnesota 
Press,  1939. 

Mowrer,  E.  R.,  Family  Disorganization,  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1927. 

• ,  Domestic  Discord,  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1928. 

Muller-Lyer,  Franz,  The  Evolution  of  Modern  Marriage,  Knopf,  1930. 

Neumann,  Henry,  Modern  Youth  and  Marriage,  Appleton,  1928. 

Nimkoff,  M.  F.,  The  Family,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1934. 

Oglesby,  Catharine,  Business  Opportunities  for  Women,  Harper,  1937. 

Popenoe,  Paul,  Conservation  of  the  Family,  Williams  &  Wilkins,  1926. 

Pruette,  Lorine,  Women  Workers  Through  the  Depression,  Macmillan,  1934. 

Reed,  Ruth,  The  Modern  Family,  Crofts,  1929. 

Renter,  E.  B.,  and  Runner,  J.  R.,  The  Family,  McGraw-Hill,  1931. 

Russell,  Bertrand,  Marriage  and  Morals,  Liveright,  1929. 

,  Divorce,  Day,  1930. 

Schneider,  D.  M.,  and  Deutsch,  Albert,  History  of  Public  Welfare  in  New  York 
State,  1867-1940,  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1941. 

Sellin,  J.  T.,  Marriage  and  Divorce  Legislation  in  Sweden,  University  of  Minne- 
sota Press,  1922. 

Stekel,  Wilhelm,  Marriage  at  the  Crossroads,  Godwin,  1931. 

Stern,  B.  J.,  The  Family,  Past  and  Present,  Appleton-Century,  1938. 

Stone,  Hannah  and  Abraham,  Marriage  Manual,  Simon  &  Schuster,  1935. 

Stouffer,  S.  A.,  and  Lazarsfeld,  P.  F.,  Research  Memorandum  on  the  Family  in 
the  Depression,  Social  Science  Research  Council,  1937. 

Thomas,  W.  L,  The  Unadjusted  Girl,  Little,  Brown,  1923. 

,  The  Child  in  America,  1928. 

Tietz,  E.  B.,  and  Weichert,  C.  Kv  The  Art  and  Science  of  Marriage,  McGraw- 
Hill,  1938. 


SELECTED   REFERENCES  905 

Van  der  Welde,  T.  H.,  Ideal  Marriage,  Covici,  Freide,  1930. 
Waller,  Willard,  The  Family,  Cordon,  1938. 

Westermarck,  Edward,  A  History  of  Human  Marriage,  3  Vols.,  Macmillan,  1921. 
Wile,  I.  S.,  et  al.,  Sex  Life  of  the  Unmarried  Adult,  Vanguard,  1934. 
Winter,  Ella,  Red  Virtue,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1933. 

Zimmerman,  C.  C.,  and  Frampton,  M.  E.,  Family  and  Society,  Van  Nostrand, 
1935. 

CHAPTER  16 

Apstein,  The  Parting  of  the  Ways. 

Blumenthal,  Albert,  Small-Town  Stuff,  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1932. 

Bossard,  Social  Change  and  Social  Problems. 

Burr,  Walter,  Rural  Organization,  Macmillan,  1921. 

Cavan,  R.  S.,  and  Ranck,  K.  H.,  The  Family  and  the  Depression,  University  of 

Chicago  Press,  1938. 

Clarke,  I.  C.,  The  Little  Democracy,  Appleton-Century,  1918. 
Colcord,  Broken  Homes. 

,  Your  Community,  Russell  Sage  Foundation,  1939. 

Cook,  L.  A.,  The  Community  Background  of  Education,  McGraw-Hill,  1938. 
DeSchweinitz,  Karl,   The  Art  of  Helping  People  Out  of   Trouble,  Houghton 

Mifflin,  1924. 

Elliott,  M.  A.,  and  Merrill,  F.  E.,  Social  Disorganization,  Harper,  1941. 
Engelhardt,  N.  L.,  Planning  the  Community  School,  American  Book  Company, 

1940. 

Gilbert,  G.  B.,  The  Country  Preacher,  Harper,  1940. 
Goodsell,  Willystine,  Problems  of  the  Family,  Appleton-Century,  1936. 
Hart,  Hastings  and  E.  B.,  Personality  and  the  Family,  Heath,  1935. 
Hart,  J.  K.,  Community  Organization,  Macmillan,  1920. 
Hayes,  A.  W.,  Rural  Community  Organization,  University  of  Chicago  Press, 

1921. 

Hertzler,  A.  E.,  The  Horse  and  Buggy  Doctor,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1939. 
Lee,  Joseph,  Play  in  Education,  Macmillan,  1915. 
Lichtenberger,  Divorce. 

Lindeman,  E.  C.,  The  Community,  Association  Press,  1921. 
Lumpkin,  K.  D.,  The  Family,  University  of  North  Carolina  Press,  1933. 
Lutes,  D.  T.,  The  Country  Kitchen,  Little,  Brown,  1936. 

,  Home  Grown,  Little,  Brown,  1938. 

,  Country  Schoolma'am,  Little,  Brown,  1941. 

McClenahan,  B.  A.,  Organizing  the  Community,  Appleton-Century,  1922. 
,  The  Changing  Urban  Neighborhood,  University  of  Southern  Cali- 
fornia Press,  1929. 
Mowrer,  Family  Disorganization. 

,  Disorganization:  Personal  and  Social,  Lippincott,  1942. 

Osborn,  L.  D.,  Community  and  Society,  American  Book  Company,  1933. 
Partridge,  Country  Lawyer. 

Phillips,  W.  C.,  Adventuring  for  Democracy,  Social  Unit  Press,  1940. 
Queen,  S.  A.,  et  al,  Social  Organization  and  Disorganization,  Crowell,  1935. 
Rainwater,  C.  E.,  Community  Organization,  University  of  Southern  California 

Press,  1920. 
,  The  Play  Movement  in  the  United  States,  University  of  Chicago 

Press,  1922. 


906  SELECTED   REFERENCES 

Sanderson,  D.  L.,  The  Rural  Community,  Ginn,  1932. 
Shaler,  N.  S.,  The  Neighbor,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1904. 
Sorokin,  P.  A.,  and  Zimmerman,  C.  C.,  Principles  of  Rural-Urban  Sociology, 

Holt,  1929. 
Steiner,  J.  F.,  The  American  Community  in  Action,  Appleton-Century,  1928. 

,  Community  Organization,  Appleton-Century,  1930. 

,  America  at  Play,  McGraw-Hill,  1933. 

Stern,  The  Family,  Past  and  Present. 

Taylor,  C.  C.,  Rural  Sociology,  Harper,  1933. 

Terpenning,    Walter,     Village    and    Open-country    Neighborhoods,    Appleton- 

Ccntury,  1931. 

Ward,  E.  J.,  The  Social  Center,  Appleton-Century,  1913. 
Warner,  W.  L.,  and  Lunt,  P.  S.,  The  Social  Life  of  a  Modern  Community,  Yale 

University  Press,  1941. 

Wood,  A.  E.,  Community  Problems,  Appleton-Century,  1928. 
Woods,  R.  A.,  The  Neighborhood  in  Nation  Building,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1923. 
Zimmerman,  C.  C.,  The  Changing  Community,  Harper,  1938. 

CHAPTER  17 

Aubrey,  E.  A.,  Present  Theological  Tendencies,  Harper,  1936. 

Barbour,  C.  E.,  Sin  and  the  New  Psychology,  Abingdon  Press,  1930. 

Barnes,  H.  E.,  Intellectual  and  Cultural  History  of  the  Western  World,  Reynal 
and  Hitchcock,  1941. 

,    The  Twilight  of  Christianity. 

Betts,  The  Beliefs  of  Seven  Hundred  Ministers. 

Braden,  C.  S.,  Varieties  of  American  Religion,  Willett,  Clark,  1936. 

Briffault,  Robert,  Sin  and  Sex,  Macaulay,  1931. 

Browne,  Lewis,  This  Believing  World,  Macmillan,  1927. 

Burtt,  E.  A.,  Religion  in  an  Age  of  Science,  Stokes,  1929. 

,  Types  of  Religious  Philosophy,  Harper,  1939. 

Calverton,  V,  F.,  The  Passing  of  the  Gods,  Scribner,  1934. 

Cantril,  Hadley,  The  Psychology  of  Social  Movements,  Wiley,  1941. 

ChafTee,  E.  B.,  The  Protestant  Churches  and  the  Industrial  Crisis,  Macmillan, 
1933. 

Cooper,  C.  C.,  ed.,  Religion  and  the  Modern  Mind,  Harper,  1929. 

Darnell,  T.  W.,  After  Christianity— What  f  Brewer  and  Warren,  1930. 

Douglass,  H.  P.,  and  Brunner,  E.  S.,  The  Protestant  Church  as  a  Social  Institu- 
tion, Harper,  1935. 

Drake,  Durant,  The  New  Morality,  Macmillan,  1928. 

Ellwood,  C.  A.>  The  Reconstruction  of  Religion,  Macmillan,  1922. 

Ferm,  V.  T.  A.,  Contemporary  American  Theology,  Round  Table  Press,  1932. 

Flower,  J.  C.,  An  Approach  to  the  Psychology  of  Religion,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1927. 

Fosdick,  H.  E.,  As  I  See  Religion,  Harper,  1932. 

Friess,  H.  L.,  and  Schneider,  H.  L.,  Religion  in  Various  Cultures,  Holt,  1932. 

Givler,  R.  C.,  The  Ethics  of  Hercules,  Knopf,  1922. 

Haydon,  A.  E.,  Biography  of  the  Gods,  Macmillan,  1940. 

Hobhouse,  L.  T.,  Morals  in  Evolution,  Holt,  1915. 

Kallen,  H.  M.,  Why  Religion?    Boni  &  Liveright,  1927. 

Kirkpatrick,  Clifford,  Religion  in  Human  Affairs,  Wiley,  1929. 

Kirchwey,  Freda,  ed.,  Our  Changing  Morality,  Boni,  1924. 

Lake,  Kirsopp,  The  Religion  of  Yesterday  and  Tomorrow,  Houghton  Mifflin, 
1925. 


SELECTED  REFERENCES  907 

Lament,  Corliss,  The  Illusion  of  Immortality,  Putnam,  1935. 

Leuba,  J.  H.,  God  or  Man?  Holt,  1933. 

Levy,  Hyman,  The  Universe  of  Science,  Appleton-Century,  1933. 

Lippmann,  Walter,  A  Preface  to  Morals,  Macmillan,  1929. 

Lowie,  R.  H.,  Primitive  Religion,  Boni  &  Liveright,  1924. 

Martin,  E.  D.,  The  Mystery  of  Religion,  Harper,  1924. 

May,  M.  A.,  Studies  in  the  Nature  of  Character,  Macmillan,  1928. 

Maynard,  Theodore,  The  Story  of  American  Catholicism,  Macmillan,  1941. 

McGiffert,  A.  C.,  History  of  Christian  Thought,  2  Vols.,  Scribner,  1932. 

,  Protestant  Thought  Before  Kant,  Scribner,  1915. 

Myers,  P.  V.  N.,  History  as  Past  Ethics,  Ginn,  1913. 
O'Toole,  G.  B.,  The  Case  Against  Evolution,  Macmillan,  1925. 
Parshley,  H.  N.,  Science  and  Good  Behavior,  Bobbs-Merrill,  1928. 
Potter,  C.  F.,  Humanism,  Simon  &  Schuster,  1930. 

,  Humanizing  Religion,  Harper,  1933. 

Radin,  Paul,  Primitive  Religion,  Viking,  1937. 

Randall,  J.  H.,  and  J.  H.,  Jr.,  Religion  and  the  Modern  World,  Stokes,  1929. 

Reese,  C.  W.,  Humanist  Sermons,  Open  Court,  1927. 

Rice,  W.  N.,  Christian  Faith  in  an  Age  of  Science,  Doran,  1903. 

Robinson,  The  Human  Comedy. 

Rogers,  A.  K.,  Morals  in  Review,  Macmillan,  1927. 

Russell,  Bcrtrand,  Religion  and  Science,  Holt,  1935. 

Russell,  Dora,  The  Right  to  Be  Happy,  Harper,  1927. 

Shapley,  Harlow,  Flights  from  Chaos,  McGraw-Hill,  1930. 

Shipley,  The  War  on  Modern  Science. 

Shotwell,  J.  T.,  The  Religious  Revolution  of  Today,  Iloughton  Mifflin,  1915. 

Sumner,  Folkways. 

Trattncr,  E.  R.,  Unraveling  the  Book  of  Books,  Scribner,  1929. 

Tufts,  J.  H.,  America's  Social  Morality,  Holt,  1933. 

Wallis,  W.  D.,  Religion  in  Primitive  Society,  Crofts,  1939. 

Ward,  H.  F.,  Which  Way  Religion?  Macmillan,  1931. 

Williams,  Michael,  and  Kernan,  Julia,  The  Catholic  in  Action,  Macmillan,  1934. 


CHAPTER  18 

Beale,  H.  K.,  Are  American  Teachers  Freef  Scribners,  1936. 

Buchholz,  H.  E.,  Fads  and  Fallacies  in  Present-day  Education,  Macmillan,  1931. 

Burnham,  W.  H.,  The  Great  Teachers  and  Mental  Health,  Appleton,  1926. 

Butts,  R.  F.,  The  College  Charts  Its  Course,  McGraw-Hill,  1939. 

Coe,  G.  A.,  Educating  for  Citizenship,  Scribner,  1932. 

Coon,  Money  to  Burn. 

Corbally,  J.  E.,  and  Bolton,  F.  E.  Educational  Sociology,  American  Book  Com- 
pany, 1941. 

Counts,  G.  S.,  The  American  Road  to  Culture,  Day,  1930. 

,  The  Social  Foundations  of  Education,  Scribner,  1934. 

,  The  Prospects  of  American  Democracy. 

< ,  The  Schools  Can  Teach  Democracy. 

Curti,  M.  E.,  The  Social  Ideals  of  American  Education,  Scribner,  1935. 

Douglass,  H.  R.,  Secondary  Education  for  Youth  in  America,  National  Council 
on  Education,  1937. 


908  SELECTED  REFERENCES 

Eby,  Frederick,  and  Arrowwood,  C.  F.,  The  History  and  Philosophy  of  Educa- 
tion, Ancient  and  Medieval,  Prentice-Hall,  1940. 

,  The  Development  of  Modern  Education,  Prentice-Hall,  1937. 

Elsbree,  W.  S.,  The  American  Teacher,  American  Book  Company,  1939. 

Ely,  Mary,  ed.,  Adult  Education  in  Action,  Am.  Assoc.  for  Adult  Education,  1936. 

GeUermari,  William,  The  American  Legion  as  Educator,  Teachers  College  Publi- 
cations, 1938. 

Gulick,  L.  H.,  Education  for  American  Life,  McGraw-Hill,  1938. 

llambidge,  Gove,  New  Aims  in  Education,  McGraw-Hill,  1940. 

Hansome,  Marius,  World  Workers  Education  Movements,  Columbia  University 
Press,  1931. 

Hewitt,  Dorothy,  and  Mather,  K.  F.,  Adult  Education,  Appleton-Century,  1937. 

Hollis,  E.  V.,  Philanthropic  Foundations  and  Higher  Education,  Columbia  Uni- 
versity Press,  1938. 

Judd,  C.  H.,  Education  and  Social  Progress,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1934. 

Kallen,  H.  M.,  Education,  the  Machine  and  the  Worker,  New  Republic  Press, 
1925. 

Keppel,  F.  P,,  Education  for  Adults,  Columbia  University  Press,  1926. 

,  Philanthropy  and  Learning,  Columbia  University  Press,  1936. 

,  The  Foundation,  Macmillan,  1930. 

Kilpatrick,  W.  H.,  et  al,  The  Educational  Frontier,  1933. 

Langford,  H.  D.,  Education  and  the  Social  Conflict,  Macmillan,  1936. 

Leary,  D.  B.,  Living  and  Learning,  Smith,  1931. 

Lindeman,  E.  C.,  Social  Education,  New  Republic  Press,  1933. 

Lynd,  Knowledge  for  What? 

Mailer,  J.  B.,  School  and  Community,  McGraw-Hill,  1938. 

Martin,  E.  D.,  The  Meaning  of  a  Liberal  Education,  Norton,  1926. 

McConn,  C.  M.,  College  or  Kindergarten?  New  Republic  Press,  1928. 

Meiklejohn,  Alexander,  The  Experimental  College,  Harper,  1932. 

Melvin,  A.  G.,  The  Technique  of  Progressive  Teaching,  Day,  1932. 

Morgan,  J.  E.,  Horace  Mann,  National  Home  Library,  1936. 

,  The  Life  of  Horace  Mann,  National  Education  Association,  1937. 

Mort,  P.  R.,  American  Schools  in  Transition,  Teachers  College,  1941. 

Myers,  A.  F.,  and  Williams,  C.  0.,  Education  in  a  Democracy  (with  revisions), 
Prentice-Hall,  1942. 

Newlon,  J.  H.,  Education  for  Democracy  in  Our  Time,  McGraw-Hill,  1939. 

.Norton,  T.  L.,  Education  for  Work,  McGraw-Hill,  1938. 

Osborne,  A.  E.,  An  Alternative  for  Revolution  and  War,  Educational  Screen,  1939. 

Pressey,  S.  L.,  Psychology  and  the  New  Education,  Harper,  1933. 

Raup,  Bruce,  Education  and  Organized  Interests  in  America,  Putnam,  1936. 

Rugg,  Harold,  Culture  and  Education  in  America,  Harper,  1935. 

,  That  Men  May  Understand,  Doubleday,  Doran,  1941. 

Russell,  Bertrand,  Education  and  the  Modern  World,  Norton,  1932. 

Schmalhausen,  S.  D.,  Humanizing  Education,  New  Education  Press,  1926. 

Sinclair,  Upton,  The  Goose-step,  Sinclair,  1923. 

Smith,  Harvey,  The  Gang's  All  Here,  Princeton  University  Press,  1941. 

Snedden,  David,  What's  Wrong  with  American  Education?  Lippincott,  1927. 

Spaulding,  Francis,  The  High  School  and  Life,  McGraw-Hill,  1938. 

Tugwell,  R.  G.,  and  Keyserling,  L.  H.,  eds.,  Redirecting  Education,  2  Vols., 
Columbia  University  Press,  1934. 

Tunis,  J.  R.,  Was  College  Worth  While?  Harcourt,  Brace,  1936. 

Tuttle,  H.  S.,  A  Social  Basis  of  Education,  Crowe!!,  1934. 


SELECTED   REFERENCES  909 

Waller,  Willard,  The  Sociology  of  Teaching,  John  Wiley  &  Sons,  Inc.,  1932. 
Washburne,  Carleton,  Remakers  of  Mankind,  Day,  1932. 
Wo<fdy,  Thomas,  New  Minds,  New  Men,  Macmillan,  1932. 


CHAPTER  19 

Appleton,  L.  E.,  A  Comparative  Study  of  the  Play  Activities  of  Adult  Savages 

and  Civilized  Children,  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1910. 
Barnes,  Can  Man  Be  Civilized? 

Barzun,  Jacques,  Of  Human  Freedom,  Little,  Brown,  1939. 
Bekker,  Paul,  The  Story  of  Music,  Norton,  1927. 

Bemis,  A.  F.,  and  Burchard,  John,  The  Evolving  House,  Technology  Press,  1933. 
Burns,  C.  D.,  Leisure  in  the  Modern  World,  Appleton-Century,  1932. 
Cheney,  Sheldon,  The  Theatre,  Longmans,  1929. 

— ,  The  Story  of  Modern  Art,  Viking  Press,  1941. 

Craven,  Thomas,  Men  of  Art,  Simon  &  Schuster,  1931. 

,  Modern  Art,  Simon  &  Schuster,  1934. 

De  Rougemont,  Denis,  Love  in  the  Western  World,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1940. 

Dulles,  F.  R.,  America  Learns  to  Play,  Appleton-Century,  1940. 

Elson,  Arthur,  The  Book  of  Musical  Knowledge,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1927. 

Ewen,  David,  Music  Comes  to  America,  Crowell,  1942. 

Faulkner,  Ray,  Ziegfield,  Edwin  and  Hill,  Gerald,  Art  Today,  Holt,  1941. 

Faure,  Elie,  Ancient  Art,  Harper,  1921. 

Feldman,  H.  A.,  Music  and  the  Listener,  Norton,  1940. 

Gardner,  Helen,  Art  Through  the  Ages,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1926. 

Gassner,  John,  Masters  of  the  Drama,  Random  House,  1940. 

Giedion,  Sigfried,  Space,  Time  and  Architecture,  Harvard  University  Press,  1941. 

Gilbert,  K.  E.,  and  Kuhn,  Helmut,  A  History  of  Aesthetics,  Macmillan,  1939. 

Gray,  Cecil,  The  History  of  Music,  Knopf,  1928. 

Greenbie,  M.  B.,  The  Arts  of  Leisure,  McGraw-Hill,  1937. 

Groos,  Karl,  The  Play  of  Animals,  Appleton-Century,  1898. 

,  The  Play  of  Man,  Appleton-Century,  1901. 

Grousset,  Rene,  Civilizations  of  the  East,  3  Vols.,  Knopf,  1941. 

Hambidge,  Gove,  Time  to  Live,  McGraw-Hill,  1933. 

Hamlin,  A.  D.  F.,  History  of  Architecture,  Longmans,  1925. 

Harrison,  Jane,  Ancient  Art  and  Ritual,  Holt,  1913. 

Hitchcock,  H.  R.,  In  the  Nature  of  Materials,  Duell,  Sloan  &  Pearce,  1942. 

Hoffman,  Malvina,  Sculpture,  Inside  Out,  Norton,  1939. 

Howard,  J.  T.,  Our  Contemporary  Composers,  Crowell,  1941. 

Jacks,  L.  P.,  The  Education  of  the  Whole  Man,  Harper,  1933. 

Johnson,  Philip,  Machine  Art,  Norton,  1934. 

Keppel,  F.  P.,  and  Duffus,  R.  L.,  The  Arts  in  American  Life,  McGraw-Hill,  1933. 

Kieran,  John,  and  Golinkin,  J.  W.,  The  American  Sporting  Scene,  Macmillan,  1941. 

Krout,  J.  A.,  Annals  of  American  Sport,  Yale  University  Press,  1929. 

Lang,  Music  in  Western  Civilization. 

Lee,  Play  in  Education. 

Loeb,  Life  in  a  Technocracy. 

Lundberg  (F),  America's  Sixty  Families. 

Lundberg,  G.  A.,  Leisure:  A  Suburban  Study,  Columbia  University  Press,  1934. 

Marquand,  Allan  and  Frothingham,  A.  L.,  History  of  Sculpturet  Longmans,  1912. 

McMahon,  A.  P.,  The  Art  of  Enjoying  Art,  McGraw-Hill,  1938. 


910  SELECTED  REFERENCES 

Maurois,  Andre,  The  Art  of  Living,  Harper,  1940. 

Nash,  J.  B.,  Organization  and  Administration  of  Playgrounds,  Barnes,  1927. 
,  Spectatoritis,  Sears,  1932.  * 

Nef,  Karl,  An  Outline  of  the  History  of  Music,  Columbia  University  Press,  1935. 
Orton,  W.  A.,  America  in  Search  of  Culture,  Little,  Brown,  1933. 
Overmyer,  Grace,  Government  and  the  Arts,  Norton,  1939. 
Pack,  A.  N.,  The  Challenge  of  Leisure,  Macmillan,  1934. 
Patrick,  G.  T.  W.,  The  Psychology  of  Relaxation,  Houghton  Mifflin,  1916. 
Rainwater,  The  Play  Movement  in  the  United  States. 
Read,  H.  E.,  Art  and  Industry,  Hurcourt,  Brace,  1935. 
Reinach,  Solomon,  Apollo,  Scribner,  1914. 

Rice,  E.  A.,  A  Brief  History  of  Physical  Education,  Barnes,  1926. 
Ruckstull,  F.  W.,  Great  Works  of  Art,  Garden  City,  1925. 
Saint-Gaudens,  Homer,  The  American  Artist  and  His  Times,  Dodd,  Mead,  1941. 
Steiner,  J.  F.,  America  at  Play,  McGraw-Hill,  1933. 
Tallmadge,  T.  E.,  The  Story  of  Architecture  in  America,  Norton,  1927. 
Terry,  Walter,  Invitation  to  Dance,  Barnes,  1942. 
Tomans,  A.  S.,  Introduction  to  the  Sociology  of  Art,  Columbia  University  Press, 

1941. 

Van  Dyke,  J.  C.,  History  of  Painting,  Longmans,  1915. 
Venturi,  Lionello,  Art  Criticism  Now,  Johns  Hopkins  Press,  1942. 
Waterhouse,  P.  L.,  The  Story  of  Building,  Appleton-Century,  1927. 
Welch,  R.  D.,  The  Study  of  Music  in  the  American  College,  Smith  College  Press, 

1925. 

Whitaker,  C.  H.,  The  Story  of  Architecture,  Halcyon  House,  1934. 
Wren,  C.  G.,  and  Harley,  D.  L.,  Time  on  Their  Hands,  National  Council  on 

Education,  1941. 

Wright,  F.  L.,  Frank  Lloyd  Wright  on  Architecture,  Duell,  Sloan  &  Pearce,  1941. 
Young,  C.  V.  P.,  How  Men  Have  Lived,  Stratford,  1931. 


CHAPTER  20 

Albig,  Public  Opinion. 

Barnes,  Can  Man  Be  Civilized f 

,  Living  in  the  Twentieth  Century. 

-, ,  The  Twilight  of  Christianity. 

Beaglehole,  Property. 

Beard,  A  History  of  the  Business  Man. 

Bossard,  Man  and  His  World. 

Burnham,  The  Managerial  Revolution. 

Burns,  Leisure  in  the  Modern  World. 

Chamberlain,  John,  The  American  Stakes,  Carrick  &  Evans,  1940. 

Chase,  Stuart,  The  Most  Probable  Tomorrow,  Harcourt,  Brace,  1941. 

Cole,  A  Guide  to  Modern  Politics. 

• ,  A  Guide  Through  World  Chaos. 

Cooley,  Social  Organization. 

Counts,  The  Prospects  of  American  Democracy. 

Davis,  Capitalism  and  Its  Culture. 

Dennis,  The  Dynamics  of  War  and  Revolution. 

Doob,  Propaganda. 

Drake,  The  New  Morality. 


SELECTED   REFERENCES  911 

Dulles,  America  Learns  to  Play. 

Ernst  and  Lindey,  The  Censor  Marches  On. 

Fodor,  The  Revolution  Is  On. 

Freeman,  Conquering  the  Man  on  the  Street. 

Furnas,  C.  C.,  The  Next  Hundred  Years,  Reynal  &  Hitchcock,  1936. 

Gore,  Property. 

Grattan,  Preface  to  Chaos. 

Hallgren,  Landscape  of  Freedom. 

Hayes,  Historical  Evolution  of  Modern  Nationalism. 

Howe,  The  News  and  How  to  Understand  It. 

Huberman,  Man's  Worldly  Goods. 

Hertzler,  Social  Institutions. 

Jackson,  Look  at  the  Law. 

Jenks,  Man  and  the  State. 

Keller,  Man's  Rough  Road. 

Keppel  and  Duff  us,  The  Arts  in  American  Life. 

Langdon-Davies,  A  Short  History  of  the  Future. 

Laski,  H.  J.,  Where  Do  We  Go  From  Here?  Viking,  1940. 

Lichtenberger,  Divorce. 

Lundbcrg,  America's  Sixty  Families. 

Lynd,  Knowledge  for  What? 

Marshall,  The  Story  of  Human  Progress. 

McConn,  College  or  Kindergarten? 

McVey,  Modern  Industrialism. 

Newlon,  Education  for  Democracy  in  Our  Time. 

Ogburn,  Social  Change. 

,  and  Nimkoff,  Sociology. 

Ogg  and  Sharp,  The  Economic  Development  of  Modern  Europe. 

Overmyer,  Government  and  the  Arts. 

Penman,  The  Irresistible  Movement  of  Democracy. 

Pink,  A  Realist  Looks  at  Democracy. 

Porritt,  The  Causes  of  War. 

Potter,  Humanism. 

Randall,  Our  Changing  Civilization. 

,  Religion  and  the  Modern  World. 

Riegel,  Mobilizing  for  Chaos. 

Sait,  Political  Institutions. 

Sargent,  Getting  US  Into  War. 

Schmalhausen,  Humanizing  Education. 

Smith,  The  Devil  of  the  Machine  Age. 

Sorokin,  P.  A.,  The  Crisis  of  Our  Age,  Dutton,  1941. 

Soule,  George,  The  Strength  of  Nations,  Macmillan,  1942. 

Steiner,  America  at  Play. 

Waller,  The  Family. 

Willey  and  Rice,  Communication  Agencies  and  Social  Life. 

Wright,  The  Causes  of  War  and  the  Conditions  of  Peace. 


INDEX 


Index 


Abelard,  Peter,  730 

Abuses  of  property,  195-197 

Academic  freedom,  problems  of,  787—791 

Activities,  human,  arising  from  needs, 
24-29 

Act  of  Settlement,  295 

Adams,  Charles  Francis,  802 

Adams,  Evangeline,  523 

Adams,  John,  234,  299 

Adler,  Alfred,  22,  814 

Adler,  Felix,  691 

Administration  of  public  education,  741- 
742 

Adult  education,  745-740,  778-781 

Advanced  Modernists,  doctrine  of,  691- 
092 

Advertising,  radio,  517,  524 

AFL,  see  American  Federation  of  Labor 

Agar,  Herbert,  279 

Age,  as  industrial  and  social  problem, 
150-158 

Agricultural  Revolution,  71,  78-81 

Agriculture,  changes  since  first  World 
War,  84-85;  control,  forms  of,  103- 
104 ;  development  of,  24 ;  Greek  and 
Roman,  72—  <4;  mechanization  of,  81— 
84;  medieval,  74-78;  Near  East,  an- 
cient, 70-72;  origins  of,  69-70 

Airplanes,  development  of,  474-476 

Air  warfare,  318-321 

Alexander  the  Great,  311-312 

Alimony,  problem  of,  633 

Allen,  Florence,  616 

Allport,  Floyd  H.,  808-809 

Alphabet,  origins  of,  453-454 

American  Association  for  Adult  Educa- 
tion, 779 

American  Association  for  the  Advance- 
ment of  Atheism,  692 

American  Association  of  University  Pro- 
fessors, 789 

American  Automobile  Association,  830 

American  Civil  Liberties  Union,  305,  593— 
594,  790,  791 

American  Federation  of  Labor,  14,  150 

American  Federation  of  Teachers,  786, 
792-793 

American  Lawn  Tennis  Association,  828 

American  Student  Union,  791 

American  Tobacco  Company,  124 

Analytical  jurisprudence,  371 

Anderson,  Paul  Y.,  559-560 

Angell,  Norman,  274,  336,  348 

Animals,  use  in  agriculture,  70,  72,  74, 
76-77 

Anthony,  Susan  B.t  617 

Anti-Semitism,  prejudice  of,  542 

Appleby,  John  F.,  82 

Aquinas,  Thomas,  211 


915 


Architecture,  development  of,  844-846, 
848,  851 

Arkwright,  Richard,  94,  107 

Armament  race,  345 

Armstrong,  Edwin  H.,  515 

Arnold,  Thurman,  158 

Art,  censorship  of,  577-580;  contempo- 
rary American,  trends  in.  850-860; 
development  of,  6,  839-844;  federal 
encouragement  of,  850-857 ;  growth  of, 
in  U.  S.,  844-850 ;  leisure-time  activity, 
838-839 

Aryan  hegemony  in  Germany,  8,  330 

Assizes  of  Jerusalem  and  Antioch,  365 

Associated  Press,  493 

Associations,  form  of  social  organization. 
15-16 

Assyria,  ancient,  see  Near  East 

Atheism,  doctrines  of,  692 

Athenian  society,  see  Greek  society 

Athletics,  historical  survey  of,  818-823; 
in  modern  education,  761-763 

Atlantic  cable,  478-479 

Atwood,  Harry  F.,  383 

Austin,  John,  371 

Automobiles,  development  of,  471-472 

Aylesworth,  M.  E.,  593 

Ayres,  Stuart,  546 


B 

Babson,  Roger,  472 

Babylonia,  ancient,  see  Near  East 

Bachofen,  J.  J.,  602 

Bacon,  Francis,  456 

Baer,  George  F.,  59 

Bagehot,  Walter,  205 

Bakewell,  Robert,  79 

Baldwin,  Roger,  305 

Bank  failures,  133 

Bank  holiday,  50-51 

Banning,  Margaret  Culkin,  570 

Bar  Association  of  New  York,  433 

"Bargain-counter  justice,"  435 

Barnard,  George  Grey,  849 

Barnard,  Henry,  732 

Barnes,  Albert  C.,  849 

Barrett,  Boyd,  711 

Bartlett,  George  A.,  628 

Bartlett,  Kenneth  G.,  525 

Barton,  Bruce,  551,  565 

Baseball,  growth  of,  823,  836 

Basketball,  development  of,  824 

Bayle,  Pierre,  681,  685 

Beaglehole,  Ernest,  164-165 

Beale,  Howard  K.,  787-788 

Beard,  Charles  A.,  230,  254 

Beck,  James  M.,  227,  252 

Becker,  Carl  Lotus,  214,  758 

Bedford,  Duke  of,  79 


916 


INDEX 


Beecher,  Catherine  E.,  825 

Behavior,  human,  change  hi,  35-38 

Bell,  Alexander  Graham,  407,  480 

Bellamy,  Edward,  51 

Bellows,  George,  343 

Bell  Telephone  Company,  483 

Bennett,  James  Gordon,  480,  489 

Bentham,  Jereinv,  370.  371,  717 

Bentley,  A.  F.,  230,  333 

Benton,  Thomas  Hart,  343,  849,  850 

Berle,  Idolph  A.,  182,  199,  417-418,  420, 

445 

Bernays,  Edward  L.,  478,  568 
Bessemer,  Sir  Henry,  95 
Belts,  George  Herbert,  689 
Bickel,  Karl  W.,  495,  530 
Bill  of  Eights,  294-295 
Bill  of  Bights  for  Teachers,  790-791 
Binder,  twine,  invention  of,  82 
Biological  causes  of  war,  32C-330 
Birth-control  movement,  617 
Black,  Hugo  L.,  414 
Black,  W.  P.,  432 
Blackatone,  William,  160,  177,  368 
Blaushard,  Paul,  700 
Bleriot,  Louis,  474 
Hlitzkrie.g,  methods  of,  818-319 
Bloc  system,  party  politics,  232 
Blount,  Charles,  575 
Blum,  !Le"on,  349 
Boas,  Franz,  44,  603 
Bonds,  social,  types  of,  7-10 
Bonger,  W.  A.,  718 
Bonuses,        excessive,       mismanagement, 

through,   131 
Books,    censorship   of,    577-580;    rise    of 

communication    through,    460-463 
Borchard,  Edwin  M.,  442 
Borsodi,  Ralph,  844 
Boss  controlled  politics.  241-243 
Bourgeois  revolution,  55 
Bowles,  Samuel,  488 
Boxing,  development  of,  836-837 
Brady,  "Diamond  Jim,"  167 
Brailsford,  H.  N.,  196,  216 
Brandeis,  Louis  D.,  411,  414,  421 
Breasted,  James  H.,  546,  680,  799 
Bridgewater,  Duke  of,  95 
Briffault,  Robert,  602 
Brindley,  James,  95 
Brinkley,  J.  R.,  594 
British  income  tax,  compared  with  U.  S., 

145 

'Bromley,  Dorothy  Dunbar,  396-398 
Broun,  Heywood,  577 
Browder,  Earl,  592,  593 
Brown,  Rollo  Walter,  710-711 
Brown,  V.  K.,  833 
Brunner,  Heinrich,  371 
Bruno,  Giordano,  opposition  to,  53 
Brutalization,  effect  of  warfare,  342 
Brvan,   William  Jennings,  62,  348,   548, 

688 

Bryant,  William  Cullen,  488 
Bryce,  James,  273,  286-287 
Buchman,  Frank  N.  D.,  693 
Buck,  A.  E.,  254 

Budget  and  Accounting  Act,  253-254 
Burke,  Edmund,  371 
Business  propaganda,  564-569    rt^rt    AM 
Butler,  Nicholas  Murray,  281,  348,  403, 

562 

Butler,  Pierce,  414 
Bye,  Raymond  T.,  139 


Byrd,  Richard,  464 
Byrnes,  James  F.,  414 

C 

Cables,  communication,  478-479 

Cadinan,  S.  Parkes,  593 

Calcord,  Joanna  C.,  642 

Caldwell,  Erskiue,  577 

Calhoun,  Arthur  W.,  184  295 

Cameron,  William  J.,  155,  567-568,  803 

Camp,  Walter  C.,  823 

Campbell.  Marcus  B.,  390 

Canals,  development  of,  95 

Cannon  law,  Catholic,  in  Middle  Ages, 
365-367 

Capella,  Martinus,  729 

Capitalism,  appraisal  of  crisis  in,  SOS- 
SCO;  ascendency  of,  125-127;  defects 
in,  127-137;  evolution  of,  122-125;  in 
ancient  world,  115-116;  industrial, 
137-139;  outlook  for,  in  TJ.  S.,  158- 
159 ;  problems  of,  149-1 53 ;  property 
under,  180-185 ;  rise  of,  historical  back- 
ground, 115-121 ;  traits  and  practices 
of,  119-120;  value  of,  to  society,  146- 
149 

Cardozo,  Benjamin,  399 

Carnegie,  Andrew,  124,  348 

Carter,  James  Gordon,  371,  732 

Cartoons,  animated,  853 

Cartwright,  Alexander  J.,  823 

Cartwright,  Edmund,  94 

Catholic  Social  Welfare  Council,  699 

Catt,  Carrie  Chapman,  617 

Censors,  types  of,  576-577 

Censorship,  appraisal  of  crisis  in,  872- 
874;  art,  books,  theater.  577-580; 
history  and  nature  of,  573-576;  libel 
racket,  580-581;  motion-picture,  585- 
591 ;  of  broadcasting,  522 ;  political, 
581-585  ;  radio,  591-594  ;  remedies  for, 
596-597;  types  of  censors,  576-577 

Cermak,  A.  J,,  258 

Chafee,  Zechariah,  Jr.,  446-447 

Chain-stores,  development  of,  102 

Chamberlain,  Houston  Stewart,  330 

Chamberlin,  William  Henry,  216,  274, 
286 

Change,  social,  and  education,  772-778 

Chase,  Stuart,  136,  138-139,  457-459 

Chase  National  Bank,  124 

Chemistry,  applied  to  industry,  95-96 

Cheyney,  E.  P.,  214 

Child  labor,  646 

Child  problems,  645-648 

Children's  Aid  Society  of  New  York, 
646-647 

Childs,  Marquis  W.,  475 

Choate,  Joseph  H.,  406-407 

Christian  art,  841-842 

Christian  synthesis,  the,  678-683 

Christianity,  divorce,  attitude  toward, 
620-621;  nature  of,  678-683 

Churchill,  Winston,  168 

CIO,  see  Congress  of  Industrial  Organ- 
izations 

City  life,  impact  of,  effect  on  rural  life 
patterns,  662-664 

City  planning,  845,  848,  851 

City-states,  early,  government  of,  202- 
205 

Civilian  Conservation  Corps,  635,  646 


INDEX 


917 


Civilization,  lawyer-made,  353-355;  on 
eupra-pig  level,  795-797 

Civil  liberties,  contemporary  crisis  of, 
296^306;  crisis  in,  306-308;  historical 
origins  of,  292-296;  laws  and  court 
cases  destroying,  298-299;  nature  of, 
290-292;  struggle  for,  290-308;  war 
influence  on,  343 

Civil-service  system,  growth  of,  252 

Clark,  Harold  F.,  83-84 

Clarke,  Edward  Y..  688 

Classes,  social  and  economic,  prejudices 
of,  535-536 

Clean,  fundamental  religious  concept,  677 

Close,  Upton,  523 

Code  Napoleon,  370 

Cohen,  Julius  Henry,  419 

Coke,  first  use  of,  94-95 

Coke,  Thomas,  80 

Coleman,  Lawrence,  859 

Collective  bargaining,   149-150 

Colleges,  development  of,  738-739 

Collins,  Anthony,  685 

Columbia  Broadcasting  System,  517,  519, 
592 

Conienius,  Johann  Amos,  731 

Commentators,  radio,  influence  of,  523 

Commerce,  development  of,  98—102 

Commercial  Revolution,  80 

Common  law,  English,  growth  of,  367- 
368 

Commonwealth  Fund,  646 

Communication,  agencies  of,  development, 
464-467;  alphabet,  origins  of,  453- 
454;  appraisal  of  crisis  in,  872-873; 
development  of,  26-27 ;  language,  ori- 
gins of,  450-453:  language,  social  and 
intellectual  problems  of,  454-459; 
means  of,  progress  in,  47o-487 ;  mod- 
ern, revolutionary  character  of,  463- 
464 ;  motion  pictures  as  factor  in.  505— 
514 ;  newspaper  as  means  of,  487—503 ; 
periodical  press,  503-505 ;  postal  serv- 
ice. 485—487 ;  printing,  invention  of, 
460-463 ;  radio,  development  of,  514- 
530;  rise  of,  through  books  and  print- 
ing, 460-463;  social  future  and,  530- 
532;  telegraphic,  476-480;  telephonic, 
480-485;  television,  527-530;  travel 
and  transportation,  improvements  in, 
467-471 ;  written  language,  origins  of, 
453-454 

Communism,  defined,  114-115 

Community,  form  of  social  organization, 
15 

Community  <  life,  meaning  of,  649-650; 
organization  supplants  primary  groups, 
664-666 

Comparative  school  of  jurisprudence, 
371-372 

Composers,  American,  850 

Comstock,  Anthony,  577,  579,  844 

Comstock  Law,  576 

Comte,  August,  19,  39Z  47 

Conduct,  historical  attitudes  toward,  714- 
718 

Congress  of  Industrial  Organizations,  14, 
150,  231 

Conrad,  Lawrence,  806-807 

Conscription,  military,  324-325 

Constitutional  government,  rise  of,  221- 
228 

Constitutional  law,  406-417 

Constitutions,  modern,  223-224 


Control,   industrial,    forms   of,    103-111; 

social,  modes  of,  18—19 
Cook,  Whitfield,  524-525 
Cooley,  Charles  H.,  13,  14,  279,  650,  651 
Coolidge,  Calvin,  551 
Coon,  Horace,  568,  802 
Coordinator  of  Information,  563 
Coquille.  Guy,  369 
Corey.  Lewis,  158 
Cornell,  Ezra,  479 

Corporate  control  of  finance,  125-127 
Corporation  law,  417-426 
Corruption  under  party  government,  248- 

259 

Cort,  Henry,  95 
Coster,  Lourens,  462 
Costs  of  party  elections,  243-244 
Cotton-gin,  invention  of,  94 
Cotton-picker,  invention  of,  82 
Coughlin,  Charles  E.,  555 
Court  cases  destroying  civil  liberties,  298- 

^t/y 
Courtroom   procedure,   law   in,    392-406; 

suggested  reforms  in,  442-449 
Cox.  Marion,  631 
Coyle,  David  Cushman,  555 
Crane,  Frederick  E.,  4zl 
Cravath,  Paul  D.,  418 
Craven,  T.  A.  M.,  464-4652  531 
Crime,    an    inroad    on    private    property, 

197;  religion,  morals  and,  712-714 
Criminal  law,  defects  of,  432-437 
Crompton,  Samuel,  94 
Cromwell,  William  Nelson,  419 
Cugnot,  Joseph,  opposition  to,  54 
Cultural  bond,  group  influence  of,  12 
Cultural    implications    of    gulf    between 

machines  and  institutions,  55—58 
Cultural  lag,  18 
Cultural  outlook,  common,  promotes  group 

life,  9 
Culture,    contemporary,    institutional   lag 

in,   58-63 ;   impact  of  war  upon,  339- 

344 ;  prejudices  of,  536 
Curriculum,    development    of,    in    public 

education,  743-744 
Curtis,  Henry  S.,  831 
Custom,  prejudices  of,  534 
Cutten,  George  Barton,  747 
Cylindrical  press,  introduction  of,  491 

D 

da  Feltre,  Vittorino,  731 

Daguerre,  Louis,  506 

Dalton  system  of  instruction,  733 

Dana,  Charles  A.,  488,  489 

Darby,   Abraham,   94-95 

Darrow,  Clarence,  432,  592-593,  688 

Darwin,  Charles,  38,  40 

Daughters   of   the  American   Revolution, 

299,  305 

Davis,  Elmer,  331,  523 
Davis,  Jerome,  793 
Davis,  John  W.,  59 
Davis,  Katharine  B.,  639 
Davis,  Kingsley,  631 
Davy,  Humphry,  80 
Dawson,  Mitchell,  422 
Debs,  Eugene  V.,  273 
Debt,  public  and  private,  menace  of,  133- 

134 

Declaration  of  the  Rights  of  Man,  295 
de  Couvertin,  Pierre,  825 


918 


INDEX 


Deering,  William,  82 

do  Gobineau,  Joseph  Arthur,  330 

Deists,  religious  liberals,  685 

Democracy,  appraisal  of  crisis  in,  809- 
870;  assumptions  of,  274r-278;  history 
of,  268-274 ;  political  future  and,  287- 
290 :  propaganda  and,  572-573 ;  testing 
of,  278-290 

Democratic  party,  237-238 

Democratic-Republican  party,  237 

Dennett,  Mary  Ware,  578,  580 

Depression,  periods  of.  80-81,  147,  198 

de  Schweinitz,  Karl,  666 

Deserted  women,  family  problems  of, 
641-643 

Devout  Modernists,  doctrine  of,  689-691 

Dewey,  John,  267,  647,  733,  776-777 

d'Holhaeh,  Baron,  685 

Dies  Committee,  work  of,  303-304,  565 

Dietrich,  John  II.,  674-675,  701 

Dillon,  Read  and  Company,  124 

Disarmament  conferences,  345-346 

Discipline,  result  of  social  organization, 
17 

Disease,  effect  of  war,  343 

Disintegration  of  primary  groups,  651- 
057 

Divorce,  causes  of,  in  IT.  S.,  625-629 ; 
extent  and  prevalence,  in  U.  S.,  622- 
625 ;  legislation  and  practices,  history 
of,  618-022;  remedies  for,  629-633 

Doherty,  Henry  L.,  126 

Domestic  industry,  medieval,  90-92,  93 

Donovan,   William  J.,  563 

Doob,  Leonard  W.,  546 

Doubleday,  Abner,  823 

Douglas,  Paul  H.,  154,  266,  267 

Douglas,  William  O.t  414 

Draper,  J.  W.,  506 

Drew,  Daniel,  131 

Drives,  basic  human,  22-24;  property, 
165-168 

Duff  us,  Robert  L.,  537 

Dunn,  C.  V.,  713 

Dunning,  William  A.,  39 

Durant,  Will,  278,  279-280 

Durkheim,  fimile,  15,  201 

Dyer,  Gus  W.,  805 

E 

,  Economic  causes  of  war,  333-336 
'Economic  prejudices,  539 

Economic   problems,   nature   of,   lld-llD 

Economic  society,  development  of,  5-6; 
group  influence  of,  11-12 

Eddy,  Sherwood,  700 

Edison,  Thomas  A.,  54,  506 

Edman,  Irwin,  838 

Education,  academic  freedom,  problems 
of,  787-791 ;  adult,  77&-781 ;  appraisal 
of  crisis  in,  876 ;  art,  848 ;  as  primary 
institution,  33-34;  contemporary,  de- 
fects of,  746-763 ;  cultural  lag  of,  61 ; 
demoralized  by  war,  340;  history  of, 
landmarks  in,  728-734;  importance  of 
today,  726-728;  mass,  734-746;  prej- 
udices of,  543;  propaganda,  571-572; 
raids  on,  781-787;  rational  system  of, 
763-772;  scientific  study  of,  746;  so- 
cial change  and.  772-778;  teachers, 
organization  of,  791-794 

Efficiency,  social,  and  institutions,  35-38 


Egypt,  ancient,  see  Near  East 

Eliot,  Charles  WM  733 

Elliott,  W.  Y.,  227 

Ely,  Richard  T.,  68 

Emerson,  Ralph  Waldo,  845 

Employment  of  women,  613-^618 

Enclosures,  in  English  agricultural  de- 
velopment, 80 

Engelbrecht,  H.  C.,  346 

Engels,  Friedrieh,  779 

Engine,  internal  combustion,  development 
of,  82;  steam,  development  of,  94 

England,  democracy  in,  271 

English  political  parties,  233-234 

Epidemics,  effect  of  war,  343 

Epstein,  Abraham,  149.  154-155 

Equal   Rights  Law,   Wisconsin,   616-617 

Ericsson,  John,  95 

Ernst,  Morris  L.,  578,  680,  585 

Estabrook,  Henry  D.,  226 

Ethical  Culture  Society,  691 

Ethics,  historical  attitudes  toward,  714- 
718 

Ethnology,  property  drives  in  light  of, 
165-168 

Etiquette,  social,  prejudices  of,  530^ 

Evolution,  agriculture,  aspects  of,  69-85 ; 
capitalism,  122-125;  law.  355-370; 
manufacturing,  trends  in,  85-112;  so- 
cial institutions,  38-47 ;  warfare,  311- 
326 

Experimental  schools,  733 

Expression,  self,  basic  human  drive,  22 

Extravagance  under  party  government, 
248-259 

P 

Fabian  Society,  779 

Factory  system,  development  of,  106-108 
Facts  and  Figures,  Office  of,  563 
Fairchildj  Henry  Pratt,  809^810 1 
Family  Me,  appraisal  of  crisis  in,  874- 
875 ;    as   primary    institution,    32 ;    as 
social   group,    11 ;    basis   of   social   or- 
ganization, o,  7;  child  care  outside  of, 
645-648 ;    deterioration    of,    651-655 ; 
development     of,      601-613;      divorce, 
problems  of,  618-633 ;  evolution  of,  46 ; 
future    of,    633-637;    illegitimacy,    as 
social  problem,  643-645;   incomes,   av- 
erage, 143 ;  instability  of,  remedies  for, 
629-633 ;  patriarchal,  break-up  of,  608- 
613;  present  concept  of,  60-61 
Faneuil,  Peter,  123 
Farago,  Ladislas,  561 
Fascism,  denned,  114-115 
Fear,  group  influence  of,  12;  reaction  to, 

as  psychological  bond,  8 
Federal      Communications      Commission, 

520-522,  529,  594 
Federal  Constitution,  295,  381-384 
Federal  payroll,  249-252 
Federal  Radio  Commission,  520 
Federalists,  political  party,  237 
Federated   American    Engineering    Socie- 
ties,  report  on  industrial  waste,   139- 
140 

Federation  of  Teachers'  Associations,  793 
Feeble-mindedness,  study  of,  733-734 
Fee  system,  legal  practice,  419,  422-424 
Feminism,  rise  of,  613-618 
Fertilization,  artificial,   early  use  of,  72, 
80 


INDEX 


919 


Fetishism,  fundamental  religious  practice, 

677-378 

Feudal  law,  364-305 
Feudal   politics,    medieval    Europe,    208- 

212 

Fichte,  Johann  Gottlieb,  455 
Field,  Cyrus  W.,  478 
Finance     capitalism,     abuses     of,     196 ; 

ascendency    of,    125-127 ;    defects    in, 

327-137;  property  under,  180-185 
Financial  raid  on  education,  781-783 
Fisher,  Irving,  218-219 
Fiske,  Irving,  528-529 
Fiske,  John,  601 
Flick,  A.  C.,  225 
Fly,  James  Lawrence,  521 
Flying  shuttle,  invention  of,  94 
Flynn,  John  T..  130,  158,  258 
Follett,  M.  P.,  263 

Football,  development  of,  823-824,  836 
Forbes,  William  HM  483 
Ford,  Henry,  108,  124,  471 
Foreign  news,  censorship  of.  584—585 
Fosdick,  Harry  Emerson,  299-300,  593 
Fouillee,  Alfred,  20 
Foundations    of    property,    psychological, 

164-165 

Fourteenth  Amendment,  183,  297 
Fox,  William,  419 
Fraenkel,  Osmond  K.,  297 
France,  suffrage  in,  271 
Frankfurter,   Felix,  414 
Franklin,  Benjamin,  805 
Franks,  medieval  law  among,  362-364 
Fraudulent  elections,  245 
Frazer,  J.  G.,  451,  673 
Frederick  the  Great,  732 
Freedom  of  press,  574-575 
Free  Thinkers  Society,  692 
French,  Daniel  Chester,  849 
Frequency    modulation,    development    of, 

514-515 

Froebel,  Friedrich,  733 
Frozen  foods,  84 

Functional  society,  development  of,  9 
Fundamentalism',  doctrine  of,  687-689 
Furnaces,  air-blast,  invention  of,  95 

G 

Gantt.  Henry  L.,  108 

Garrison,  William  Lloyd,  548 

Gaudet,  F.  J.,  437 

Geographic  influence,  on  social  develop- 
ment, 7 ;  on  social  groups,  10-11 ; 
prejudices  of,  535 

General  Motors  Corporation,  137 

Gerard,  James  W.,  287 

German  Imperial  Code,  370 

Germany,  censorship  in,  582;  control  of 
trade,  110;  planned  economy,  98; 
propaganda  in,  556-559 ;  recreation  in, 
825;  suffrage  in,  271 

Gibbons,  John  M.  F..  396-397 

Giddings,  Franklin  Henry,  8,  14,  15,  19, 
39,  240,  268,  533 

Gilbreth,  Wank  B.,  108 

Gild  industry,  medieval,  90-91,  105,  110 

Ginn,  Edward,  563 

Girdler,  Tom,  149 

Gisnet,  Morris,  375 

Gitlow,  Benjamin,  299 

Glass  industry,  development  of,  93 

Gods,  rise  of,  674-677 


Goebbels,  Paul  Joseph,  556,  582 

Goldberg,  Louis  P.,  401 

Goldenweiser,  Alexander,  37 

Goldman,  Emma,  301 

Golf,  development  of,  824 

Goodsell,  Willistyne,  651-352 

Goodyear,  Charles,  96 

Gorrnley,  M.  J.,  470 

Gould,  Jay,  131 

Government,  appraisal  of  crisis  in,  868- 
869 ;  as  social  institution,  34 ;  develop- 
ment of,  27-28 ;  evolution  of,  46 ;  ex- 
penditures of,  248—253 

Government  Reports,  Division  of,  563 

Graft,  in  party  politics,  256-259 

Grant,  Madison,  330 

Gras,  N.  S.  B.,  80-81,  127 

Gray,  Elisha,  480 

Greek  society,  agriculture  in,  72-73;  art 
in,  840-;841 ;  capitalism  in,  116 ;  cen- 
sorship in,  573 ;  city-states,  government 
of,  203-205;  civil  liberties  in,  292- 
293;  commerce  and  trade,  99,  102; 
contributions  to  Christianity,  681 ;  de- 
mocracy in,  269 ;  divorce  in,  619 ;  edu- 
cation in,  728-729;  family  in,  606 ; 
inheritance  of  property,  187 ;  manufac- 
turing in,  88-89  ;  property  in,  172-174  ; 
recreation  in,  816,  818;  warfare, 
methods  of,  311-312 

Greeley,    Horace.   488 

Griffith,  D.  W.,  ^06 

Groos,  Karl,  813 

Group  activity,  modes  of,  18-19 

Group  life,  foundations  of,  7-10 

Groups,  social,  leading  forms  of,  10-13 ; 
primary,  13-14;  secondary,  14;  we- 
groups,  14-15 

Gulick,  Luther  H.,  545,  831 

(run powder,  use  in  warfare,  316 

Gutenberg,  Johann,  460,  462 

H 

Habeas  Corpus  Act,  294 

Habit,  prejudices  of,  534 

Hague,  Frank,  259 

Haines,  Charles  G.,  60,  406 

Hall,  Edward  J.,  483 

Hall,  G.  Stanley,  647,  722,  733,  813 

Hall,  Joseph,  95 

Hamilton,  Alexander,  215,  226,  237,  382 

Hamilton,  Alice,  373,  401 

Hamilton,  G.  V.,  639 

Hamilton,  Walton  H.,  29,  161,  222 

Hamlin,  Alfred  D.  F.,  838 

Hammurabi,  code  of,  162,  172,  358 

Hancock,  John,  123 

Hand,  Learned,  418 

Hanighen,  F.  C.,  346 

Hanna,  Mark,  243 

Hanseatic  League,  control  of  trade,  110, 

176 

Hansen,  Alvin  H.,  158 
Harding,  Warren  G.,  242,  349 
Hargreaves,  James,  94 
Harper,  Charles  Rainey,  744 
Harris,  G.  S.,  437 
Harrison,  Jane,  816 
Hartshorne,  Hugh,  713 
Hartwell,  Edward  M.,  825 
Harvesting  machines,   invention  of,  82 
Harvey,  George,  242 
Hatch  Acts,  261 


920 


INDEX 


Hayes,  Carlton  J.  H.,  219-220,  333 

Hays,  Will,  587,  589 

Hcaly,  William,  647 

Hearst.  William  Randolph,  489,  494,  495 

Heisenberg,  Werner,  758 

HelvStius,  Claude,  731 

Henry  II,  367-308 

Henry,  Patrick,  300,  382 

Herbert  of  Cherburg.  Lord,  685 

Herrick,  Myron  T.,  242 

Herring,  E.  P.,  247 

Herroii,  Carl  V.,  338 

Hertz,  Ileinrich,  479 

Hertzler,  J.  O..  30,  32 

Hewett,  W.  W*.,  139 

Hibbard,  Angus  J.,  483 

Hightower,  P.  II.,  713 

Highways,  construction  of,  473-474 

llifi,  Rowland,  486 

Hitler,  Adolf,  8,  350,  554,  556 

Ilobbes,  John,  371 

Hobhouse,  L.  T.,  194 

Hobson,  J.  A,,  194 

Hockey,  development  of,  824 

Hoe  culture,  69-70 

Holbrook,  Stewart  H.,  307,  308 

Holcombe,  A.  N.f  247,  266 

Holding  companies,  127-131 

Holland,  Thomas  Erskine,  371 

Holmes,    Oliver   Wendell,   301,   399,   413 

Holmes,   Samuel  J.,  643-644 

Holt,  Benjamin,  82 

Holy  Roman  Empire,  210 

Hoover,  Calvin  B.,  287 

Hoover,  Herbert,  59,  139,  147,  242,  796 

Hopkins,  Ernest  Jerome,  433 

Hopkins,  Harry,  857 

Hopkins,  Mark,  754 

Hopson,  Howard,  198 

Howard,  Roy  W.,  494,  580 

Ho  wells,  T.  H.,  713 

Hubbard,  Elbert,  844 

Hughes,  Charles  Evans,  405,  415 

Hull,  Cordell,  335 

Human  behavior,  basis  of,  10 :  change  in, 

35-38 

Human  drives,  basic,  22-24 
Humanism,  doctrines  of,  691-692,  701 
Hume,  David,  177,  685,  716 
Hussey,  L.  M.,  388 
Hussey,  Obed,  81-82 
Hutchins,  Robert  M.,  772,  790 


Illegitimacy,   as  social  problem,  643-645 

Incitement  to  Disaffection  Act,  306,  502 

Income,  classes  of,  143—144 

Income  tax,  federal,  145-146 

Industrial  revolutions,  first,  94-95,  219- 
220;  property  after,  178-180;  second 
and  third,  95-98 

Industry,  appraisal  of  crisis  in,  864-865; 
control,  forms  of,  104-109 ;  evolution 
of,  46,  66-69 ;  Greek,  88-89 ;  medieval, 
90-92 ;  modern,  early,  92-93 ;  Oriental, 
87-88;  recreation  afforded  by,  832; 
revolutions.  52-53,  94-102,  219-220; 
Roman,  8vM)0;  unemployment,  153- 
156 ;  waste  in,  138-139 ;  see  also  Agri- 
culture, Manufacturing 

Inflation,  an  inroad  on  private  property, 
197-198 

In-groups,  development  of,  14-15 


Inheritance  of  property,  185-189 

Innocent  III,  211 

Institute  for  Propaganda  Analysis,  550, 

552,  556,  559,  567,  595 
Institute    of    Social    and    Religious    Re- 

search, 713 
Institutional  lag  in  contemporary  culture, 


Institutions,  social,  appraisal  of  crisis, 
861-864;  change  in,  35-38;  defined, 
29-30;  development  of,  30-31;  evolu- 
tion of,  38-^7  ;  gulf  between  machines 
arid,  52-55  ;  impact  of  urban  life  on, 
657-662;  legal  criticisms  of,  372-377; 
machines  and,  implications  of  gulf  be- 
tween, 55-58;  panorama  of,  22-47; 
primary  and  secondary,  31-35;  social 
efficiency  and,  35-38;  warfare  as,  321 

Insull,   Samuel,  198 

Interests,  human,  arising  from  needs,  24- 

Intemational  Harvester  Company,  124 
International    Telephone    and    Telegraph 

Corporation,  482 
Inventions,    94-97;    mechanical,    opposi- 

tion to,  53-54;  stimulated  by  war,  339 
Ise,  John,  777 
Italy,  after  first  World  War,  349-350 


Jacks,  L.  P.,  807-808,  811 

Jackson,  Andrew,  party  politics  and,  236 

Jackson.  Percival  E.,  375,  392-393,  420, 

431,  442-443 

Jahn,  Friedrich  Ludwig,  822 
James,  William,  534 
Jastrow,  Joseph,  596 
Jaures,  Jean,  348,  349 
Jazz  music,  849-850 
Jefferson,  Thomas,  81,  237,  275-276,  299, 

548,  685 

Johnson,  Andrew,  548 
Johnson,  Gerald,  595 
Jones,  Bassett,  134 
Jones,  Robert  M.,  388 
Jordan,  D.  S.,  329 
Josephson,  Matthew,  801 
Journalism,  cultural  lag  of,  61-62 
Judaism,    contributions    to    Christianity, 

679-680 

Junior  colleges,  development  of,  745 
Junior  high  school,  development  of,  745 
Jury  trial,  travesty  of,  437-442 
Justification,  social,  of  property,  189-195 
Justinian,  code  of,  361 

K 

Knhn,  Otto,  128 

Kallen,  Horace  M.,  61,  751 

Kaltenborn,  H.  V.,  523 

Kant,  Immanuel,  717 

Karolyi,  Michael,  301 

Kay,  John,  94 

Kayakawa,  S.  I.,  456,  457 

Keith,  Arthur,  543-544 

Keller,  Albert  Galloway,  40-42,  160,  166 

Kelley,  Edward,  579 

Kellogg  Pact,  347 

Kelly,  Fred  C.,  198,  424-425,  456 

Kelly,  William,  54,  123 

Kemal,  Mustapha,  606 

Kent,  Rockwell,  849 


INDEX 


921 


Keynes,  J.  MM  158 

Kindergarten,   establishment  of,   733 

Kinship,  as  social  bond,  7 

Kirkpatrick,  Clifford,  697-698 

Klatt,  Ellen,  639 

Kohler,  Joseph,  371 

Kroeber,  A.  L.,  8G 

Kuhn,  Loeb  and  Company,  124,  128 


Labor,  child,  640 ;  free,  81 ;  organized, 
problems  of,  149-153;  slave,  89-90, 
103,  104,  195,  799-800 

La  Follette,  Robert  M.,  262,  273,  300 

La  Guardia,  Fiorello,  579 

Lake,   Kirsopp,   703-704 

Land  transportation,  beginnings  of,  465— 
466 

Language,  differentiation  of,  in  medieval 
culture,  211-212;  origins  of,  450-453; 
social  and  intellectual  problems  of, 
454-459 

Laski,  Harold  J.,  305,  306 

Lasswell,  Harold  D.,  196,  546,  562 

Lavine,  Emanuel,  433 

Law,  appraisal  of  crisis  in,  870-871 ; 
cannon  law,  Catholic,  361,  365-367; 
code  of  Hammurabi,  162,  172,  358; 
common,  English,  367-368;  constitu- 
tional, 406-117;  corporation,  417-426; 
criminal,  defects  of,  432-437 ;  cultural 
Ing  of,  60 ;  defects  in  current  system, 
377-381 ;  development  of,  6";  evolution 
of,  355-370;  feudal,  364-365;  Franks, 
early  medieval  among,  362-364;  insti- 
tutions and  practices,  criticisms  of, 
372-377;  in  the  courtroom,  392-406; 
jury  trial,  travesty  of,  437-442 ;  mak- 
ing, problems  arising  out  of,  381-391 ; 
nioderji  times,  early,  368—370 ;  national, 
rise  of,  367-368;  natural,  406-417; 
prejudices  of,  540-541;  primitive,  355- 
358 ;  rank-and-file  lawyers,  activities 
and  methods  of,  426-432 ;  Roman,  358- 
362 ;  theories  and  schools,  modern, 
370-372 

Law-making,  problems  arising  out  of, 
381-391 

Law  Merchant,  The,  365 

Law  schools,   361-362,  370-372 

Laws  destroying   civil  liberties,   298—299 

Lawyer-made  civilization,  our,  353-355 

Lawyers,  rank-and-file,  activities  and 
methods,  426-432 

Lawyers'  lawyer,  418-419 

Lazarus,  Moritz,  813 

League  of  Nations,  347 

Le  Bon,  Gustave,  11 

Lee,  Higginson  and  Company,  124 

Lee,  Ivy,  549,  568 

Lee,  Joseph,  831 

Leech,  Margaret,  577 

Legal  institutions  and  practices,  criti- 
cisms of,  372-377 

Legal  practice,  commercialized,  417-426 ; 
suggested  reforms  in,  442-449 

Legion  of  Decency,  586 

Leisure,  appraisal  of,  876 ;  art-activity, 
838-839 ;  ethics  of,  804-807 ;  evolution 
of,  797-804;  recreation  and,  812-815; 
social  and  psychological  phases  of,  807- 
812 

Le  Play,  Fre"de*ric,  7 


Lerner,  Max,  415 

Leuba,  J.  H.,  712 

Levenson,  Eleanore,  401 

Lewis,  Dio,  825 

Lewis,  Joseph,  692 

Lewis,  Sinclair,  627,  628 

Lewisohn,  Ludwig,  629 

Lewisohn.  Sam  A.,  435 

Libel  racket,  580-581 

Liberty,  crisis  in,  306-308 

Liberty  League,  418,  554 

Lichtenberger,  J.  P.,  653 

Lilburne,  John,  270 

Lincoln,  Abraham,  300 

Lindeman,  E.  C.,  188-189 

Lippmnn,  Walter,  155,  708,  803 

List,  Friedrich,  335 

Little,  Clarence  C.,  759-760 

Livestock,  use  in  agriculture,  70,  72,  74, 

76-77 

Lobby,  national,  power  of,  246-247 
Locke,  John,  177,  178,  369,  685,  731 
Lockhart,  Robert,  824 
Lockwood,  Belva,  617 
Locomotive,   steain,   invention  of,  95 
Loeb,  Harold,  98 
Lombard,  Peter,  211 
Loom,  power,  invention  of,  94 
Lorentz,  Pare,  585 
Lowell,  A.  Lawrence,   788 
Lowell,  Francis   Cabot,   123 
Lowenthal,  Max,  128,  158 
Lowie,  Robert  H.,  44,  169,  603 
Lucretius,  39 
Lundberg,  Ferdinand,  287,  355,  376,  377, 

420,  422,  431,  432,  442 
Lundberg,  George  A.,  811 
Lynd,  Robert  S.,  46-47,  572,  776 

M 

MacDonald,  Ramsay,  283,  285 

MacDonald,  William,  227 

Machine  politics,  236,  241-243 

Machines,  development  of,  52-53,  94-97 ; 
institutions  and,  gulf  between,  social 
implications  of,  55-58 

Maclver,  R.  M.,  15,  263 

Mackay,  John  W.,  480 

MacLeish,  Archibald,  563 

Magic,  distinguished  from  worship,  674 

Magna  Carta,  294 

Maguire,   John   MacArthur,  446 

Mahan,  Alfred  T.,  317 

Mail-order  houses,  development  of,  102 

Maine,  Henry  Sumner,  371 

Maitland,  F.  W.,  371 

Malinowski,  Bronislaw,  329,  603 

Man,  as  an  animal,  3 ;  as  a  social  being, 
3-4 

Manichaeism,  contributions  to  Christian- 
ity, 680-681 

Mann,  Horace,  732 

Manorial  system,  74-75,  90-92,  103 

Manton,  Martin  T.,  403-404 

Manufacturing,  control,  forms  of,  104- 
109;  evolution  of,  85-112;  first  indus- 
trial revolution,  94-95;  Greek  and 
Roman,  88-90;  industrial  revolutions, 
94-98;  in  ancient  Near  East,  87-88; 
medieval,  90-92;  modern,  early,  92-93 

Marconi,  Guglielmo,  479 

Marett,  R.  R.,  672 


922 


INDEX 


Marin,  John,  849 

Marriage,  family  and,  601-607 

Marriage  Counsel  and  Education,  Bureau 
of,  631 

Marshall,  John,  215 

Martial  Relations  Institute,  612 

Martin,  Everett  Dean,  11,  770 

Marx,  Karl,  3S,  771) 

Mass  production,  1)5-98 

Mass  purchasing  power,  inadequate,  143- 
146 

MauroiH,  Andr<5,  342,  616 

May,  Mark  A.,  713 

Mayo,  Morrow,  82 

McConnell,  Francis  J.,  700 

McCormick,  Cyrus  H.,  81 

McDougall,  William,  164,  814 

McEvoy,  J.  P.,  510 

McGuire,  John  MacArthur,  404 

McReynolds,  James  C.,  414 

Menus,  Gardner,  182,  199 

Mechanization  of  agriculture,  81-84 

Mechanized  warfare,  318-321 

Medical  science,   development  of,   25 

Medieval  society,  agriculture  in,  74-78; 
art  in,  841-843;  capitalism  during, 
118-121 ;  censorship  in,  574 ;  civil 
liberties  in,  293-294 ;  commerce  and 
trade,  100,  102;  decline  of,  49  50;  de- 
mocracy in,  269-270 ;  education  in, 
729-731;  feudal  politics,  208-212;  in- 
dustry, 90-92 ;  inheritance  of  property, 
187;  law  in,  302-367;  property  in, 
174-176 ;  property  rights,  162 ;  recrea- 
tion in,  816,  820;  warfare,  methods  of, 
314-316 

Medill,  Joseph,  488 

Meiklejohn,  Alexander,   771 

Mellett,  Lowell,  563,  591 

Mencken,  H.  L.,  578,  628-629,  723,  757, 
760 

Mental  hygiene  movement,  733-734 

Mercantile  system,  120-121 

Merriam,  Charles  E.,  763 

Mesopotamia,  see  Near  East 

Metal  working,  early,  87-88 

Methods  of  warfare,  changing,  311-321 

Metropolitan  Life  Insurance  Company, 
569 

Metropolitan  Motion  Picture  Council,  590 

Michels,  Robert,  240,  273 

Middle  Ages,  see  Medieval  society 

^Military  system,  development  of,  323-326 

Mill,  James,  59 

Miller,  Clyde  R.,  545,  550,  552 

Miller,  Gerrit  Smith,  823 

Milton,  John,  575 

Mishkin,  Charles,  444-445 

Mismanagement  through  finance  capital- 
ism, 127-131 

Mitchell,  Margaret,  548 

Mithraism,  contributions  to  Christianity, 
680 

Modern  society,  capitalism  in,  120-121  ; 
divorce  in,  621-629;  law  in,  368-370; 

Property  in,   176-178;  property  rights 
i,  163;  religion  in,  702-712;  warfare 
in,  316-321 

Moley,  Raymond,  430-431,  432,  448 
Monaghan,  Robert,  429 
Monkg,   as   medieval   farmers,    77 ;   book- 
making  by,  460 ;  industry  by,  91-92 
Monogamy,  603-605 


Montessori,  Marie,  733 

Moore,  John  Bassett,  408 

Moral  codes,  genesis  of,  718-720;  ra- 
tional, essentials  of,  720-725 

Morals,  religion  and  crime,  712-714 

More,  Louis  T.,  718 

Morell,  Peter,  526 

Morgan,  J.  P.,  124,  126,  577 

Morgan,  Lewis  Henry*  43-45 

Morris,  William,  111,  843 

Morse,  Samuel,  opposition  to,  54,  477 

Moses,  Robert,  848,  850 

Motion  pictures,  censorship,  585—591 ;  in- 
dustry, rise  of,  505-514 

Motion  Picture  Producers  and  Distribu- 
tors of  America,  587 

Motion  Picture  Research  Council,  512- 
513 

Motorbuses,  development  of,  472-473 

Mowrer,  Ernest  R.,  624 

Mumford,  Lewis,  68 

Mural  painting,  847,  851 

Murchison,  Carl,  713 

Murphy,  Frank,  414 

Museums,  status  of,  850-851 

Music,  interest  in,  845-846,  847,  849-850, 
851-852 

Muslims,  as  medieval  farmers,  77-78; 
manufacturing  by,  92 

Mussolini,  Benito,  349-350 

Mutiny  Act,  295 

Mutual  aid,  value  of  social  organization, 
16-17 

Mutual  Broadcasting  System,  520 

Mutual  interest,  group  influence  of,  11, 
12-13 

Muzzey,  David  S.,  17,  313,  533 

N 

Naismith,  James,  824 

National    Association    of     Broadcasters, 

523 
National   Association   of   Manufacturers, 

568 

National  Board  of  Review,  586-587 
National  Broadcasting  Company,  517 
National  City  Bank  of  New  York,  124 
National  Committee  for  Mental  Hygiene, 

645-646 

National  Council  on  Freedom  from  Cen- 
sorship, 588 
National  Education  Association,  741.  743, 

786 

National  Electric  Light  Association,  569 
National  honor,  concept  of,  337—338 
National  Industrial  Recovery  Act,  149 
National  Labor  Relations  Act,  149-150 
National  law,  rise  of,  367-368 
National  parks,  development  of,  as  recrea- 
tion centers,  828 
National  problems,  how  war  complicates, 

309-310 
National    Recreation    Association,     829, 

831-832,  834 

National  state,  rise  of,  212-214 
National  Youth  Administration,  635,  640 
Nationalism,     history     of,     200-221;     in 
United  States,  214-217;  prejudices  of, 
537-538;    sovereign    states    and,    217- 
219 ;  war  psychology  and,  219-221 
Natural   law,   doctrine  of,  369,   370-371, 
406-417 


INDEX 


923 


Nazi  Germany,  see  Germany 

Near  Bast,  ancient,  agriculture  in,  70- 
72  ;  art  in,  840 ;  capitalism  in,  115-116 ; 
city-states,  government  of,  202-205; 
civil  liberties  in,  292;  commerce  and 
trade,  99,  101-102;  divorce  in,  619; 
education  in,  728;  family  in,  605-606; 
inheritance  of  property,  186 ;  manu- 
facturing in,  87-88 ;  property  in,  171— 
172  ;  property  rights  in,  162  ;  recreation 
in,  817-818;  warfare,  methods  of,  311 

Needs,  human,  arising  from  basic  drives, 
23-24 

Negroes,  prejudice  against,  542,  545 

Neighborhood,  breakdown  of,  655-656 

Neilson,  James,  95 

New  Deal,  64,  85,  133,  143,  154,  413, 
424,  555 

New  Oxford  Movement  692-693 

New  School  for  Social  Research,  779 

Newspaper,  daily,  development  of,  466, 
487-503 

Newsreels,  informational  pictures,  506 

New  York  City  Legal  Aid  Society,  446 

New  York  Society  for  the  Suppression  of 
Vice,  577-578 

New  York  State  Crime  Commission,  re- 
port of,  435 

Nickerson,  Hoffman,  325,  333 

Nicolai,  G.  M.,  329 

Niepce,  Joseph,  506 

Non-marriage,  results  of,  638-640 

Novicow,  Jacques,  40,  329 

O 

Odegard,  Peter,  570 

Ogburn,  William  F.,  97,  523,  610 

Ogden,  C.  K.,  450 

Old  age,  as  industrial  and  social  prob- 
lem, 156-158 

Oligarchical  tendencies  in  party  politics, 
240-241 

Olympic  games,  revival  of,  824-825 

Omens,  belief  in,  58-59 

O'Neill,  Eugene,  579 

Onions,  Peter,  95 

Order,  social  organization  need  for,  17 

Organization,  social,  basis  of,  5-6 ;  con- 
tributions of,  16-18;  costs  of,  17-18; 
forms  of,  15—16 ;  historical  development 
of,  5-6;  meaning  of,  3-5;  value  of, 
16-18 

Organization  of  teachers,  791-794 

Organized  labor,  problems  of,  149-153 

Orient,  see  Near  East,  ancient 

Osborn,  Henry  Fail-field,  330 

Others-groups,  development  of,  14-15 

Out-groups,  development  of,  14-15 

Overstreet,  Harry  B.,  264-266 

Owen,  Robert,  779 

Oxford  movement,  686 


Pacifism,  contemporary  regard  for,  301 

Paetow,  Louis  J.,  455 

Paetus,  Sextus  Aelius,  361 

Pageantry,  growth  of,  853 

Paine.  Thomas,  685 

Painting,  appreciation  of,  845-847,  849 

Paley,  William  S.,  592 

Palmer,  A.  Mitchell,  308 


Pankhurst,  Emmeline,  617 

Paper,  early  use  of,  454 

Papyrus,  early  use  of,  454 

Parker,  Francis,  733 

Parker,  Thomas  C.,  859 

Parker,  .Valeria  H.,  631 

Parochial  schools,  735 

Parrish,  Wayne  W.,  83-84 

Parry,  Albert,  816 

Party  government,  corruption  and  extra- 
vagance under,  248-259;  problems  of, 
239-248 ;  reform  measures,  fate  of, 
259-267 ;  rise  of,  232-239 

Party  leaders,  230 

Party  politics,  costs  of  elections,  243-244 

Patriarchal  empires  of  antiquity,  govern- 
ment of,  205-208 

Patriarchial  family,  break-up  of,  608-613 

Patrick,  George  T.  W.,  813 

Patriotism,  331-332;  nationalism,  and 
war  psychology,  219-221 ;  prejudices 
of,  537 

Peace,  war  influence  on,  344 

Peary,  Robert  E.,  464 

Peck,  William  G.,  282 

Peckstein,  Louis,  745 

Pecora,  Ferdinand,  396 

Pensions,  expenditures  for,  255-256 

Peoples  institute,  779 

Pepper,  George  Wharton,  261 

Periodical  literature,  503-505 

Perjury  in  courtroom,  396-398 

Perkins,  Frances,  616 

Perpetuation,  self,  basic  human  drive,  22 

Persian  contributions  to  Christianity,  680 

Personal  liberty,  291 

Personal  property,  distinguished,  161,  16.3 

Petition  of  Rights,  294 

Pfeil,  Stephen,  160 

Phoenicians,  capitalism  among,  116 ;  see 
also  Near  East,  ancient 

Photography,  discovery  of,  506 

Pierce,  Bessie  L.,  763 

"Pinhead  jurisprudence,"  395-396 

Pitkin,  Walter  B.,  343,  156 

Platt,  Thomas  C.,  241 

Playground  Association  of  America,  831 

Playgrounds,  development  of,  831-832 

Plow  culture,  agriculture,  71,  73,  76 

Political  bond,  promoting  group  life,  9 

Political  causes  of  war,  336-339 

Political  censorship,   581-585 

Political  opinions,  current,  60 

Political  parties,  role  of,  229-232 

Political  prejudices,  538 

Political  problems,  growing  complexity 
of,  217-219 

Political  propaganda,  554-564 

Political  society,  development  of,  6 

Pollock,  Channing,  157 

Pollock,  Frederick,  371 

Polyandry,  604 

Polygyny,  604 

Pork  barrel  system,  254-256 

Postal  service,  improvement  of,  485-487 

Postal  Telegraph  Company,  480 

Post  Office  Department,  censorship  of, 
576,  579 

Potter,  Charles  Francis,  701 

Potter's  wheel,  early  use  of,  88 

Pound,  Cuthbert,  434 

Pound,  Roscoe,  355,  370,  377 

Power,  development  of,  96-97 


924 


INDEX 


Powys,  John  Cowper,  705 

Prejudice,  remedies  for,  504-595 ;  role  of, 
in  modern  life,  533-545 

Prelude  to  second  World  War,  345-348 

Prentiss,  Mark  O.,  395 

Preservation,  self,  basic  human  drive,  22 

Pressey,  S.  L.,  813,  822 

Price,  Byron,  585 

Primary  groups,  community  organization 
supplants,  664-666;  disintegration  of, 
651-657 ;  role  of,  in  social  life,  650-651 

Primitive  society,  art  in,  839-840;  civil 
liberties  in,  292 ;  commerce  and  trade, 
101;  divorce  in,  619;  education  in, 
728;  family  in,  601-604;  inheritance 
of  property,  186;  law  in,  355-358; 
leisure  in,  798 ;  manufacturing,  85-87 ; 
moral  codes  in,  718 ;  property  in,  168- 
171;  property  rights,  162;  recreation 
in,  816,  817;  religion  in,  671-674,  677- 
678 ;  tribal  society,  government  of,  201- 
202;  warfare,  methods  of,  311 

Prince  of  Wales,  sinking  of,  320 

Printing,  invention  of,  460-463 

Pritchett,  Henry  S.,  762 

Private  property,  future  of,  198-199; 
major  inroads  on,  197-198 

Profit  system,  111 

Progressive  education  movement,  733,  815 

Progressive  party,  273 

Propaganda,  appraisal  of  crisis  in,  873 ; 
business,  564-569;  democracy  and, 
572-573 ;  devices  and  processes  of,  550— 
554 ;  educational,  571-572 ;  history  and 
nature  of,  545-550;  political,  554-564; 
religious,  569-571 ;  remedies  for,  594- 
597 ;  war,  effect  of,  342-343 ;  war,  use 
of  radio,  524 

Propeller,  screw,  invention  of,  95 

Property,  abuses  of,  195-197;  after  In- 
dustrial Revolution,  178-180 ;  appraisal 
of  crisis  in,  866-868;  cause  of  war, 
196-197;  concepts,  161-163;  defini- 
tions, 160-161 ;  drives,  in  light  of  psy- 
chology, ethnology,  sociology,  165-168; 
history  of,  168-185 ;  in  early  Greece, 
172-174;  in  early  modern  times,  176- 
178;  inheritance  of,  185-189;  in  me- 
dieval society,  1747-176;  in  primitive 
society,  168-171 ;  in  Roman  society, 
174 ;  legal  protection  of,  406-417 ;  pri- 
vate, development  of,  46;  private,  fu- 
ture of,  198-199;  private,  major  in- 
roads on,  197-198;  psychological  foun- 
dations of,  164-165 ;  social  justification 
of,  189-195;  under  finance  capitalism, 
180-185 ;  war  effect  on,  340 
Proportional  representation,  264-266 

Protestantism,  divorce  under,  621;  en- 
couraged capitalism,  119-120;  rise  of, 
683-685 

Prothero,  R.  W.,  78 

Psychological  bond,  group  influence  of, 
11 ;  of  human  society,  8 

Psychological  causes  of  war,  330-333 

Psychological    foundations    of    property, 

164-165 
Psychology,  property  drives  in  light  of, 

Public  education,  732,  734-746 
Public  forum  movement,  746 
Puddling  process,  invention  of,  95 
Pulitzer,  Joseph,  489 


Pupin,  M.  I.,  695 

Purchasing  power,  mass,  inadequate,  143- 
146 

Q 

Quigley,  Martin,  585-586 
R 

Race,  prejudices  of,  536,  541-542 

Racial  kinship,  as  social  bond,  8 

Radicalism,  contemporary  reception  of, 
299-301 

Radio,  censorship,  591-594 ;  development 
of,  514-530 ;  industry,  growth  of,  516- 
517 

Radio  Corporation  of  America,  517 

Radio  newspaper,  527 

Railroads,  development  of,  467-471 

Randall,  John  Herman,  694-695,  696,  708 

Rank  and  grades,  prejudices  of,  536 

Rationalism,  rise  of,  685-687 

Ratzenhofer,  Gustav,  333 

Rautenstrauch,  Walter,  134,  158 

Raymond,  Henry,  488 

Real  property,  distinguished,  161,  163 

Reaper,  invention  of,  81-82 

Recreation,  appraisal  of,  876;  cost  of, 
annual,  835 ;  development  of,  28 ;  facil- 
ities for,  828-829 ;  history  of,  815-827 ; 
in  United  States,  827-838;  leisure  and, 
812-815 

Reed,  Stanley,  414 

Reforms,  fate  of,  party  politics,  259-267 ; 
suggested,  in  legal  practice  and  court- 
room procedure,  442-449 

Refugees,  323 

Religion,  appraisal  of  crisis  in,  875;  as 
primary  institution,  33 ;  basis  of  social 
organization,  5;  Christian  synthesis, 
the,  678—683 ;  concepts  and  practices, 
fundamental,  677-678;  conduct  and 
ethics,  attitudes  toward,  714-718;  con- 
flict of  science  with,  693-699;  control 
of  medieval  church,  210-211 ;  cultural 
lag  of,  62 ;  development  of,  6,  669-686 ; 
evolution  of,  47 ;  factor  promoting 

froup  life,  9;  group  influence  of,  12: 
umanizing  of,  699-702 ;  morals,  crime, 
and,  712-714 ;  nature  and  social  im- 
portance of,  669-670 ;  potency  of,  670 ; 
prejudices  of,  535,  541 ;  primitive  so- 
ciety, development  in,  671-674,  677- 
678;  propaganda  in,  569-571;  protes- 
tantism and  rationalism,  683—687 ;  rise 
of  gods,  674-677;  role  of,  in  modern 
life,  702-712 ;  twentieth-century  groups, 
687-693 

Renard,  George,  70 

Republican  party,  238 

Republics,  ascendancy  of  the,  221-228 

Repulse,  sinking  of,  320 

Revenues  and  expenditures,  federal,  proc- 
ess of  determining,  253 

Revolutions,  agricultural,  78-81  ;  com- 
mercial, 80;  industrial,  52-53,  81,  94- 
98;  social,  behind  second  World  War, 
348-352;  world,  36-37,  48-50 

Rice,  Stuart  A.,  472,  512,  526 

Riegel,  O.  W.,  532,  583-584 

Riley,  William  B.,  688 

Ripley,  W.  Z.,  129-130 


INDEX 


925 


Ripuarian  law,  362 

Rivers,  W.  H.  B.,  164 

Roads,  development  of,  95,  465-466,  473- 
474 

Robinson,  Edward  S.,  355,  813 

Robinson,  James  Harvey,  219,  269,  597, 
095-696,  720,  749,  759,  774 

Robinson,  Joseph  T.,  414 

Rockefeller,  John  D.,  Jr.,  848 

Rockefeller,  John  D.,  Sr.,  124 

Rodell,  Fred.  376-377,  378-381,  390,  391, 
408,  41&-419,  431,  443,  541 

Roebuck,  John,  95 

Rogers,  Lindsay,  349 

Roman  Catholic  Church,  canon  law  of, 
361,  365-367;  control  over  medieval 
culture,  210-211 ;  divorce,  attitude 
toward,  620-621;  education,  735;  in- 
fluence in  Middle  Ages,  683 

Roman  society,  agriculture  in,  73-74 ;  art 
in,  841;  capitalism  in,  116-118;  cen- 
sorship in,  573 ;  civil  liberties  in,  292- 
293 ;  commerce  and  trade,  99,  102 ; 
contributions  to  Christianity,  681-682 ; 
decline  of,  49;  democracy  in,  269;  di- 
vorce in,  619-620;  education  in,  729; 
family  in.  60(5-607;  inheritance  of 
property,  187 ;  law  in,  358-362 ;  manu- 
facturing, 89-90;  patriarchal  govern- 
ment of,  207-208;  property  in,  174; 
property  rights  in,  162;  recreation  in, 
817,  819 ;  warfare,  methods  of,  312-313 

Romanticism,  school  of,  685-686 

Roosevelt,  Eleanor,  351-352 

Roosevelt,  Franklin  D.,  50,  282,  300,  414, 
555 

Roosevelt,  Theodore,  348,  802 

Root,  Elihu,  241,  405 

Ross,  E.  A.,  19,  649 

Rotation  of  crops,  78-79 

Rousseau,  Jean  Jacques,  270 

Rubber  industry,  development  of,  95-96 

Rural  life  patterns,  effect  of  city  life  on, 
662-664 

Rural  play  group,  decay  of,  656-657 

Ruskin,  John,  111,  843 

Russell,  Bertrand,  624,  625 

Russell  Sage  Foundation,  154 

Russia,  after  first  World  War,  349 ;  civil 
liberties  in,  295-296;  constitution, 
226;  control  of  farming,  104;  control 
of  industry,  109;  control  of  trade,  110; 
feminism  in,  617;  inheritance  of  prop- 
erty, 188 ;  planned  economy,  98 ;  prop- 
erty rights  in,  185;  suffrage  in,  272 

Ryan,  John  A.,  157,  699 


Saarinen,  Eliel,  848,  851 

Sacred,    fundamental    religious    concept, 

677 
Sacrifice,  fundamental  religious  concept, 

677 

St.  John,  Charles  W.,  437 
Sait,  E.  M.,  266 
Salaries,        excessive,        mismanagement 

through,  131 
Salic  law,  362 
Sanger,  Margaret,  617 
Sapir,  Edward,  451 
Sargent,  Dudley  A.,  825 
Sargent,  Porter,  753-754 


Sarnoff,  David,  517 

Say,  J.  B.,  59 

Schaffle,  Albert,  19 

Schlesinger,  A.  M.,  214 

Schnitzler,  Arthur,  577 

Schoeffer,  Peter,  462 

School  buildings,  735-738 

Shuler,  Robert  P..  594 

Schuman,  Frederick,  274,  561 

Schwimmer,  Rosika,  301,  413 

Science,  conflict  of  religion  with,  693- 
699 ;  development  of,  29 ;  stimulated  by 
war,  339 

Scopes  trial,  688 

Scott,  Jonathan  French,  332,  571,  763 

Scripp,  E.  W.,  489 

Sculpture,  modern,  849 

Seagle,  William,  385,  441,  580 

Secularism,  influence  on  family  life,  609- 
610 

Seldes,  George,  346,  501,  584 

Seldes,  Gilbert,  529 

Self-esteem,  prejudice  of,  536 

Self-expression,  basic  human  drive,  22 

Self-preservation,  basic  human  drive,  22 

Sellars,  Roy  W.,  707 

Senior,  Nassau,  196 

Sentences,  percentage  of  each  kind,  given 
by  judges,  437 

Sex,  abnormal,  639 ;  as  socializing  influ- 
ence, 7 ;  basis  of  social  organization,  5 ; 
Christian  influence  on,  607-608 ;  double 
standard,  617 ;  human  characteristics, 
601-602;  monogamy,  practice  of,  603- 
604 ;  mores,  embodiment  of  present,  60- 
61 ;  polyandry  and  polygyny,  practice 
of,  604;  Protestant  influence  on,  607- 
608;  secularism,  influence  on,  609-610; 
unmarried  adult,  638-640 

Shand,  Alexander,  814 

Shapley,  Harlow,  693 

Shaw,  Clifford,  647 

Shearer,  W.  B.,  346 

Shinn,  Henry  A.,  374 

Shipbuilding,  93 

Sills,  Milton,  511-512 

Skidmore,  Thomas,  779 

Skiing,  popularity  of,  830-831 

Slater,  Samuel,  123 

Slavery,  exploitation  by,  195 

glesinger,  Donald,  789-790 

Slichter,  Sumner  H.,  151 

Small,  A.  W.,  333 

Smeaton,  John,  95 

Smith,  Adam,  17,  59,  107.  177,  717 

Smith,  Alfred  E.,  448,  554 

Smith,  Charles  B.,  692 

Smith,  G.  Elliot,  69,  450 

Smith,  Hart,  801-802 

Smith,  Preserved,  461-462,  463 

Smith,  Reginald  Heber,  405 

Smith,  Young  B.,  394 

Snyder,  Carl,  137,  190 

"Social  Darwinism,"  328-329 

Social  implications  of  gulf  between  ma- 
chines and  institutions,  55-58 

Socialist  party,  273 

Social  liberty,  291 

Social  organism,  society  and  the,  19-21 

Social     organization,     see     Organization, 

social 

Social  revolution,  behind  second  World 
War,  348-352 


926 


INDEX 


Social  Security  Act,  641 

Society,  form  of  social  organization,  15 ; 

impact   of   war   upon,   339-344;   social 

organism  and,  19-21 
Society  for  the  Prevention  of  Cruelty  to 

Children,  647 

Sociological  causes  of  war,  333 
Sociological  school  of  jurisprudence,  372 
Sociology,    property    drives    in   light   of, 

165-168 

Socio-religious  organizations,   711-712 
Sokolsky,  George,  5G5 
Somerville,  Lord,  79 
Spanish  Civil  War,  347 
Spartan  society,  see  Greek  society 
Speculation,  as  inroad  on  private  prop- 
erty, 198 

Spencer,  Herbert,  8,  19,  20,  38,  39.  813 
Spinning  machines,  invention  of,  94 
Sports,  historical  survey  of,  818-825 
Stability,  social  organization  needed  for, 

17 

Stakhariov,  Alexey,  109 
Standard  Oil  Company,  124 
Stan  ton,  Elizabeth  Cady,  017 
State  activity,  nationalism  and,  217-219 
State   Board   of  Censorship,   New   York, 

586,  587 

State  capitalism,  123,  127 
Steamboat,  development  of,  95 
Stein,  Ludwig,  15 
Steiner,  Frank,  713 
Steiner,  Jesse  F.,  827,  837-838 
Steinheil,  Karl  A.,  477 
Stephenson,  George,  95 
Stern,  Bernhard  J.,  53 
Steuer,  Max,  419 
Stevens,  Thaddeus,  548 
Stock-breeding,   development  of,   79 
Stockton,  Robert,  333 
Stopes,  Marie,  617 
Stowe,  Harriet  Beecher,  548 
Strachey,  John,  301 
Strunskv,   Simeon,  155,  803 
Studeba'ker,  John  W.,  560-561,  746,  780 
Sturm,  Johannes,  731 
Suffrage,  woman,  616 
Sumner,  John  S.,  577,  578,  579,  580 
Sumner,  William  Graham,  31,  330 
Superstitious   beliefs,    58-59 
Supreme  Court,  Federal,  408-416 
Surpluses,  agricultural,  84 
'Sutherland,  E.  II.,  422 
Swaine,  Robert  T.,  418 
Swancara,  Frank,  389 
Swing,  Raymond  Gram,  523 


Tabloid  newspapers,  489 

Taboo,    fundamental    religious    practice, 

677 

Taft,  William  Howard,  404,  562 
Talbot,  W.  H.  Fox,  506 
Tank  warfare,  318-321 
Tarde,  Gabriel,  97,  813 
Taussig,  F.  W.,  191 
Taxation,  an  inroad  on  private  property, 

197 

Taylor,  Frederick  W.,  108 
Teachers,  academic  freedom  of,  787- (91; 

bill  of  rights  for,  790-791 ;  dismissal  of., 


788-790;  organization  of,  791-794;  re- 
strictions on,  783-787 

Teachers  Union,  786 

Techniques  of  warfare,  changing,  311- 
321 

Technocracy,  industrial  control  «by,  109, 
285,  289 

Technology,  evolution  of,  46,  62;  modern 
machine,  97-98  % 

Telegraph,   development  of,  476-480 

Telephone,  development  of,  467,  480-485 

Telephoto,  introduction  of,  491-492 

Teletypesetting  machine,  invention,  of, 
491 

Television,  development  of,  527-530 

Tennis,  popularity  of,  828 

Textbooks,  prejudice  of,  332-333 

Textiles,  early,  88;  early  modern  period, 
92-93,  94-95 

Thayer,  Webster,  396 

Theater,  censorship  of,  577-580;  modern, 
852-853 

Theodosius  II,  code  of,  361 

Third  Degree,  in  criminal  law,  433-434 

Thomas,  Norman,  273 

Thomusius,  Christian,  732 

Thompson,  W.  S.,  258,  327 

Thompson,   William  G.,  432 

Thorndike,  Edward  L.,  779 

Thrasher,  Frederic  M.,  647 

Threshing  machine,  invention  of,  82 

Tindal,  Matthew,  575,  685 

Toleration  Act,  295 

Tonnies,  Ferdinand,  15 

Tools,  primitive,  85-86 

Totalitarianism,  established  in  Europe, 
349-351 

Total  warfare,  320-321,  326 

Townshend,  Lord,  78-79 

Tozzer,  A.  M.,  58 

Trade,  control  of,  109-111;  development 
of,  26,  98-102 

Traditions,  common,  promotes  group  life, 
9 

Trailers,  development  of,  472 

Transitional  character  of  era,  48-52 

Transportation,  appraisal  of  crisis  in,  871- 
872;  beginnings  of,  465-467;  develop- 
ment of,  25,  26,  96;  early,  88;  improve- 
ments in,  467-476 

Travel,  as  antagonist  of  prejudice,  544 ; 
recreation  and,  829-830 

Trawney,  R.  H.,  178 

Trial  by  jury,  travesty  of,  437-442 

Tribal  society,  government  of,  201-202 

Troeltsch,  Ernst,  177 

Trotter,  Wilfred,  202 

Trusts,  industrial,  development  of,  124- 
125 

Tull,  Jethro,  78 

Turner,  Frederick  Jackson,  11,  215 

Tuttle,  Charles  H.,  397 

Twelve  Tables,  Laws  of  the,  359-360 

Two-party  system,  231 

Tylor,  E.  B.,  672 

Type,    printer's,   early,   402 

Typesetting  machines,  invention  of,  461 

U 

Unemployment,    industrial,    problem    of, 

153-156 
United  Press  agency,  493-494 


INDEX 


927 


United  States  Office  of  Education,  735 
United  States  Steel  Corporation,  124,  137 
Universal  suffrage,  271.-272,  GIG 
Universities,    development   of,    730,    738- 

739 

Unmarried  adult,  problems  of,  638-640 
Untormeyer,  Louis,  419 
Urban  life,   impact  of,  on  social  institu- 
tions, 657-6G2 


Vaerting,   Mathilde  and  Mathis,  G03 

Vail,  Theodore  N.,  483 

Van  Devanter,  Willis,  414 

"Vanishing  voter,"  281 

Voblcn,  Thorstein,  160,  192-193,  801,  844 

Vinogradpff,  Paul,  371 

von  Liebig,  Justus,  80 

von  Lilienfeld,  Paul,  19 

von  Savigny,  Friedrich,  371 

W 

Wages  and  Hours  Act,  616,  646 

Wagner  Act,  150 

Walker,  "Jimmy,"  258 

Walker,  Ralph,  848 

Wallace,  Henry,  304,  551 

Wallace,  W.  K.,  285 

Wallas,  Graham,  2(52,  277,  717 

Waller,  Willard,  637,  788 

Walpole,  Robert,  233 

War,  appraisal  of  crisis  in,  869;  as  social 
institution,  33,  321-323;  causes  of,  in 
contemporary  society,  326-339 ;  chang- 
ing methods  and  techniques  of,  311- 
321 ;  complicates  national  problems, 
309-310;  evolution  of,  311-32G ;  family 
life  and,  637 ;  impact  of,  on  society  and 
culture,  339-344 

Ward;  Lester  F.,  38,  773,  776 

War  psychology,  nationalism,  patriotism 
and,  219-221 

Washington,   George,   party   politics   and, 

Waste  in  industry,  138-139 

Watch  and  Ward  Society,  578 

Water  sports,   popularity  of,  830 

Water  transportation,  beginnings  of,  466 

Watson,  Thomas  A.,  480 

Watt,  James,  94 

Waugh,  W.  T.,  463 

Weber,  Max,  177,  804 

Weed,  Thurlow,  488 

We-groups,  development  of,  14—15 

Weir,  E.  T.,  149 

Wells,  H.  G.,  52,  596 

Wcrgeld,  table  of,  362-363 

Westermarck,  Edward,  602-603 

Western  Union  Telegraph  Company,  479 

Wheatstone,  Charles,  477 


Wheeler,  Burton  K.,  414 

Whelpton,  P.  K.,  156 

Whig  party,  237 

Whipple.  Leon,  291 

White,  Andrew  D.,  693 

White.  Leslie  A.,  44 

Whitehead,  A.  N.,  696 

Whitlock,   Brand,  388-389 

Whitney,  Eli,  94,  108,  339 

Widows,  social  problems  of,  640-G41 

Wigmore,  John  H.,  402 

Wile,  Ira  S.,  639 

Wilkinson,  John.  95 

Willcox,  O.  W.,  61,  83 

Willey,  Malcolm  M.,  472,  512,  526 

Willkie,  Wendell,  199 

Wilson,  Wroodrow,  349 

Winthrop,  Alden,  129,  181 

Wireless    telegraph,    development   of,    479 

Wirt,  William,  nominated  by  Anti-Ma- 
sonic party,  236 

Wollstonecraft,  Mary,  617 

Women,  deserted,  problems  of,  641-643 ; 
education  of,  732;  employed,  G13-(J1S; 
suffrage  for,  538-539,  GIG 

Wood,  Leonard,  245 

Wood,  Thomas,  524-525 

Woodhull,  Victoria,  617 

Woolsey,  John  Munro,  299 

Woolston,  Thomas,  685 

World  fairs,  853 

AVorld  Peace  Foundation,  563 

World  Peaceways,  563 

World's  Christian  Fundamentals  Asso- 
ciation, 688 

World  War,  first,  317-318,  349;  second, 
318-321,  345-348,  352 

Worman,  E.  C.,  827,  832 

Worms,  Rene,  20 

Wormser,  I.  Maurice,  397,  427 

Wright,  Frank  Lloyd,  848,  851 

Wright,  Quincy,  338 

Wright  brothers,  474 

Writing  materials,  454,  460 

Written  language,   origins  of,  453-454 

Y 

Young,   Arthur,    79-80 
Young,  Charles  V.  P.,  819 
Young,  Eugene  J.,  582-583 
Young,  Kimbal,  13 
Young,  Owen  D.,  517,  591 

Z 

Zaharoff,  Basil,  346 
Zangwill,  Israel,  200 
Zilboorg,  Gregory,  321 
Zukor,  Adolph,  506